View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE CLASSICALCONCEPT OF THE
LENDER OF LAST RESORT
Within the past ten years, a series of events has
raised questions about the soundness of modern financial systems and reawakened interest in what is
known among monetary
last resort

economists

responsibilities

as the lender of

of the central

bank.

The

concept of lender of last resort relates to the question
of how a central

bank should react

to a financial

crisis and involves, in particular, a prescription for
central bank action to preserve the liquidity of the
financial system and to forestall financial panic. The
term itself originated in the writings of Walter Bagehot, a leading British writer in banking and finance
in the second half of the 19th century.
But the idea
behind it is of an earlier vintage and several wellspecified prescriptions
for central bank action to
prevent panic can be found, in particular, in the
copious literature centering around the problems of
the Bank of England in the period 1797 to 1844.
Among the more dramatic
have

revived

function

squeeze

1970

associated

most recently,

crunch

in the commercial

of last

National Bank.

paper

authorities

the

market
crisis,

and ultimate

in

and,

demise

of

In each of these cases, the

Reserve

provoked

the following interrelated

resort

of 1966,

with the Penn-Central
the distress

actions of the Federal
latory

in the lender

have been the credit

credit

Franklin

interest

of recent events which

and other bank regu-

discussion

centering

on

issues.

1. What is the appropriate response of a central bank
in times of financial crisis? Should it try to prevent
or forestall an initial bank failure that might trigger a
panic? Or should it act only to prevent the primary
failure from spreading to other institutions?
These
alternative responses correspond to two contrasting
views of the duty of the lender of last resort.
The
first holds that the central bank’s job is to prevent
the occurrence of shocks or at least minimize their
initial impact on the financial system. A second view
is that the lender of last resort exists not to prevent
shocks, but rather to minimize the adverse repercussions of such shocks either by insulating the sound
institutions from the distress of the unsound ones or
by insuring that the banking system is sufficiently
strong and resilient to absorb shocks.
2. Is the lender
to the individual
ing system as
extend to other

of last resort’s primary responsibility
bank or to the market, i.e., the banka whole?
Does this responsibility
sectors of the financial system?
ECONOMIC

3. How and on what terms should the lender of last
resort make aid available? Via open market operations? Emergency loans through the discount window? If the latter, should a penalty rate be charged?
4. Is the central bank’s crisis-averting
function in
conflict with its monetary-control
function?
Can the
bank effectively act as an unconstrained
last-resort
lender within a policy framework emphasizing stable
monetary growth?
5. What is the overriding objective of the lender of
last resort?
To prevent bank failures per se? To
arrest a massive forced sale of assets and the consequent collapse of asset values? To insure that financial institutions will be able to meet their loan commitments?
Or to prevent panic-induced reductions in
the money stock?
6. How has the central bank’s lender of last resort
function been influenced by (1) the availability of
deposit insurance and (2) the FDIC’s procedure in
handling bank failures?

The current debate over these issues has been
confined to a rather esoteric circle of professional
experts.
It has not produced-nor
will it likely
produce-anything
like the rich literature generated
by the running debate over similar issues in 19th
century England.
For that matter, it appears to
have been carried on with little in the way of reference to this earlier literature.
One result is that the
lender of last resort concept itself appears to have
lost some of the clarity and precision of its original
formulation, which embodied a specific set of policy
rules and precepts. The term “lender of last resort”
has been bandied about freely but it is clear that the
meaning it now conveys varies, and perhaps widely,
from user to user, In particular, the term has not
always been used to convey the sense intended by its
classical framers.
It should be noted at the outset that the pristine
notion of lender of last resort emerged as a prescription for central bank action in an English banking and
monetary
the U.S.

system that differed markedly

from that in

in the second half of the 20th century.

one thing, the U.S.,

unlike

19th century

For

Britain,

is

no longer on the gold standard,

the last effective link

between

supply

gold and

severed in 1968.
removes

the

one constraint

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

money

Departure

having

been

from the gold standard

on the lender of last resort,

namely the necessity of protecting the gold reserve
and preserving the gold convertibility of paper currency at a fixed rate of exchange.
A second difference between the two financial systems was created
in the 1930’s by the introduction of Federal deposit

especially relevant today. The first concerns a possible conflict between the central bank’s responsi-

insurance,

stable framework of monetary growth, it must exercise a moderate and continued restraint on the rate

an innovation

that now protects

banking system and most depositors.

the U.S.

Deposit insur-

ance has removed a chief cause of panics and bank
runs, namely loss of public confidence in the banking
system’s

ability

to convert

demand

deposits

into

cash. Consequently, there is now less danger of the
recurrence of old-fashioned cash drains, i.e., those
massive, panic-induced withdrawals of coin and currency, which, in fractional reserve banking systems,
used to be a chief source of multiple reductions in the
money stock.
Third, the essentially unit-banking
system in this country, featuring literally thousands
of banks operating in market areas limited geographically, contrasts with the incipient branch banking
system of late 19th century England, in which a relatively small number of banks were beginning to serve
an essentially national market. A branch system with
its capability of channeling funds quickly from the
financial center to outlying areas may have less need
for last-resort loans than a unit system in which
individual banks or localities lack adequate access to
money market supplies of cash. These and other key
differences in banking and monetary environments
account for many of the variations wrought on the
classical lender of last resort concept in this country.
Given the current interest in the lender of last
resort function, it is useful to examine the original
version of that concept if only for purposes of clarification and historical perspective. This article. therefore, traces the emergence of the classical doctrine of
the lender of last resort in 19th century England and
discusses the content of that doctrine.
The first
section of the article extracts from the writings of
leading 19th century banking theorists the basic
tenets of the classical doctrine.
These tenets are
then listed in the second and concluding section.
NINETEENTH CENTURY VIEWS OF THE DUTIES
OF THE LENDER OF LAST RESORT
Henry

