View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Origins,

Too Big to Fail:
Consequences,
and Outlook
Robert L. Hemi

It should be emphasized that th enkws expressed in thrisah-le are the author’s
and not rzecessafily those of the Bank or th Federal Reserve System.

I. INTRODUCTION
The General Accounting Office estimates the cost
of the thrift industry bailout to be around $150 billion.
George Benston, professor at Emory University,
helps his students grasp the immensity of this number
by asking them to imagine how hard it is to become
a millionaire. He then asks them to imagine 150,000
millionaires being made paupers (NW Yoz&Times,
6/10/90). The most important lesson of the thrift
debacle is the need to close insolvent and nearly
insolvent financial institutions promptly [Kane (1989);
Bartholomew (199 l)].
“Too big to fail” refers to the practice followed
by bank regulators of protecting creditors (uninsured
as well as insured depositors and debt holders) of
large banks from loss in the event of failure. In this
article, attention is focused on the resulting transfer
of the decision to close a troubled bank from its
creditors to bank regulators. The paper argues that
the policy of too big to fail created in banking the
same kinds of problems of timely closure that
existed in the thrift industry.
The policy of too big to fail resulted from a
fundamental deficiency in bankruptcy arrangements
for banks. In banking there is no arrangement
analogous to that existing for nonfinancial corporations unable to meet their debts, where the
troubled corporation continues to operate while its
creditors determine whether it is viable. It is usually
undesirable to liquidate a large corporation immediately following a failure to pay its debts. The corporation may be viable if restructured.
Also, an
orderly, rather than an immediate, liquidation can
increase the salvageable value of its assets. For nonfinancial corporations, therefore, Chapter 11 of the
bankruptcy law provides a procedure under which
a bankruptcy judge supervises the operation of a
corporation that cannot pay its debts. Creditors and
existing management then negotiate whether to
liquidate or restructure.
Banks are not subject to bankruptcy law. For
banks, there is no Chapter 11 administered by the
FEDERAL

RESERVE

courts. In its absence, the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation (FDIC) and the Federal Reserve have
come to run an informal Chapter 11 for banks.
Particularly since the early 198Os, deposit insurance
and the discount window have been used to keep
in operation banks that otherwise would have been
closed by the market. l This arrangement has been
useful in that it prevents the abrupt closing of large
banks. In contrast to corporate bankruptcy proceedings, however, the decision to allow a bank to
fail is made by public officials rather than the bank’s
creditors. This arrangement has delayed the resolution of insolvencies.
Section II relates the genesis of the policy of too
big to fail. Section III examines how it encourages
risk taking. Section IV advances a reform that would
provide deposit insurance while leaving the decision
to close a troubled bank to bank creditors. Using this
reform as a benchmark, Section V asks whether the
changes in bank regulation mandated by the Comprehensive Deposit Insurance Reform and Taxpayer
Protection Act of 1991 will ensure that banks are
closed neither too soon nor too late and that banks
take neither too much nor too little risk.
II.

THE DEVELOPMENT OF
Too BIG TO FAIL

A. A Brief History of Restrictions on Bank
Competition
Free entry, the sine qua non of competition, has
never had the constitutional protection in banking
that it has in other industries. The Constitution
r The FDIC has argued that the policy of too big to fail has been
imposed on it by statutory restrictions that require the least costly
method of resolving a bank failure. Specifically, the FDIC can
economically liquidate a small bank, but not a large one. Large
bank failures, consequently,
are handled bv ourchase and
assumption arrangements, which avoid liquidation, but require
the FDIC to iniect enough funds into the sale of closed banks
to restore thei; solvency and to avoid depositor losses. This
situation reflects the absence of a Chapter 11 arrangement for
banks that would allow either the market or regulators to close
banks without forcing immediate liquidations.
BANK

OF RICHMbND

3

prohibits states from interfering with trade across
their boundaries. The commerce clause (Article I,
Sec. 9) states, “No tax or duty shall be laid on
articles exported from any state.” In 1869, in Paul
v. Virginia, the Supreme Court extended the protection of the interstate commerce clause to corporations by ruling that a state could not exclude an
out-of-state corporation from doing business in it.
[See Butler (1982), especially Ch. IV.] Banks are
engaged in commerce in the sense that they are
middlemen. They make money on the difference
between the rates at which they borrow and lend.
It has never been acceptable politically, however, to
extend to banking the constitutional protection of
free entry across state boundaries accorded other
corporations.z
The ability of states to exclude out-of-state banks
allowed state legislatures to organize their intrastate
banking industries into a large number of small banks,
each of which enjoyed some local monopoly power.
Around the turn of the century, when the demand
for banking services grew in rural areas, state
legislatures passed laws prohibiting banks from
meeting this demand through branching. By 1929,
almost all states had laws either prohibiting or restricting intrastate branching. Along with low capital
requirements for establishing a bank, the result was
a banking industry consisting of large numbers of unit
banks. The National Banking Act included ambiguous language that was often interpreted as forbidding interstate branching by national banks. In 1927,
the McFadden Act eliminated any ambiguity by
specifically prohibiting national banks from branching
across state lines. As a result, banks could not diversify geographically their loans and the sources of their
deposits. [For a history of prohibitions on branching,
see Mengle (1990)].
Competition in banking was further restricted
during the Depression. At the time, many blamed
the Depression on excessive competition. It appeared
plausible that individual insolvent firms could be
made solvent by restricting competition. In many
industries, consequently,
government
regulation
attempted to raise prices by restricting competition.
The government divided financial intermediation into
2 Ironically, the European Common Market is using the U.S.
federal model to promote open competition in banking. Starting in 1993, banks will be free to branch across national boundaries. Furthermore, in general, host-country regulators cannot
place any restrictions on the activities of branches of foreign banks
not imposed by the home-country regulator. [See Coleman and
Hart (7/29/9 l).] The combination of guaranteed free entry and
home-country regulation sharply curtails the ability of hostcountry regulators to limit competition in the banking industry.
4

ECONOMIC

REVIEW.

separate industries that could not compete with each
other. Glass-Steagall separated fund-raising for corporations into banking and securities industries.
Insurance companies, savings and loans, and credit
unions were assigned their own regulators and
spheres of influence. The Banking Act of 1933 prohibited the payment of interest on demand deposits,
and Regulation Q limited the interest banks could
pay on time and savings deposits. Later, the 1956
Bank Holding Company Act restricted the ability of
banks to operate nationally through multibank
holding companies. Justice Department
antitrust
guidelines restricted competition by limiting the
ability of banks to acquire other banks.
B. Increased Competition for Banks
Beginning in the late 196Os, innovations in communications and computer technology eroded restrictions on competition in banking by making it
possible for nonbank institutions like money market
mutual funds to offer bank-like services to bank
customers. By lowering the cost of bookkeeping and
disseminating information, this technology lessened
the advantage that banks had possessed formerly in
gathering deposits and monitoring the credit risk of
borrowers. The emergence of new competitors to
banks has reduced the viable size of the traditional
banking industry.
The dramatic increase in competition facing banks
is apparent in the minimal extent to which businesses
relied on domestic banks in 1990 for additional credit.
Baer and Brewer (199 1) report the following statistics.
In 1990, business credit provided by domestic banks,
finance companies, U.S. branches of foreign banks,
offshore sources, and by nonfinancial commercial
paper grew 7.3 percent. Domestic banks provided
only a small fraction, 7 percent, of this growth in
funding. The year 1990 was unusual in that many
banks were attempting to increase their capital-toasset ratios by restricting asset growth. The figures
reflect, however, a longer-run decline in bank
business lending. Over the decade of the 198Os,
banks’ share of short- and medium-term lending to
businesses declined at an annual rate of 1.5 percent.
Furthermore,
as Baer and Brewer point out, the
market is continuing to develop new substitutes for
bank lending like asset-backed commercial paper
(backed by trade receivables) and prime rate funds
(backed by commercial loans). These sources, which
are not included in the above sources, added about
two percentage points in 1990 to growth in shortterm business credit.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

Beginning in the last half of the 196Os, a series of
financial innovations eroded regulatory restrictions
on competition in deposit gathering. High market
rates of interest produced by high rates of inflation
generated incentives to escape the low ceilings on
deposit rates fixed by Reg Q and the prohibition of
payment of interest on demand deposits. In the
1960s the Eurodollar market developed as a way
of allowing large depositors to put their deposits
on banks’ books in Europe, where Reg Q did not
apply. In the 1970s automatic teller machines
allowed banks to evade some geographical restrictions on banking. Money market funds and NOW
accounts allowed depositors with small accounts to
avoid ceilings on deposit rates. Money market funds
permit savers with small amounts of savings to bypass
financial institutions and invest indirectly in commercial paper, which is issued only in large denominations. NOW accounts are checkable deposits that
evade the prohibition of payment of interest on
demand deposits through the technicality of being
labeled a savings account.
Banks have lost their dominant role not only as
collectors of relatively cheap funds from small savers
but also as suppliers of loans to low-risk businesses.
Many large corporations issue commercial paper
directly to financial intermediaries like pension funds,
rather than borrow from banks. By the end of 1989,
money market funds, with more than 20 million accounts, held about $455 billion in assets, much of
it commercial paper. Moreover, the Glass-Steagall
Act, which forbids banks from underwriting corporate
securities, has prevented banks from meeting the
changing needs of their corporate clients by underwriting their debt issues. In addition, a variety of firms
not regulated as banks lend to corporations and consumers. Subsidiaries owned by AT&T,
Ford,
General Electric, and Sears make commercial loans.
Automobile companies finance car loans through
financial subsidiaries. American Express, AT&T, and
Sears finance consumer loans through their credit
card divisions.
Regional banks retain a comparative advantage in
making loans to companies too small to enter the
money market. They are, however, losing their comparative advantage in gathering deposits. In particular,
they rely on deposit insurance as an aid in competing
with money market funds for the relatively large accounts of older depositors.
Securicization, the packaging of illiquid assets like
mortgages and car loans into a security that can be
sold, has eroded the former natural monopoly
FEDERAL

RESERVE

possessed by banks to transform a portfolio of illiquid assets into liquid liabilities. Securitization has
increased the range of financial intermediaries that
can hold the illiquid assets formerly held only by
banks. Pension funds, insurance companies, mutual
funds and individuals now hold assets that formerly
were held chiefly by banks. In the decade of the
197Os, banks held 34.8 percent of the financial assets
of financial intermediaries, which include, in addiinstitutions,
tion to banks, other depository
government-sponsored
enterprises, insurance companies, pension and retirement funds, and money
market and other mutual funds. By 1989, this figure
had fallen to 26.6 percent [U.S. Treasury (1991),
Ch. I, Table 71.
Government policies have also created competitors
for banks. The sharp rise of market rates in 1972
in combination with fixed Reg Q ceilings on time
and savings deposits produced an outflow of funds
from thrifts and banks. In order to maintain the flow
of funds to housing without raising Reg Q ceilings,
the government expanded the financing activities of
the Federal National Mortgage Association, or
“Fannie Mae,” and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Corporation, or “Freddie Mac.” Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac purchase mortgages and then either
hold them for their own account or package them
so they can be held by institutional investors. These
federally sponsored credit agencies compete with
banks and thrifts for the financing and warehousing
of mortgages.
Tax laws have placed banks at a disadvantage in
competing for the long-term savings of individuals.
For example, certain laws make some portion of an
employee’s wages tax-exempt if placed in a long-term
savings plan (such as a 401-K plan that allows the
employee to defer taxes on interest income from investments). These laws encourage corporations and
state and local governments to replace banks as
deposit gatherers. Corporations and state and local
governments then negotiate directly with pension and
thrift funds. Because these funds typically are large
enough to evaluate the risk of their assets, they can
hold commercial paper and bonds issued by corporations. This financial intermediation
completely
bypasses banks.
C. The Extension of Deposit Insurance
Had the market forces described above been left
unopposed, they would have forced a contraction of
the banking industry in the 1980s. Contraction was
postponed through the extension of deposit insurance
BANK

