View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ELIMINATING RUNAWAY INFLATION:
LESSONS FROM THE GERMAN HYPERINFLATION
Thomas M. Humphrey

The German hyperinflation
of 1923 is a classic
example of what can happen when the monetary
authorities let themselves be guided by false and misleading theories.
In this case the fallacious theories
included
( 1) an external shock or balance of payments theory of inflation and exchange rate depreciation, (2) a reverse causation
theory of the link
between money and prices, (3) the notion that the
real money stock rather than the nominal money
stock is the appropriate indicator of monetary ease or
tightness,
(4) the real bills doctrine according
to
which the money supply should accommodate itself to
the needs of trade, and (5) the idea that the central
bank can stabilize nominal
market interest
rates
simply by pegging its discount rate at some arbitrary
level.
Misleading
Theories
The authorities
adhered to
these theories to a ludicrous degree.
For example,
at the height of the inflation when a postage stamp
and a newspaper cost 90 billion marks and 200 billion
marks respectively, and when the money supply was
expanding
at a rate of 1300 percent per month and
30 paper mills were working overtime just to keep
the Reichsbank supplied with paper for its banknotes,
the authorities
were actually insisting
that money
growth had nothing to do with inflation.
On the
contrary, they blamed inflation on external nonmonetary factors and declared that money growth was the
consequence not the cause of inflation.
Like modern
government
officials who attribute our present inflation to the machinations
of the OPEC cartel, they
located the source of inflation in the postwar punitive
actions of the Allies. More specifically, they traced a
chain of causation running from reparations
burdens
to balance of payments
deficits to exchange
rate
depreciation
to rising import prices and thence to
general price inflation to rising money demand and
finally to the money stock itself. That is, they argued
that external shocks operating through the balance
of payments caused the inflation, that the resulting
rise in prices created a need for more money on the
part of business and government
to carry on the same
level of real transactions,
and that it was the duty of
the Reichsbank
to accommodate
this need, a duty

which it could accomplish without affecting prices.
Far from seeing currency expansion as the source of
inflation, they argued that it was the solution to the
acute shortage
of money caused by skyrocketing
prices. In this connection they advanced the peculiar
theory that monetary
excess could not possibly be
the source of German inflation since the real or pricedeflated
value of the German
money stock was
smaller than it had been before the inflation started.
They failed to realize that excessive nominal money
growth itself was responsible for the shrinkage in the
real money stock. They did not see that inflationary
monetary
growth,
by generating
expectations
of
future inflation (expectations
that constitute the anticipated depreciation
cost of holding money)
had
greatly reduced the demand for money and had stimulated a corresponding
rise in velocity. This inflationinduced rise in velocity had caused prices to rise
faster than the nominal ‘money stock thus producing
the observed shrinkage in the real money stock (see
chart on following page).
This sequence of events,
however, was beyond their comprehension.
Hence
even though the nominal money stock was several
trillion times larger than at the beginning of the inflation, they argued that it was still not large enough because prices had actually risen faster than the money
stock. They thought that they could prevent further
shrinkage of the real money stock by increasing the
nominal money stock. In so doing they succumbed to
the fallacy that the policymakers
can systematically
control real economic variables (e.g., the real money
stock) by controlling
nominal
economic variables
(e.g., the nominal money stock).
Real Bills Doctrine
Another
fallacious
theory to
which they adhered was the real bills or needs of
trade doctrine, which says that money can never be
excessive as long as it is issued against bank loans
made to finance real transactions
in goods and services. What they overlooked was that the demand
for loans also depends on the level of prices at which
those real transactions
are effected. They forget that
rising prices would require an ever-growing
volume
of loans just to finance the same level of real transactions.
Under the real bills criterion
these loans

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

3

4

ECONOMIC

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

would be granted and the money stock would therefore expand.
In this manner price inflation would
generate the very monetary expansion
necessary to
sustain it and the real bills criterion would not limit
the quantity of money in existence.
In short, they
failed to understand
that the real bills criterion cannot
distinguish between the price and output components
of economic activity and therefore constitutes no bar
to the inflationary
overissue of money.
Inflationary
Discount Rate Policy
They also
made the mistake of pegging the discount rate at a
level of 90 percent, which they regarded as constituting an appropriate
degree of monetary
tightness
at a time when the market rate of interest on bank
loans was more than 7300 percent per year.
This
huge interest differential of course made it extremely
profitable
for banks to rediscount
bills with the
Reichsbank and then to loan out the proceeds, thereby
producing
additional
inflationary
expansions
of the
money supply and further upward pressure on interest rates.
If the monetary authorities
recognized
this, however, they said nothing about it.
Monetary Reform Measures But I do not intend
to dwell on the hyperinflation
per se. Rather I wish
to discuss the very successful monetary reform that
ended it in a prompt and relatively painless manneran accomplishment
that seems beyond our powers
today. Regarding the monetary reform the facts are
as follows.
On November
15, 1923 the government
announced
that it intended
to get inflation
under
control.
Acting quickly, it did four things.
l

First, it transferred
responsibility
for monetary control from the Reichsbank to Dr. Hjalmar H. Schacht, the newly appointed
Commissioner for the National Currency.

l

Second, it issued a new currency called the
Rentenmark
to circulate with the old currency.
The Rentenmark
was declared to be equal in
value to one prewar gold mark or one trillion
depreciated paper marks.

l

Third, it established
a fixed upper limit on
the amount
of Rentenmarks
that could be
issued.
According
to Costantino
BrescianiTurroni, perhaps the leading authority on the
hyperinflation
episode, this limitation was crucial to the success of the monetary
reform-1

1 Costantino Bresciani-Turroni,
The Economics of Inflation (New York: Augustus Kelley, 1968), pp. 347-348,
402.

l

Fourth, it directed the Reichsbank to stop the
discounting
of Treasury bills, which meant in
effect that the Reichsbank
would issue no
more paper money for the government.

The Miracle of the Rentenmark
The reform was
an instant success.
The new currency was in great
demand and circulated
at its declared gold value.
Within weeks the rate of inflation, which had been
raging at an annual rate of 300,000 percent, dropped
to virtually zero.
And this was accomplished
at a
cost of only 10 percent lost potential output in 1924,
the year following the monetary reform.2
To get an idea of the magnitude
of this accomplishment were it to be attempted today, we can use
the late Arthur
Okun’s rule of thumb calculation
(which he derived from evaluating
simulations from
six econometric
models) that the cost in terms of
lost output per each 1 percentage point reduction in
the rate of inflation is 10. percent of a year’s GNP.
According to Okun’s 10 percent rule, it should have
required a 50 percent GNP gap sustained for 600
centuries
to eliminate
Germany’s
300,000 percent
inflation rate.3 In fact, however, the German inflation was virtually
eliminated
by early 1924 at the
cost of only a 10 percent GNP gap.
How did they do it? How did the German authorities manage to eliminate an inflation that was infinitely worse than ours today and yet do it so quickly
and painlessly?
What recipe for success did they
have that our authorities lack today? Most observers
correctly note that the key to stopping the inflation
was the eradication
of inflationary
expectations
and
the restoration of confidence in the German currency.
But they offer only the vaguest of explanations
as to
why that confidence was so easily restored, attributing it either to a yearning of the German national
spirit for monetary order and stability or to a naive
belief on the part of the public that the new Rentenmark was worth one prewar gold mark simply because it was declared to be worth that much on the
face of the note.
The Credibility Hypothesis
There is, however,
a more plausible explanation
that stresses the credibility associated with the government’s
policy declarations.
According
to that explanation,
when the
2 Frank D. Graham, Exchange,
Hyperinflation:
ton University

Prices, and Production
in
Germany, 1920-1923 (Princeton:
PrincePress, 1930), p. 319.

3 The computation

is Roy Webb’s.

See his article, “De-

pression or Price Controls:
A Fictitious
Dilemma For
Anti-Inflation
Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Review 66 (May/June
1980), p. 4.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

5

German officials announced in November
1923 their
intention
to halt inflation, the public was fully convinced and accordingly
swiftly revised downward its
expectations
of future inflation.
People believed the
government
not only because it had placed the responsibility
for stabilization
in new hands but also
because prior to the monetary
reform it had taken
decisive steps to reduce the budgetary
deficits that
were an immediate
cause of inflationary
money
growth.4
Consisting
of drastic cuts in expenditures
(particularly
welfare relief to striking workers)
and
the levying of taxes in real (i.e., gold) rather than
nominal terms, these measures were widely regarded
as an essential prerequisite
to monetary stabilization
and a clear indication of the government’s
intention
to end inflation.
People also believed the government
because

it had not tried to mislead

the preceding

hyperinflation.

misunderstood

the public

True,

during

the officials

the cause of the hyperinflation.

had
But

they at least had not lied to the public about the policy
rule they were following at the time.
On the contrary, throughout
ties candidly
objective

growth

shortages

to

episode the authori-

that

their

inflation

overcome

president
installation

stock.

In

this

main

policy

with sufficient

inflation-induced

of money and to stabilize

money

presses

acknowledged

was to accommodate

monetary
the

the inflationary

the real value of

connection

Reichsbank

Rudolf Havenstein
even boasted of the
of new high-speed
currency
printing

that would enable

with skyrocketing

money

growth

to keep up

prices.

Because the authorities
had instituted
budget reforms compatible with monetary stability and because
they had not lied to the public about the policy rule
in effect during the preceding hyperinflation,
there
was ample reason for the public to believe the authorities’ announced
intention
to change the policy
Conserule and halt inflationary
money growth.
quently, inflationary
expectations were swiftly revised
to zero when the halt was announced,
thereby allowing the speedy removal of inflation
without large
increases in lost ouput.
Evidently,
policy credibility
was essential to the reversal of inflationary
expectations and the resulting rapid termination
of inflation.

Lessons of the Monetary Reform
There are at
least three lessons to be learned from the monetary
reform that ended the German hyperinflation.
First,
the task of subduing inflation is easier
l

if the policymakers
of credibility,

l

if they accurately
the public, and

l

if they convince
stop inflation.

Unfortunately,
ing in many
inflation

have established

convey

the public

these ingredients
countries

rhetoric

and persistent
inflation.

their

increases

intentions

to

of their resolve

to

have been sadly lack-

in recent

has been

a record

years

where

accompanied

in the basic

anti-

by steady

trend

rate

of

Credible Policy Strategies
A second lesson to be
learned from the German stabilization
episode is that
a credible anti-inflation
policy must focus on a single
objective, namely the elimination
of inflation.”
A
shifting-targets
policy that focuses now on inflation,
now on unemployment,
now on interest rates or the
foreign exchange value of the dollar or still some
other objective will be largely ineffective in fighting
inflation.
The public, having observed the past tendency of the authorities
to shift from one policy objective to another, will expect monetary restraint to
be abandoned upon the first signs of economic slack
as monetary policy shifts from fighting inflation to
fighting unemployment.
Knowing that monetary restraint will be temporary, wage and price setters will
have no incentive to accept lower rates of wage and
price increases when such restraint
occurs.
As a
result, the inflation
rate will respond but little to the
short-lived efforts to reduce it.
The preceding should not be taken to imply that
is inherently
resistant to all policy strategies.

inflation
On

the

contrary,

were

the

government

to drop

its

shifting-targets
policy strategy for one devoted solely
to eliminating
inflation, the inflation rate might subside rapidly once the public was convinced that a true
anti-inflation

policy

was in force.