Thornton

The principal

architects

of the

classical lender of last resort doctrine were Henry
Thornton, who wrote at the beginning of the nineteenth century, and Walter Bagehot, whose chief
writings appeared during the third quarter of the
century.
In his 1802 classic, The Paper Credit of
Great Britain, Thornton expounded on many issues
relating to central banking, but four in particular are

bility as controller

of the money supply and its func-

tion as lender of last resort.
To the extent that the
central bank bears the responsibility for providing a

of monetary

expansion.

But

coping

with unusual

liquidity strains through exercise of the lender of
last resort function calls for abandonment
of this
restraint and relinquishing
control over monetary
growth. Hence, some banking specialists have noted
an apparent conflict between these two central banking objectives.
Thornton, however, saw no inconsistency

between

a policy of stable monetary growth and the sort of
action required to deal with liquidity crises.
In the
foliowing passage, which Joseph Schumpeter
has
called the Magna Charta of central banking, Thornton distinguishes between the long-run target growth
path of the money stock and temporary emergency
deviations from the path. The proper policy of the
Bank of England, Thornton says, is
To limit the total amount of paper issued, and to
resort for this purpose, whenever the temptation to
borrow is strong, to some effectual principle of
restriction;
in no case, however, materially to diminish the sum in circulation, but to let it vibrate
only within certain limits; to afford a slow and
cautious extension of it, as the general trade of the
kingdom enlarges itself; to allow of some special,
though temporary, increase in the event of any
extraordinary
alarm or difficulty,
as the best
means of preventing a great demand at home for
guineas*
and to; lean to the side of diminution in
exchanges of gold going abroad, and of the general
exchanges continuing long unfavourable; this seems
to be the true policy of the directors of an institution circumstanced like that of the Bank of England.
To suffer either the solicitations
of merchants, or the wishes of government, to determine
the measure of the bank issues, is unquestionably to
adopt a very false principle of conduct.
[2 ; 259]

Thus, to Thornton, the main responsibility of the
central bank was to regulate the money stock so that
it expands at a steady pace roughly comparable to the
long-term trend growth rate of output. But the bank
must also counter those severe specie drains that periodically threatened to deplete its gold reserve and
force suspension of convertibility.
These drains were
of two types: (1) external or foreign, composed of
exports of gold to cover an adverse balance of payments in the country’s international accounts and (2)
internal, consisting of panic-induced increases in the
quantity of gold held by domestic residents. External
drains call for a restrictive policy. In the case of a
*Thornton
is here referring
the guinea being the name
England at the time.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

to the public’s demand for
for the standard gold coin

gold coin.
in use in

3

panic and internal drain, however, the bank should be
prepared temporarily to expand sharply its note issue
and its loans in order to satisfy the public’s demand
for liquidity. There need be no conflict between the
monetary control and lender of last resort functions,
however, since the first refers to the long run and
the second to temporary periods of emergency.
If
the central bank, in its role as lender of last resort,
responds
crisis,
quently,

appropriately

the panic

to the threat

will be averted

the deviation

of a liquidity

quickly.

of the money

Conse-

stock from

its

long-run target path will be small, both in magnitude
and duration.
The second issue considered

by Thornton

concerns

the extent of the lender of last resort’s responsibility
to individual banks as opposed to the banking system
as a whole. Are these responsibilities strongly interrelated? Are banks so interdependent that the failure
of one would endanger ail the others? Is it therefore
necessary that the lender prevent the failure of even
unsound banks, i.e., are rescue operations necessary
to preserve the stability of the payments mechanism?
Thornton’s answer is as follows:
It is by no means intended to imply, that it would
become the Bank of England to relieve every distress which the rashness of country banks may
bring upon them: the bank, by doing this, might encourage their improvidence. There seems to be a
medium at which a public bank should aim in
granting aid to inferior establishments, and which
it must often find very difficult to be observed.
The relief should neither be so prompt and liberal
as to exempt those who misconduct their business
from all the natural consequences of their fault,
nor so scanty and slow as deeply to involve the
general interests. These interests, nevertheless, are
sure to be pleaded by every distressed person whose
affairs are large, however indifferent or even
ruinous may be their state. [2 ; 188]
Thornton, in this passage, makes four key points.
First, the lender of last resort’s primary responsibility
is to the market (“the general interests”)
and not to
the individual bank. The central bank has no duty
to sustain particular institutions. Second, he advises
against bail-out operations for banks whose distress
arises from “rashness,” “improvidence,” or “misconduct.”
By subsidizing the risk-bearing
function of
poorly-managed
banks, such rescue operations, he
says, would encourage other banks to take excessive
speculative risks without fear of the consequences.
In
short, individual imprudence should be punished by
losses.
Only if the financial repercussions
of such
punishment threaten to become widespread should
the lender of last resort intervene.
His third point,
however, is that even in this latter case, aid should
be extended sparingly and on relatively unfavorable
terms. Finally, he is skeptical of the claim that eco4