OF RICHMOND

5

coverage in the form of the policy of too big to fail.
This extension provided a subsidy to banks by lowering their costs of funding relative to the costs they
would have incurred if some holders of their liabilities
had not been protected from loss. Too big to fail
arose from pressures created by the lack of satisfactory institutional arrangements for closing banks
rather than from a conscious decision on the part of
policymakers.
The FDIC was created in 1933 to protect depositors holding small accounts. It was not created
to keep insolvent banks in operation. That task was
assigned to the Reconstruction Fiance Corporation.
[See Todd (1988), App. C, and Todd (1991).] The
emergence of too big to fail is recounted in Bailout
by Irvine Sprague, a former director of the FDIC.
Sprague recounts the transformation of the FDIC
from an agency charged with covering losses of insured depositors of already failed banks into a modern
day Reconstruction Finance Corporation that pmwzfi
failures by protecting all creditors of large banks from
loss.3
Beginnings
From 1950 until 1982, Section 13(c)
of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act allowed the
FDIC to prevent a bank from failing if the bank were
judged “essential to provide adequate banking service in its community.” Sprague points out that
legislative history is an unclear guide to the intended use of the “essentiality” clause, but that “this
authority was not intended for widespread use”
[Sprague (1986), p. 28). Probably, it was included
to prevent the failure of banks in rural areas served
by a single bank. In any event, as Sprague points
out, the language effectively gave the FDIC complete discretion because “the courts have always
upheld an agency’s discretionary authority. . . . No
challenge has been successful. So there you have it.
A bank can be bailed out if two of three FDIC board
members determine it should be” (Sprague, p. 28).
Since the passage of the Garn-St. Germain Act in
1982, the FDIC has had the additional authority to
prevent failures by arranging purchase and assumption transactions if it determines that liquidation of
the bank is a costlier alternative.
3 Even when the too big to fail doctrine is applied, banks can
fail in that their charters are revoked and their stockholders lose
their investments. Too big to fail means that the FDIC and the
Federal Reserve prevent a lack of funding from closing large,
troubled banks while the FDIC arranges a takeover by another
bank (a purchase and assumption transaction). The FDIC subsidizes the takeover so that bank depositors (uninsured as well
as insured) do not incur any losses.
6

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

In 1971, Unity Bank in Boston became the first
bank bailed out under the essentiality doctrine. One
of the FDIC directors opposed the bailout on the
grounds “that bailouts were bad public policy and
doing the first one would lead to many more, possibly
an uncontrollable flood” (Sprague, p. 46). That director was persuaded not to vote while the other two
directors, Sprague and Wille, voted to keep Unity
afloat, even though it was mismanaged. Unity was
saved because of a fear that the failure of a bank
considered to be a black institution would set off
riots in black neighborhoods. Sprague (p. 48) notes,
“[MJy vote to make the ‘essentiality’ finding and
thus save the little bank was probably foreordained,
an inevitable legacy of [the riots in] Watts.” At the
time, Sprague reports he believed Unity could not
set a precedent because it was “a unique case, one
of a kind” (Sprague, p. 49). In fact, shortly thereafter, the FDIC bailed out Bank of the Commonwealth, a large, mismanaged bank in Detroit for the
same reason.
In retrospect, Sprague identifies the bailout of
Unity as the first step in establishing too big to fail
as public policy. “[Tjhe important precedent was,
of course, the irreversible turn we had taken with
Unity, away from our historic narrow role of acting
only after the bank had failed. . . . Now we were
in the bailout business, how deeply no one could then
tell” (Sprague, p. 49). Sprague then goes on to
describe how over time too big to fail became
embedded in banking regulation through the precedent of saving one troubled bank at a time, rather
than as a result of a conscious decision. By Chapter
15 of Bailout, Sprague says: “Of the fifty largest bank
the top
failures in history, forty-six-including
twenty-were
handled either through a pure bailout
or an FDIC-assisted transaction where no depositor,
insured or uninsured, lost a penny. In effect, the
forty-six enjoyed 100 percent insurance protection.
The four lonely exceptions . . . were the result of
unusual circumstances” (Sprague, p. 242).4
Continental
Illinois
Because of its size, the
bailout of Continental Illinois exemplified most clearly
the transformation of the FDIC into a modern
Reconstruction
Finance Corporation.
Although
only 10 percent of Continental’s deposits were insured, the FDIC protected all of its depositors. [The
4 The major “lonely exception” was.
liquidated because the FDIC believed
and possibly fraudulent loan practices
sive litigation as to render impossible
tion transaction.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

Penn Square, which was
that the bank’s negligent
might create such extena purchase and assump-

following draws on Sprague (1986), Part 4. See also
Thomson and Todd (1990).] In the late 1970s and
early 198Os, Continental grew rapidly by taking
on high-risk loans. In particular, Continental purchased $1 billion in oil and gas loans from Penn
Square, collateralized by drilling rigs and other assets
made worthless when the oil drilling business collapsed. Continental’s downfall began with the bankruptcy of Penn Square Bank in Oklahoma City in
July 1982. On May 9, 1984, foreign depositors began
to withdraw deposits from Continental. Initially, the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago assisted it with discount window loans, which eventually totaled $7.6
billion.
Because no buyers could be found for Continental, the FDIC decided to keep it in operation through
“open bank assistance.” It purchased $1 billion in
preferred stock from Continental’s holding company,
which lent the funds to Continental. This arrangement amounted to capital forbearance in that Continental was allowed to remain in operation with an
amount of private capital below regulatory standards.
(It also protected the creditors of the holding company, as well as the bank.)
Recent Developments
Two recent bank failures
illustrate the blanket coverage extended to uninsured
depositors under the policy of too big to fail. On
August
10, 1990, the Comptroller
of the
Currency closed National Bank of Washington and
named the FDIC as receiver. Because of the lapse
of time between the dissemination of information
about the bank’s problems and the closing of the
bank, depositors at the Nassau branch had begun to
withdraw funds beginning early in 1990. Discount
window lending by the Fed might have permitted
a sizable portion of these deposit withdrawals.
The foreign deposits remaining when the bank was
seized, although not formally insured by the FDIC,
were protected. According to newspaper accounts,
the FDIC protected Washington National’s foreign
deposits in order to provide assurance to foreign
depositors at money-center banks that their deposits
were protected (American Banker, 9/‘27/90). The
policy of too big to fail has effectively extended insurance to deposits in banks’ overseas branches.5
On January 6, 199 1, the FDIC took control of the
Bank of New England Corporation’s banks-Bank
of New England, Connecticut Bank and Trust, and
Maine National Bank. The FDIC’s initial estimate
of the loss was $2.3 billion (Financial Times, l/8/91).
5 By the end of 1990, these deposits totaled about $300 billion
and amounted to 5 1 percent of the deposits of the nine largest
U.S. banks.
FEDERAL

RESERVE

Newspaper commentary accompanying the rescue
makes clear how broad the criteria have become for
bailing out a bank’s uninsured creditors (Wail Street
JoumaL, l/7/91):
The arrangement will protect from loss all depositors, even
those with accounts exceeding the $100,000 insurance
ceiling. Mr. Seidman made it clear in an interview that the
urgency of the rescue transcended the bank’s difficulties.
“We’re looking at an eroding economy, particularly in New
England,” he said. . . . Over the weekend, government
officials stressed the need to improve credit conditions in
New England to slow economic deterioration there.

At present, “too big to fail” appears to be a
misnomer as even small banks are usually not allowed
to fail with a loss to uninsured depositors. As William
Seidman, former chairman of the FDIC, noted
(Wad Street Jbumai,

6/S/9 1):

Some people mistakenly believe that small-bank failures
usually are resolved through a payout of insured depositsa liquidation, where uninsured depositors and creditors
suffer some loss. The reality is that, currently, about nine
out of ten small-bank failures are resolved through “purchase
and assumption” transactions. In a P&4 [purchase and
assumption transaction], all the deposits (including those
over the $100,000 insurance limit) generally are assumed
by a healthy bank. Of the 169 banks that failed in 1990,
only 20 were resolved through a payout of insured deposits.
The rest were resolved through P&As.

While deposit insurance expanded principally
through growth of the policy of too big to fail, explicit increases in the size of covered deposits and
regulatory actions also expanded its coverage.
Regulators used increases in coverage per account
to lower the cost of funds and to increase their
availability to banks and thrifts when increases in
market rates above Reg Q prompted disintermediation. Increases in coverage per account coincided
with peaks in market rates: 1966, 1969, 1974, and
1980. FDIC-insured deposits as a fraction of total
deposits increased from about 55 percent in 1965
to more than 70 percent in the 1980s [U.S. Treasury
(1991), Conclusions and Recommendations, Figures
6 and 71.
During the 198Os, the FDIC also increased the
kinds of bank liabilities protected from loss. It extended insurance to the deposits of pension plans by
“passing through” the $100,000 insurance limit to.
the individual participants of the plans. It insured
brokered deposits. 6 The FDIC also insured private
6 In 1984, the FDIC and FSLIC adopted regulations to deny
deposit insurance to certificates of deposit purchased from a
broker. The regulations, however, were overturned by a federal
court, and Congress was unwilling to pass legislation allowing
the regulatory agencies to prohibit brokered certificates of
deposit.
BANK

OF RICHMOND

7

parties to swap
receivership.

transactions

with

banks

in

The current low rate of return to banking is consistent with the argument that the policy of too big
to fail has kept the banking industry from contracting in response to increased competition. In the
197Os, the return on assets for insured commercial
banks was .77 percent. From 1985 to 1989, this
figure fell to .55 percent [U.S. Treasury (1991),
Ch. I, Table 61. The decline in the value of bank
stocks relative to the S&P 500, which began in the
late 1970s and became more pronounced beginning
in 1986, reveals investor skepticism about the future
profitability of the banking industry given its current
size. Even with the rally in bank stocks in early 199 1,
the P/E ratio of money-center and large regional
banks is only half that of firms in the S&P 500
(American Banker, 311819 1).
D. Pressures to Postpone Closing
Insolvent Banks
Regulators incur a variety of pressures to postpone
closing a troubled bank. Closing a bank produces
active disapproval from those affected adversely. In
contrast, beneficiaries are unaware of the costs indirectly imposed on them by the relaxation of market
discipline involved in keeping a troubled bank afloat.
Beneficiaries include consumers who benefit from
competition and potential entrants in the banking
industry.
The ability of regulatory agencies to keep open a
troubled bank inevitably invites political pressures.
Congressmen pass on constituent discontent over the
job losses and personal disruptions that accompany
the closing of a bank. The case of the Keating Five
is instructive. Beginning in 1987, five senators apparently intervened with the Federal Home Loan
Bank Board in order to keep Lincoln Savings and
Loan in operation. The Senate Ethics Committee
found the intervention itself appropriate. The only
issue was whether it was appropriate to accept money
from Mr. Keating while intervening on his behalf with
federal regulators. In summarizing the report of the
Ethics Committee, Congmsional &art&y [Cranford
(1991), p. 5181 noted:
Significantly, the committee found nothing intrinsically
wrong with the intervention by these five senators with
federal regulators in 1987 in behalf of Charles H. Keating.
. . . Each had ample information to justify contacting
regulators about the fairness of the regulatory treatment
Lincoln was receiving. The case has hung on the nexus
between the five senators’ intervention and the enormous
political contributions that they collected from Keating.
8

