View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ON LABOR MARKET INDICATORS
William E. Cullison
The unemployment
rate is, perhaps, the most
closely watched of all economic statistics.
In many
quarters, it is taken as a good indicator of current
economic conditions and of overall well-being in the
country.
Among professionals, however, the unemployment rate is widely recognized as a controversial
statistic that is often of limited accuracy as a measure
of labor market conditions as well as of general
welfare.
As it is currently structured, the statistic
is designed to measure the extent of the so-called
“involuntary” unemployment in the economy. Thus,
unemployment, as defined by the Bureau of Labor
Statistics, includes only those persons who are not
employed and are actively seeking work. This definition of unemployment is a source of pitfalls for the
social as well as the economic interpretation
of
changes in the statistic.
One such pitfall relates to the so-called “discouraged” worker effect.
“Discouraged”
workers are
workers who are unemployed but who have been
frustrated with their job search and no longer actively
seek work.
These workers are not included in the
unemployment statistics.
The number of “discouraged” workers varies with the state of the economy,
and because such workers are excluded from the
unemployment statistics, the unemployment rate may
understate labor market slackness during recessions
and understate labor market tightness during recoveries.
The “discouraged” worker effect is not the only
source of dissatisfaction with the unemployment rate’s
usefulness as an indicator.
Others include the socalled “additional” worker effect (another member
of the household enters the labor market to supplement the family’s income when the principal breadwinner loses his job) and the definition of employment (part-time
workers are defined as employed
even if they desire full-time work).
Professionals, of
course, have been aware of these limitations for years.
The criticisms have intensified recently, however,
because the unemployment
rate’s usefulness as a
coincident indicator has apparently diminished since
1969.
Before 1969, turning points in the unemployment
rate tended to coincide with those in other important
indexes of economic activity.
During the 1970 recession and the subsequent recovery, however, the
unemployment
rate rose above 6 percent and re-

mained close to its cyclical peak until June 1972, well
after recovery had begun.
The 20-month plateau
around the 6 percent peak level was the longest such
aberration in the history of the series. Moreover, the
unemployment rate has never since regained its low
1968 and 1969 levels. Throughout the first months
of 1973, when other economic indicators were rising
strongly and the economy was approaching full capacity, the unemployment rate continued to indicate
a relatively slack labor market.
Gauging
Labor
Market
Pressures.
Economic
statisticians have long recognized that unemployment
data should be interpreted in the light of the behavior
of other labor market statistics, especially that of
employment data.
Geoffrey Moore, former U. S.
Commissioner of Labor Statistics, has made a compelling argument that employment data are, as a
matter of fact, superior to unemployment data as
labor market indicators.
In one of his more recent
statements, written for the Wall Street Journal,1 he
reasons as follows :
. . . the concept of employment is firmer than the
concept of unemployment.
Having a job and being
paid for it is, for the most part, an observable
experience. . . . The concept of unemployment is
quite different.
For those who have had a job and
have just
been laid off, the situation
may be
obvious. Nevertheless,
unless the worker is doing
something to seek work, he will not be counted as
unemployed . . . . Moreover, those who . . . have
been laid off usually constitute less than half of the
unemployed.
The rest have either quit their jobs
voluntarily or have not recently
(or ever) had a
job.2

Another important consideration,
also noted by
Moore, is that the employment numbers, being substantially larger than the unemployment numbers,
contain less relative sampling error.
Most observers no doubt would agree with Moore
respecting the technical superiority of the employment figures.
But a practical problem in relying
exclusively on employment data is there is no generally agreed upon standard against which to measure
changes in employment.
Moore has suggested a
simple employment/population
ratio as a yardstick,
but such a ratio may itself suffer from serious limitations.
1 Geoffrey
Moore.
“A Measuring
Street Journal, May
9, 1975.

Stick

for

Employment,”

Wall

2 Ibid.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

3

itself, with considerable unemployment and a great
deal of inflation.
What was largely overlooked
was the record high employment ratio.3

This article examines Moore’s employment/population ratio in detail and proceeds to develop a somewhat more refined “labor market pressure index”
that may offer an even more sensitive indicator of
labor market conditions.