ECONOMIC

nomic welfare is inevitably harmed when a bank fails.
This argument, he notes, would provide every large
bank, no matter how poorly run, with an automatic
justification for aid. He is aware that occasionally
the public interest may be better served by the demise of inefficient banks, i.e., that the resulting improvements in resource allocation may outweigh any
adverse spillover side effects of the failure.
The third issue addressed by Thornton was whether the lender of last resort should try to prevent
shocks to the financial system.
Here Thornton answered in the negative.
The lender of last resort
exists, he said, not to prevent shocks but to minimize
the secondary repercussions following upon shocks.
He argued that a panic could be triggered by any
kind of “alarm,” e.g., rumors of a foreign invasion,
an initial bank failure, etc. The central bank has no
responsibility
for stopping these triggering events.
But it does have a responsibility for arresting the
panic and stopping it from spreading throughout the
system. In his own words,
...Ifany one bank fails, a general run on the
neighboring ones is apt to take place which if not
checked at the beginning by a pouring into the
circulation a large quantity of gold, leads to very
extensive mischief. [2 ; 180]
The proper response, according to Thornton, is not
to stop the initial failure, but instead to pump liquidity into the market.
In Thornton’s view, the actual
occurrence of a widespread panic would be properly
attributable not to the event of the initial bank failure,
but to the failure of the central bank to insulate the
economy from the impact of that event.
In this
regard, he distinguished between the effects of (1)
the closing of an individual bank and (2) policy
errors of the lender of last resort. The closing of an
individual bank, he says, by itself contributes very
little to “general distress” or “general commercial
difficulty.”
By contrast, policy errors of the lender
of last resort create “a general shock to credit” that
“produces Distress through the whole Kingdom.”
[2 ; 287-8, 304-5]
Finally, Thornton identified the paramount objective or primary purpose of the lender of last resort.
Today, opinion varies as to the lender’s ultimate
objective, with all of the following being mentioned:
(1) preventing widespread bank failures, (2) preserving confidence in the banking system, (3) preventing a massive dumping of assets and the consequent collapse of asset values, (4) guarding against
the danger of massive currency withdrawals, and (5)
insuring that banks and other lending institutions
will be able to meet their loan commitments.
Thorn-

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

ton, however,

saw the lender

of last resort’s

over-

riding objective as the prevention of panic-induced
declines in the money stock, declines that might produce depressions in the level of economic activity.
The threat

of a panic, he argued, tends to cause

substantial shifts both in the public’s preferences regarding the forms in which money balances are held
and bankers’ preferences
monetary liabilities-notes

concerning the volume of
and deposits-they
are

willing to create per unit of reserves.
Financial
crises or other alarms shake the public’s confidence in
the ability of the banking system to convert its note
and deposit liabilities into gold.
Consequently, individuals suddenly desire to hold a larger proportion
of their money balances in the form of gold or equally
safe liquid assets such as Bank of England notes.
The rise in the desired cash ratio (i.e., desired gold
holdings as a proportion of other types of money
balances) induces widespread attempts on the part
of the public to convert notes and deposits into gold
or its equivalent. Simultaneously, commercial banks,
finding their solvency threatened, will contract their
note issues sharply in an effort to raise the reserve
ratio. Bankers will want to bolster their reserve ratios
both to meet the likely heavy cash withdrawals and
also to allay public suspicion of financial weakness.
The result of the rise in the currency and reserve
ratios is a contraction in the money stock, unless
the central bank introduces compensating changes in
its note issue.
And if the money stock contracts,
Thornton argued, output and employment will be
adversely affected.
To prevent the onset of depression, therefore, the lender of last resort must temporarily increase its note issue to offset the impact of
the rising currency and reserve ratios on the money
stock. In short, by preventing panic-induced contractions in the money stock, the lender of last resort contributes to the stabilization of real economic activity.
Walter
Bagehot
The classical
lender of last
resort doctrine received its fullest development in the
writings of Walter Bagehot.
In his seminal 1873
volume, Lombard
Street, Bagehot stressed many of
the same points made earlier by Thornton. Following
Thornton, he distinguished between the appropriate
response to internal versus external cash drains. An
internal drain, he said, should be countered by a
policy of lending freely and vigorously so as to erase
all doubt about the availability of bank accommodation. An external drain, however, should be met by a
sharp rise in the central bank’s lending rate, the high
interest rate serving to attract foreign gold and encouraging the retention of domestic gold. This latter

action,

Bagehot

thought,

the nation’s gold reserve,
the monetary base.

was necessary

to protect

i.e., the gold component

of

Thus he stressed that

...the first
duty of the Bank of England was to
protect the ultimate cash of the country, and to
raise the rate of interest so as to protect it. [1 ;
155]
A sufficient gold reserve, of course, was necessary
both for the preservation of the gold standard and for
the maintenance of public confidence in the gold
convertibility
of paper currency.
Regarding public
confidence, he argued that “a panic is sure to be
caused” if the gold reserve falls below “a certain
minimum

which I will call the ‘apprehension

mum.’ ”