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

Congresional

f$wztier& [Cranford (199 l), p. 5 191
also reports Sen. DeConcini’s reply to the report of
the Ethics Committee:
As the committee
I had strong reason
was being treated
further had reason
unfairly at stake.

effectively acknowledges, in early 1987
to believe that a major Arizona company
unfairly by the federal government. I
to believe that 2,000 Arizona jobs were

Pressures on regulators to keep troubled banks
afloat do not have to be political. Regulators may
temporize because they are genuinely uncertain
whether a bank is insolvent. It is often difficult to
measure the market value of a bank’s assets and, consequently, the market value of its capital. Regulators
want to be fair, and they want to be perceived as
fair in the media. Given the ambiguity of measures
of capital, they naturally tend to close a bank only
when it is clearly insolvent. 7 Their desire for fairness
presents them with another dilemma over troubled
banks: given a chance, some of these banks will
recover. If regulators were to close a bank that is
not obviously insolvent, they would inevitably be
criticized for the “premature and unnecessary” closure
of a bank that “if given a chance, would make it.”
They would receive especially heated criticism from
small borrowers with special, ongoing relationships
with the troubled bank.8
In the case of the Bank of New England, the
Comptroller of the Currency only closed the bank
when depositors actually began to run it. In an
American Banker (l/9/9 1) article, Comptroller Clarke
and FDIC Chairman Seidman were reported as
having said that “they did not act until last weekend
because only then was it certain that the Bank of New
England Corp. had no chance to survive.” In the same
article, Karen Shaw, president of the Institute for
Strategy Development, noted: ‘There was the hope,
even if it was an errant hope, that the bank would
survive. It had made it through several crises.”
Rather than liquidate a large bank for failure to
meet a capital standard, regulators are more likely
7 “Regulators, attuned to the necessities of congressional relations, and no more willing than other human beings to put other
people out of work, will forbear until the death rattle is clearly
audible” [Wallison (1991), p. 121.
8 Such criticism is unlikely to acknowledge the moral hazard
problems of allowing a troubled bank to remain open. “History
and what little we know of human nature suggest that as weak
bank managements struggle to survive they will reach for more
risky investments to pay for their more costly funds, obscure
from examiners the dangerous condition of their enterprise,
appeal to their elected representatives as needy constituents and
surrender only when all hope is gone” [Wallison (1991), p. 12):

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

’

to try to find a merger partner for the bank while
allowing it to remain in business. Such partners,
however, are hard to find. Possible merger partners
have an incentive to wait until the condition of a
troubled bank deteriorates to the point where it is
actually taken over by the FDIC. They can then
negotiate with the FDIC. In this way, banks not only
avoid a possible costly court fight with the troubled
bank’s stockholders, but also open up the possibility that the FDIC will add incentives to make the
acquisition more attractive.
An additional incentive to procrastination in closing a bank is the multiplicity of regulators. Understandably, each regulator would like for the other
regulator to receive any criticism for closing a bank.
For example, the Comptroller of the Currency has
the responsibility for declaring national banks insolvent. The Comptroller, however, does not use its
own resources to keep a troubled bank afloat. It has
an incentive, therefore, to wait and hope that the Fed
will effectively close the bank by pulling its discount
window loan or that the FDIC will close the bank
by refusing to grant a waiver for the bank to attract
insured brokered deposits. Also, state regulators may
have been reluctant to revoke the charters of insolvent state-chartered banks. Closing down a bank that
they examine may appear as an admission of failure.
III. THEPROBLEMSWITH

Too BIG TO FAIL
Restrictions on the ability of market forces to close
banks embodied in the policy of too big to fail started
to cause problems when banks began to experience
significant external competition in the 1970s and
1980s. The extension of deposit insurance in the
form of the policy of too big to fail provided a subsidy to banks that kept the banking industry from
contracting. It also encouraged risk taking. Kept from
shrinking by an extension of the implicit subsidies
of deposit insurance, banks responded to the loss of
low-risk corporate customers by turning to riskier
investments. Many banks also increased the subsidy
from deposit insurance by holding riskier asset portfolios without increasing their capital.
A. FDIC Insurance as a Subsidy to Risk
Taking
This section first explains why governmentsponsored insurance subsidizes risk taking by failing to price- risk. The remainder of the section
documents the increase in the riskiness of the banking system since the 1960s. Banks have acquired
FEDERAL

RESERVE

increasingly risky asset portfolios, with no increase
over this period in capital ratios.
Insurance offered by a private company pools
individual risks by establishing a fund into which
premiums are paid and from which losses are met.
The insurance company is the residual claimant on
the fund. It makes money when the fund grows and
loses money when it declines. For this reason, the
insurance company places restrictions
on its
policyholders that limit the risks they take. Private
insurance cannot subsidize risk taking. It must price
risk accurately or go out of business.
Although the FDIC uses the term “insurance fund,”
its fund is fundamentally different from the kind of
fund maintained by a private insurance company.
With the FDIC fund, there are no residual claimants
whose own money is at stake. The Treasury keeps
a tally on the cumulative difference between incoming FDIC deposit premia and outgoing FDIC expenditures and includes interest on the positive balance.
This tally is the FDIC “insurance fund.” The FDIC
fund can be depleted, but it cannot become insolvent. If the current receipts from the premia paid by
banks are insufficient to cover current FDIC expenditures, then FDIC deposit insurance commits the
taxpayer to pay the difference. It is this commitment
that allows deposit insurance to be used to subsidize
risk taking.
In contrast to a private insurance arrangement that
limits risk taking, FDIC insurance encourages risk
taking. The subsidy banks receive from the guarantee
of their deposits by the government increases with
the riskiness of their asset portfolio and decreases
with the amount of capital they hold. FDIC deposit
insurance does not lower the cost of funds appreciably
for a conservatively managed, highly capitalized bank,
but it does for a risk-taking, poorly capitalized bank.
Both kinds of banks pay the same flat rate on their
insured deposits.9
The encouragement given by deposit insurance to
risk taking was kept in check as long as restrictions
9 In principle, risk-based capital guidelines can offset the incentives deposit insurance creates for risk taking. In practice,
however, such guidelines are hard to implement. They assign
risk on the basis of broad categories, which do not differentiate
between riskiness of assets within categories. Also, it is often
hard to defend the relative assessment oj risk across categories.
For examole. the 1988 Basle Aareements on risk-based capital
guidelines’ stipulate that mortgaie-backed
securities, which are
often subject to significant risk from interest rate fluctuations,
require only one-fifth the capital of a commercial loan. The most
important drawback to risk-based capital guidelines is their failure
to reward risk reduction through asset diversification.
BANK

OF RICHMOND

9

on competition gave banks a high franchise value.
A high franchise value acts like a large amount of
capital. It limits risk taking because stockholders bear
significant losses if the bank fails. Increased competition in banking, however, has eroded the franchise
value of banks, especially since the 1970s [Keeley
(1990)].
B. Evidence of Increased Risk in the
Banking System
Deposit insurance has allowed the banking industry
to pursue riskier investment strategies in the 1980s
without increasing its capital. In the early 196Os,
insured commercial banks had a ratio of capital to
total assets of about 8 percent.iO In the 198Os, this
ratio fell to about 6 percent [U.S. Department of
Commerce (1965), Table 607, and U.S. Department
of Commerce (1985), Table 8261. The 6 percent
aggregate figure conceals significant variation among
banks. At year-end 1989, the largest 25 banks had
a ratio of capital to assets of only 4.8 percent [U.S.
Treasury (199 l), Ch. II, Table 21. Barth, Brumbaugh
and Litan (1990, Table 3) report that, as of June
1990, 183 banks with assets of $11.2 billion were
operating with capital-to-assets ratios of less than 3
percent. An additional 67 banks with combined assets
of $80 billion had capital-to-assets ratios between
3 and 3.5 percent.
There is also evidence that, for troubled banks,
capital based on the book value of assets overstates
capital based on market values. Using cross section
data to study the relationship between book and
market values, Mengle (1991, p. 2 1) finds that,
among banks that failed, capital based on book values
significantly overstated capital based on market
values. Mengle (1991, p. 19) also notes:
Failures are far more common than book value insolvency
numbers would suggest; in any given year, the number of
failures far outstrips the number of book value insolvencies
in either the current or the previous year. . . . only 6
percent of the banks that failed in 1985 had reported
themselves to be book value insolvent in 1985.

Moreover, the stock market values many banks
less highly than the book value of their capital.
Barth, Brumbaugh, and Litan (199 1, Table 6) show
that for 20 of the 25 largest U.S. banks, the market
value of their equity is less than the book value.
While the ratio of book capital to assets has
changed very little for the banking system over the
lo At the time, this capital ratio was adequate because restrictions on competition made banking relatively safe. The absence
of any change in the bank prime rate from August 1960 through
December 1965 used to be cited as evidence of the cartelization of banking.
10

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

last two decades, banks’ asset portfolios have become
riskier. The loss of blue chip corporate customers
to the commercial paper market left remaining bank
loan portfolios riskier. Particularly
since the
mid-1980s bank lending has been concentrated in
high-risk categories. From 1985 through 1990, 65
percent of the increase in bank loans was in real
estate. Of the increase in real estate lending during
this period, 43.5 percent was in commercial real
estate [Board of Governors (March 1991), Table
1.25, “Assets and Liabilities of Commercial Banks”
and Board of Governors (December 1991), Table
1.54, “Mortgage Debt Outstanding”]. Banks purchased large amounts of mortgage-backed securities,
which present considerable interest rate risk, and
became heavily involved in off-balance sheet activities
such as loan commitments and standby letters of
credit, In dollar terms, these latter activities grew
from 58 percent of assets in 1982’to 116 percent
in 1989 [U.S. Treasury (1991), Ch. I, p. 271.
The increase in the riskiness of bank asset portfolios could not have occurred without the subsidy
to risk taking provided by deposit insurance. Consider the contrasting management of the banks
described in the following quotations:
Long dependent on a regional economy that rises and falls
with the auto industry’s swings, banks in the region [Midwest] rarely stray far from the basics of opening checking
accounts, backing small businesses and managing trust funds.
Economic uncertainty has generally kept them from seeking
quick gains through risky loans to commercial developers,
junk bond artists or Third World nations (Wu~Stmt.hnza~,
4/11/91).
Each week, Walter Connolly [head of the Bank of New
England Corp.] would survey the numbers from his banking
empire, 450 branches that stretched from the top to the
bottom of New England. If the numbers didn’t look rightif a bank had lost even a bit of market share-Connolly
would get the bank’s president on the phone and demand
to know what had happened. No matter what he was told,
he had the same answer: “Grow it, grow it.” “The whole
culture was one of growth,” said Donald J. Kauth. . . .
“Size was success to Walter,” said one colleague. “He
wanted to retire as the chairman of the biggest bank in
Boston” (Washington Post, 119191).