A

Critical

represents
Ratio

The data

for Moore’s employment/population
ratio were derived simply by dividing the number of persons
employed by the total working age population.
For
purposes of this article, that technique was modified
slightly and the ratios were calculated by dividing
those employed (16-64)
by the population (civilian
resident non-institutional)
in that age bracket.
This
ratio, along with the unemployment rate, is plotted
in Chart 1 for the period January 1955 to June 1975.
The chart clearly shows that the employment/population ratio for all civilian workers, in contrast to
the unemployment rate, exhibits a definite upward
secular trend over the time period as a whole. The
upward trend has been particularly pronounced since
1965, and as a result each succeeding month of 1974
set a new record high. This behavior pattern differs
considerably from that of the unemployment rate,
which has not yet regained its 1969 level.
The theoretical rationale usually associated with
the well-known Phillips curve relationship argues
that as an economy approaches full utilization of its
labor resources, certain scarcities of critical skills
develop.
As firms endeavor to expand production,
they must bid against one another for workers, thus
introducing upward pressure on wages and, ultimately, prices. Conversely, slack conditions in labor
markets cause wage and price pressures to subside.
But the experience of 1973-1974 did not follow this
script. Moore has indicated that part of this apparent
anomaly may be attributable to the statistical deficiencies in the unemployment rate as an economic
indicator.
Indeed, his employment/population
ratio
conforms more closely than the unemployment rate
to the relationship between inflation and labor market
conditions that was widely accepted in the 1960’s.
The high levels of the employment/population
ratio
in 1973 and early 1974 coincide with the rapid rates
of increase in the consumer price index at that time.
As Moore notes:
High employment ratios have been associated with
high rates of inflation. . . . There has been relatively little inflation when the percentage employed
has been in the range 53.5% to 55.5%, but higher
employment ratios have been associated with increasingly sharp advances in the rate of inflation.
...
In general, rates of wage and price inflation
have been far more closely correlated
with the
employment
ratio than with the unemployment
rate. . . . In particular,
1974 was . . . in a class by

4

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

finement

statistics

of this sort

refinements
respecting

of analysis.

the relationship

employment/population

workers
nents,

further

Some

is separated
plotted

unambiguous

between

pressures.

of these
he draws

the employment

For
ratio

re-

example,
for

when

all

civilian

into male and female

compo-

in Chart
support

ratio

to the interpretation

and provokes

cast doubt on the inferences

ratio and inflation
the

employment

a useful contribution

of labor market
Moore’s Employment/Population

Moore’s

View

1, the data no longer

to Moore’s

lend

inference.

The behavior of the ratio for all civilian workers
over the period observed results from two conflicting
trends.
The male employment/population
ratio exhibits a definite downward
trend from 1955-1975.
This ratio, in fact, was higher during the 1960-1964
time period, a period of relatively stable prices, than
it was in the 1972-1974 time period.
The female employment/population
ratio, in pronounced contrast to the male series, exhibits a substantial upward trend over the same time period.
This upward tendency, of course, is associated with
well-known changes in women’s work preferences,
and it is particularly pronounced since 1965. In any
event, the upward trend in female employment more
than offset the downward trend in the male ratio, and
as a result the total employment/population
series
exhibited a moderate but definite upward trend.
This domination of the total employment/population
series by increased female participation leads to some
ambiguity in interpreting the series.
The record ratios registered in 1973 and 1974,
for example, can logically be interpreted in either
of two conflicting ways. They may, as Moore suggests, indicate labor scarcities.
On the other hand,
the higher percentage employed may have been entirely attributable to an increased supply of females
in the labor force and thus indicate nothing about
labor market slackness or tightness.
Viewed from
this perspective, the closer association of prices with
the employment ratio could possibly reflect nothing
more than parallel trends in excess aggregate demand
and increased female participation in the labor force
in the late 1960’s and early 1970’s.
Employment ratios adjusted for long-term trends
in labor force participation and calculated for major
labor force groups might represent a useful refinement of Moore’s efforts to improve the interpretation
3 Ibid.

JULY/AUGUST

1975

Chart

EMPLOYMENT/POPULATION

1

RATIO AND UNEMPLOYMENT

JANUARY

1955 - JUNE

1975

RATE (INVERTED)

of labor market data.
sure index” directed
the paragraphs

A so-called “employment prestoward this end is offered in

that follow.