[1 ; 156-7]

mini-

It follows that the lender of

last resort should strive to keep its gold reserves
above this critical threshold.
Bagehot thought that a persistent external drain
would trigger an internal drain as the public, observing the diminution of the gold stock, would seek to
convert deposits and country bank notes into gold.
“Unless you can stop the foreign export,” he said,
“you cannot allay the domestic alarm.” In this most
likely case where “periods of internal panic and
external demand for bullion commonly occur together,” the lender of last resort must
...treattwo opposite maladies at once-one requiring stringent remedies, and especially a rapid
rise in the rate of interest; and the other, an alleviative treatment with large and ready loans. [l;
27]
Therefore, “the best remedy . . . when a foreign drain
is added to a domestic drain” is the provision of
“very large loans at very high rates.”
[1; 27, 28]
Here is the origin of the famous Bagehot Rule“lend freely at a high rate.”
Like Thornton,
Bagehot stressed that last-resort
lending should not be a continuous practice but
rather a temporary emergency measure applicable
only in times of banking panics.
And, in perfect
accord with his predecessor, Bagehot argued that if
the central bank responded promptly and vigorously,
the panic would be ended in a few days, by implication an interval not long enough for the money
stock to depart significantly
from its appropriate
long-run growing track.
Bagehot also viewed the lender of last resort as a
primarily macroeconomic concept. The central bank,
he said, bears the responsibility of guaranteeing the
liquidity of the whole economy but not that of particular institutions in the economy.
He prescribed
last-resort lending as a remedy solely for pervasive
general emergencies affecting the entire banking system. He did not prescribe the remedy for isolated

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

5

emergency

situations

a few specific banks.

affecting

an individual bank or

Nor did he intend it to be used

to prevent very large or key banks from failing as a
consequence

of poor management

and inefficiency.

As shown below, he did not think that support

of

such distressed key banks was necessary to forestall
panics. Like Thornton, he emphasized that the task
of the central bank was not to prevent initial failures
but rather to prevent
through the system.

a wave of failures

spreading

Bagehot also followed Thornton in arguing that
the lender of last resort exists not to prevent shocks
but to minimize the secondary repercussions following upon shocks.
His views on this point are contained in his analysis of panics.
A panic, he said,
can be triggered by a variety of exogenous events“a bad harvest, an apprehension of foreign invasion,
a sudden failure of a great firm which everybody
trusted.”
[1; 61] But “no cause is more capable of
producing a panic, perhaps none is so capable, as the
failure of a first-rate joint stock bank in London.”
[1 ; 29]
The shock of this initial failure must be
contained before it gets out of hand, for “in wild
periods of alarm, one failure makes many.”
The
problem is how to “arrest the primary failure” that
causes “the derivative failures.”
Bagehot’s solution,
quoted below, stresses the liberal provision of liquidity to the whole system rather than loans to the
distressed bank.
A panic, in a word, is a species of neuralgia, and
according to the rules of science you must not
starve it. The holders of the cash reserve must be
ready not only to keep it for their own liabilities,
but to advance it most freely for the liabilities of
others. They must lend to merchants. to minor
bankers, to ‘this man and that man,’ whenever the
security is good . . . . The way in which the panic
of 1825 was stopped by advancing money has-been
described in so broad and graphic a way that the
passage has become classical.
‘We lent it,’ said
Mr. Harmon, on behalf of the Bank of England, ‘by
every possible means and in modes we had never
adopted before; we took in stock on security, we
purchased Exchequer bills, we made advances on
Exchequer bills, we not only discounted outright,
but we made advances on the deposit of bills of
exchange to an immense amount, in short, by
every possible means consistent with the safety of
the bank, and we were not on some occasions overnice. Seeing the dreadful state in which the public
were, we rendered every assistance in our power.’
After a day or two of this treatment, the entire
panic subsided, and the ‘City’ was quite calm.
[1 ; 25]
Conspicuously absent is any mention of the need to
channel aid to specific institutions, as would be implied by bail-out operations.
Bagehot’s emphasis is
clearly on aid to the market rather than to the initially distressed bank. He obviously did not think it
necessary to prevent the initial failure at all costs.
6

ECONOMIC

Up to this point, Bagehot has been depicted largely
as a follower or disciple of Thornton.
But Bagehot
did more than just elaborate, refine, and coordinate
Thornton’s
analysis.
He also contributed several
original points that added substance to the lender of
last resort doctrine and advanced it beyond Thornton’s formulation.

At least five of these points de-

serve mention.
First,

Bagehot

distinguished

between

the central

bank’s extending support to the market after a crisis
began and its giving assurance of support in advance
of an impending

crisis.