Deposit
not the
deposit
finance
growth
assets.

insurance subsidizes the risk-taking bank,
conservatively managed bank. In particular,
insurance makes it possible for a bank to
rapid growth with cheap deposits even if that
is achieved by acquiring low quality and risky

C. Systemic Risk
The policy of too big to fail is often defended as
a response to inherent instability in the banking
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

-.

system. This section makes the opposite argument,
namely, that deposit insurance and the policy of too
big to fail have created instability in the banking
system.
Because too big to fail entails closing banks without
imposing losses on depositors, there is an ongoing
possibility that the FDIC will have to ask Congress
for funds to close insolvent banks.” The regressive
character of the wealth transfers involved in bailing
out the creditors of large banks, however, makes it
difficult for Congress to appropriate funds for the
FDIC. The ongoing possibility of a need for additional funding to operate the FDIC, combined with
the uncertainties
surrounding the congressional
appropriations
process, creates a potential for
systemic instability. In a situation where many banks
are poorly capitalized, a run on a large bank at a time
when the deposit insurance fund is depleted could
cause bank runs to spread uncontrollably. Under
current
institutional
arrangements,
therefore,
regulators must maintain control over the timing of
the closing of insolvent banks. This control can
only be achieved by protecting all creditors of banks
(including uninsured depositors) from loss. Current
institutional arrangements make too big to fail an
imperative.
Too big to fail, however, is part of a vicious
circle. Protecting all creditors from loss limits incentives for creditors to monitor the riskiness of bank
asset portfolios. Banks can then hold only minimal
amounts of capital while making risky investments
without increasing the rate they pay on deposits.
This behavior, however, creates precisely the
weakness in the banking system that makes too big
to fail appear to be an imperative. Ironically, deposit
insurance has produced the systemic instability it was
supposed to prevent.

ii At present, the FDIC possesses only a limited ability to
generate additional revenue through increases in the premium
it levies on deposits. Additional premium increases will reduce
the ability of banks to compete with other financial intermediaries. Banks are already subject to the special tax imposed
by noninterest-bearing reserve requirements. In the past, required
reserves and FDIC deposit premia have collected similar
amounts of revenue. For example, in December
1990,
depository institutions held $57.5 billion in required reserves,
and the three-month Treasury bill rate was 6.8 percent. At an
annual rate, the reserve requirement tax was collecting $3.9
billion in revenue (068 x $57.5). In 1989, FDIC assessment
income came to $3.5 billion.
FEDERAL

RESERVE

IV. THEWORLDWITHOUT
Too BIGTO FAIL
A. The New Legislation
The policy of too big to fail resulted in part from
a lack of satisfactory institutional arrangements for
closing insolvent banks in a timely way. The 1991
Deposit Insurance Reform Act addresses the problem of timely closure by requiring regulators to close
a bank when its capital falls below a specified level.
[The Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee
(1988) has been the primary proponent of this
approach.]
The new act requires bank regulators to establish
five capital categories: well capitalized, adequately
capitalized, undercapitalized,
significantly undercapitalized, and critically undercapitalized. It requires
regulators to classify as critically undercapitalized any
bank with a capital-to-assets ratio of 2 percent or less.
Regulators must close such a bank within 90 days.
Furthermore, the act legislates a list of strictures
that bank regulators must impose on banks in the
undercapitalized and significantly undercapitalized
categories.
The mandatory early intervention written into the
new law probably derived from the political difficulty in introducing market discipline by explicitly
limiting deposit insurance.r2 The law intends that
regulators close troubled banks before insured
deposits are put at risk. Consequently, the FDIC
would not have to absorb a loss when a bank fails.
It follows that the new law should remove the former
subsidy to risk taking created by deposit insurance.
Its intent is to make deposit insurance superfluous
without explicitly limiting or repealing it.
Will the Deposit Insurance Reform Act end the
policy of too big to fail through the prompt closing
of troubled banks? Will banks begin to assume an
optimal amount of risk? Answering these questions
requires a benchmark against which the legislation
can be judged. This benchmark is taken to be a banking system in which market discipline controls both
the closure decision and the riskiness of bank asset
portfolios. How would such a system work?
B. Market Closure
Such a system could apply the arrangements for
corporate bankruptcy to the banking industry. Under
iz Direct attempts to limit deposit insurance, such as reducing
the $100.000 deoosit limit. limitine the number of allowable
accounts per hou’sehold, and provid%g for a depositor deductible, proved too controversial to include in the new law.
BANK

OF RICHMOND

11

corporate bankruptcy law, the timing of the closure
decision of troubled firms is approximately right.i3
Although much of corporate bankruptcy law would
not be applicable, it would be possible to recreate
its major features for banks. First, bankruptcy law
provides a market mechanism for placing corporations in receivership. That is, the decision to place
a corporation in receivership is made by a firm’s
creditors or management rather than by public
officials. Second, corporations in receivership are not
allowed to fail catastrophically. Chapter 11 allows a
bankrupt corporation to continue in operation while
it is either reorganized or liquidated in an orderly
fashion. Third, bankruptcy law provides a rule for
apportioning losses among a firm’s creditors. Fourth,
although insolvent corporations are not liquidated
abruptly, they are not kept in operation with government money. The individuals involved have the
necessary incentives to close institutions that are not
viable.
These features of corporate bankruptcy law could
be approximated for banks.14 First, the policy of too
big to fail could be eliminated by rescinding the ability
of any government agency to offer guarantees to bank
creditors, including depositors. Bank creditors then
would have their own money at risk in a bank failure.
Analogous to corporate bankruptcy, bankruptcy of
a bank would be triggered by failure to honor an
obligation for payment. is Second, a petition for
bankruptcy would put a bank into the kind of
receivership provided for, by Chapter 11 in corporate
bankruptcy. Third, when a bank went into receivership its depositors would incur an immediate loss
(haircut) on the amount of their deposits at the close
of the day preceding the bankruptcy decision.16
Regulators would set the size of the loss so that the
failed bank would again possess positive net worth.
Apart from the haircut, depositors would have complete access to their funds, unlike creditors in a corporate bankruptcy. Fourth, if necessary, banks in
receivership could obtain new funds from debtor-inpossession financing, that is, financing in which new
lenders receive priority in repayment over existing
holders of subordinated debt.
ia Dotsey and Kuprianov (1990) discuss relevant issues in the
context of the problems with the S&L industry in the 1980s.
I4 A detailed proposal is available from the author.
1s Although creditors could petition a bankruptcy court to close
a bank that did not honor its debts, most petitions for bankruptcy
would probably be voluntary petitions by bank management
made to stop an incipient run.
I6 The American Banker’s Association (1990) and Boyd and
Rolnick (1988) have advocated depositor haircuts.
12

ECONOMIC

REVIEW.

C. A Proposal to Restructure
Deposit Insurance
The provision of a Chapter 11 arrangement for
banks, which would ensure that banks never failed
abruptly, would protect the payments system. The
issue remains, however, of whether allowing bank
depositors to close a bank through a run could
precipitate
a system-wide
run. In particular,
economists differ over whether the ability of the
Federal Reserve to undertake large-scale open market
purchases of securities to supply reserves to the banking system would be sufficient to prevent a general
run of the banking system.17 This issue is likely to
remain contentious. A system of deposit insurance,
however, could be designed that would keep the
closure decision in the hands of bank creditors while
still protecting against bank panics. Deposit insurance, which currently is an entitlement granted
whenever a bank creates a deposit, could be fixed
in quantity and priced by the market.
Specifically, the Treasury would auction deposit
insurance certificates to banks, which would sell them
to depositors desiring to insure their deposits. The
amount of these certificates, however, would be kept
less than the total deposits in the banking system.
In addition, individual banks would be able to offer
insurance certificates only up to a fraction of their
total deposits. In this way, all banks would have some
depositors genuinely at risk in the event of a failure.‘*
An advantage of this proposal is that it is agnostic
on the issue of whether instability is an inherent
feature of banking. On the one hand, if policymakers
believe that the banking system is prone to instability,
they can maintain permanently a relatively high ratio
of deposit insurance certificates relative to the total
deposits of the banking system. On the other hand,
I7 Anna Schwartz argues that it would. She observes (personal
communication to the author): “There were runs before the
public could confidently count on a lender of last resort to nip
them in the bud. I keep asking why Britain had its last run on
banks in 1866, but the U.S. continued to experience them
until 1933. In the first case, the lender of last resort had learned
what to do to prevent a run, and the public knew it.” Diamond
and Dybvig (1983), in contrast, construct a model in which in
principle it is possible to have bank runs that would not be
offset by open market purchases.
I* For example, assume a depositor has $20,000 in deposits at
the time his bank enters bankruptcy court and $15,000 in deposit
insurance certificates. Assume also that depositors receive a haircut of 5 percent. The depositor, then, receives a haircut of 5
percent on the $5,000 of deposits not covered by his certificates.
When a bank is placed into bankruptcy and its depositors
incur haircuts, the bank submits the deposit insurance certificates
registered with it to the Treasury. The Treasury becomes a
claimant on the failed bank for an amount equal to the percentage haircut applied to the bank’s certificates.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

they may believe that the best way to ensure a stable
banking system is through market discipline that gives
individual banks an incentive to hold high levels of
capital and limit risk taking. They could then gradually eliminate the certificates.