Confronted

with

a

new policy environment,
economic agents would have
an incentive
to alter their wage- and price-setting
4 On this point see Ragnar Nurkse’s comments
in The
Course and Control of Inflation
(Geneva:
League of
Nations,
1946), pp. 22-23, 68-73.
Nurkse stresses
the
contribution
made by the fiscal reforms to the success of
the stabilization
of the mark. In particular. he notes that,
since budget deficits were largely-financed
by inflationary
money growth, decisive steps to reduce those deficits and
bring the budget under control improved
the prospects
for monetary stabilization
and thereby lowered inflationary expectations.

6

ECONOMIC

behavior
ment

in a manner

to lower

rates

consistent

with

rapid

adjust-

of inflation.

The third lesson is that we should be wary of pessimistic conclusions
that inflation
can only be removed

5 What

follows

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

draws

heavily

from Webb,

op. cit., p. 5.

at the cost of a protracted
and painful recession.
Those conclusions often are derived from econometric
models estimated for the period when the government’s shifting-targets
policy was in effect.
These
models usually assume that economic agents will not
change their wage- and price-setting
strategies when
the policy environment
changes.
This assumption, is
questionable.
For as mentioned above, if the focus of
monetary
policy were to change from a shiftingtargets strategy to one of permanently
eliminating
inflation, the context in which wage and price decisions are made would be drastically
altered.
Responding
to the new policy environment,
people
would adjust their expectational
and price-setting
behavior accordingly.
Consequently,
inflation would be
less intractable and costly to subdue than in the past
and the inflation rate could be brought down more
swiftly and painlessly than indicated by the econometric models. The trick of course would be in convincing the public that the policy environment
had
indeed changed.
But this could be done if the policymakers were to announce
anti-inflation
targets and
then demonstrate
that they were meeting those targets.
Given a successful track record of meeting
stated anti-inflation
targets, policy credibility
would
be restored thus making it easier to get inflation
under control.

on this score, indicating as it does a tendency for the
lessons to be more often forgotten than remembered.
Over the past year, however, there are signs that the
authorities both at home and abroad may have started
to apply the lessons and that they may have abandoned their old shifting-targets
policy of responding
to the most pressing short-run
concerns for a new
longer run policy of eliminating
inflation.
The current recession, bringing pressures on the policymakers to shift from fighting inflation to fighting unemployment, should reveal whether this is in fact the
So should the ensuing
recovery when the
case.
central bank undoubtedly
will be called upon to accelerate money growth to keep interest rates from
rising.
If the authorities
can resist these pressures
and stick to their longer term policy of eliminating
inflation they will have shown that they have indeed
learned the lessons of the German hyperinflation.

Conclusion
The preceding
has enumerated
three
lessons taught by the stabilization
episode that ended
the German hyperinflation.
Whether modern policymakers will ever consistently
apply these lessons remains to be seen. Certainly the post-World
War II
policy record in many countries is hardly encouraging

League of Nations.
The Course and Control
of
Inflation : A Review of Monetary Experience in
Europe After World War I. Geneva:
League of
Nations, 1946.

References
Bresciani-Turroni,
Costantino.
The Economics of
Inflation:
A Study of Currency Depreciation in
Poet-War Germany (1931). Translated by Millicent
E. Sayers.
With a Foreward by Lionel Robbins.
New York: Augustus Kelley, 1968.
Graham, Frank D. Exchange, Prices, and Production in Hyperinflation:
Germany, 1920-1923. Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1930.

A
Webb, Roy H. “Depression or Price Controls:
Fictitious
Dilemma
For Anti-Inflation
Policy.”
Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond 66 (May/June 1980), pp. 3-6.

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF RICHMOND

7

NEGOTIABLE CERTIFICATES OF DEPOSIT.
Bruce I. Summers

Negotiable certificates of deposit (negotiable CDs)
are the most important source of purchased funds to
U. S. banks that are practitioners
of liabilities management.
Moreover,
they have become one of the
major types of liquid assets in the portfolios of many
investors.
Recent financial
market
developments,
including
increased competition
among financial institutions,
high and sometimes
volatile patterns
of
interest rates, and regulatory changes have all led to
significant
changes in the money markets generally,
and in the market for negotiable CDs in particular.
This article describes the market for negotiable CDs,
placing particular
emphasis
on developments
that
have occurred over the past decade or so.
Types
of Issuers
It is possible
to distinguish
between four general classes of negotiable CDs based
on the type of issuer, because the characteristics
of
these four types of CDs, including
rates paid, risk,
and depth of market, can vary considerably.
The
most important,
and the oldest of the four groups,
consists of negotiable
CDs, called domestic
CDs,
issued by U. S. banks domestically.
Dollar denominated negotiable
CDs issued by banks abroad are
called Eurodollar
CDs or Euro CDs,1 while negotiable CDs issued by the U. S. branches of foreign
banks are known as Yankee CDs.
Finally,
some
nonbank depository institutions,
particularly
savings
and loan associations, have begun to issue negotiable
CDs. These are referred to as thrift CDs.
Domestic
CDs
Negotiable
CDs issued by U. S.
banks domestically
are large denomination
(greater
than $100,000) time deposit liabilities evidenced by a
The certificate
written
instrument
or certificate.
specifies the amount of the deposit, the maturity date,
the rate of interest, and the terms under which interest is calculated. While banks are free to offer market
determined interest rates on time deposits in amounts
above $100,000, negotiable CDs included, the mini-

mum denomination
acceptable for secondary market
trading in domestic CDs is $1 million.
The term to
maturity on newly issued domestic CDs is the outcome of negotiation between a bank and its customers,
the individual
instrument
usually tailored to fit the
liquidity requirements
of the purchaser.
Regulations
limit the minimum
maturity
on deposits of U. S.
banks to 30 days.2
Newly issued domestic CDs
typically
have maturities
that run from 30 days to
12 months.
The average maturity
of outstanding
negotiable CDs is about three months.
Interest
rates on newly issued negotiable
CDs,
called primary market rates, are determined
by market forces and sometimes are directly negotiated between the issuer and the depositor.
Domestic CD
rates are quoted on an interest-bearing
basis; rates
on most other money market instruments,
such as
Treasury bills, bankers acceptances, and commercial
paper are calculated on a discount basis. Interest is
computed for the actual number of days to maturity
on a 360-day year basis and can be either fixed for
the term of the instrument
or variable.
Interest on
fixed-rate negotiable CDs with original terms to maturity of up to one year is normally paid at maturity ;
on longer-dated
instruments,
interest is normally paid
semiannually.
If variable, the rate usually changes
every month or three months and is tied to the secondary market rate on domestic CDs having maturities equal to the variable term of the contract.
Domestic CDs may be issued in either registered
or bearer form.
The great majority
of negotiable
CDs, however, are bearer instruments.
In fact, most
banks automatically
classify bearer CDs as negotiable
instruments
and classify registered
CDs along with
large time deposits open account as nonnegotiable
instruments.
Domestic CDs are paid for in immediately
availThey are reable funds on the day of purchase.
deemed for immediately
available funds on the maturity date. Many investors in domestic CDs prefer
to purchase and settle in New York. For this reason,
regional banks that are active in the CD market issue

1 Some dollar denominated CDs are issued in foreign
locations other than Europe.
For example, banks in
Hong Kong have issued Asian CDs, while the branches
of at least two U. S. banks have issued Nassau CDs.
Markets for these instruments
are just developing,
however.

8

ECONOMIC

a The Federal
Reserve
Board has
however, that the minimum maturity
reduced to 14 days.

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

recently
proposed,
of time deposits be

and redeem their CDs sold to national
customers
through a New York correspondent
bank acting as a
clearing agent.
Early History3
As corporations
became more
adept at cash management
during the 1950’s, they
were able to economize on their holdings of demand
deposits.
Since few banks offered corporations
interest-bearing
deposits as alternatives
to checking
balances,
businesses
turned
to other
investment
sources, particularly
commercial
paper,
Treasury
bills, and repurchase
agreements
with securities
dealers.
Consequently,
there was a sharp decline in
the importance of corporate deposits on the banking
system’s balance sheet.
Large money center banks
especially felt this loss of funds since they relied on
corporate demand deposits to a greater extent than
other, smaller banks.
This situation prompted First
National City Bank of New York to introduce negotiable CDs, which were offered first to the bank’s
foreign customers in August 1960. Investor response
to this move was only modest, however, due in part
to the lack of a secondary market for the certificates.
In February 1961 First National City Bank began to
offer negotiable CDs not only to foreign investors,
but to domestic investors as well.
A simultaneous
development crucial to the success of the new instrument was the announcement
by the Discount
Corporation of New York, a large Government
securities
dealer, that it would make a secondary market for
the negotiable CDs of money center banks.
The new negotiable CD was specifically designed
to attract corporate deposits, and to serve as a source
of funds flexible enough to accommodate changes in
Other major New York
short-term
loan demand.
banks quickly followed ‘the lead of First National
City Bank in offering negotiable CDs, and most of
the leading U. S. Government
securities
dealers
quickly became active in the secondary
market.
Within
two months, negotiable
CDs outstanding
at
New York City banks reached $400 million, and by
September
1961 the figure rose to almost $1,100
million.
It should be noted that commercial
banks, primarily the large regional banks located outside New
York, had years of experience issuing interest-bearing
certificates of deposit and large time deposits open
account prior to 1961. Time deposits open account
had been offered to the foreign depositors of banks
since the 1930’s. Also, banks would sometimes pay

3 This discussion of the early history of domestic CDs
relies heavily on the work of Brewer [2] and Fieldhouse
[4].

interest on “link certificates” arranged by their loan
customers
to fulfill compensating
balance requirements.
Finally, a number of regional banks outside
New York and Chicago routinely
issued negotiable
CDs at the request of their corporate
customers.
Although
legally negotiable,
these CDs issued by
large regional banks lacked an organized secondary
market, a factor that limited their use as true money
market instruments.
Large regional banks that had
been active issuers of negotiable CDs promptly established themselves as competitors with the New York
money center banks in 1961.
The Importance of Regulation
Unlike most other
participants
in the domestic money market, commercial banks are heavily regulated.
Government
regulation has had an important influence on the development of the market for negotiable CDs since its inception.
Two Federal Reserve regulations
in particular have had an influence on the negotiable CD
market, namely Regulation
Q, which governs interest paid on deposits by member banks, and Regulation D; which prescribes reserve requirements
that
must be held against deposits.
Until May 1973, Regulation Q specified an interest
ceiling that could not be exceeded on newly issued
negotiable CDs of at least some maturities. At times,
these ceilings were binding, i.e., they limited banks
to paying rates below open market rates.
In the
early period of the development
of the market for
negotiable CDs, for example, there was a 1 percent
ceiling rate on time deposits of less than three
months’ maturity.
Since market interest rates on
competing instruments
were greater than 1 percent,
this ceiling effectively prohibited banks from issuing
short-dated
CDs. Then in late 1961, the rate on 3month Treasury bills edged upward and exceeded the
2½ percent Regulation
ceiling rate in effect for 3to 6-month CDs. Within the first year in which they
were offered, therefore, banks were forced into a
noncompetitive
position vis-à-vis the money market
alternatives
to negotiable CDs in the maturity range
out to six months.
In July 1963 the Regulation
Q ceiling for CDs
maturing in three months or longer was raised to a
competitive 4 percent. The artifically low rate ceiling
on CDs of less than three months’ maturity
was
raised in November 1964, so that banks were finally
able to compete with other money market instruIn subsequent periods, however, Regulation
ments.
Q ceilings again became binding,
with important
consequences
for the negotiable CD market.
These
episodes will be examined
later when growth in
domestic CDs is discussed.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