He argued that the lender

of last resort’s duty did not stop with the actual provision of liquidity in times of crisis, but also involved
making it clear in advance that it would lend freely
in all crises. As he put it,
. . . the public have a right to know whether [the
central bank]-the
holders of our ultimate bank.
reserve-acknowledge
this duty, and are ready to
perform it. [1 ; 85]
This assurance alone, he thought, would dispel uncertainty about and promote confidence in the central
bank’s willingness to act, thus generating a pattern
of stabilizing expectations
that would help avert
future panics.
Second, he advocated that last resort accommodation be made at a penalty rate. Borrowers should
have relief in times of crisis, but they should be prepared to pay a price that implied a stiff penalty. The
central bank has a duty to lend, but it should extract
a high price for its loans.
A penalty rate had the
appeal of distributional equity, it being only fair that
borrowers should pay handsomely for the protection
and security afforded by the lender of last resort.
Distributive justice aside, the penalty rate, Bagehot
claimed, would produce at least three additional beneficial results. First, it would encourage the importation and prevent the exportation of specie, thus protecting the nation’s gold reserve.
It would achieve
this result (1) by attracting short-term capital from
abroad, and (2) by exerting a deflationary influence
on the level of economic activity and domestic prices,
thus improving the external balance of trade. Second,
the high rate of interest would reduce the quantity of
precautionary cash balances that overcautious wealthholders would want to hold. Without the high rate
to deter them, these cashholders might deplete the
central gold reserve. As Bagehot put it, the penalty
rate would serve as “a heavy fine on unreasonable
timidity,” prompting potential cashholders to economize on the nation’s scarce gold reserve.
[1 ; 97] In
this connection, he advocated that the penalty rate be
established

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

Concerning the type of collateral on which the
central bank should lend, Bagehot’s answer was clear.

. . . early in the panic, so that the fine may be paid
early; that no one may borrow out of idle precaution without paying well for it; that the Banking
reserve may be protected as far as possible. [1 ; 97]
Last

and most important,

The Bank should stand ready to lend on any and all

the penalty rate would

provide an incentive for banks to exhaust all market
sources

of liquidity

and even develop new sources

before coming to the central bank.
individual

banks

money management
new channels

to develop

protect

to mobilize existing

system.

that

reliance

recourse

techniques

allocative

liquidity,

of

strengthen

on the central

to the latter’s

the pen-

efficiency

In short, the penalty

the gold reserve,

discourage

better

and the capital market to develop

alty rate would promote
financial

By encouraging

in the

rate would

the free market,
bank, and insure

lending

facilities

was

truly a last resort.
Bagehot’s

analysis,

it should be noted, implies still

another use for the penalty rate, namely that of providing a test of the soundness of distressed borrowers.
A penalty rate set a couple of percentage points above
the market rate on alternative sources of funds would
encourage illiquid banks to turn to the market first.
Success in obtaining accommodation at the market
rate would indicate that lenders judge these borrowers to be a sound risk.
The borrowers and their
assets would pass the market test. On the other hand,
resort to the central bank would tend to indicate
weaknesses in the borrowing institutions.
The banks
may be unable to borrow in the market at the lower
rate.
Fearing default, lenders may demand a risk
premium in excess of the difference between the market and the penal rate.
The risk premium would
force the stockholders of the banks to make a decision
either to close the banks, to arrange a merger with
other banks, or to resort to the central bank’s lending
facility.
Either way, the penalty rate will have provided a test of the banks’ soundness.
Bagehot’s third contribution was his specification
of the types of borrowers the lender of last resort
should accommodate, the kinds of assets it should
lend on, and the criteria it should use to determine
acceptability of those assets. Regarding the types of
borrowers, Bagehot stated that the Bank of England
should be willing to accommodate anyone with good
security.
Last resort loans, he said, should be available “to merchants, to minor bankers, to this man
and that man.” The objective of the central bank in
time of panic is to satisfy the market’s demand for
liquidity.
It makes little difference, said Bagehot,
whether this objective is accomplished via loans to
merchants,

to bankers,

or to whomever.

sound assets,
current

or as he put it, “on every

security,

kind of

or every sort on which money is

ordinarily lent.” Besides the conventionally eligible
bills and government securities, acceptable collateral
should include “all good banking securities,” and
perhaps even “railway debenture stock.” In another
passage he makes the point that the “amount of the
advance is the main consideration

. . . not the nature

of the security on which the advance is made, always
assuming the security to be good.” The basic criterion was
ordinary

the

paper

be indisputably

good

in

or normal

that

times.

The latter qualification

is

important.
It implies that the lender of last resort
should not be afraid to extend loans on assets whose
current market value is temporarily below book value
owing to depression in the securities market.
To summarize, Bagehot felt that few restrictions
should be placed on the types of assets the central
bank might lend on, or the kind of borrowers it might
accommodate.
This position was consistent with his
advocacy of price as opposed to non-price rationing
mechanisms.
He recommended that the central bank
eschew qualitative restraints-eligibility
rules, moral
suasion, administrative discretion and the like-and
instead rely on the penalty rate to ration borrowing.
Fourth, Bagehot provided a precise delineation of
the extent of the lender of last resort’s responsibility
to individual banks as distinguished from the banking
system as a whole.
Concerning the question of
whether this responsibility included assistance to insolvent banks, Bagehot’s answer was an unequivocal
no. The central bank’s duty, he said, is not to rescue
“the ‘unsound’ people” who constitute “a feeble minority.”
Such businesses, he said, “are afraid even
to look frightened for fear their unsoundness may be
detected.”
[1 ; 97]
In short, the job of the central
bank is not to prevent failure at all costs but rather to
confine the impact of such failure to the unsound
institutions alone.
Bagehot meant for his strictures to apply even to
those key banks whose failure, in the absence of
central bank action, could shatter public confidence
and start a falling-dominoes chain-reaction sequence
of financial collapse.
Thus, he acknowledges that if
owing to the defects in its government, one even
of the greater London joint stock banks failed,
there would be an instant suspicion of the whole
system. One terra incognita being seen to be faulty,
every other terra incognita would be suspected. If
the real government of these banks had for years
been known, and if the subsisting banks had been
known not to be ruled by the bad mode of govern-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