The Employment

Pressure

Index

The

employ-

ment pressure index is a measure of excess supply or
excess demand for labor. An underlying assumption
in the construction of the index is that actual employment is a proxy for labor demand and that population and trends in participation
rates determine
long-term labor supply.
Its theoretical basis is described in detail elsewhere.4
Briefly, however, it is
derived by dividing actual employment figures by
estimates derived from long-term trend and changes
in population.
The employment
equation
ET=

estimates

a+

were derived from the

b1t + b2t2 + b3P

where ET
is the employment estimate, t is time
(January
1954 = 1), and P is population in the
relevant group.
The least squares multiple regression technique was used to estimate a, b1, b2, and b3.
Separate estimations were made for each of sixteen
employment categories grouped by sex, race, and age
(16-19, 20-24, 25-34, 35-64) from monthly data for
the 1955-1975 time period.
The estimates for each
of the categories were then summed to get an aggregate estimate for each month, and the total was
divided into the actual employment figure for the
appropriate month to determine the pressure index.
The resulting data for the period January
1955
through June 1975 are shown in the Appendix.
Chart 2 shows the employment pressure index for
total employment in comparison to the unemployment rate.
Interpreting
the Pressure
Index
The employment pressure index takes changing work preference
patterns into account, because long-run changes in
labor supply are incorporated into the trends.
Because of this, the pressure index data parallel the
unemployment
rate data much more closely than
employment/population
ratios.
Even so, there have
been some important differences between the unemployment rate and the employment pressure index
(EPI),
particularly since 1970.
During the 1970-1971
recession, when the unemployment rate leveled off at approximately 6 percent,
the EPI continued to fall, not reaching a definite
lower turning point until June 1971.
After that,
4 See William
Cullison,
“An
Employment
Pressure Index as an
Alternative
Measure of Labor Market Conditions.”
The Review of
Economics
and Statistics,
Vol. 57. No. 1, February
1975, for a
detailed description
of the theory underlying the employment
pressure index.

6

ECONOMIC

according to the pressure index, a vigorous recovery
in the labor market ensued, reaching a peak in
January 1974 and remaining at relatively high levels
until August

of that year.

Thus, the pressure index indicated
market conditions were much tighter

that labor
during the

fourth quarter of 1973 and the first quarter of 1974
than did the unemployment rate. The index had, by
then, recovered to its 1968 level, while the unemployment rate averaged 5.0 percent compared with 3.6
percent

in 1968.

Hence,

it appears

that the EPI

may have been the better indicator of the extent of
the recovery from the 1969-1970 recession, although
both indicators pointed to a substantial deterioration
in employment conditions beginning in September
1974.
Chart 2 also shows employment pressure indexes
and unemployment rates for males and females separately.
Although the relationship between the EPI
and the unemployment rate is much closer for males
than for females, it is obvious that a close relationship exists for both groups.
Using the EPI,
a
picture emerges of tight labor markets for both male
and female workers in 1974 that is consistent with
Moore’s conclusion about employment during that
year.
The employment pressure index for males
reached a record level in January 1974, and the EPI
for females recorded relatively high, although not
record levels, throughout the first half of 1974.
The pressure index thus tends to corroborate
Moore’s conclusions that in early 1974 the employment statistics were considerably
more consistent
with the behavior of price and other economic data
than were the unemployment data. The employment
pressure index indicates a great deal of pressure on
labor markets at that time, although a record level
only for males.
However, much of the inflation
during 1974 has been attributed to scarcities of raw
materials and other basic production inputs and foods.
Increased production of basic commodities may have
necessitated a more male-intensive
labor force than
production increases in other types of commodities
would have, and according to the EPI, employable
males were scarce in early 1974.
Finally, the recent behavior of the EPI is noteworthy.
Although the unemployment rate indicates
further deterioration
in the employment scene: in
April and May (1975), the EPI indicated some improvement in each of the two months.
Final conclusions are, of course, premature, but the employment pressure index may thus be indicating that the
downturn ended in March and that recovery is under
way.

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1975

Chart

EMPLOYMENT

2

PRESSURE INDEX AND UNEMPLOYMENT
JANUARY 1955 - JUNE 1975

RATE (INVERTED)

Summary
A number of arguments
have been
cited for the use of employment in conjunction with
unemployment
statistics
as economic
indicators.
Basically, these arguments are :
1.
2.
3.

Employment
“discouraged”

no standard
employment.
propriate
tions.

to less relative
by the

against

article,

pressure

Moore

PRESSURE

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

for labor

index

INDEX

1975

in
an

an ap-

market

condi-

and developed

may provide additional

that

provide

on this ratio, represented

ing labor market conditions

EMPLOYMENT

changes

suggested

ratio might
stick

data as an

has been that there is

which to measure

Geoffrey

A refinement

APPENDIX

ECONOMIC

however,

measuring

employment

data are not biased
worker effect.

with using employment

indicator,

employment/population

Employment data are firmer, involving fewer
definitional problems.
Employment data are subject
sampling error.