9

Both Regulations
D and
require that time deposits have a minimum maturity of thirty days. This
effectively restricts the minimum maturity of newly
Moreover,
issued negotiable CDs to one month.
Regulation
prohibits commercial banks from purchasing their own outstanding
negotiable
CDs, an
action that would be interpreted
under the regulation
as payment of a deposit before maturity.
Some investors have horizons much shorter than 30 days and
might prefer to avoid having to routinely enter the
secondary market to raise cash by selling negotiable
CDs. Consequently,
banks have had an incentive to
develop alternative
instruments
to negotiable
CDs
to meet these investors’ demands.
The 30-day minimum maturity
requirement
on negotiable
CDs is
likely an important factor explaining the rapid growth
in bank repurchase agreements, which are considered
nondeposit liabilities and are therefore not subject to
the 30-day minimum
maturity
requirement
on interest-bearing
deposits.
Member banks of the Federal Reserve System, a
group that accounts for the largest share of negotiable
CDs outstanding,
have always been required to hold
noninterest-bearing
reserves against deposits as prescribed by Regulation
D. Beginning
September
1,
1980, all depository institutions
having either transactions accounts or nonpersonal
time deposits (which
include virtually all negotiable CDs) will be required
to hold reserves as specified in Regulation
D. Reserve requirements
increase the cost of funds to depository institutions
since a portion of total assets
must be set aside in noninterest-earning
reserve accounts. Reserve requirements
against negotiable CDs
have varied over the years and have at times been
graduated by both the maturity of the deposit and the
amount of total balances held. The Federal Reserve
varies reserve requirements
primarily
as an aid in
achieving
the objectives
of monetary
and credit
policy. In the case of CDs, however, Regulation
D
has also been used to achieve a bank regulatory goal,
namely the lengthening
of the maturity structure of
the commercial
banking system’s liabilities.
Thus,
the size of reserve requirements
on CDs has at times
been inversely related to maturity.
Growth in Domestic
CDs There is, unfortunately,
no precise measure of the total amount of domestic
negotiable CDs outstanding.
This is primarily
because not all reporting
banks classify their large
time deposits consistently.
The best measure of the
volume of domestic CDs outstanding
is the series
comprising the CDs of all large banks that report to
the Federal Reserve on a weekly basis (the large
Negotiable CDs outstandweekly reporting banks).
10

ECONOMIC

ing of all large weekly reporting
Chart

1.

Negotiable

CDs of the large

City banks and large regional
rately

banks are shown on
New

York

banks are shown sepa-

on the same chart.

It is clear from Chart 1 that domestic CDs have
grown rapidly but unevenly,
especially after 1968.
The chart also shows that there is a close but imperfect relationship
between changes in the volume
of outstanding
negotiable
CDs for large regional
banks and for the large New York banks.
The rate
of growth in negotiable
CDs issued by New York
banks generally lags the rate of growth experienced
by the regional banks during periods when outstandDuring
the 1975-77
ings are increasing
rapidly.
runoff in negotiable CDs, the percentage decline was
less for the New York banks than for the regional
banks;
the shallower
trough for the New York
banks suggests that these institutions
are more reliant
on such deposits as a primary source of funds. Comparing the trends for the two series suggests that
large regional banks have been expanding their negotiable CD positions faster than the New York money
center
institutions,
a situation
explained
by the
spread of liabilities management
practices outside the
money centers and by the generally
faster rate of
increase in business lending at regional banks during
the last decade.
The share of total negotiable
CDs
attributable
to the New York banks has trended
downward since 1975, falling from nearly 60 percent
to less than one-third by late 1979.
Within the first decade of its existence, the market
for negotiable CDs suffered two major setbacks from
an otherwise rapid growth trend.
These episodes,
which occurred in 1966 and 1969-70, both were a
result of binding Regulation
Q ceilings.
The Regulation Q ceiling on negotiable CDs of all maturities
was raised to 5½ percent in December 1965, following the pattern set by short-term
open market rates.
When market rates moved above this level in early
1966, however, the Federal Reserve took no further
action to keep banks competitive in the money markets; this was a departure from previous practice and
reflected the System’s desire to slow growth in bank
Consequently,
new issues of domestic CDs
loans.
declined and outstandings
dropped by about $3 billion or 16 percent in the last quarter of 1966. Secondary
market activity
also slumped
during
this
period.
When short-term
rates dropped sharply in
early 1967, however, new issue and secondary market
activity quickly recovered.
This interest

rate decline was short-lived,

and by late 1967 open market
push up against

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

the Regulation

rates

however,

again

Q ceiling.

began

to

The ceiling

rate on 6-month to l-year CDs was raised by one
percentage point to 6% percent in 1968, but by later
in the year even longer term negotiable
CDs lost
competitiveness
with other money market instruments.
A wide gap opened between Regulation
Q
ceiling rates and open market rates in 1969, and this
gap was not eliminated when the ceilings were raised
on CDs of all maturities
in January
1970.
Outstanding negotiable CDs declined by over $13 billion,
or more than half of the total amount outstanding,
between December
1968 and February 1970.
The
decline would have been even greater had it not been
for a special exemption
that allowed banks to sell
CDs to foreign official institutions
(i.e., governments
and central banks) without regard to the regulatory
ceiling.
During the runoff, banks issued about $2
billion in negotiable CDs to such investors.
The secondary market in negotiable CDs almost completely
disappeared
during this period as dealers eliminated
their positions and trading declined to almost zero.
This, of course, greatly reduced the liquidity of the
remaining
negotiable CDs outstanding.

In June 1970, the collapse of the Penn Central
Transportation
Company
gave rise to fears of a
general liquidity crisis, as businesses
found themselves unable to issue commercial paper.
One very
important action taken in response to this crisis was
removal of the Regulation
Q ceiling on short-term
CDs, i.e., those with maturities
from 30 to 89 days.
Bank new issue rates on l- to 3-month CDs quickly
rose to competitive
levels and the volume of outstanding CDs resumed rapid growth.
The ceiling on
longer term negotiable CDs was removed three years
later in May 1973. Since the early 1970’s, therefore,
the market for domestic CDs has been conducted in
an atmosphere
free of constraints
on interest rates.
Strong demand for bank credit, particularly
for
business loans, led to a boom in the issuance of domestic CDs between 1972 and 1974.
During this
period the Federal
Reserve attempted
to dampen
credit expansion by raising reserve requirements
on,
and thus increasing the cost of, negotiable CDs. In
June 1973, for example, a 3 percent supplemental
reserve requirement
was added to the existing 5 per-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

11

cent requirement,
and applied to increases in CDs
above the amount outstanding
on May 16, 1973 (a
20 percent supplemental
requirement
on Eurodollar
borrowings
had been in effect since January
1971).
Simultaneous
changes were made to lower reserve
requirements
on Eurodollars
in an attempt to equalize
the reserve costs for these two sources of funds.
In
September
1973 the supplemental
reserve requirement on CDs was raised to 6 percent while reserve
requirements
on Eurodollars
remained
unchanged.
The CD requirement
was lowered back to 3 percent
in December, however.
This temporary
inequality
of reserve requirements
between domestic CDs and
Eurodollars
explains the temporary
decline in CD
volume appearing in Chart 1 for the second half of
1973.
A recession-induced
decline in business loan demand of unprecedented
proportions
occurred at large
banks between 1975 and 1977. Domestic CDs followed this decline, falling by over $28 billion in the
approximately,
two year period from January
1975
to April 1977. Rapid growth resumed in mid-1977
and continued through 1978, after which a six-month
decline totaling over $16 billion occurred.
This decline was prompted
by a surge in the growth of
small time deposits, spurred by large increases in
Money Market Certificates, combined with softening
in the demand for total bank credit.
Accelerating
credit demand by businesses, however, led to renewed
growth in domestic CDs after mid-1979.
Money Center
versus Regional
About one-third
of domestic CDs are issued by a handful of large
money center banks in New York City, while the
remainder
are issued by about two hundred
large
regional banks located around the U.. S. Although
both the money center and regional institutions
sell
their newly issued instruments
primarily
to large
national
and multinational
investors,
the former
group of banks is much more -heavily involved in
this market.
Banks issuing negotiable CDs usually
post a list of base rates, with spreads expressed in
increments
of five basis points, for the various maturities they are writing.
These rates are adjusted
upward or downward
depending
on the particular
bank’s need. for funds and on market conditions.
Regional banks located in cities that serve as headquarters
for major corporations
are often able to
book a large portion of their CDs directly through
the main office, without having to work through a
New York correspondent.
The regional issuers that
are most active in the CD market, however, keep a
supply of blank but signed certificates in New York
so that investors not located in their area and wishing
12

ECONOMIC

to purchase their CDs can do so conveniently.
Regional banks that issue large amounts of domestic
CDs but that depend heavily on purchases
by investors located outside their geographic area typically
employ a sales force to actively market their certificates.
Although
almost all banks on occasion sell their
newly issued certificates
to securities dealers, most
prefer to sell directly to investors. The advantages of
selling directly to retail include paying a lower rate
on the new issues, since the dealer intermediary
is
eliminated, and having more information
over where
certificates are ending up. Banks would prefer that
their CDs be held as investments
and not sold before
maturity, since secondary market sales could compete
with attempts to market new offerings in the future.
Although
dealers sometimes
hold CDs for investment purposes, most of their purchases are passed
through to retail investors in the secondary or resale
market.
Regional banks that are attempting
to build
a name in the domestic CD market, or that are trying
to reestablish
a name after a period of inactivity,
generally must operate through dealers.
In these
cases, the dealers accept marketing
responsibility
for
the newly issued certificates.
When particularly
large
offerings, come to market most banks, even the money
center institutions,
rely on dealers to help distribute
the issue. A new offering of several hundred million
dollars, for example, may be difficult to place directly
even for a bank with a large
base of regular customers.
Over the years, investors have developed preferences for the CDs of certain issuers, or groups of
issuers, that are reflected in the rate structure
on
CDs. The rate required on the CD of a top name
bank may be 5 to 25 basis points lower than that
required on the CD of a lesser known institution.
Historically,
the rate spread on domestic CDs of the
top and lesser name issuers has fluctuated with the
level of interest rates, the spread widening in high
Prior to 1974, investors disinterest rate periods.
tinguished
roughly between two groups of issuing
banks in the domestic CD market, prime and nonprime. The prime banks included the large and wellknown major money-center
institutions,
while the
nonprime category included the smaller, lesser known
In 1974, is concerns
about the
regional banks.
liquidity.

of the

banking

system

were. aroused

by

problems at Franklin
National
Bank and Herstatt
Bank of West Germany, investor tiering of domestic
CDs by issuer became more flexible and complicated.
Size remained important,
but investors’ perceptions
of financial strength began to be formed more spe-