V. BANKCLOSURE
ANDRISKTAKING
WITH THENEWLEGISLATION
Under the new law, how well will regulators
approximate the results that would be achieved by
competitive market forces? Will troubled banks
be closed neither prematurely nor tardily? Will banks
take the right amount of risk, neither too much nor
too little?
A. Optimal Closure
The new law continues to rely heavily on the
discretion of government regulators. Regulators still
decide when to write down the book value of a bank’s
assets and, as a consequence, when to lower the
credit category into which a bank falls. Fear of triggering a run could still make regulators reluctant to
downgrade a large banks capital category.
Alternatively, the new law could create political
pressure to close troubled banks prematurely. It gives
regulators a whole arsenal of weapons for limiting risk
and restricting the activities of troubled banks. If a
bank does fail with a significant loss to the FDIC,
bank regulators could easily be accused of negligent
supervision.19 In order to avoid the criticism of
negligence, regulators might write down the book
value of a bank’s assets at any sign of trouble. In the
spirit of the new law, they might take strong action
against any bank whose capital falls below even the
most conservative capital categories.
B. Optimal Risk Taking
Even if banks are closed promptly when the book
value of their capital falls below 2 percent, losses
to the deposit insurance fund may remain large.
Limiting losses to the insurance fund will also require
limiting the riskiness of bank asset portfolios. The
new legislation leaves uncertain whether limiting bank
risk wilI occur through imposition of market discipline
or through regulator intervention.
I9 Pratt’s Lener (December 20, 1991) commented: “When
Senate Banking Committee Chairman Riegle prematurely (and
unjustly) dispatched Comptroller Clarke to regulatory boot hill,
he delivered a powerful message of his own: Mess up and I’ll
have your head. And now that Congress has legislatively signed
what it perceives to be a $9.5 billion check for the FDIC and
RTC, its proclivity for the Riegle-style witch hunt will increase.”
FEDERAL

RESERVE

Consider, in this regard, the failure on August 10,
1990, of National Bank of Washington (discussed
earlier). National Bank of Washington was the second bank closed under the powers granted by the
Financial Institution Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act of 1989. These powers allow regulators
to seize a bank before it becomes insolvent. On
March 3 1, 1990, the bank had a capital-to-assets ratio
of 5 percent (Consolidated Reports of Condition and
Income). When seized four months later, it still had
a capital-to-assets ratio of 1.4 percent. Measured by
the book value of its assets, it was solvent. When
National Bank of Washington was closed and sold
to Riggs National Bank, however, the FDIC had to
retain $539 million in its assets, one-third of the
bank’s $1.6 billion in assets. The FDIC’s initial
estimate of its loss was $500 million (American Banker,
9/27/90). National Bank of Washington was in fact
deeply insolvent when it was closed.
The new law requires regulators to close within
90 days a bank with a capital-to-assets ratio of 2
percent or less. The experience with National Bank
of Washington, which was closed when it had a book
value capital ratio of 1.4 percent, suggests that the
new law will not necessarily prevent failures that
impose heavy losses on the FDIC.
A study by Alton Gilbert (1992, Table 4) of 1,000
banks that failed since 1985 puts the average loss
ratio at 27 percent (the loss to the FDIC divided by
the book value of the failed bank’s assets). Under
the system of bank regulation that existed prior to
the Deposit Insurance Reform Act, the standard practice was for regulators to close banks when their book
capital-to-assets ratio reached 0 percent. With the
passage of the new act, they will close banks when
this ratio reaches 2 percent. Given the magnitude
of the historic loss ratio, 27 percent, the change from
0 to 2 percent should not be expected to have a
significant effect in reducing FDIC losses.
Two other changes in the regulatory regime could,
however, keep FDIC losses small in the future. First,
the public could come to believe that federal
regulators will allow large banks to fail with losses
to uninsured depositors. Uninsured depositors would
then begin to exert a discipline on bank risk taking
by demanding a return on their deposits commensurate with the riskiness of banks’ portfolios. Market
discipline would force banks to price risk correctly
by imposing higher interest rates on the uninsured
deposits of banks with risky asset portfolios. Correct pricing by banks would limit the riskiness of their
asset portfolios.
BANK

OF RICHMOND

13

Second, bank regulators might be drawn heavily
into limiting bank risk. Because of the difficulties in
evaluating risk, this involvement would probably take
the form of relatively crude quantitative limits on
different kinds of investments. Attempts by regulators
to restrict the riskiness of bank asset portfolios,
however, could prevent banks from allocating capital
efficiently by balancing risk and return. Reducing the
riskiness of bank assets is not an end in itself. After
all, banks exist because of the need to make risky
loans. They are financial intermediaries that specialize
in pricing risk and monitoring risky lending. If
regulators are drawn into this second alternative, they
could greatly harm the banking industry’s ability to
extend credit efficiently.
VI.

CONCLUDINGCOMMENT

The new legislation may remove most of the subsidy offered by deposit insurance. Increases in the
deposit insurance premium levied by the FDIC could
even turn deposit insurance into a net tax. If implicit

subsidies in deposit insurance kept banking from contracting in the 198Os, then the new legislation, by
removing these subsidies, will precipitate a contraction of banking. The contraction may be particularly severe among large banks that lost corporate
customers to the commercial paper market in the
1980s. The difficulties in achieving optimal closure
and risk taking in banking discussed above are
likely to be exacerbated by the need for the banking industry to contract. This contraction could be
impeded by the tendency of failed banks to be
merged rather than closed and by legal restraints that
prevent banks from diversifying freely into other
financial and commercial activities.
Banking is still different from other industries.
There is no active.market for corporate control in
which raiders can acquire a bank and shrink it.
There is no market-driven bankruptcy procedure.
Consequently,
there is no market mechanism to
assure efficient shrinkage of the banking industry.
It is important that this problem be understood and
publicly debated.

REFERENCES
American Banker. “Banks Halt Their Binge in Mortgage

Federal

Securi-

ties.” May 8, 1990, p. 1.
“FDIC Vetoed Plan to Curb Its Coverage in
DC Failure.” September 27, 1990, p. 1.
. “Regulators Defend Timing
Boston Bank.” January 9, 1991, p. 1.

in Seizure

of

American Bankers Association. “Federal Deposit Insurance: A
Program for Reform.” March 1990.
Baer, Herbert and Elijah Brewer III. “The Credit Crunch and
the Diminishing Role of Banks.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, July 199 1, processed.
Barth, James R., Philip F. Bartholomew, and Michael G. Bradley.
“Reforming Federal Deposit Insurance: What Can Be
Learned from Private Insurance Practices?” Research Paper
#161, Federal Home Loan Bank Board, June 1989.
Barth, James R., R. Dan Brumbaugh, Jr., and Robert E. Litan.
“The Banking. Industry in Turmoil: A Report on the
Condition of the U.S. Banking Industry and the Bank
Insurance Fund.” Report to the Financial Institutions
Subcommittee of the House Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, 1Olst Cong., 2nd sess., December
1990.
Philip F. Estimating the Cost of Reguiatwy
Forbearance During the Thnji Crisis. Congressional Budget

Bartholomew,

Office, 1991, processed.
of the Federal Reserve System. Annual
D.C.: Board of Governors,

Stattitical Digest. Washington,

March 1991.
14

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

Bulletin.

December

Washington,
199 1.

D.C.:

Boyd, John H. and Arthur J. Rolnick. “A Case for Reforming
Federal Deposit Insurance.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis Annual Report, 1988.
Butler, Henry Nolde. Legal Change in an Interest--Croup Pen-pective: The DemrSe of Special Corporate Charters. Ph.D.
Dissertation,
Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State
University, May 1982.

“Even After a Five-Month Surge, Bank Stocks
Remain Dirt Cheap.” March 18, 1991, p. 1.

Board of Governors

Reserve

Board of’Governors,

Coleman, Martin and Susan Hart. “Europe Can Teach U.S. a
Few Lessons on Reform.” American Banker, July 29, 199 1,
p. 4.
Cranford, John R. “Decision in Keating Five Case Settles
Little for Senate.” Congmsiona~ Quarterly, March 2, 1991,
pp. 517-23.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Philip Dybvig. “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance? and Liquidity.” Journalof PoktzkalEGonotny
91 (June 1983): 401-19.
Dotsey, Michael and Tony Kuprianov. “Reforming Deposit
Insurance: Lessons from the Savings and Loan Crisis.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 76
(March/April 1990): 3-28.
Financial Times. “Lifeboat

Rushes Into New England Storm.”
January 8, 1991, p. 17.

Gilbert, R. Alton. “Effects of Legislating Prompt Corrective
Action on the Losses of the Bank Insurance Fund.”
January 1992, photocopy.
Kane, Edward J. T& S&L Insurance Mexs: Hti Did It Happen?
Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 1989.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

Kaufman, George G. “Banking Risk in Historical Perspective.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Stmcture and Competition, 1986, pp. 23 l-49.
Keeley, Michael. “Deposit Insurance, Risk and Market Power
in Banking.” American Economic Review 80 (December
1990): 1183-1200.
Mengle, David L. “The Case for Interstate Banking.” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 76 (November/December
1990): 3-17.
. “Market Value Accounting and Bank Failures.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, June 199 1, processed.
Mengle, David L. and John R. Walter. -“How Market Value
Accounting Would Affect Banks.” Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Stmcturz
and Competition, forthcoming 199 1.
Nm YonP 7Imes. “Numbers

Todd, Walker F. “Lessons of the Past and Prospects for the
Future in Lender of Last Resort Theory.” Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago Proceedings of a Conference on Bank
Stmcture and Competition, May 11-13, 1988, pp. 533-77.
“Banks Are Not Special: The Federal Safety
Net and’ Banking Powers” in Catherine England (ed.),
Chveming Banking’s Fututv: Markets vs. Regrdath.
Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1991.
U.S.

U.S. Treasury.
1991.

RESERVE

the Financial System.” February

. “In Great Lakes Region Many Bankers Prove
Caution Can Pay Off.” April 11, 1991, p. 1.
. “The Facts About the FDIC.” June 5, 1991,
p. A12.
Wallison, Peter J. “Treasury Bank Plan: Strangle the Weak.”
WaD Street Journal, February 13, 1991, p. 12.
Washington Post. “Bank of New England

Out-Paced

Rivals.”

January 9, 1991, p. Fl.

Thomson, James B. and Walker F. Todd. “An Insider’s View
of the Politics of the Too Big to Fail Doctrine.” Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper #9017, December 1990.

FEDERAL

“Modernizing

. “Bruised by the S&L Fiasco, Lawmakers Now
Try to Show They Are Born Again Bank Guardians.”
March 19, 1991, p. A26.

Rolnick, Arthur and Warren E. Weber. “The Causes of Free
Bank Failures: A Detailed Examination.” humal
of
Monetary Economics 14 (November 1984): 267-91.

Sprague, Irvine H. Bailout. New York: Basic Books, 1986.

of Commerce. StathicaL Abstract of tke
D.C.: 1965 and 1985.

l&a/l Street Journal. “U.S. Recession Claims Bank of New
England As First Big Victim.” January 7, 1991, p. 1.

Crunch.” June 10, 1990, p. El.

Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee. “An Outline of a
Program for Deposit Insurance Reform.” Statement No. 38.
Mid America Institute for Public Policy Research, Chicago,
December 5, 1988.

Department

United States. Washington,

BANK

OF RICHMOND

15

Financial Evolution
Long-Run
New Evidence

and the

Behavior of Velocity:
from U.S. Regional Data
Peter N. Ii-eland’

I.

INTR~IXJC~T+I~N

Monetary economists have devoted considerable
effort to establishing a link between the financial
innovations of the past two decades and the coincident instability of conventional econometric money
demand specifications. i They have paid little attention, in contrast, to the more general question of how
financial developments may have influenced the demand for money over longer periods of U.S. monetary history. Thus, one survey of the literature notes,
new hypotheses about the effects of financial innovation “have for the most part been tested on the same
body of data that suggested them in the first place”
uudd and Scadding (1983, p.10011. It is unclear
whether these hypotheses can be useful in understanding the effects of earlier innovations or in
predicting the effects of future innovations.
The utility of a stable econometric money demand
function, however, lies precisely in its ability to
forecast out-of-sample so as to indicate, for instance,
what rate of nominal money growth will be consistent with a desired rate of inflation. A satisfactory
theory attributing changes in money demand to
innovations in the financial sector must therefore
account for the effects of a long history of past
innovations and be able to predict the effects of future
innovations.
Such a theory has recently been
developed and tested by Michael Bordo and Lars
Thanks go to Marvin Goodfriend,
Robert Hetzel, Tom
Humphrey, Jeff Lacker, Barbara Mace, and Richard Manning
for making helpful suggestions, and to Andy Atkeson and Rachel
van Elkan for providing unpublished worksheets containing
regional demand deposit data. The opinions expressed herein
are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of
the above-mentioned individuals, the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, or the Federal Reserve System.
l

1 The first among recent empirical studies to attribute money
demand instabilitv to financial innovation include Enzler.
Johnson, and Paulus (1976) and Goldfeld (1976). Judd and
Scadding (1982) and Goldfeld and Sichel (1990) survey the
subsequent literature.
16

ECONOMIC

REVIEW.