The difficulty
economic

insights

since 1969.

as the
in this

in interpret-

A VALUATION APPROACH TO
BANK HOLDING COMPANY ACQUISITIONS
Walter A. Varvel*

The commercial banking system in this country
has undergone an unparalleled consolidation movement since the mid-1960’s.
Bank holding companies
(BHCs)
have been active since the turn of the century, yet they have become an important force in the
banking structure only since 1965. The phenomenal
growth in the number of corporations that hold stock
in one or more banks and the increased concentration
of banking resources in such entities have prompted
much discussion and a wealth of analytical studies of
the potential impact of this development on the nation’s financial system.
Central to many of these
studies has been the question of how acquisition by a
holding company may affect the performance of an
acquired commercial bank. Related to this issue, and
often confused with it, is the question of the motivation for such acquisitions. The latter question has yet
to be adequately answered.
Most efforts to explain the economic basis for bank
holding company acquisitions have evolved from a
framework designed to measure the resulting impact
on the community served by an acquired bank.
Attention has been centered on the consistent findings
that the profitability of a bank has not been improved,
relative to similarly
situated independent
banks,
through acquisition to an extent that would clearly
justify acquisition by a wealth-maximizing
bank
holding company. But conclusions based on measurements of bank profitability alone ignore the possibility that owners’ claims on earnings streams are
altered significantly by the transaction.
This article examines the hypothesis that the incentives for acquisition lie primarily in potential
benefits accruing to owners, i.e., shareholders, who
have claims on the earnings streams of the two firms
involved.
The framework for the analysis centers
on a comparison of the valuation of expected future
earnings streams for both sets of stockholders under
the alternative assumptions, first, that the acquisition
is not consummated and, second, that it is consummated.
Rational behavior implies that owners will
exchange claims to earnings only if they value those
received more than those released.
*The author would like to acknowledge
the assistance of
Strand with the data processing involved in this article.

Some Previous Evidence
Among efforts to establish the existence of a “valuation disparity” sufficient
to justify a BHC acquisition have been those by
Thomas Piper and Steven Weiss.1
In a study of
acquisitions during the period 1947 through 1967,
Piper argued that the economic incentives for acquisitions of banks “center on the resultant changes,
both in the cash flows and earnings of the acquired
banks and in the valuation of these cash flows” [3,
p. 98]. He emphasized the importance of comparing
the value of alternative ownership interests.
For the
acquisitions studied, Piper compared the value received by the stockholders of the bank being acquired
with the value they relinquished and found that the
value of the claims bank stockholders obtained was
significantly greater than their previously held claims
on the bank.2 In fact, the ratio at which the holding
company stock was exchanged for that of the bank
was so favorable to the bank’s shareholders that a
careful examination of possible earnings differentials
between the firms was not necessary.
The market
values of the stocks have been an adequate (albeit
imperfect) gauge of this differential.
A much closer
look, however, is necessary when trying to explain
why BHCs have been willing to pay such premiums.
Piper’s original study and his later work with
Weiss shifted emphasis from the valuation
of the
stocks traded in the acquisition to the profitability
of
acquisitions to the stockholders of the parent holding
company. Each study concluded that, due to the high
premiums paid for bank stock, acquisitions
have
failed to improve the earnings of the holding companies.
The shift from valuation to profitability,
however, begs questions concerning the manner in
which owners value a given income stream.
A valuation framework that includes a constant
discount rate, adjusted for expectations
of risk,
rules out any possibility that the manner in which
1 Piper’s analysis of bank acquisitions [3]
and his subsequent work
with Weiss [4] clearly recognized than an alteration in ownership
positions
resulted from acquisitions.
Their consideration
of this
point was an important shift from concentration
on bank performance alone.

Robert

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK

2 Piper’s results showed that the market value of BHC stock received
exceeded the book value of the bank by 30%. In his later study with
Weiss, comparing the claims on holding company earnings received
by former stockholders of the acquired bank relative to earnings of
the bank stock, the median premium was found to be 16%.

OF RICHMOND

9

earnings are valued may change in response to the
operating policies and earnings performance of the
firm.
While such an assumption greatly simplifies
the analysis, it ignores a potentially important source
of the valuation disparity underlying the incentives
for the acquisition of commercial banks by BHCs:
i.e., changes in owners’ discount rates due to their
evaluation of risk.3
Valuation
via a Risk-Adjusted
Discount
Rate
The most widely used model for valuing risky, multiperiod earnings streams is the risk-adjusted discount
rate.
Through this technique, a measure of the
magnitude of the earnings flow, usually expected
value, is evaluated by a discount rate that takes into
account the rate of time preference and some measure

the investors’ measure of risk following the acquisition or the manner in which a given change in risk
affects the capitalization rate. Since the individuals
making the valuation comparisons have not changed,
it seems reasonable to assume, for simplicity, that
the exact form of the capitalization rate function in
terms of risk does not change.4
As long as an increase (decrease)
in the measure of risk faced by
owners is reflected in an increase (decrease)
in the
discount factor used to evaluate an earnings stream,
emphasis may be placed on the expected behavior of
risk under alternative situations.
If it is assumed
that a detected difference in the measure of risk
results in different capitalization rates, valuation disparities may be sought by comparing alternative
earnings performances and measures
of risk.