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

cifically, so
that the top tier of preferred
banks
dropped in number and tended to vary over time.
Nonetheless,
investors still place the greatest emphasis in assessing risk on bank size, so that New York
City banks continue the dominate the top tier. The
more conventional
factors used to assess risk, for
example, capital ratios, asset growth rates, and earnings variability,
remain of secondary importance
in
determining
which banks are classified in the top
tier. An implication of this is that portfolio managers
have the opportunity
to improve yield, without taking
a commensurate
increase in risk, by investing in the
domestic CDs of regional banks that meet the traditional tests of financial soundness
but that do not
fall within the top tier.4
Eurodollar
CDs
Like a domestic
CD, a Eurodollar CD is a dollar denominated
instrument
evidencing a time deposit placed with a bank at an
agreed upon rate of interest for a specific period of
time. Unlike a domestic CD, however, a Euro CD
is issued abroad, either by the foreign branch of a
U. S. bank or by a foreign bank.
The market for
Euro CDs is centered in London and is therefore
frequently called the London dollar CD market,
This market originated in 1966 with a Eurodollar
CD issue by the London branch of Citibank.
The
incentive to U. S. banks to start issuing CDs abroad
was provided by regulations
restricting
their ability
to raise funds in the domestic money market, especially Regulation Q. Since it is free of interest rate
regulation, the Eurodollar
market provides banks the
opportunity
to raise funds for domestic lending even
when their ability to issue domestic CDs is restricted.
The Euro CD market has grown rapidly since 1966.
As shown on Chart 2, Euro CD outstandings
at
London banks totaled over $43 billion at year-end
1979. The foreign branches of U. S. banks dominate
the London dollar CD market, accounting
for about
60 percent of all CDs issued by banks located in
London.
Japanese banks rank second in importance,
their share of the market having increased from 9
percent in 1976 to 17 percent in 1979.

porations that are active purchasers of domestic CDs
m the U. S. In fact, some of the largest CD dealers
in the U. S. are represented
in London, where they
make an active market in Euro CDs. These dealers,
and many large investors as well, view their investment activity as essentially
one worldwide position
and manage their Euro CD and domestic CD portfolios in an integrated fashion.
Inasmuch as there is a five-hour time zone difference between London and New York, perfect synchronization
of delivery and payment on Euro CDs
is very difficult.
Therefore,
settlement
for Euro
CDs is normally two working days forward, which
is the value date, and payment is made in clearing
house funds. Dollar settlement is made in New York,
even though the certificates themselves are issued and
held in safekeeping in London.
The First National
Bank of Chicago has set up a Euro CD clearing
center in London to smooth payment and delivery on
these instruments.The clearing center, which is open
to banks, dealers, and investors,
operates on the
clearinghouse
concept, where debits and credits are
cancelled by computer
and only net settlement
is
made.
Yankee
CDs
Yankee
CDs are negotiable
CDs
issued and payable in dollars to bearer in the U. S.
(more specifically,
in New York)
by the branch
offices of major foreign banks.
They are sometimes
referred to as foreign-domestic
CDs.
The foreign
issuers of Yankee CDs are well-known
international
banks headquartered
primarily
in Western
Europe,
Investors in Yankee CDs look
England, and Japan.
to the creditworthiness
of the parent organization
in
assessing their risk, since the obligation of a branch
of a foreign bank is in actuality an obligation of the

Euro CD maturities
run from 30 days out to 5
years, but shorter terms ranging from one month to
one year are most common.
By and large, the customer base is the same as that for domestic CDs, i.e.,
most Euro CDs are placed with the same large car-

4This
pointed
accept
center
ability

conclusion is reached by Crane [3]. It should be
out, however, that investors
may be willing to
somewhat
lower yields on the CDs of money
banks if these instruments
have greater marketthan CDs issued by regional banks.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

13

parent bank. The Yankee CD market is primarily a
shorter term market; most newly issued instruments
have maturities
of three months or less.
Foreign banks have operated branches in the U. S.
for many years, most being located in New York
These banks were initially
established
to
City.
provide credit services to their parent banks’ multinational business customers.
Their number increased
greatly during the 1970’s, and the U. S. branches
became more aggressive
competitors
for the loan
business of U. S. corporations.
Their major sources
of funds have included
borrowings
from foreign
parent organizations,
purchases in the Federal funds
market, and more recently the issuance of large time
deposits to U. S. investors.
At year-end
1979 the
time deposits of U. S. branches of foreign banks due
to private investors and public bodies totaled about
$25 billion.
It is estimated that about $20 billion of
this amount was in the form of negotiable
CDs.
Some individual foreign branches have Yankee CDs
outstanding
well in excess of $1 billion.
The U. S. branches of foreign banks at first placed
most of their Yankee CDs directly with their established loan customers, who through experience were
familiar with the reputations
of the issuers.
Since
their names were not well known outside this small
group, the U. S. branches of foreign banks were
forced to rely on dealers to market their CDs as
reliance on this source of funds grew.
The largest
part of their offerings have until recently been placed
through dealers, several of which are now active
market
makers for Yankee
CDs.
Foreign
bank
names have become much better known and acceptable in the U. S., however, so that today it is much
more commonplace
for foreign branches to sell their
negotiable CDs directly at retail.
Secondary market
trading in Yankee CDs has increased greatly in just
the last several years so that the liquidity of such
instruments
now rivals that of better rated domestic
CDs.
An important institutional
feature of foreign banking operations
in the U. S. is that, until recently,
foreign branches have been state-licensed
and not
subject to Federal Reserve regulations.
Thus, until
recently Yankee CDs have not been subject to reserve requirements
under Regulation
D. This exemption from regulation
probably
helped establish
the market for Yankee CDs, because the U. S.
branches of foreign banks could pay higher rates on
their certificates than could domestic banks but still
not incur higher costs than their U. S. banking competitors as a result of savings on reserve requireThe International
Banking Act of 1978
ments.
provides that large foreign banks doing business in
14

ECONOMIC

the U. S. should be subject to the same Federal
Reserve regulations
as domestic banks.
The U. S.
branches of large foreign banks become subject to
Regulations
D and Q as of September 4, 1980.
Yankee CDs, along with certain other managed
liabilities of the U. S. branches
of foreign banks,
became subject to reserve requirements
for the first
time in October 1979. This change subjected certain
managed
liabilities
above a base amount
to an 8.
percent reserve requirement,
which was subsequently
increased to 10 percent in March 1980, and then
reduced to 5 percent in May 1980. The imposition
of marginal
reserve requirements
on the managed
liabilities of the U. S. branches of foreign banks may
have had the effect of slowing the growth of Yankee
CDs. This is because the market is still young, with
new issuing banks entering
regularly.
These new
banks entering
the Yankee
CD’ market
typically
market
their negotiable
CDs aggressively
in an
attempt to build volume and goodwill quickly. Starting from a low or zero reserve exempt base, however,
the newly entering banks bear a reserve cost on all
of. their negotiable CDs, not just a fractional amount
like established issuers.
This higher cost has likely
discouraged new entries into the Yankee CD market.
Thrift
Institution
CDs
Thrift
institutions,
particularly savings and loan associations
(SLAs),
have
become active competitors for large time deposits not
subject to Regulation Q ceilings.
Most of their large
domestic time deposits are practically
if not legally
nonnegotiable,
i.e., there is very little secondary
market activity in thrift CDs. The large denomination CDs of FSLIC
insured
SLAs totaled nearly
$30 billion at year-end 1979.
Recent changes
in Federal
Home Loan Bank
Board regulations
grant Federally
insured savings
and loans considerably broadened authority to market
Euro CDs. At least one large California
SLA has
placed a $10 million package of unsecured
CDs in
the Eurodollar
market.
The success of such placements depends on the size and financial strength of
the issuing thrift.
Other thrifts have taken steps to
place Euro CDs that are backed by mortgage loan
collateral.
Part of this process involves obtaining a
credit rating from Standard
& Poor’s Corporation,
So far, these
which is now making such ratings.
mortgage-backed
offerings
have been for longer
terms, i.e., five years.
Nonnegotiable
CDs
Nonnegotiable
CDs are an
important part of total large time deposits issued by
In fact, nonnegotiable
CDs of
commercial
banks.
U. S. banks have grown faster than domestic negotiable CDs in recent years and now are more impor-

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

tant than domestic negotiable
CDs as a source of
funds. It is important to understand
what nonnegotiable CDs are, because many investors active in the
market for negotiable CDs are willing to substitute
between the two types of instruments.
Nonnegotiable
CDs are not considered
money
market instruments
because they lack the liquidity of
negotiable
certificates.
Some nonnegotiable
instruments, such as time deposits open account, are legally
nonnegotiable.
Others, such as registered CDs, are
technically negotiable but are in practice nonnegotiable because of the administrative
difficulty involved
in changing
ownership.
Some banks have ceased
issuing certificates and have instead instituted bookentry accounting
procedures
for registered
CDs.
This practice seems to confirm that liquidity
is a
secondary consideration
to investors purchasing
such
instruments.
Among the largest investors in nonnegotiable
CDs
are public bodies, e.g., state and municipal governments.
Often, state law requires that public bodies
invest their funds locally, that all investments
be
registered in the name of the governmental
unit, and
that investments
be secured. A large share of banks’
total large time deposits are secured CDs issued in
registered form to state and local governments.
As
might be expected, regional banks are more heavily
dependent upon such funds than are the money center
banks.
It is not just public bodies that invest in nonnegotiable certificates, however.
Some corporate investors are willing to sacrifice the liquidity provided by
an instrument
that can be traded in the secondary
Also, some
market for a small increase in yield.
banks have gentleman’s
agreements
with customers
who take their registered or book-entry
CDs which
provide that, in the event cash is needed on an emergency basis, the bank will exchange the registered
CD for a bearer CD.
In addition to nonfinancial
corporations,
some money market funds have invested in nonnegotiable
CDs.
Risk and Return
Negotiable
CDs subject
investors to two major types of risk, credit risk’ and marketability risk. Credit risk is the risk of default on
the part of the bank issuing the CD. This is relevant
even for U. S. banks which are insured by the FDIC,
since domestic CDs are issued in large denominations
and deposit insurance only covers up to $100,000 of a
Marketability
risk reflects the
depositor’s
funds.
fact that a ready buyer for a CD might not be available when the owner is ready to, sell. Although the
secondary market in CDs is well developed, it does
not possess the depth of the U. S. Government
se-

curities market.
These risks are reflected in the
yields on negotiable CDs. It should be noted, however, that yields on money market instruments
may
vary for reasons other than differences in risk, e.g.,
due to changes in their relative supplies.
Chart 3 plots the spread between the secondary
market yields on two types of 3-month CDs, domestic
and Euro, and the secondary market rate on 3-month
Treasury bills. The spread is positive and tends to
widen in periods of high interest rates. For example,
the domestic CD-Treasury
bill spread was generally
below 100 basis points for the periods 1971-72 and
1976-78, but widened greatly in 1973-74. The spread
peaked at 458 basis points in August
1974.
The
chart shows that rates on Euro CDs are almost
always above those on domestic CDs, typically by
about 20-30 basis points, and that the Euro-domestic
CD rate spread tends to widen in periods, of high
interest rates. The higher rate on Euro CDs in part
reflects the credit risk premium required by investors
in these instruments;
this premium tends to increase
in periods of stress in the financial markets.
There
is no reserve requirement
against such deposits, and
therefore the total cost to the issuing institution
is
not necessarily greater than the total cost to a domestic bank issuing a CD. In fact, the reserve adjusted costs of domestic and Euro CDs tend to be
very close in times of financial market normalcy [6].
There is no published rate series for Yankee CDs.
Dealers indicate, however, that Yankee CD rates
move very closely, within plus or minus 10 basis
points, of Euro CD rates.
These two types of CDs
are good substitutes
and their rates should be expected to move close together except due to technical
factors, such as relative supply. On average, though,
Yankee CD rates average somewhat lower than Euro
CD rates.
There are two reasons for this.
First,
Yankee CDs, unlike Euro CDs are subject to U. S.
laws and regulations and therefore do not bear sovereign or foreign country risk.
Second, it is easier
and less costly for dealers to engage in Yankee CD
transactions
than in Euro CD transactions.
Yankee
CDs are purchased in the U. S. and positions are
financed with RPs or Federal funds, while Euro
CDs are purchased
abroad and entail international
money transfers.
Quality Ratings
One major rating firm, Moody’s
Investors Service, Inc., has begun to rate the CDs of
banks. So far; only a small number of regional U. S.
banks have received ratings and a handful of applications are in process.
Foreign banks issuing Yankee
CDs, however, have more actively sought formal
ratings than have U. S. banks.
This is understand-