Jonung (1987, 1990) as part of an extensive research
project on the long-run behavior of the income velocity of money.2
Bordo and Jonung suggest that the institutional and
financial factors that systematically influence the demand for money in an economy over the entire
course of its development are of two types. On the
one hand, the process of monetization-meaning
the
growth of the commercial banking system in addition to the expansion of formal market activity at the
expense of barter and production for own use-ought
to increase the demand for money as an economy
grows. On the other hand, the emergence of a variety
of nonbank financial intermediaries offering assets
that potentially substitute for money and the invention of cash management techniques used to economize on real balances ought to have the opposite
effect of lowering money demand. Bordo and
Jonung’s hypothesis is that the first set of effects
will dominate early in the course of economic
development but will be eclipsed by the second set
in later stages of growth; velocity will therefore tend
to trace out a U-shaped pattern over time. In recently
published work [Bordo and Jonung (1987, 1990)],
they provide evidence that this pattern can indeed
be found in both U.S. and international data.
This paper shows how Bordo and Jonung’s
hypothesis derives from traditional theories of velocity’s long-run behavior. It then discusses some
objections that have been raised in reviews of their
empirical work. In response to these objections, it
examines a new data set containing figures for demand deposit velocity by region in the United States
since 1929. Regression equations estimated with the
new data support Bordo and Jonung’s theory. The
2 The income velocity of money is defined as the ratio of
national income (in nominal terms) to the nominal money supply.
It is therefore a convenient measure of how money demand
compares to income, with lower money demand relative to
income translating into higher velocity and vice versa.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

attribute the secular decline in velocity to the concurrent secular rise in real income. To explain the
trend’s subsequent reversal, which at the time their
volume was written had only just begun, Friedman
and Schwartz point to postwar expectations of greater
economic stability that worked, they said, to decrease
the demand for money as a safe and highly liquid
asset.

regional figures are also found to be consistent with
an explanation for the recent weakness in Ml velocity. These results suggest that the new data set
represents a valuable untapped source of evidence
with which a variety of hypotheses about the behavior
of velocity can be tested.

II. THEORIES OFVELOCITY%
LONGRUNBEHAVIOR

Friedman and Schwartz’s luxury good hypothesis
became increasingly difficult to apply in explaining
the postwar behavior of M 1 as its velocity continued
to rise. Thus, a number of researchers, including
LatanC (1960), Meltzer (1963), and Lucas (1988)
argue instead for a unitary income elasticity and a
significantly negative interest rate elasticity of
money demand, thereby implying that movements
in velocity are directly attributable to movements in
interest rates. In their later work, Friedman and
Schwartz (1982) also include an interest rate variable
in regression equations used to describe the demand
for money in the United States and the United
Kingdom from 1869 to 1975. Figure 2, which shows
the behavior of the commercial paper rate from 1869
to 1989, does suggest the existence of a close
velocity-interest rate relationship, as both variables
trace out U-shaped patterns over time.

Figure 1 displays the long-run behavior of the income velocity of the U.S. monetary aggregate Ml,
using gross national product as the measure of income.3 It shows that Ml velocity declined secularly
from 1869 until the end of World War II and has
risen secularly since then.
The downward trend in velocity prior to 1945, as
well as the short-run movements that accompanied
it, is documented in great detail by Friedman and
Schwartz (1963).4 They propose that real money
balances be viewed as a luxury good, having an
income elasticity in excess of unity, and therefore
3 All data sources are listed in the appendix.
4 Friedman and Schwartz use M2 as their empirical definition
of money. The long-run behavior of M2, however, does not diier
substantially from that of Ml until after World War II, when
MZ velocity levels off and Ml velocity rises sharply. Thus,
Friedman and Schwartz’s explanation of M2 velocity’s initial
downward trend works equally well in explaining the prewar
behavior of Ml.

After studying the long-run demand for money in
two countries, however, Friedman and Schwartz
(1982) conclude that movements in velocity cannot

Figure1

Ml

VELOCITY
1869-l 989

8

1

1870

1880

1890

1900

1910

FEDERAL

1920

RESERVE

1930

1940

BANK OF RICHMOND

1950

1960

1970

1980

17

Figure

COMMERCIAL

2

PAPER

RATE

1869-l 989
14
12

8
6

1870

1880

1890

1900

1910

1930

1920

be attributed exclusively to movements in income
and interest rates. Figure 3 displays the FriedmanSchwartz M2 velocity and interest rate data for
the United States and the United Kingdom from 1880
to 1910.5 Although interest rates in both countries
moved within a narrow range, velocity fell sharply
in the United States while remaining remarkably
stable in Britain. Friedman and Schwartz (pp. 146-47)
explain the divergence in the two velocity series by
noting that while in 1880 the United Kingdom’s
economy was far more financially sophisticated than
that of the United States, by 1910 this gap had
narrowed:
From 1880 to 1910, the United States population nearly
doubled, but the number of banks multiplied more than
sevenfold. The fraction of the population residing in rural
areas had declined from over two-thirds to only a bit over
one-half; the fraction of the work force in agriculture had
declined from one-half to less than one-third. . . .
. . . the change in relative financial sophistication of the
United Kingdom and the United States . . . was probably
by all odds the single most important factor accounting for
the divergent trends in real balances.

By using a dummy variable in their two-country
model to capture the effects of changing levels of
financial sophistication in the United States relative
to Britain during the late nineteenth and early
5 Friedman and Schwartz use net national product as the measure
of income in computing velocity for both countries. Their
interest rates are the six-month commercial paper rate for the
United States and the three-month bill rate for the United
Kingdom.
18

ECONOMIC

REVIEW.

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

twentieth centuries, Friedman and Schwartz take an
approach to modifying a money demand equation that
mirrors the approach taken by many others to repair
conventional money demand specifications for the
most recent two decades: they acknowledge that in
one instance financial innovation has apparently
shifted the relationship between income, interest
rates, and the demand for money, without considering the possibility that other episodes of instability
in this relationship may have occurred and may yet
occur. Friedman and Schwartz’s approach is, in fact,
exactly the same as that of Hafer and Hein (1982),
who use period-specific dummy variables to restore
stability to a money demand equation for the years
following 1973.
Bordo and Jonung’s hypothesis, in contrast, views
all observed episodes of money demand instability
as symptomatic of an ongoing process of financial
evolution; indeed, their hypothesis suggests that it
is not appropriate to regard money demand instability
as episodic at all, but rather as a predictable and
regular phenomenon. That is, the Bordo-Jonung
hypothesis implies that when the demand for money
equation is properly specified to include proxies for
their two types of ongoing financial innovation, the
equation will be stable for the 189Os, the 198Os, and
all decades in between without needing periodspecific variables. Thus, Bordo and Jonung’s work
both acknowledges and extends that of Friedman and
Schwartz and those who have studied the effects of
more recent financial innovations.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

Figure

3

SHORT-TERM

M2 VELOCITY

880

The
idea that financial
innovations
may
systematically influence velocity over long periods
of time is not solely Bordo and Jonung’s. In fact, they
give credit to Knut Wicksell, who argues (1936,
Ch. 6, Sec. C) that the velocity of currency is likely
to increase as an economy’s banking system develops,
for inspiring their work. Irving Fisher (1963, Ch. V,
Sec. 3) lists among the determinants of velocity
“habits as to the use of book credit and to the use
of checks,” both of which have varied considerably
over time. Warburton (1949), who finds that the
initial downward trend in velocity seen in Figure 1
extends back to 1799, attributes the trend to changes
such as the increase in the share of national output
sold in organized markets, the increase in the fraction of the population working for wages instead of
producing for their own consumption, and the increase due to specialization in the number of intermediate payments required in production, all of which
Bordo and Jonung would classify as aspects of the
monetization process. Among more recent studies,
both Townsend, (1987) and Goodfriend (1991)
describe how improvements in communications and
information-gathering
technologies
facilitate the
substitution of privately issued securities for currency as means of payment; their analyses suggest
that technological progress may simultaneously drive
the process of real economic growth and allow the
payments system to evolve over time. Bordo and
Jonung’s work is unique, however, in the extent to
FEDERAL

RESERVE

1885

1890

INTEREST

1895

1900

RATE

1905

1910

which it attempts to find quantitative evidence, drawn
from a variety of data sources, in support of their
hypothesis.
III.

EVIDENCEOFVELOCITYS
LONGRUNBEHAVIOR

Bordo and Jonung take four distinct approaches
to document that the financial evolution that accompanies the process of real economic growth exerts
an ongoing systematic influence on velocity’s longrun behavior. First, the authors show that, as
predicted by their theory, the U-shaped velocity
pattern found in Figure 1 for the United States can
be found in data from a number of other countries
as well. Second, they modify the traditional regression equation expressing velocity as a function of
income and interest rates by adding proxies for the
two types of institutional changes identified by their
hypothesis. The ratio of M2 to currency and the fraction of the labor force employed outside of the
agricultural sector should both increase as part of the
monetization process and therefore have a negative
effect on velocity. Meanwhile, the ratio of nonbank
financial assets to total financial assets should be a
proxy for the rise of nonbank financial intermediaries
and the development of money substitutes and
therefore have a positive effect on velocity. When
estimated using data extending back into the nineteenth century for Canada, Norway, Sweden, the
BANK OF RICHMOND

19

United Kingdom, and the United States, the regression coefficients on these three proxies all have the
expected signs.
Next, Bordo and Jonung focus in detail on the
monetization process as it occurred in Sweden from
1871 to 1913. They show that a number of other
proxies for institutional change, including the number
of commercial bank accounts per capita and the share
of agricultural wages paid in cash, enter significantly
into regression equations for velocity. Finally, they
show that evidence of U-shaped velocity patterns can
be found in cross-sectional data from 84 countries;
those with low levels of income per capita have
tended to experience falling velocity in the postwar
years, while those with more developed economies
have recently seen velocity rise over time.
In spite of their success in presenting an extensive and diverse body of evidence to support their
hypothesis, Bordo and Jonung have not escaped
criticism. Reviewers have found problems with their
empirical work, with most of the criticism directed
at the augmented velocity equations estimated for
the five advanced industrialized countries. Raj and
Siklos (1988), in commenting on an earlier presentation of Bordo and Jonung’s results [Bordo and
Jonung (1981)], warn that the significance of the
institutional variables in the velocity equations may
be the product of a spurious regression rather than
a true economic relationship. Granger and Newbold
(1986, pp. 20516) demonstrate that standard test
statistics from a regression of one random walk
variable on another, independent
random walk
variable will often incorrectly suggest that the two
are correlated. Since Raj and Siklos find that the
variables in Bordo and Jonung’s regressions behave
like random walks, the test statistics from these
regressions may be misleading. Bordo and Jonung’s
proxies continue to be significant when the equations
are reestimated in first-differenced form, however.
Because differencing serves to remove the random
walk component from each variable, Raj and Siklos
conclude that the test results are probably not
spurious.
In more damaging reviews, Hamilton (1989) and
Huizinga (1990) point out that it is difficult to
defend the assumption, made implicitly by Bordo and
Jonung when they use single-equation econometric
methods, that financial variables such as the
MZ-currency ratio and the ratio of nonbank finan-,
cial assets to all financial assets, used as independent variables in their model, are truly exogenous
in a world in which the supply of as well as the
demand for money and other assets responds to
20

ECONOMIC

REVIEW.

changes in income and interest rates. Both Hamilton
and Huizinga note, for example, that the ratio of M2
to currency is approximately equal to the M2 money
multiplier. If, through the reserve decisions of banks,
the money multiplier depends on the nominal interest
rate, Hamilton (pp. 341-43) demonstrates that the
MZ-currency ratio may appear to be significant in
Bordo and Jonung’s regressions not because it is
standing proxy for the effects of monetization on
money demand, but because it is an important
variable in determining money supply. Bordo and
Jonung’s parameter estimates, therefore, potentially
suffer from simultaneous-equations
bias.‘j
The simultaneity problem is a difficult one to
overcome in the study of money demand, and direct
attempts to do so have met with only limited success.’ In fact, by repeating their analysis with a
variety of data sets, Bordo and Jonung take what is
perhaps the only route toward establishing that their
estimates do not suffer from this problem. Indeed,
Hamilton (p.343) admits as much:
When one finds, as they document, evidence of a consistent, reproducible pattern that is robust across a large
number of specifications, one begins to establish a compelling scientific case that there is a predictable regularity
in the correlations warranting a structural interpretation.