of the degree of riskiness associated with an earnings
flow.
Individuals must make estimates of future
earnings and apply a subjectively determined discount
rate to them.
Since this approach is not based on any specific
assumption as to what constitutes the risk associated
with expected earnings, it has serious shortcomings.
Unless a specific, dynamic measure of risk is incorporated within the framework, the detection of
differences in valuation due to differences in risk is
not possible. In order to measure the effect on valuation of an acquisition, knowledge of the pre-acquisition capitalization rate and the response of that rate
to the acquisition is required.
It is entirely possible
that the addition of another income stream with a
different discount rate may alter owners’ capitalization rates in subsequent periods.
A specific present
value of earnings
cannot,
however, be derived without information concerning
owners’ attitudes toward risk and the trade-off they
are willing to make between risk and return.
This
becomes a serious stumbling block in the search for
the motivation for acquisition, but it need not be insurmountable.
There are two distinct sets of investors involved in any acquisition: the independent
bank shareholders and those of the BHC.
Each
group obtains a claim on an earnings stream that is
somewhat altered from its previous holdings.
The
acquisition is beneficial if the capitalized value of the
transformed earnings stream is greater than that the
stockholders
perceive
would have been available
through holding on to their existing claims.
A
change in this valuation through a shift in capitalization rates, then, could result from either a shift in

the bank stock, usually in
ratio, is then determined
power of the buyer and
competition in the buying

3 If owners are concerned with more than just the mean level of
earnings, and a measure of risk does affect their discount factor(s),
a reduction in the risk associated with a given earnings distribution
will reduce the discount factor if owners are risk averse and result
in a higher valuation of those earnings.
Comparison
of earnings
means alone will not detect this disparity.

4 For a discussion of the dependence of the form of an individual’s
capitalization
rate function in the presence of uncertainty
on the
form
of his underlying
utility
function,
see Douglas
Vickers,
Chapters 2 and 4.
Vickers
suggests that the capitalization
rate
function is nonlinear in the coefficient
of variation of net income
and concave upward.

10

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

The Basis for Acquisition
The suggested
approach for analysis of the economic basis for acquisition is founded upon the premise that the firm that
engages in banking determines its operating and organizational structure on the basis of optimization of
the economic value of the ownership of the firm,
i.e., the owners’ wealth position.
Owners’ wealth is
perceived as the capitalized value of the expected
future earnings stream.
Since the objective to be
maximized is in value terms, specific attention must
be given to its components.
In general
terms,
value, profit, and the owners' capitalization rate
(which is adjusted for considerations of time preference and risk).
The essential consideration of the analysis for bank
owners is the difference in the valuation of their
ownership position if they (a) continue their present
structure of organization and production as opposed
to (b) trading their bank stock for partial interest
in a holding company.
For BHC owners, it is the
difference in the valuation of their ownership claims
perceived through (a) the present BHC structure
and (b) the expanded organization created through
acquisition.
The first disparity provides an incentive
for the present bank owners to make the transaction,
while the second provides the incentive for holding
company acquisition activity.
The purchase price of

JULY/AUGUST

1975

terms of a stock-exchange
by the relative bargaining
sellers and the degree of
and selling of bank equity.

Regardless

of the measure

of risk utilized, accep-

tance of the proposition that owners’ conceptions of
risk may change over time and may be altered by
specific actions of the firm has important implications
for the risk-adjusted
discount rate and may significantly alter valuation of the earnings accruing to
owners.
The provision of a dynamic capitalization
rate (p), which is a function of the risk associated
with a given earnings stream, provides a valuation
framework that considers both the earnings experience and the behavior of the discounting function
used by owners in evaluating their ownership position. In present value terms,

where V is the present value of the future earnings
equity in period t, pt is the owners’ capitalization
rate5 applied to earnings in period t, and H is the
economic horizon of ownership in the firm. In this
framework, valuation disparities may be sought for
both sets of participants in the transaction-the
bank
stockholder and the shareholder of the BHC.
Bank owners will have an incentive to trade their
stock only if a valuation disparity is established between the capitalized value of the stream of bank
profits accruing to owners through continued ownership in the bank and that realizable from gaining an
ownership interest in the holding company. Specifically, they have an incentive to trade their stock for
that of a holding company only if:

where VB is the ownership

valuation

of the bank,

company obtainable by bank owners, and VHC is the
total ownership valuation of the BHC.
The bank
owners’ valuation of their portion of holding company
earnings will, in this case, be greater than their
valuation of expected bank earnings.
Previous findbeen large enough to assure the necessary
in valuation of earnings.