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF RICHMOND

15

able, since they are still attempting
to establish their
names with U. S. investors.
The rating process used
by Moody’s for CDs is virtually identical to that used
for rating commercial paper. It is not the particular
issue that is rated but rather the issuing organization
The CD ratings, like those for commercial
itself.
paper, are designated P-l, P-2, and P-3. Because of
the closeness of the rating processes, one should never
expect to see a divergence
between a bank’s CD
rating and its commercial paper rating. It is possible,
however, for a bank’s CD rating to differ somewhat
from the commercial paper rating of its parent holding company.
Standard & Poor’s Corporation
has begun rating
the CDs of SLAs.
Like Moody’s, S&P has experience rating commercial paper issued by SLAs, but
has so far applied bond rating methods to thrift CDs
because of their longer terms. If asked to rate shortterm thrift CDs, S&P will likely apply a variant of
its commercial paper rating system.
Rates and Maturities
During
the first decade of
their existence, negotiable CDs were written exclusively under fixed interest coupon contracts.
Certificates were written specifying a particular
rate of
interest that would be paid for a given term to maturity.
This pricing arrangement
suited investors
16

ECONOMIC

quite well, at least during the relatively stable interest
rate environment
of the 1960’s.
Those seeking a
compromise between return and liquidity could invest
in short-dated
negotiable
CDs, while those seeking
extra yield could extend the maturity of their investments out to six months or perhaps even longer.
So
long as the upward sloping yield curve remained the
norm, banks and investors had a reasonable basis for
trading off higher yield against longer term.
In the latter part of the 1960’s interest
tions changed
increased,

and

dramatically.
the general

Interest
level

rate condi-

rate fluctuations
of rates

began

to

trend upward.
Under such circumstances,
investors
can be expected to shift their preferences to shorter
term instruments,
and this happened in the CD market; by 1974 the average maturity
of outstanding
domestic CDs fell dramatically
to about two months
from the three-and-one-half-month
length more common in the 1960’s. In September
1974 the Federal
Reserve provided banks an incentive to lengthen their
negotiable
CD maturities
by restructuring
reserve
requirements
in such a way as to raise the reserve
cost of shorter term certificates.
This incentive was
reinforced in December 1974 when reserve requirements were set at 6 percent for negotiable CDs with
an original maturity of less than six months and at
3 percent for negotiable
CDs with an original ma-

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

turity of six months or more: In ‘October 1975 the
reserve requirement
was further lowered to 1 percent
for CDS with original maturities
of four years or
more, and finally in January
1976 the requirement
was lowered to 2½ percent on certificates with original maturities of from six months to four years. In
keeping with this pattern, the marginal reserve program introduced
in October 1979 exempts CDs’ with
original maturities of one year and greater.
In addition to these changes in reserve requirements,
domestic banks had an incentive to increase CD maturities as a result of the deteriorating
liquidity positions of their balance sheets.
By the mid-1970’s,
therefore, the time was ripe for a fundamental
change
in the terms under which negotiable CDs had traditionally been offered.
Fixed-Rate Rollover CDs Early in 1977 a large
New York bank, Morgan Guaranty Trust Company,
introduced
to its customers
on a selective basis
fixed-rate
rollover CDs, or “roly poly” CDs, in
minimum amounts of $5 million.
These instruments
had full terms to maturity of from two to five years,
but consisted of a series of 6-month maturity instruments.
Investors would sign a contract to leave a
deposit with the bank for, say, four years, but instead of receiving a CD maturing
in four years
would receive a 6-month CD. The contract obligated
the investor to renew; or roll over, the 6-month instrument eight consecutive times at the rate negotiated at the inception of the contract.
Although the
bank hoped to qualify for the four year CD reserve
requirement
with these deposits, a ruling by the
Federal Reserve made the rollover CDs reservable
at the higher 6-month maturity reserve requirement.
These instruments
bore rates somewhat above the
rate on Treasury notes of equal maturity, but below
the rate offered on a straight two to five year CD.
The feeling was that an investor would earn the
long-term
rate but get enhanced liquidity
since a
single 6-month issue in the series could be sold in the
This fixed-rate
type of instrusecondary market.
ment proved more attractive
to the issuing banks
than to the investing public during a period of rising
interest rates.
Consequently,
a sizable market in
fixed-rate
rollover CDs never developed.
Variable
rate or variable
Variable Rate CDs
coupon CDs (VRCDs or VCCDs) have the rollover
feature described above but also entail periodic resettings of the coupon rate and periodic payment of
Interest on each component
or “leg” of a
interest.
VRCD is calculated according to the same rules as
on conventional
CDs. The dated date is the original
dated date for the first leg, and for subsequent
legs

it is the date of the interest payment on the preceding
leg.
VRCDs were first offered in the Euro CD
market, where floating rate instruments
were an
accepted method of doing business long before they
were in’ the U. S The VRCD was initially introduced in the domestic and Yankee CD markets by
those large banks having Euro CD experience,
but
the new method of writing certificates
was quickly
adopted by the major regional banks as well. VRCDs
were introduced domestically in 1975, grew in popularity in the latter 1970’s, and have now become a
major innovation
in the market for negotiable CDs.
VRCDs range in full maturity from six months to
four years, the most common full maturities
being
six months and one year.
The rollover period for
these instruments
varies. For example, from 1975 to
1977, three- and six-month rollovers were common.
The higher short-term
interest rates of 1979 and
1980, however, have resulted in the three-month
and
one-month
rollovers becoming standard.
Investor
preferences for full maturity and rollover frequency
are directly related to expected interest rate patterns,
‘periods of stable or declining rates leading to preferences for longer full maturities and longer rolls, and
periods of rising rates and upward
sloping yield
curves leading to preferences for shorter maturities
and ‘shorter rolls. The four VRCD issues having -the
greatest
popularity
at present are ( 1) six-month
‘(full ‘maturity) /three-month
(roll), (2) six-month/
one-month,
(3) one-year/three-month,
and (4) oneyear/one-month.
Coupon

rates set on

each new leg of VRCDs

are

based on the preceding day’s secondary market CD
rates reported daily by the Federal Reserve Bank of
These are averages of offered
New York.
quoted by major dealers.
Collection of interest
ments,

and of principal

presenting

the VRCD

at final maturity,
to the issuing

rates
pay-

is made by
bank

or the

issuing bank’s agent. When presented for collection
of interest, the certificate is stamped with the amount
of the previous period’s interest and the new coupon
rate.
Payment of interest and principal is made in
immediately
available
funds.
VRCDs
normally
carry an interest premium over the rate one would
expect to receive on a conventional
CD. This premium, which compensates
investors for the credit risk
entailed by tying funds up for longer
periods, increases with the maturity of the VRCD.
The premium has usually been about 15 basis points for sixmonth full maturities,
20 basis points for one-year
full maturities, and 25 basis points for eighteen-month
full maturities.
As in the case of conventional
CDs,
VRCDs issued by the top tier banks carry somewhat

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

17

lower rates. than those issued by the lesser name
institutions.
The typical size of a VRCD issue ranges from $50$200 million for large banks and $25-$100 million for
smaller banks, but issues as large as $400 million are
not uncommon.
The largest portion of VRCD issues
is underwritten
by dealers, who usually charge the
issuing bank a small commission
for underwriting
and distribution
services.
Dealers have been willing
to take larger positions in VRCDs than in longer
term conventional
CDs since there is less market risk
involved and because retail demand has proved quite
strong. So far, retail demand has been so strong that
dealers have placed a major portion of newly issued
VRCDs on an order basis.
Investors treat VRCDs as a conventional
CD once
the coupon has been set for the last time and the
certificate is on its last leg. Since VRCDs carry an
interest premium over the rate paid on a conventional
CD, a VRCD, on its last leg offers the potential for
trading profits.
Estimates
by market participants
place the total
amount of VRCDs outstanding
in early 1980 at $12
billion, about double the amount outstanding
only
six months earlier.
Most of these are domestic CDs.
Thus, in the short time since they have become popular, VRCDs have grown to equal over 10 percent of
the total volume of domestic CDs outstanding.
To
date, money market funds have been the most active
investors in VRCDs.
Dealers
There are currently
about 25 dealers in
CDs, all of which are active in the domestic CDs of
top tier banks and some of which specialize in regional names or Yankee CDs.
The center of the
dealer market is New York City, but the larger
dealers have branches in major U. S. cities and in
London.
Two main functions of the CD dealers are
to distribute
CDs at retail, either after first taking
new issues into their own positions or by acting as
brokers, and to support a secondary market in negotiable CDs. In accomplishing
the latter, dealers must
stand ready to make a market, i.e., buy and sell CDs.
Bid and offering prices are constantly
maintained
and the typical spread is between 5 and 10 basis
points, but narrower
spreads on good names with
short remaining
terms to maturity are common.
The normal round-lot trade in negotiable CDs between dealers and retail customers is $1 million, but
increases to $5 million for interdealer trades.
There
is, of course, a great deal of variety among the CDs
being traded at any given time with respect to issuer,
maturity, and other contractual terms. Consequently,
dealers post bid and asked prices for certificates
18

ECONOMIC

issued by a particular tier bank, with maturity identified as early or late in a particular
month.
For
‘example, the bid and ask price for a top trading
name might be for “early December” or “late January.”
Financing
of dealer CD positions is largely done
using RPs.
Since CD collateral is more risky than
U. S. Government
security collateral, RPs against
CDs are usually slightly more expensive than RPs
against, say, Treasury
bills.
For the same reason,
it is more difficult to get term RP financing for CDs.
Normal practice in the RP market is to finance the
face value of a money market instrument.
Since
CDs bear interest, dealers must finance any accrued
interest on CDs held in position from some source
other than RP, e.g., from capital..
Growth in dealer activity has paralleled growth in
the market for negotiable CDs. As the market expanded in the 1960’s daily average dealer transactions
were in the $50-$60 million range, and the daily
average dealer positions ranged from $200-$300 million.
As mentioned,
the secondary market nearly
dried up in 1969, daily average dealer transactions
falling to only $9 million and daily average positions
falling to only $27 million during that year. Dealer
activity burgeoned in the 1970’s, when trading opportunities increased due to the more aggressive marketing of negotiable
CDs by regional banks and with
the development
of the Yankee CD. By 1975, for
example,
daily average dealer positions
increased
about five-fold to $1.4 billion and transactions
inBy 1979,
creased sixteen times to $800 million.
positions further expanded to $2.7 billion and transactions to $1.7 billion.
Summary

The market

domestically

for negotiable

CDs issued

by U. S. banks grew rapidly

the effects of interest
the 1960’s.

rate regulation,

Regulation

could be paid on domestic

Q restrictions

but, due to

unevenly

during

on rates that

CDs led to the introduction

of the Euro CD in 1966. After interest- rate ceilings
on domestic CDs were removed in the early 1970’s
the market grew dramatically.
Regional banks became particularly
active issuers during this period,
and the U. S. branches of foreign banks began issuing
Yankee CDs. Most recently, savings and loan associations have also begun issuing CDs. Investors
can
now choose among a number of issuers in selecting
CDs, i.e., domestic, Euro, Yankee, and thrift.
Not only have the types of issuers multiplied, but
the character of CD contracts has changed as well.
The conventional
fixed-rate CD, which is primarily a
short-term
instrument,
has been modified to extend

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

the term and float the rate.
The resulting
instrument, the variable rate CD, has quickly gained popularity among investors.
The terms under which
VRCDs are offered, however, change constantly
in
response to investor preferences.