7

ment which had ruined the bank that had fallen,
then the ruin of that bank would not be hurtful.
The other banks would be seen to be exempt from
the cause which had destroyed it. But at present
the ruin of one of these great banks would greatly
impair the credit of all. Scarcely any one knows
the precise government of any one; in no case has
that government been described on authority; and
the fall of one by grave misgovernment would be
taken to show that the others might as easily be
misgoverned also. And a tardy disclosure even of
an admirable constitution would not much help
the surviving banks: as it was extracted by necessity, it would be received with suspicion. A skeptical world would say ‘of course they say they are all
perfect now; it would not do for them to say anything else.’ [1 ; 129]
Even in this case, however,
for

appropriate

Bagehot

the central bank

poorly-governed

key banks.

did not think it

to extend

Rather it is “the ‘sound’

people, the people who have good security
who constitute

“the majority

of last resort

function

preted

to mean that unsound
to fail.

to offer”

to be protected.”

lender

permitted

aid to

Instead

The

should not be interbanks

should not be

it implies

that

failure

should not be allowed to spread to sound institutions.
To Bagehot,

the distinction

“no advances
“which

the

indeed

is crucial.

In his words,

need be made”

[central]

Bank

will

on assets

on

ultimately

lose.”

Again, in another passage he offers assurance

that if

the lender of last resort

“should refuse bad bills or

bad securities”

not make the panic really

it “will

To arrest a panic, he says, it is sufficient that

worse.”

the Bank guarantee
vent

merchants

“great majority”

to provide liquidity to the “sol-

and

bankers”

who

of the market.

comprise

that “the alarm of the solvent merchants
will be stayed.”
Finally,

and bankers

[1 ; 97]

Bagehot

warned

against

undue reliance

on the lender of last resort and stressed
strengthen individual
pointed

the

This policy assures

banks.

out, was not meant

prudent bank practices.

the need to

The central

bank, he

to be a substitute

Consistent

for

with his laissez-

faire, free market philosophy, he argued that the basic
strength of the banking system should rest not in the
availability

of last resort accommodation

on the resources
banks.

and soundness

In this connection

but rather

of the individual

he stated that

ECONOMIC

in glowing terms the self-reliant
system of banking,”

char-

composed

“of many banks keeping their own cash reserve, with
the penalty of failure before them if they neglect it.”
[1 ;

160]

Elsewhere

he pointed out that “under a

good system of banking . . . a large number of banks,
each feeling that their credit was at stake in keeping a
good reserve,

probably

would keep one ; if any one

did not, it would be criticized

constantly,

and would

soon lose its standing, and in the end disappear.”
52]

[1 ;

In relying on its own soundness rather than the

resources

of the central

bank,

such

a system,

he

noted, “reduces to a minimum the risk that is caused
by the deposit.
deposited

If the national

in banks in any way, this is the way to

make it safe.”

[1 ; 53]

One final observation
Bagehot’s

rather

should be made concerning

views on the most appropriate

bating instrument
banking

of the central

experts

regard

most effective

bank.

panic-comToday many

open-market

than discount-window

crises.

money can safely be

operations

accommodation

way to deal with systemic

Bagehot

he consistently

liquidity

probably would have agreed.

True,

prescribed

open-

market purchases

loans rather

than

of assets as the means of stopping

panics, but only because

the latter

widely used in his day.

Had the technique

market operations
he undoubtedly

as the

weapon was not
of open

been highly developed at that time,

would have approved

of its use, at

least in those cases where there was no danger of the
gold stock being depleted

by a foreign

most expeditious

means of stopping an internal

Open market

operations

resorting

On

Bagehot

drain.

was for

drain.

these occasions,

to the
cash

are quite consistent

with his dictum “that in time of panic” the central
bank

“must

advance

freely

and vigorously

public . . . on all good banking
largely

as the

Moreover,

public

open market

ask

particular

securities;
them.”

operations

appealed to his preference
cation mechanisms.

for

[1 ;

to the
and as
96-7]

also would have

for market-oriented

allo-

He would have approved of this

policy instrument,

which regulates the total

amount of money but not its allocation

among users

or uses.

. . . we should look at the rest of our banking
system, and try to reduce the demands on the Bank
[of England] as much as we can. The central
machinery being inevitably frail, we should carefully and as much as possible diminish the strain
upon it. [1 ; 36]
8

He described

acter of “the natural

Shortcomings

of the Classical

Concept

of the classical doctrine as a consistent

A picture

and fully self-

contained set of policy rules is not altogether
for

the doctrine

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

does contain

several

correct,

weaknesses.

First,

it offers little in the way of specific guidelines

for distinguishing

sound from unsound institutions.

comings

of that concept.

can be stated succinctly.

The principal
The classical

conclusions
doctrine that

Yet this is precisely the kind of knowledge the lender

emerged during the 19th century was a predominantly

of last resort needs in deciding whether to grant or

market-oriented,

macroeconomic,

withhold aid.

cept that stressed

the following

What criteria

use to determine
solvent?