disparity

5 The owners’ discount rata in period t (pt) may be further specified: pt =
(1+r1)
(1+r2)
. . . (1+rt-1)
(1+rt),
where rt is
dependent on the owners’ time preference pattern i (assumed constant) and an appropriate
measure of risk, e.g., the coefficient
of
variation of net income (Vn),
which is the standard deviation of
the probability
distribution of expected net incomes divided by the
mean of the probability distribution function.
p, then, may also be
expressed as functionally
dependent on these same variables:

Similarly, an incentive for holding company acquisitions exists on the demand side for bank stock only
if present company stockholders view a similar valuation disparity.
In particular, only if the acquisition
of a commercial bank improves the capitalized value
of owners’ earnings over that perceived without acquisition will present owners move to acquire the
bank ; i.e., only if:

where (VHC) ~B is the ownership valuation of the
holding company without acquiring the bank, ß is
the proportion of ownership interest in the company
is the capitalized value of the earnings stream of the
holding company including the proposed acquired
bank. Even though their percentage ownership (ß)
falls with an acquisition, present owners may still
benefit if earnings increase significantly or if risk,
and, therefore, the vector of owners’ capitalization
rates following acquisition

is reduced.

For an acquisition to occur, then, both valuation
disparities must exist.
The present owners of an
independent bank and of a holding company will
agree to participate in an exchange of stock if each
group perceives a positive shift in its ownership valuation resulting from the transaction.
Equations (2)
and (3) represent the conditions necessary for consummation of an acquisition agreement.
Of particular interest is the fact that nowhere in (3) is there
any implication that the bank’s profitability must be
increased following acquisition.
If the owners are
assumed to maximize the value of their ownership
position, they will be concerned with the valuation of
their share of the holding company rather than that
of a single subsidiary. It may be that factors such as
the structure of organization, production considerations, and costs that optimize the economic valuation
of the consolidated company’s earnings stream conflict with the attainment of the maximization of one
of its subsidiaries’ returns.
Such an hypothesis is
consistent with empirical results heretofore obtained
that suggest that bank profitability is not significantly
enhanced through holding company affiliation.
In fact, if it is recognized that the acquisition of a
bank may have a positive impact on the level and/or
stability of earnings of other subsidiaries within a
BHC organization, consideration of changes in bank
profitability is an inadequate tool with which to ex-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

11

amine the economic basis for acquisition.
It is essential that the analysis consider both the earnings ex-

result could also occur, however, through a reduction
in owners’ risk with equivalent or improved future

perience and associated expectations of risk of each
ownership position. An examination of both levels of
alternative earnings and the manner in which those
earnings are valued is necessary before conclusions
may be reached.

earnings. Any motivation for acquisition arising from
the combination of reduced earnings and reduced

Empirical

Investigation

The argument

risk or increased earnings and increased risk following acquisition is entirely dependent on trade-offs
between risk and return within individual preference
functions. Since such information is not known, substantiation
of our hypothesis must rest on those
cases where movements in risk and return do not
have conflicting effects on valuation.

presented

to this point suggests that a valuation framework, by
taking expectations of future earnings and a measure
of risk associated with the pattern of future earnings
into account, can explain the economic motivation of
both independent bank owners and BHC shareholders to negotiate an acquisition.
The remainder of
this article investigates the gains accruing to holding
company shareholders through acquisition.
A BHC’s acquisition of a commercial bank involves
the dilution of its present ownership in an attempt
to increase
the present value of the ownership
retained.
This result is assured if the original BHC

The tendency in recent experience for multi-bank:
holding companies to acquire numerous commercial
banks, and at relatively short intervals,
seriously
complicates the empirical task of isolating the impact
of individual bank acquisitions
on BHC earnings
performance.
The only feasible empirical test has to
involve the entire acquisition program of the holding
company and concerns itself with whether or not
the policy of expansion through acquisition improves
the value of earnings accruing to owners.

owners believe that following the acquisition their
earnings will be greater, with equivalent or reduced
risk, than they would be without acquisition.
This

Benefits of acquisition may be explored by a direct
comparison of the trends in the earnings experienced

Table

EARNINGS

PERFORMANCES

IN LEAD BANK

*Significant
Note:
Sources:

12

at the

Standard
Moody’s

.20

THROUGH

FOLLOWING

I

BHC AND CONTINUED

REORGANIZATION

level.

deviations

in parentheses.