The rate of change in the market for negotiable
CDs has been particularly rapid in recent years. This
change is the outcome of competitive forces working
to redesign a financial market to better suit the needs
of its major participants.

References
1. Bergner,
Trading
February

George H. “Investors

The

Opportunities.”
11, 1980.

Offered Interesting
Money Manager,

9. Quint, Michael.
“Foreign
Banks Becoming
Innovative Issuers of New Form of CDs.”
American
Banker, November
9, 1978.

of
of

10.

Marie Elizabeth.
Slovin, Myron B., and Sushka,
“An Econometric
Model of the Market for Negotiable Certificates
of Deposits.”
Journal of Monetary Economics (October 1979), pp. 561-568.

3. Crane,
Dwight
B.
“A Study of Interest
Rate
Spreads
in the 1974 CD Market.”
Journal of
Bank Research (Autumn
1976), pp. 213-224.

11.

Smith, Duncan-Campbell:
“London a main centre
for dollar
CDs.”
Financial
Times
(London),
February
18, 1980.

Certificates
of Deposit.
Publishing
Company,
1962.

12.

Stanko, James.
Variable Coupon CDs Continue to
Gain Popularity Among Nation’s Banks and Investors. New York: Carroll, McEntee & McGinley
Incorporated.

13.

Stigum,
Marcia.
The Money Market:
Reality, and Practice.
Homewood,
Illinois:
Jones-Irwin,
1978.

Myth,
Dow-

14.

“The London dollar certificate
of deposit.”
of England
Quarterly Bulletin (December
pp. 446-452.

Bank
1973),

15.

Treadway,
Charles T., III.
“The Negotiable Certificate of Deposit: A Money Market instrument.”
Thesis, Stonier Graduate
School of Banking, June
1965.

2.

Brewer,
C. R. “Negotiable
Deposit.”
Thesis,
Stonier
Banking, June 1963.

4. Fieldhouse,
Richard.
Boston:
The Bankers
5. Foldessy,
Roll-Over
Deposits.”

Time Certificates
Graduate
School

Edward
F.
“Morgan
Guaranty
Offers
CDs To Lure
Long-Term
Corporate
Wall Street Journal, April 13, 1977.

Grow.” Columbia
6. Giddy, Ian H. “Why Eurodollars
Journal of World Business (Fall 1979), pp. 64-60.
7. Martin, Nancy.
CD.” American

“Morgan
Offering
A ‘Roly Poly’
Banker, April 16, 1977.

8. Melton, William C. “The Market for Large Negotiable CDs.”
Quarterly Review, Federal
Reserve
Bank of New York (Winter 1977-78), pp. 22-34.

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF RICHMOND

19

CURRENT ISSUES IN MONETARY CONTROL*
Statement by
WILLIAM POOLE
Professor

of Economics,

Before the Subcommittee

Brown University

on Domestic

Monetary

Policy

of the
Committee

on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs
U. S. House of Representatives
March 25, 1980

I am very pleased to be here this morning to discuss issues of monetary control and of the Federal
Reserve’s new definitions
of the monetary
aggregates. These are not the big, sexy issues of monetary
policy regarding
our overall monetary
management
for purposes of reducing inflation and maintaining
a
fully-employed
economy.
However, without proper
attention
to monetary
control these big issues will
never be resolved satisfactorily.
I am, therefore, delighted that this Committee,
which has taken the
lead in investigating
these mundane issues, is taking
them up again in the current set of hearings.

on a quarter-by-quarter
and year-by-year
basis is
very loosely related to variations
in money growth
rates quarter-by-quarter
or year-by-year.
If money
growth averages three percent per year for a decade,
it matters relatively little whether that three percent
average arises from an absolutely rock steady three
percent growth per year or as an average of fluctuating money growth-say,
zero percent in even
years and six percent in odd years. This observation
has frequently
been used by the Federal
Reserve
and by many economists to justify a lack of concern
over short-run money growth.

I will begin by outlining briefly the importance
of
monetary control issues, both for the long run and for
the short run.
I will then discuss in some detail
monetary control problems and the steps the Federal
Reserve and the Congress‘ should take to improve
the accuracy of control.
Finally,
I shall discuss
issues of measurement
of monetary magnitudes.
Importance
of Monetary
Control
Control of the
money stock over the long run is a necessary and
sufficient condition to control the rate of inflation.
If we print too much money, then its value will fall,
if not immediately
then surely eventually.
That the
price level is a direct function
of the quantity
of
money is one of the oldest propositions
in economics.
Indeed, in these days of faulty business cycle forecasts I would remind you that the quantity theory
proposition
is also one of the more reliable propositions in economics.
In short, if we do not control
the money stock we will not be successful in controlling inflation.

Indeed, in some business cycle theories variations
in short-run money growth can, in principle, provide
an important element of stabilizing policy. When the
economy is weak money growth should be higher and
when the economy is booming money growth should
be lower. But I should emphasize the importance of
the qualifying
phrase “in principle”.
For countercyclical monetary policy to be successful it is obviously necessary that the variations
in money growth
be well-timed with respect to the needs of the economy. Although there is a lively debate among business cycle theorists
over whether
fluctuations
in
money growth can in principle be stabilizing,
after
the experience
of the last fifteen years no one can
believe that fluctuations
in money growth have been
stabilizing in fact. Moreover, the experience of the
last fifteen years is not an aberration.
Careful examination of the record from the earliest days of the
Federal Reserve System suggests that there has never
been a period in which monetary
policy has been
systematically
stabilizing.

The proposition that the price level is a function of
the level of the money stock, or that the rate of
inflation is a function of the rate -of growth of the
money stock, is correct as a long-run matter.
However, it is clearly the case that the rate of inflation

* Paper presented
at a seminar at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, March 26, 1980. The views expressed
herein are those of the author and not necessarily
those
of the Federal
Reserve
Bank of Richmond
or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

20

ECONOMIC

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

From long experience
with attempts at countercyclical monetary policy in the United 8tates and in
other countries it is clear that, given the current state
of knowledge, the potential gains are small and the
risks are great of attempting
deliberate countercyclical fluctuations
in money growth.
By a failure to
control the money stock more carefully
over the
short run the Federal Reserve has lost control over
the money stock over the longer run.
Instead of
fluctuating
money growth averaging
three percent
over a decade, we have seen the six percent years
followed by additional six percent and even eight and
ten percent years. It has been all too easy to put off
monetary
discipline to the future-to
say that this
year is an especially inconvenient
time to reverse last
year’s money surge.
Time and again we have put
off our money stock diet until tomorrow;
we have
taken too many one last drinks attempting
to satisfy
our apparently insatiable thirst to print more money.
It is self-evident that if we are to have stable and
low money growth in the long run we must find a
way either of preventing
short-run
money growth
fluctuations
from occurring
in the first place or of
insuring that they will in fact be offset by fluctuations
in the opposite direction in succeeding periods.
We
have simply failed at this latter course; we should
now eliminate the short-run fluctuations and do so by
paying much more careful attention to close money
stock control on a month-by-month
basis.
There is a special advantage
to tight short-run
control of the money stock today.
If today’s inheritance were one of fifteen years of stable long-run
money growth and experience with prompt Federal
Reserve action to reverse unwanted changes in money
growth, then money surges today would be met with
a ho-hum shrug.
But that is not our inheritance
in
1980. With good reason, surges in the money stock
today generate
fears that the Federal
Reserve is
losing control or caving in. I personally believe that
the Federal Reserve is currently
doing a fine job
and is very much on the right track.
But my optimism is tempered with realism.
In addition, I can
well understand
the extreme skepticism. with which
current
Federal
Reserve policy is treated in the
market-place.
The Federal Reserve’s inner commitment is not enough; it must earn the confidence of
the markets by solid and sustained performance.
I have

discussed

with respect

but let me hasten
needs

consistent

Administration
not,

the

the issue. of monetary

to the Federal

Reserve’s

control

responsibilities

to add that the Federal
and

sustained

support

and the Congress.

Administration

and

Reserve
from

the

More often than
the

Congress

have

badgered
badgering

the Fed to do the wrong thing instead of
the Fed to stop doing the wrong thing.

One of my favorite examples of harmful pressure
on the Fed occurred in October 1977. ‘As reported
in the Wall Street Journal the next day, on October 20, 1977 the White House posted a “Notice to
the Press” that criticized
Federal
Reserve policy.
The thrust of that notice was that the Fed’s efforts
to restrict money growth were forcing up interest
rates which would damage the economy.
Near the
end of the Wall Street Journal report is the following
paragraph:
After cautioning about the dangers of further
tightening, the statement declared : “Rapid growth
of the money supply is a matter of concern when it
occurs in the context of very rapid economic expansion, high employment and a worsening outlook
for inflation.
Those are not the circumstances
we
face

presently.”

The word

“not”

was underlined.

The entire article from which the above paragraph
is extracted makes for very sobering reading indeed
after the inflationary
experience of the last two years.
Technical

Problems

in Monetary

me now turn to technical
Initially,

let us assume

of the currently
M-l or M-2.

defined

Control

issues of monetary
that we want
monetary

Let
control.

to control

aggregates,

one
either

The basic structure of the monetary control problem is institutionally
rather complicated but intellecFederal Reserve open market
tually rather simple.
operations-the
purchase
and sale of government
securities by the Fed-control
the monetary
base,
which is defined as the sum of currency in circulation
and bank reserves.
When the Federal Reserve buys
government
securities, it pays for them by writing a
check on itself, which directly increases the reserves
of the banking system. Conversely, when the Federal
Reserve sells government
securities it receives checks
in payment and clears those checks by subtracting
them from bank reserve balances
on deposit at
Federal Reserve Banks. With exceptions to be discussed below, through Federal Reserve open market
operations
the monetary
base can be controlled
to
the penny.
This basic fact is extremely important.
The Federal Reserve is under- no obligations
of any contractual or technical kind to engage in open market
operations.
If the Fed stops buying government
securities, then the monetary base will stop growing.
It may or may not be wise for the Federal Reserve to
stop the growth of the monetary base in its tracks.
But let there be no misunderstanding;
although the
Federal Reserve and many economists frequently say

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK. OF RICHMOND

21

that the Fed “has no choice” concerning increases in
the monetary base, those views refer to policy and
not to any technical impediments
whatsoever.
While Federal Reserve control of its open market
operations, and therefore of the monetary base, is the
single most important
element in monetary control,
it is nevertheless
true that the relationship
of the
money stock to the monetary
base is not perfectly
predictable. There are a. number of reasons why this
relationship
is somewhat loose, and I will outline the
major considerations
below.
First,
the monetary
base has two componentsmember bank reserves on deposit at Federal Reserve
Banks and currency in the hands of the public. Currency is one of the components
of the money stock.
Reserves, however, are not a direct component
of
the money stock but rather support the deposits that
are a component of the money stock. The importance
of the currency/deposit
ratio will be discussed later;
at this point let us consider why the relationship
of
deposits to reserves is not perfectly stable and predictable.
Commercial
quired
various

banks

that are member

to hold reserves.
classifications

in specified

of deposits.

banks

bank size. The current bill on Federal Reserve membership and reserve requirements
will move far in this
direction although, because of a lower requirement
on the first $25 million of transactions
type deposits,
not quite all the way to absolutely uniform requirements.?
Another reason for the instability
in the reserve/
deposit ratio in the aggregate is that reserve requirements are assessed against many bank liabilities that

† Editor’s note: The reference here is to the Depository
Institutions
Deregulation
and Monetary
Control Act of
1980 which was passed on March 31 and which establishes, effective September
1, reserve requirements
of 3
percent on the first $25 million of transactions
deposits
and 12 percent on amounts in excess of that figure.