Likewise, Friedman and Schwartz (199 1) argue that
confidence in statistical results on money demand
can be established only by repeating the analysis with
data from as many time periods and as many countries as possible. The remainder of this paper takes
Hamilton’s and Friedman and Schwartz’s advice:
it attempts to answer the critics of Bordo and
Jonung’s empirical work by looking for evidence to
support their financial-innovations hypothesis in a
new data set.

IV. NEW EVIDENCE FROM
U.S. REGIONAL DATA
A. A New Data Set
Andy Atkeson and Rachel van Elkan, both working at the University of Chicago, have recently
6 Of course, the effect of interest rates on reserve decisions is
just one of many potential sources of simultaneous-equations
bias in Bordo and lonune’s work. For instance. Goodfriend
(1991) describes how thgspread
of the commercial banking
system and the coincident development of interbank credit
markets allow banks to economize on their holdings of reserves.
Thus, the supply of as well as the demand for money is intimately related to the process of monetization.
7 See Goldfeld and Sichel (1990) for a review of work on the
problems of simultaneity and exogeneity as they relate to the
estimation of money demand functions.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

Table 1

compiled a data set containing figures for demand
deposits by region in the United States from 1929
to 1988. Along with the Commerce Department’s
state personal income data, these figures may be
used to construct series for demand deposit velocity by region over a 60-year period. The Commerce Department’s regional definitions, used here,
are given in Table 1.

Regional Definitions,
U.S. Department of Commerce

Mideast:
Delaware, District of Columbia,
Jersey, New York, Pennsylvania

As the public’s currency holdings cannot be broken
down geographically, demand deposit velocity is the
closest analog to Ml velocity available at the regional
level. Indeed, Figure 4 reveals that the U-shaped pattern found in the aggregate Ml series is shared by
alI eight regional demand deposit velocity series, with
velocity in each region falling before World War II
and rising thereafter.

Great Lakes:

Indiana,

Maryland,

Michigan,

Southwest:
Rocky

Arizona,

Mountain:

Missouri,

Nebraska,

New Mexico,

Oklahoma,

North

Nevada,

Oregon,

Texas
Utah, Wyoming

Washington

the data to test Bordo and Jonung’s hypothesis.
Specifically, the theory predicts that for earlier years
(during which the commercial banking system was
still expanding geographically) a negative correlation
should be observed between velocity and indexes of

4

DEPOSIT VELOCITY
14

l- - Southeast
Mideast
Mideast (excluding

--

NY)

Rocky Mountain
Southwest
Far West

--

I
I

Great Lakes
New England

12

10

8

8

6

6

01929

New

Ohio, Wisconsin

Colorado, Idaho, Montana,

Far West: California,

Figure

12

New

Southeast: Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky,
Louisiana, Mississippi,
North Carolina, South Carolina,
Tennessee, Virginia, West Virginia

Since the patterns found by region may simply
be reflections of the pattern found in the aggregate, the time-series properties of the data shown in
Figure 4 should not necessarily be thought of as providing new and independent evidence in support of
the assertion that velocity ought to follow a U-shaped
pattern as an economy develops. There is, however,
considerable variation in levels of velocity across
regions at any given point in time, suggesting the
possibility of using the cross-sectional properties of

14

Illinois,

Plains:
Iowa, Kansas, Minnesota,
Dakota, South Dakota

B. Empirical Strategy

DEMAND

Connecticut,
Maine, Massachusetts,
Rhode Island, Vermont

New England:
Hampshire,

1939

1949

1959

1969

1979

1929

1939

FEDERAL

1949
RESERVE

1959
BANK

1969

1979

OF RICHMOND

1929

1939

1949

1959

1969

1979

:
21

financial sophistication across regions. For later
years (with the spread of nonbank intermediaries) this
correlation should turn positive.
C. Cross Section Regression Equations
State personal income data provide two proxies
for the level of financial development by region.
The first, personal income per capita, is a simple
proxy under the assumption that the processes of
real economic growth and financial evolution are
synchronized. The second, the share of total earnings originating in finance, insurance, and real estate
(FIRE), the narrowest industrial class including banks
and nonbank financial intermediaries for which data
beginning in 1929 are available, is a more direct
measure of financial sophistication. Although the
share of earnings in FIRE does not distinguish between growth in banking and growth in nonbank
finance, such a distinction is not necessary because
changes in the proxy should primarily reflect changes
in banking early on and changes in nonbank finance
later.
Let vit denote demand deposit velocity in region
i at time t, PIPCit denote personal income per capita
in region i at time t, and FIREit denote the share
of total earnings originating in finance, insurance, and
real estate in region i at time t. Bordo and Jonung’s
hypothesis predicts that vit should be negatively correlated with both PIPCit and FIREit for early t and
positively correlated for later t. Thus, consider the
cross section regression equations
&PIPCit

(1)

Vit

(2)

vit = 6t + TtFIREit

=

(1Yt +

+ eit
+ uit’

to be estimated for each t from 1929 to 1988 (a total
of 120 regressions). Bordo and Jonung’s hypothesis
predicts that fit and -rt should be negative for the early
years and positive later. More generally, the coefficients should increase as functions of t.8
D. Results: 1929-1980
Figure 4 reveals that the Mideast region inclusive
of New York has considerably lower levels of velocity
than the other regions. Comparing the numbers

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

Equations (1) and (2) are estimated by ordinary
least squares. The slope coefficients /3 and y are
plotted as functions of t in Figure 5 to see if they
increase over time as expected. Since each coefficient is estimated using only eight observations, the
standard errors are quite large. The point estimates,
however, show the data from 1929 to 1980 to be
consistent with Bordo and Jonung’s hypothesis. The
coefficients follow upward paths over the first 50
years for which data are available; for years prior to
World War II they are negative, and after World War
II they become positive. In fact, beginning in 1959
for p and in 1969 for y, the slope estimates are at
least one standard deviation greater than zero.
The changes that underlie the switch from negative
to positive slope coefficients in the 1940s may be
seen in Table 2. Between 1942 and 1946, velocity
fell in every region, but the decline was less pronounced in New England, the Mideast, and the Great
Lakes than in the other regions. Attributing these
relative changes to the geographic expansion of the
banking system is consistent with data presented in
Goldsmith (1958, Ch. V), which document the
spread of commercial banking from the northern
United States to the South and West during 19291949.
E. Results: 1981-1988

* For the reasons given in Section IV.B, equations (1) and (2)
focus only on the cross-sectional patterns appearing in the
regional data. An alternative and perhaps equally informative
approach would be to pool all the observations in the data set
and specify a model that simultaneously tests both the crosssectional and time-series implications of Bordo and Jonung’s
hypothesis. This task is left for future research efforts.

22

for the Mideast as a whole to those for the Mideast
excluding New York State indicates that it is the
New York data that make this region an outlier.
In fact, if figures for New York are included in
the data set used to estimate (1) and (Z), they
dominate the regressions, generating coefficients
pt and -yt that are negative for all t. Including
New York reveals only that as a financial center
for the world, New York City has a high concentration of demand deposits, a high level of income
per capita, and a large fraction of its labor force
employed in finance. Thus, the data for the Mideast region exclusive of New York State, used to
obtain the results discussed below, are more informative in assessing the relevance of the BordoJonung hypothesis.

In contrast to the first 50 years of data, the most
recent figures fail to display the pattern predicted by
Bordo and Jonung’s theory, with the slope coefficients
falling over time and even becoming negative again.
Driving this reversal, as may be seen in Table 3, is
declining velocity in the more financially sophisticated
regions: New England, the Mideast, and the Far
West. The timing of the breakdown in the expected

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

Figure5

01s COEFFICIENTS
(with

f 1 standard

error

band)

V ON FIRE

V ON PIPC
Slope

Slope

0.003
3b

0.002

0.001

0

-0.001

- 0.002

- 0.003

I’
0
I
\

- 0.004

,
,

- 0.005
1929

New

1939

1949

1959

1969

1929

1839

1949

1959

1969

1979

Table 2

Table 3

Changes in Demand Deposit Velocity

Changes in Demand Deposit Velocity

1942-1946

1981-1986
-0.58
-0.65
- 0.63
- 1.26
- 1.93
- 1.51
- 1.97
- 1.60

England

Mideast

1979

(excluding

New York)

Great Lakes
Plains
Southeast
Southwest
Rocky Mountain
Far West

pattern of coefficients suggests that it may be related
to the coincident break in M 1 velocity’s postwar trend
(see Figure l), which has received considerable
attention in the money demand literature.9
9 See, for example, Rasche (1987), Stone and Thornton (1987),
Darby, Mascara, and Marlow (1989), and Hetzel and Mehra
(1989).
FEDERAL

RESERVE

New England
Mideast

(excluding

Great Lakes
Plains
Southeast
Southwest
Rocky Mountain
Far West

New York)

- 1.90
-0.66
+ 0.80
+ 1.58
+0.97
+ 2.84
+ 2.73
-0.16

In fact, one explanation that has been offered
for Ml velocity’s mysterious behavior is also consistent with the surprising cross-sectional pattern
to have emerged in the past decade. Stone and
Thornton (1987) argue that the weakness in Ml
velocity during the 1980s is most likely the result
of two distinct forces. First, the nationwide introduction of NOW accounts in 1981 attracted funds
BANK