How

whether

should the central bank
which

Unfortunately

assets

(1) Assuming the central bank acts appropriately
in a crisis, there need be no conflict between its
monetary control and lender of last resort duties.
Prompt and vigorous action will stop any panic
before the money supply has gotten too far off track.

are

the classical

doctrine does not say.
Second,

the classical

doctrine

awareness of the complexities
the condition

of distressed

fact that the activities
vistigation,

shows insufficient

banks.

Neglected

of examination,

is the

auditing,

for a proper

of a bank’s condition-are

necessarily

processes.

vealed as bankrupt

and are allowed

re-

(4) The lender’s duty is a twofold one consisting
first, of lending without stint during actual panics
and second, of acknowledging beforehand its duty to
lend freely in all future panics.

to fail at the

In the real world, however, things are seldom

that simple.
extend

(3) The lender of last resort exists not to prevent
the occurrence but rather to neutralize the impact of
financial shocks. The lender must prevent the spread
of shock waves through the financial system.

In the simplistic classical

view, unsound banks are quickly and irrevocably
outset.

in-

required

time-consuming

(2) The lender of last resort’s responsibility is to
the entire financial system and not to specific institutions.

involved in determining

and analysis-all

determination

In particular,

last-resort

to purchase

it may be necessary

loans to distressed

the time required

make an informed judgment

to

(5) The lender should be willing to advance indiscriminately to any and all sound borrowers on all
sound assets no matter what the type.

banks simply

for the authorities
of the condition

to

of the

(6) In no case should the central bank accommodate unsound borrowers.
The lender’s duty lay in
preventing panics from spreading to the sound institutions, and not in rescuing unsound ones.

banks.
The third and perhaps
of the classical

doctrine

lender of last resort’s
tors and noteholders

most serious
is its failure

shortcoming
to specify the

role in protecting
of failed banks.

the deposi-

(7) All
accommodation would occur at a penalty
rate, i.e., the central bank should rely on price rather
than non-price mechanisms to ration use of its lastresort lending facility.

When a poorly-

managed bank fails there is good reason for the stockholders

and management

to be punished by losses.

But there is less justification
noteholders

assets,

(8) The overriding objective of the lender of last
resort was to prevent panic-induced declines in the
money stock (Thornton)
or at least the gold-reserve
component of the monetary base (Bagehot).

and

of man-

Hence it may be desirable that some

be established

note liabilities
ing

for the depositors

having to bear the consequences

agement errors.
mechanism

to transfer

the deposit and

(9) The basic strength
of the banking system
should rest not on the availability of last resort loans
but on the resources and soundness of individual
banks.
Sound and prudent banking, rather than
reliance on last-resort
accommodation,
is the hallmark of a secure banking system.

of the failed bank, together with matchto other

institutions.

mergers may take time, however.

Such

arranged

During the transi-

tion period the central bank may have to make loans
in order to permit the merger to be accomplished
an orderly fashion.

con-

a bank is solvent or in-

does one decide

good and which bad?

penalty-rate
points:

Unfortunately,

Thomas

there is no recog-

nition of this possible merger-facilitating
central bank in the classical

in

M. Humphrey

role for the

doctrine.
REFERENCES

KEY COMPONENTS OF THE CLASSICAL DOCTRINE
This
classical

article

has sketched

the development

of the

concept of the lender of last resort in 19th

century England and pointed out several of the short-

1.

Bagehot,
Walter.
Lombard
Street.
Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1962.

2.

Thornton, Henry.
An Enquiry
into the Nature and
Effects
of the Paper Credit of Great Britain
(1802).
New York: Rinehart and Company, Inc., 1939.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

Homewood,

9

1974

Financial Highlights:
While

1973

was generally

viewed

as a year of

renewed excitement and somewhat unusual developments in financial markets, by 1974 standards it was
placid. Looking back over the past year at monetary
and fiscal policy and developments
capital markets,
economic

in the money and

one is struck by the intensity

and market

pressures

that

of the

interacted

to

mold 1974 into an unusual year when judged by historical patterns of market behavior.
A few key
developments stand out as singularly characteristic
of 1974.
Pressures in the farm and construction
sectors persisted throughout the year, resulting in
substantially
increased Agency borrowing and restructured patterns of savings flows and mortgage
rate behavior.
Moreover,
continued inflationary
pressures along with soaring short-term market rates
precipitated a shift in investor preference from longto short-term securities.
Prodded upward by monetary policy expectations,
persistent
inflation, and
liquidity pressures, short-term rates exceeded 1973
highs, shifting the patterns of investment behavior
as rate spreads adjusted to market forces.
Monetary Aggregates
M1, currency outside commercial banks plus private demand deposits, measured on an end-month-of-quarter
basis, expanded
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 5.5 percent in the first quarter of 1974.
This increase
represented a nearly 2 percent jump in growth over
the same period a year earlier. Measured on a quarterly average basis, however, M1 expansion slowed
from its pace a year earlier, posting a 5.8 percent in-

ber reversed itself.
For February and March, M1
showed sharp gains of 9.7 and 9.2 percent, respectively.
The pronounced increases in the last two
months of the quarter can be attributed to sizable income tax refunds and a net redemption of maturing
Treasury debt that combined to shift the ownership of
demand deposits from the public to the private sector.
M2, time deposits other than large CD’s plus MI, advanced at a 9.3 percent annual rate in the first quarter
compared to 10.8 percent in the previous
Rapidly
rising bank time and savings
boosted M2 growth throughout the quarter.