Table I

RESERVE REQUIREMENTS:
FEDERAL
RESERVE BULLETIN, JANUARY 1965
RESERVE

are re-

REQUIREMENTS

OF MEMBER

BANKS

(Per cent of deposits)

percentages
of
These required

reserve ratios differ substantially
from one bank to
another. As of this writing, required reserves against
demand deposits of more than $400 million are 16.5
percent, while the requirement
for deposits of less
than $2 million is only 7.5 percent.
If a depositor
writes a $100 check on an account in a very large
bank and that check is deposited in a very small bank,
then in the first instance-there
is no change in deposits for the two banks together;
the large bank’s
deposits decline and the small bank’s deposits increase by the same amount.
However, the large bank
had been holding 16.5 percent required reserves, or
$16.50, against that $100 deposit whereas the small
bank must hold only 7.5 percent, or $7.50, against
that deposit.
Thus, even though there is no change
initially
in total deposits, the transfer of deposits
releases reserves of $9.00 and leaves the banking
system with surplus reserves which may be used to
support deposit expansion.
Differential
reserve requirements
on different size
banks destabilize the average reserve requirement
for
the banking system as a whole.
As deposits are
shifted from one bank to another a given total of
reserves in the banking system can support a larger
or smaller total of deposits.
The needed reform is
simple and obvious.
All banks (and other financial
institutions)
should be subject to the same flat reserve requirement
on their deposits independent
of

22

ECONOMIC

1 When two dates are shown. first-of-month or midmonth dates record
changes at country banks, and other dates (usually Thurs.) record changes
at central reserve or reserve city banks.
2 Demand deposits subject to reserve requirements are gross demand
deposits minus cash items in process of collection and demand balances
due from domestic banks.
3 Authority of the Board of Governors to classify or reclassify cities as
central reserve cities was terminated effective July 28. 1962.
Note.-All
required reserves were held on deposit with F.R. Banks.
June 21, 1917 until late 1959. Since then, member banks have also been
allowed to count vault cash as reserves, as follow: Country hanks-in
excess of 4 and 2½ per cent of net demand deposits effective Dec. 1, 1959
and Aug. 25, 1960. respectively.
Central reserve city and reserve city
banks--in excess of 2 and I per cent effective Dec. 3. 1959. and Sept. I.
1960. respectively.
Effective Nov. 24, 1960. all vault cash.

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

do not appear in the definitions of the money stock.
For example, when bank liabilities in the form of
certain managed liabilities increase, banks must hold
additional
reserves to satisfy their reserve requirement against those liabilities.
With less reserves
available to support demand deposits, assuming the
total supply of reserves is unchanged,
growth in
managed
liabilities
will force a reduction
in total
deposits.
In recent years the Federal Reserve has continually
moved in the direction of more complicated
reserve
requirements
and so the problem of instability in the
reserve/deposit
ratio has been exacerbated.
Table I
and Table II show the reserve requirement
schedules

reported in the Federal Reserve Bulletins for January 1965 and January
1980. Table I is small and
reports
all reserve
requirement
changes
between
December 31, 1948 and January
1, 1965. Table II
is large, has extensive
fine print in footnotes, and
can only report reserve requirements
in effect on one
date, December 31, 1979, and the date when those
requirements
took effect.
Comparing the
clear that reserve
sorts of purposes
it is fair to say
rarely even been
serve has changed

two reserve requirement
tables it is
requirements
have been used for all
other than money control.
Indeed,
that monetary
control issues have
considered
when the Federal Rethe reserve requirement
structure.

Table II

RESERVE REQUIREMENTS:
1.15

MEMBER

BANK RESERVE

FEDERAL

RESERVE BULLETIN,

JANUARY

1980

REQUIREMENTS1

1. For changes in reserve requirements
beginning 1963, see Board’s
Annual Statistical Digest. 1971-1975 and for prior changes. see Board’s
Annuol Report for 1956, table 13.
2. (a) Requirement schedules are graduated, and each deposit interval
applies to that part of the deposits of each bank. Demand deposits
subject to reserve requirements are gross demand deposits minus cash
items in process of collection and demand balances due from domestic
banks.
(b) The Federal Reserve Act specifies different ranges of requirements
for reserve city banks and for other banks. Reserve cities are designated
under a criterion adopted effective Nov. 9,. 1972, by which a bank having
net demand deposits of more than $400 million is considered to have the
character of business of a reserve city bank. The presence of the head
office of such a bank constitutes designation of that place as a reserve
city. Cities in which there are Federal Reserve Banks or branches are also
reserve cities. Any banks having “et demand deposits of $400 million or
less are considered to have the character of business of banks outside of
reserve cities and are permitted to maintain reserves at ratios set for banks
not in reserve cities. For details, see the Board’s Regulation D.
(c) Effective Aug. 24, 1978. the Regulation M reserve requirements
on net branches due from domestic banks to their foreign branches and
on deposits that foreign branches lend to U.S. residents were reduced to
zero from 4 percent and 1 percent, respectively. The Regulation D reserve
requirement on borrowings from unrelated banks abroad was also reduced
to zero from 4 percent.

(d) Effective with the reserve computation period(beginning
Nov. 16,
1978, domestic deposits of Edge corporations
are subject to the same
reserve requirements as deposits of member banks.
3. Negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW) accounts and time deposits
such as Christmas and vacation club accounts are subject to the same
requirements as savings deposits.
4. The average reserve requirement on savings and other time deposits
must be at least 3 percent, the minimum specified by law.
5. Effective Nov. 2, 1978, asupplementary
reserve requirement of 2
percent was imposed on large time deposits of $100,000 or more, obligations of affiliates, and ineligible acceptances.
Effective with the reserve maintenance period beginning Oct. 23, 1979,
a marginal reserve requirement
of 8 percent was added to managed
liabilities in excess of a base amount. Managed liabilities are defined as
large time deposits,
Eurodollar
borrowings,
repurchase
agreements
against U.S. government
and federal agency securities, federal funds
borrowings from nonmember institutions, and certain other obligations.
In general, the base for the marginal reserve requirement is $100 million or
the average amount of the managed liabilities held by a member bank,
Edge corporation, or family of U.S. branches and agencies of a foreign
bank for the two statement weeks ending Sept. 26, 1979.
NOTE. Required reservcs must be held in the form of deposits
Federal Reserve Banks or vault cash.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

with

23

A typical recent example is the addition on March 14
of reserve requirements
on increases in consumer
revolving
credit and money market mutual
fund
shares.
If the Congress wants to discourage growth
in these items, then it should do so by an explicit tax
rather than by a hidden tax in the form of a reserve
requirement
that will make monetary
control, and
therefore inflation control, more difficult.
It is precisely because the Federal Reserve and the Administration have been willing to use devices of this type
that our reserve requirements
system is a mess.
There ought to be a law against it.
A relatively minor, but unnecessary,
factor of the
same type is the existence of reserve requirements
against U. S. Treasury deposits in commercial banks
(“tax and loan” accounts), which are not included in
any of the various M’s. As these Treasury deposits
rise and fall, total required reserves rise and fall,
changing the ratio of total reserves to deposits that
are included in the various M’s. Reserve requirements against Treasury deposits in commercial banks
should be eliminated.
Another factor that has reduced the stability of the
ratio of reserves to deposits is the system of lagged
reserve accounting introduced in 1968. Tight monetary control requires that there be a predictable relation between the reserves the Federal Reserve creates
or destroys and the deposits banks create or destroy.
Under our present system of lagged reserve accounting, reserve requirements
for a given statement week
are based on banks’ deposits two weeks earlier.
Looked at the other way around,
bank deposit
creation in a given week will not change a bank’s
required reserves at all in that week but only with a
lag of two weeks.
Because

there

temporaneously,

is a zero reserve
this

relation

requirement

between

ation one week and deposit creation

con-

reserve

cre-

that same week is

more variable than used to be the case. Moreover,
bank deposit creation in one week may lead the
Federal Reserve to simply ratify the deposit creation
by supplying the required reserves two weeks later.
After all, -no matter how stingy the Federal Reserve
is in supplying reserves this week there is absolutely
nothing the banks can do this week about the level
of their deposits two weeks ago. Since the banks can
not do anything about their deposits of two weeks
ago, there is a natural tendency for the Federal Reserve to avoid putting banks through a wringer that
can not today change what happened in the past, and
so to simply underwrite
banks’ deposit creation with
minimum fuss.
The solution
24

to the lagged reserve accounting

prob-

ECONOMIC

lem is simple;
promptly
system.

the

Federal

to a contemporaneous

Reserve

reserve

It should admit that moving

raneous accounting
a mistake.

should

move

accounting

from contempo-

to lagged accounting

in 1968 was

Let me now look quickly at the currency issue.
When individuals
cash checks at banks, they withdraw currency from banks and in the first instance
there is simple exchange of deposits for currency
with no change in the total of currency in circulation
plus deposits.
However, since currency in the vaults
of the banks-vault
cash-is
one of the components
of bank reserve balances used for meeting legal reserve requirements,
banks will find that they have a
reserve shortage when currency flows out of banks
into general hand-to-hand
circulation.
Unless the
currency
drain is offset by Federal
Reserve open
market operations,
banks will be forced to contract
deposits further. A currency drain out of the banking
system tends to depress the money stock; a currency
flow into the backing system tends to expand the
money stock.
The Federal Reserve attempts to avoid this instability by open market operations offsetting currency
flows. However, the required amount of open market
operations
is always subject to uncertainty
because
flows into and out of vault cash can occur without
the Federal Reserve discovering
the fact until the
data are reported with a lag of about a week. That
lag is not very important
in practice ; however, the
problem can be eliminated
completely by a simple
change in Federal Reserve regulations.
The reserve
regulations
should be altered so that vault cash in
the banks would not count as one of the components
of bank reserves but rather would be treated as a
deduction from gross demand deposits in calculating
net demand deposits subject to reserve requirements.
This treatment
would be the same as the one that
presently applies for bank cash items in the process
of collection-checks
held by banks that are drawn
on other banks and are in the process of being collected.
The discussion so far has assumed that the Federal
Reserve can control the size of the monetary basethe sum of bank reserves and currency in circulation
-to
the penny if it chooses to do so. In fact, that
assumption
is not quite correct.
To begin with, it must be emphasized that although
the Federal Reserve has always had the technical
means to control the monetary base extremely accurately, until last October 6 it has never chosen to do
so. Especially in recent years the Fed has chosen
instead to peg the Federal funds rate-the
interest

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

rate banks charge when they lend reserve
each other.