Bank and Finance Manual

and

internal

records

ECONOMIC

of seven

Federal

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

OWNERSHIP

AND ACQUISITION

Reserve

1975

Banks.

over the post-acquisition period under the alternative
ownership positions.
The appropriate comparison
involves the values of earnings accruing to those
owners holding stock in a BHC at the time of acquisition-for
they are the individuals contemplating the
transaction.
A major problem with this approach is
that data that would reveal the earnings of a holding
company had the acquisition not taken place are not
available.
Fortunately, however, this technique is applicable
to one group of acquisitions within the last decade.
Many of the acquisitions in the late 1960’s were fa-

Table

II

COEFFICIENTS OF VARIATION OF GROWTH RATES
OF NET INCOME THROUGH BHC AND LEAD BANK
FOLLOWING ACQUISITION

cilitated by the simple reorganization of an independent bank into another corporate form that was permitted to acquire additional banks.
This was especially prevalent in states
branching were prohibited

where mergers and/or
or limited by state law.

The corporate transformation often involved nothing
more than the exchange of new BHC stock for the
stock of an existing bank. At the same time, additional BHC shares were issued in exchange for the
stock of one or more additional banks.
In other
words, the lead bank owners frequently traded 100%
ownership in the bank for less than total ownership in
an expanded banking organization.
Comparison of
the earnings trend of that specific set of owners following reorganization
with what they would have
realized had they retained their independent ownership in the bank provides a measure of the potential
benefits to owners via acquisition through a BHC
organization.
Such a comparison is possible making use of previous empirical results that have shown commercial
bank profitability to be relatively unaffected by acquisition.
This comparison was chosen because it provides the only appropriate data available that examine
the incentives for acquisition.
Reports of Income
exist for the years following acquisition for the holding company on a consolidated basis and for the lead
bank separately.
These provide the basis for the
direct comparisons of owners’ valuation.
There are
no comparable data available that reveal the earnings
performance of a multi-bank holding company excluding any particular acquired bank.
Benefits accruing to original owners of these lead banks through
reorganization and acquisition, then, may be used as a
subsample to shed light on the economic incentives
present in the larger population of BHC acquisitions.
If bank earnings are not affected by acquisition, the
appropriate comparison to be made is between the
trends of the ownership valuations of (a) the original
bank owners’ equity interest in the bank and (b) the
6 The
Ware

reader is referred
for a good sample

to Fischer, Lawrence,
of this literature.

Piper,

Talley.

and

*Significant
Note:
Sources:

at the

Standard

.05 level.

deviations

in parentheses.

See table I.

interest obtained by that same group of owners in
the expanded BHC organization
through an exchange of stock.
This comparison, requiring complete knowledge of
stock splits, dividends, and dilution of owners’ percentage share of total earnings, began the year immediately preceding the acquisition and continued for
at least five years after the time of acquisition.7 The
sample was restricted to those reorganizations
occurring between 1962 and 1969, with all but three
occurring since 1966. The average levels of earnings,
average growth rates in earnings, and coefficients of
variation of levels and growth rates of earnings (as
measures of owners’ risk) were computed over the
period for both of the ownership alternatives.
These
sample data permit mean difference tests to be performed on the arguments of the valuation function.
7 The sample consisted of 18 BHCs and associated lead banks located
in seven Federal Reserve Districts with data available for at least
five years after reorganization.
The lead banks, all members of the
Federal Reserve System, ranged in deposit size from approximately
$100 million to $650 million at the time of reorganization.
The
necessary information
was available for the sixth year for seven of
these holding companies and banks and was incorporated
into the
analysis.
Earnings accruing to original owners were computed by
multiplying total net income of the firm by their percentage ownership in the firm for each year.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK

OF RICHMOND

13

Table

EARNINGS

*Significant
**Significant
Notes:

.10 level.

at the

.05 level.

Standard
Sixth

Sources:

at the

deviations

year

See Table

data

based

THROUGH

YEAR

in parentheses.
on seven BHCs and associated

lead

banks.

Other

years

based

on sample

size of

18.

I.