OF RICHMOND

23

out of other interest-bearing assets; since M 1 includes
NOW account balances, this substitution caused its
velocity to decrease. Second, if the demand for
money is a function of permanent income (or wealth)
rather than current income, as suggested by Friedman (1959) then velocity measured using current
income will fall as permanent income increases
relative to current income. In particular, expectations
of improved future income following the recessions
of the early 1980s can explain the decrease in
measured M 1 velocity.
If the availability of NOW accounts has drawn
funds out of demand deposits as well as out of nonM 1 assets, then demand deposit velocity should have
increased even as Ml velocity fell. Table 3 reveals
that, in fact, demand deposit,velocity did continue
to rise throughout the 1980s in regions other than
New England, the Mideast, and the Far West.
Interest-bearing checkable deposits were available
before 1981 in New England and New Jersey, so the
nationwide introduction of these accounts would not
have put the same upward pressure on velocity in
New England and the Mideast region (the two regions
with large decreases in velocity) as it did elsewhere.
Moreover, patterns in real estate prices suggest that
the nationwide increase in wealth during the 1980s
was concentrated in New England, the Mideast, and
the Far West, putting downward pressure in
measured velocity through the permanent income
effect in those three regions, but not in the others.
Thus, NOW accounts explain why velocity rose in
some regions, while changes in permanent income
explain why velocity fell in others; together, the two
parts of Stone and Thornton’s hypothesis explain why
the regression coefficients change sign in the 1980s.
If Stone and Thornton’s theory is correct, the
regional regression results for the 1980s do not
contradict Bordo and Jonung’s hypothesis. The
introduction of NOW accounts was a consequence
of regulatory change rather than institutional or
technological
innovation,
for interest-bearing
checkable deposits existed prior to their prohibition
in 1933. To the extent that regional patterns in
velocity during the 1980s are the product of this
regulatory change, the patterns say nothing about the

24

ECONOMIC

REVIEW.

accuracy of Bordo and Jonung’s predictions for the
effects of financial evolution. Since Bordo and Jonung
use permanent income as the scale variable in their
velocity equations, they would also predict that
velocity measured using current income would fall
when permanent income increases; regional patterns
induced by changes in permanent income are not
evidence against Bordo and Jonung’s theory either.
On the other hand, since deviations of permanent
income from current income are by definition transitory, Bordo and Jonung’s hypothesis implies that
barring further significant regulatory change, the slope
coefficients in equations (1) and (2) should soon
become positive again. Thus, only if the experience
of the 1980s is found, in light of future developments,
to be an exceptional aberration in an otherwise
unbroken pattern will the most recent data help in
establishing their hypothesis as a useful guide for
predicting the effects of financial innovation.
V.

CONCLUSIONS

The empirical results obtained here show Bordo
and Jonung’s hypothesis to be consistent with 50
years of regional demand deposit data from 1929 to
1980. Although the figures for 1981-1988 fail to fit
the expected pattern, they have an explanation that
is not inconsistent with the Bordo-Jonung hypothesis.
Overall, therefore, the regional data can be counted
as part of the large and diverse body of evidence that
Hamilton (1989) and Friedman and Schwartz (199 1)
argue is necessary to support the claim that the
correlations found between velocity and various
proxies for financial sophistication reflect the structural relationship implied by Bordo and Jonung’s
theory.
In addition, the regional figures support Stone and
Thornton’s (1987) explanation for the weakness in
Ml velocity during the 1980s. This finding suggests
that regional data are a valuable untapped source of
evidence with which competing hypotheses about the
recent behavior of Ml can be tested. In particular,
any theory that purports to explain the fall in velocity must also explain why this reversal in trend
has been confined to the east and west coasts.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

APPENDIX:
MI, United States, 1869-2892:

The M 1 series is extended back to 1869 by multiplying M2 figures by
0.962, the ratio of Ml to M2 in 1892, the first year
for which Ml data is available. The M2 data is taken
from Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz,

Monetary Trend in the United States and the United
Kingdom: Thir Relation to Income, Prices, and Interest
Rates, 2867-2975. Chicago: University of Chicago

Press, 1982. Table 4.8, Column 1. 28922914: U.S.
Bureau of the Census, Hfitorical Stahl& of the United
States, Coioniai Times to 1957. Washington, D.C.,
1960. Series X-267. Adjusted upward to link with
later data. 1925-2970: U.S. Bureau of the Census,
Historial Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times
to 2970. Washington, D.C., 1975. Series X-414.
1971-1989:
Economic Report of the President.

Washington,

D.C.,

1991. Table C-67.

Gnxs National Pmduct,

United States,

1869- 19.28:

Nathan S. Balke and Robert S. Gordon, “The
Estimation of Prewar Gross National Product:
Methodology and New Evidence.” .hmaLof PO/i&al
Economy 97 (February 1989): 38-92. Table 10. 2929,
I933,

1939-1989:

DATA SOURCES
Three-Month Bil Rate, United Kingdom, 2880-1920:

Friedman and Schwartz (1982). Table 4.9, Column
6.
Demand Deposits by Region, United States, 1929- 2 988:

Unpublished worksheets compiled by Andy Atkeson
and Rachel van Elkan. For 1929-1949, their data are
figures for total demand deposits less interbank and
federal government demand deposits at all banks,
taken from Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, All Bank Statistics, United States,
2869-2955. April 1959. For 1950-1968, the data are
figures for business and personal demand deposits
at all banks, as reported in various issues of Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Assets and Liabilities
and Capital Accounts-Commercial and Mutual Savings
Banks. For 1969-1977, the data are figures for de-

mand deposits at all insured commercial banks, as
reported in various issues of &ets and Liabilities and
Capital Accoun&Gxmne&~

and Mutuui &wings Ban&

For 1978-1988, the data are unpublished figures for
demand deposits at all insured commercial banks,
obtained directly from the FDIC.

Economic Report of the President

(1991). Table B-l. 2930-2932, 2934-2938: U.S.
Department of Commerce, Th National Income and

Personal Income by Region, United States, 1929- 1982:
U.S. Department of Commerce, State Perxonai In-

Product Accounts of the United States, I929-1982:
Statistical Tables. Washington,
D.C., September

cMne: 1929-2982. Washington, D.C., February 1984.
2983-2988: U.S. Department of Commerce, Sureq
of Current Business. August issues, 1986-1990.

1986. Table
Six-Month

1.1.

Commercial Paper Rate,

United States,

2869-2975: Friedman and Schwartz (1982). Table
4.8, Column 6. 2976-1989: Economic Report of the
President (199 1). Table C-7 1.
MZ Velociity, United States,

2880-1920: Friedman
and Schwartz (1982). Table 4.8, Column 1 (MZ)
divided by Column 2 (Net National Product).

Personal Income per Capita by Region, United States,
2 929- 1982: State PersonaL Income, 2 929- I 982 ( 1984).
1983-1988: Survey of Current Businea. August issues,

1986-1990.
&wnings by Region and by Industry, United States,
1929-2982: State PersonaiIncome, 2929-1982 (1984).
1983-1988: Survey of Current Business. August issues,

1986-1990.
MZ Wocity,

United Kingdom, 2880-2920: Friedman

and Schwartz (1982). Table 4.9, Column 1 (MZ)
divided by Column 2 (Net National Product).

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF RICHMOND

25

REFERENCES
Bordo, Michael D. and Lam Jonung. “The Long-Run Behavior
of the Income Velocity of Money in Five Advanced
Countries, 1870-1975: An Institutional Approach.” Economic
Znq~~~ 19 (January 1981): 537-45.
. Th Long-Run Behuvibr of the Velocity of CirmZation: Th International Etidence. Cambridge: Cambridge

Hafer, R. W. and Scott E. Hein. “The Shift in Money
Demand: What Really Happened?” Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis Reviee~ 64 (February 1982): 11-16.
Hamilton, James D. “The Long-Run Behavior of the Velocity
of Circulation: A Review Essay.” JoumaZ of Monetary
Economics 23 (March 1989): 335-44.

University Press, 1987.
Hetzel, Robert L. and Yash P. Mehra. “The Behavior of
Money Demand in the 1980s.” Journal of Money, Cn?dit,
and Banking 21 (November 1989): 455-63.

. “The Long-Run Behavior of Velocity: The
Mode(ig
Institutional Approach Revisited.” Jouma/ofPoky
12 (Summer 1990): 165-97.
Darby, Michael R., Angelo R. Mascara, and Michael L. Marlow.
“The Empirical Reliability of Monetary Aggregates as
Indicators: 1983-1987.” ZGonomic Inquiry 27 (October
1989): 5.55-85.
Enzler, Jared, Lewis Johnson, and John Paulus. “Some Problems of Money Demand.” Brvohings Papen on Economic
Actiti~ (1976): 261-80.
Fisher, Irving. The Purchasing Power of Money. New
Augustus M. Kelley, 1963.

York:

Friedman, Milton. “The Demand for Money: Some Theoretical
and Empirical Results.” Journal of PoliticaL Economy 67
(August 1959): 327-5 1.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of
the UnitedStates, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
. Monetary Trends in the United States and the United
Kingdom: Ttir Relation to Income, Price, and Interest Rates,

1867-2975. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.
“Alternative Approaches to Analyzing Economic
Data.” Aherikan Economic Review 8 1 (March 199 1): 39-49.
Goldfeld,

Stephen

Goldfeld, Stephen M. and Daniel E. Sichel. “The Demand
for Money” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Frank H. Hahn
(eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics. Amsterdam: NorthHolland, 1990.
Raymond W. Financial Intermediaries in the
Amerikan Economy Since 1900. Princeton: Princeton Univer-

Goldsmith,

sity Press, 1958.
Goodfriend, Marvin. “Money, Credit, Banking, and Payments
System Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Reviezz 77 (January/February 1991): 7-23.

26

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

Latant, Henry A. “Income Velocity and Interest Rates: A
Pragmatic Approach.” Rewiew of Economics and Statistics 42
(November 1960): 445-49.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. “Money Demand in the United States:
A Quantitative Review.” Carnegie-Rochester Confemnce ties
on Public Pohy 29 (Autumn 1988): 137-68.
Meltzer, Allan H. “The Demand for Money: The Evidence
from the Time Series.” Journal of Political Economy 71
(June 1963): 219-46.
Rasche, Robert H. “Ml-Velocity and Money-Demand
Functions: Do Stable Relationships Exist?” Camegik-Rochster
Conference Series on Public Pohy 27 (Autumn 1987): 9-88.

Stone, Courtenay C. and Daniel L. Thornton. “Solving the
1980s’ Velocity Puzzle: A Progress Report.” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Rex&xv 69 (August/September
1987): S-23.
Townsend, Robert M. “Economic Organization with Limited
Communication.” Amtian Economic R&m 77 (December
1987): 954-70.
Warburton,

C. W. J. and Paul Newbold. Forecasting Economic
Academic Press, 1986.

Time Series, 2d ed. Orlando:

Judd, John P. and John L. Scadding. “The Search for a Stable
Money Demand Function: A Survey of the Post-1973
Literature.” Journal of Zkonomic Litetatum 20 (September
1982): 993-1023.

Raj, Baldev and Pierre L. Siklos. “Some Qualms About the
Test of the Institutionalist Hypothesis of the Long-Run
Behavior of Velocity.” Economic Inquiry 26 (July 1988):
537-45.

M. “The Case of the Missing Money.”
Bmokings Papers on Economic Act+
(1976): 683-730.

Granger,

Huizinga, John. “Comments on ‘The Long-Run Behavior of
Velocity: The Institutional Approach Revisited.’ ” Journal
of Policy Modeling 12 (Summer 1990): 199-204.

Clark. “The Secular Trend in Monetary Velocity.”
1949): 68-91.

Quarter& Joumai ofEconomics 63 (February

Wicksell, Knut. Interest and Prices. London: Macmillam,

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1991

1936.