Whenever

the Federal

to rise above the Fed’s target
reserves

to check the increase;

rate tended
would absorb

to fall below
reserves

balances

to

funds rate tended

the Fed would
whenever

the Fed’s

target

supply

the funds
the Fed

to check the fall.

The pegging of the Federal funds rate was ended
in substantial
degree last October.
The Federal
Reserve widened the range of Federal funds rate
fluctuations that it would tolerate without intervening
in the market.
However, the Fed has not adopted
the policy of permitting
the funds rate to fluctuate
with market forces without any intervention
whatsoever. I would be more confident that the October 6
reforms were permanent
if the Federal
Reserve
would abandon its intervention
policy altogether and
control its open market operations without reference
to the Federal funds rate.
There are two technical impediments
to precise
Federal Reserve control of the monetary base. The
first arises from so called “operating
factors”.
The
most important of these is Federal Reserve float. In
the process of clearing checks, the Federal Reserve
on the average adds reserves to banks’ reserve accounts before the checks are cleared and subtracted
from other banks’ reserve accounts, thus injecting
extra reserves
into the banking system. There would
be no problem if float were constant, but in fact float
fluctuates
in a rather random
and unpredictable
fashion.
For example, whenever
a major winter
snow storm disrupts operations
at O’Hare Airport
checks are cleared more slowly and float balloons.
Perhaps the Federal Reserve could predict fluctuations in float more accurately
if it were to add
several meteorologists
to its staff; on the other hand,
perhaps not. The only practical way for the Fed to
reduce the fluctuations
and the average size of float
is to invest additional
resources in computers
and
personnel to speed check clearing.
Another volatile operating factor involves changes
in U. S. Treasury deposits at Federal Reserve Banks.
When checks are drawn on these accounts funds are
transferred
to member bank reserve accounts,
increasing bank reserves and the monetary base. Conversely, when tax receipts and the proceeds from
sales of U. S. Government
securities are deposited in
U. S. Treasury accounts at Federal Reserve Banks,
member bank reserve accounts decline. The Federal
Reserve and U. S. Treasury
have worked together
for many years to forecast changes in Treasury
deposits at Federal Reserve Banks, so that open market
operations can offset these changes.
To my knowledge there are no further steps available to reduce

the disturbances
to the
Treasury operations.

monetary

base

caused

by

The second important
technical
impediment
to
precise Federal Reserve control over the monetary
base is the operation of the Fed discount window.
Member banks can borrow at their own initiative
from the Federal
Reserve, and these borrowings
create additional reserves.
Member bank borrowing
through the discount window fluctuates a great deal
and these fluctuations
are largely
unpredictable.
Banks can create deposits first and then borrow the
reserves necessary to meet the reserve requirements
against those deposits later. Or banks can let deposits
run off and use the reserves released from reserve
requirements
to pay off borrowings
at the discount
window rather than to make new loans that will bring
deposits back to their original level.
To some extent, the Federal Reserve can control
the amount
of borrowing
through
administrative
means.
However, the only really reliable method of
controlling bank borrowing is to insure that the banks
do not have an incentive to do so. The discount
window should be closed, except for borrowing in a
genuine liquidity crisis or other emergency applying
to one or more banks.
The vast bulk of borrowing
through the discount window has always been for an
entirely different purpose-that
of short-run
reserve
adjustment
by member banks.
The window works
rather like the overdraft loan feature of my checking
account, except that much of the time the discount
rate is below market rates of interest and so banks are
subsidized when they borrow at the discount window
to avoid their reserve
levels.

balances

below required

It is easy for me and easy for a bank to avoid

an overdraft;

all we need do is keep a margin

extra funds in our accounts
carefully

falling

and monitor

of

the accounts

to keep track of our balances.

Banks do not want to hold excess balances earning
zero interest;
neither do I. But that is no reason
for an agency of the Federal Government
to lend to
me at a subsidy rate so that I can avoid an overdraft
while keeping my excess balances near zero.
For
some time I have recommended
a different mechanism.
Banks should be permitted
to carry over a
reserve deficiency to the next statement
week, but
with the penalty that in the next week extra reserves
must be held equal to 110 percent of the deficiency.
Thus, if a bank has a deficiency, it would in effect
borrow from its next week’s reserves rather than
from the discount window, and so no additional reserves would flow into the banking system to raise
the monetary base. Similarly, to be symmetrical and
ease banks’ reserve management
problems, the Fed

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF RICHMOND

25

should permit
serves.

a 90 percent

carryover

of excess

re-

Even on emergency borrowings
the discount rate
should be kept continuously
above market rates of
interest so that banks have an incentive to borrow in
the market place rather than to find an excuse to
have an emergency
so they can borrow from the
Federal Reserve at a subsidy rate. If a bank needing
funds borrows
in the market place, then it must
borrow reserves from some other bank and such
borrowing
does not change the total amount of reserves in existence.
The Federal Reserve should not rely on discretionary changes in the discount rate to keep it above
market rates of interest, but rather should tie the
discount rate to market rates of interest in an automatic fashion.
My recommendation
is that the discount rate charged in a particular week should always
be a percentage point above the average three-month
Treasury bill rate in the prior week.
The reform of tying the discount rate to market
rates of interest, however, is always subject to the
problem of untying.
I would like to see the Congress
write a discount rate formula into the Federal Reserve Act subject to change only in emergency circumstances.
The Congress
has not provided
the
Federal Reserve with unlimited authority to change
reserve requirements
and it should not provide unlimited authority for discount rate changes either.
One final element of the monetary control process
needs to be examined-the
matter of data availability.
The relation
between the monetary
base and the
money stock can be made substantially
more stable
and predictable, but it will never be precisely predictable. For this reason, it is of great importance
that
the Federal Reserve have accurate and timely data
on the assets that are included in the various definitions of the nation’s money stock. The Federal Reserve should be granted broad authority by the Congress to collect the monetary data it needs.
One of
the biggest gaps in the past was timely data on deposits in nonmember
banks.
That situation has improved substantially
in recent years but there are
other gaps in the data base. If the Congress is concerned about inflation
then it must be concerned
about the amount of money in circulation.
And if it
is concerned about the amount of money in circulation, then it must provide the Federal Reserve with
the power to collect the data necessary to measure
that magnitude.
The above list of recommended
reforms in the
Federal Reserve’s monetary control mechanism may
fairly be described as a laundry list. The fact of the
26

ECONOMIC

matter is that improved monetary control is a matter
of a large number of individually
small reforms.
I
have worked on this topic for some period of time,
beginning
with a paper in 19721 that provided an
extensive analysis, including
empirical estimates, of
self-inflicted
regulatory
impediments
to accurate
money stock control.
The Federal Reserve Board
and staff have never been very interested
in the
subject, and have never conducted a comprehensive
study of the issues involved.
The individual
topics
have been treated, if at all, on a piece meal basis and
reform has generally been rejected on the grounds
that the individual
matter is too small to be worth
doing in the light of other compelling considerations.
This attitude of unconcern reflects, I believe, a general attitude of unconcern over the Federal Reserve’s
most basic and most important
function-that
of
controlling
the quantity of money.
In recent years
the Fed has greatly improved its data and the conceptual basis of its monetary measures;
it ought to
put at least as much effort into reforming
its own
reserve regulations and monetary control procedures.
Money Stock Measurement
The Federal Reserve
has recently announced
new definitions
of its monetary aggregates. I believe that it has done an excellent
job in this matter.
There were many difficult issues
involved and many judgment
calls had to be made.
Part of the Fed’s problem in the redefinition
project was a data problem. A number of newly invented
assets and changed market practices had to be investigated with a view as to whether these new assets
should or should not be included in the new concepts
of money.
In a number of cases the data available
were substantially
weaker than desirable for the purpose of making these decisions.
In some cases assets
that on a conceptual basis ought to be included in a
redefined money stock could not be included because
of the absence of data. For example, there is a strong
case for including
travelers
checks outstanding
in
one of the monetary aggregates,
but historical data
on the amounts outstanding
do not exist and there
seems little likelihood of obtaining authority to collect
such data.
My only quarrel with the Fed’s new money stock
definition is that the M-IA concept makes no sense.
The M-IA
measure is essentially
the old M-lthat is, M-l without any corrections
for the new
types of checking accounts that created the need for

1 William
Poole and Charles
Lieberman,
“Improving
Monetary
Control,” in Arthur M. Okun and George L.
Perry,
eds., Brookings
Papers
on Economic
Activity,
1972:2, 293-335.

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1980

redefinition

of M-l

that the Fed
House

drop

and Senate

not to present
The major
did-except
job-but

and that

growth

redefinition

concept

Committees
targets

the likelihood

on demand

ceilings

at avoidance
data.
NOW

for M-IA.

it did an excellent

that the new definitions

At today’s

of interest

interest

and

accounts,

vision in the definition

serious

example,

and Regulavery extensive

distortions
the

M-1B

an obviously

of M-l.

ago there was considerable

in our
measure

necessary

However,

ambiguity

will

rates the pro-

deposits

are producing

For

the

ask the Fed

issue is not the job the Fed

for the M-1A concept

monetary
includes

the M-1A

money

tion Q interest
efforts

I recommend

Banking

soon be obsolete.
hibition

in the first place.

re-

some years

as to whether

NOW accounts were really substituting
for demand
deposits, or whether the check withdrawal
feature
was simply
withdrawing
problem

a cheaper
funds

and more convenient

from

was a direct

a savings

result

way of

account.

of the prohibition

The
of

interest on demand deposits;
were it not for that
prohibition,
NOW accounts would never have been
invented.

Similarly,

money

shares have been added
again, there is substantial

market

mutual

fund

into the new M-2.
Here
ambiguity about the proper

treatment of money market fund shares.
The problem would never have existed were it not for Regulation Q ceilings on time deposits. The entire money
market mutual fund industry would not exist without
that one regulation.

The market will continue to invent and innovate to
get around existing regulations
of the types I have
mentioned
above.
These forces are not to be regretted ; they reflect the very same profit-seeking
and
innovative behavior that is responsible for computers,
jet aircraft, and the entire range of technological advance that has produced our high standard of living.
But financial
innovations
motivated
by regulatory
avoidance will pose continuing
difficulties for interpretation
of monetary
data.
Reform of monetary
control might make possible much more accurate
control of, say, M-1B as currently
defined but we
will always be in danger of controlling
a magnitude
that has become increasingly
out-moded
because of
financial market innovations.
To appreciate what interest rate controls have done
it is worth noting that the menu of financial assets
available in 1965 was very similar to that available
in 1920, or in 1880 for that matter. Technical change
per se has had relatively
little effect on the basic
structure of the financial system. The costs of clearing checks have been reduced, and the speed of clearing increased, but today a check still looks and works
about the way it did 100 years ago. But since 1965
we have seen NOW accounts, POW accounts, ATS
accounts, money market mutual funds, loophole certificates, and so forth. Interest ceilings are inefficient
and distorting
in their own right but one of their
biggest costs is the monetary
confusion
they have
caused and will continue
to cause.
The ceilings
should be ended promptly and that is a matter for the
Congress and not for the Federal Reserve.

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF RICHMOND

27