Table I shows that the mean difference in average
annual earnings over the entire post-acquisition period was substantial.
Previous owners of the lead
banks realized an average improvement of $330,978
per year through the reorganization.
This sum was
not statistically significant, however, due largely to
the considerable variance within sizes of firms included in the sample. The growth rates in net income
did display a significant difference, though only at
the .20 level. Specifically, the growth rate in earnings through the BHC was an average of 3.45%
greater per year than would have been the case had
the owners maintained their interest in the bank
alone.
Growth rates may be especially revealing
since they, at least partially, compensate for size
discrepancies within the sample. At the same time
there was no significant difference between coefficients
of variation of net income over the entire
period. The coefficients of variation of growth rates
of income, however, exhibited a significant difference
at the .05 level over the interval.
Specifically, this
measure of risk was substantially reduced
through
the acquisition program, as reflected in Table II.
A comparison of earnings experience over time,
shown in Table III, indicates that holding company
owners
actually
experienced
reduced
earnings
through reorganization
and acquisition in the first
year relative to the experience of the bank alone.
This first-year reduction in earnings appears attributable to the large premiums paid for bank stock.
Each year thereafter, however, earnings are progres14

III

BHC AND LEAD BANK BY INDIVIDUAL

ECONOMIC

sively larger under the BHC structure.
This trend
is also reflected in the difference in growth rates of
earnings.8
In general, therefore, it appears that
earnings for the BHC not only increased faster on
an absolute basis when compared to the bank but
also on a percentage basis, indicating that the difference between the two increases over time.
If owners are aware of this trend, they may willingly accept losses in the first year after acquisition
in order to receive claims on increasingly improved
earnings in later years. If primary interest is placed
on later years by omitting the first year’s results
from the analysis, the inference is altered somewhat.
The average annual difference in net income increases
to $444,784,
while the difference in coefficients of
variation of net income remains slightly negative.
These differences are still not significant, however.
The difference in average income growth rates increases to 5.27%, significant now at the .10 level,
while the difference in coefficients of variation of
income growth rates widened, i.e., became more negative.
This difference remained significant at the
.05 level.
Summary
and Conclusions
Trends
are established within the first few years following acquisition,
therefore, that improve the present value of earnings
flowing to owners relative to that attainable without
8 If BHC earnings are depressed in the immediate post-acquisition
period, the experience of the third and fourth years following
reorganization
are not surprising.
since most of the BHCs in the
sample made additional acquisitions in those years.

REVIEW, JULY/AUGUST

1975

reorganization.

Owners

have experienced

improve-

ments in the level of earnings to which they hold
claims and, apparently, this improvement grows over
time.
In addition, to the extent that the owners’
conception of risk is accurately measured by the
coefficient of variation of income growth rates, risk
is reduced through the acquisition program.
If,
as assumed, this is reflected in lower capitalization
rates associated with the expanded banking organization, a basis for disparity in both the numerator and
is present.

BHCs through acquisition may be questioned.
It
does, however, provide a rational explanation for the
formation of many BHCs that is consistent with the
theory of wealth maximization.

REFERENCES
1. Fischer, Gerald C. Bank Holding Companies.
York: Columbia University Press, 1961.

New

2. Lawrence,
Robert J. The Performance
of Bank
Holding Companies. Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1967.

These results become even more meaningful when
it is realized that earnings streams attained through
a BHC structure may be somewhat depressed by

3. Piper, Thomas R. The Economics of Bank Acquisitions by Registered Bank Holding Companies. Research Report No. 48. Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, March 1971.

subsequent acquisitions during the period of analysis.
This tendency would decrease the difference in earnings performance when comparisons are made over a
short post-acquisition
interval and with firms that
acquired other institutions after the time of the original acquisition.
A note of caution should be injected, however.
The sample used represents a special class and a
very small proportion of the total population of acquisitions taking place. Whether or not measuring
benefits to lead bank owners who formed holding
companies to acquire other firms is representative of
the benefits accruing to stockholders of established

4. Piper, Thomas R. and Steven J. Weiss. “The Profitability of Bank Acquisitions by Multi-Bank Holding
Companies,” New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Sept.-Oct. 1971, pp.
2-12.
5. Talley, Samuel H. The Effect of Holding Company
Acquisitions on Bank Performance.
Staff Economic
Study No. 69. Washington:
Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, 1971.
6. Vickers, Douglas. The Theory of the Firm: Production, Capital, and Finance.
New York:
McGraw
Hill, Inc., 1968.
7. Ware, Robert F. “Performance
of Banks Acquired
by Multi-Bank Holding Companies in Ohio,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
March-April 1973, pp. 19-28.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK

OF RICHMOND

15