quarter.
deposits

Measured on both a quarterly average and endmonth-of-quarter
basis, growth of the narrowly defined money stock (M1) accelerated in the second
quarter. High U. S. money balances held by foreign
official institutions
and foreign commercial banks
accounted for much of the M1 growth.
In April,
the expansion of M1 slowed somewhat from a month
earlier, posting a 6.1 percent annual rate of growth.
Over one-third of this rise was accounted for by the
growth of foreign official and foreign commercial
bank demand balances. By May, when the growth of
money balances had eased considerably, the narrow
money supply expanded only 4.3 percent.
This fig-

Table la

crease.
Although the quarterly average method of
reporting M1 is more nearly comparable with the
measurement of other economic aggregates, the endmonth-of-quarter
basis is a more sensitive indicator
of short-run movements in the money stock. Table Ia
shows quarterly M1 and M2 growth for 1973 and
1974, reported both ways for comparative purposes.
For the remainder of this discussion, however, the
end-month-of-quarter
rates will be used.
As usual the monthly growth rates of M1 showed
wide fluctuation throughout the first 3 months of
1974. In January M1 declined at an annual rate of
2.7 percent as a holiday-related
accumulation
of
foreign bank deposits that had raised M1 in Decem10

ECONOMIC

M:

Annual
rates of growth
the final months of the

Q:

Annual
months

Source:

rates
calculated
of the quarters.

Board

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

of

Governors,

1975

calculated
quarters.
from

from

average

Federal

average

levels

Reserve

in

System.

levels

all

in

three

ure jumped to 9.1 percent in June with transfers of
funds to the oil-exporting
countries distorting the

Table lb

MONETARY

money stock figures temporarily, as demand balances
bulged briefly before funds were passed on to foreign recipients. Over the second quarter, M2 grew at
a fairly rapid 7.7 percent annual rate, substantially

AGGREGATE

GROWTH

RATES

(seasonally adjusted annual rates)

off the pace a year earlier and slightly slower than
the first quarter growth. The time and savings component of the broad money supply grew at nearly
8.6 percent over the period.

While this growth was

slower than in the first quarter, it was still noticeably
rapid given the high level of market rates.
In part because of increased upward pressure on
money market rates in the preceding months, monetary aggregate growth slowed noticeably in the third
quarter.
Growth of the narrow money stock decelerated sharply over the period, showing only a 1.6
percent annual rate advance from July to September.
The slowdown resulted, in part, from a delayed response to sharp increases in interest rates that occurred during the first half of the year.
It also
partly reflected a System attempt to cool the fairly
rapid monetary aggregate expansion that characterized the first half of 1974.
The 1.6 percent third
quarter growth of M1 was down significantly from
the 6 percent rate of expansion experienced in the
first half of the year; and for the first nine months of
1974, M1 averaged a 4.5 percent annual rate of
growth, contrasting rates of expansion of 8.5 and 6.0
percent in 1972 and 1973, respectively.
The broad
money stock also experienced slower expansion in
the third quarter, posting a 4.6 annual growth rate.
Growth of the aggregates picked up gradually in
the fourth quarter from the depressed level of the
previous quarter.
M1 grew in October at a 3.8
percent annual rate.
The decline in interest rates
that began in early October did not exert full influence on M1 until November when the aggregate expanded at a 6.0 percent annual rate. Influenced by a
sharp rise in commercial bank time deposits other
than large CD’s, M2 growth spurted at an 8.3 percent annual rate through October; and in November,
M2 expanded at a 9.3 percent annual rate, the highest
since June.
The expansion of the aggregates that characterized
the first two months of the fourth quarter waned in
December as M1 growth slowed to a 2.1 percent
annual rate. Most of the growth was in the currency
component
with demand deposit balances
little
changed, a condition true of most of the period since
mid-year.
M1 expansion over the second half averaged 2.8 percent, and for the year M1 posted a 4.5
percent annual rate of growth, off 1½ percentage

points from a year earlier. The slowed growth of M1
and commercial bank time deposits other than large
CD’s combined to limit M2 expansion in December
to 2.5 percent, reducing M2 growth for 1974 to 7.1
percent, down from 8.6 percent in 1973.
Another variable that should be mentioned in conjunction with any discussion of monetary aggregates
is the adjusted bank credit proxy (ABCP).
A
complicated
network
of interacting
relationships
exists between M1, M2, and ABCP.
As the total of
all member bank deposits subject to reserve requirements plus nondeposit sources of funds such as Eurodollar borrowings and the proceeds of commercial
paper issued by bank holding companies or other
affiliates, ABCP is a sensitive measure of the volatility of bank liabilities.
The total volume of negotiable and non-negotiable CD’s outstanding, while only
partially included in M2 figures, are totally included
in ABCP and have had a significant impact on money
and credit markets over the past few years.
The growth of large CD’s accelerated sharply in
the first quarter of 1974, growing at a seasonally
adjusted annual rate of 31.2 percent after declining
23 percent in the previous quarter.
The pattern of
growth reflects, in part, the lowering of the marginal
reserve requirement on CD’s from 11 to 8 percent
in December 1973, thus making CD’s a less expensive
source of bank funds. With short-term rates generally falling during the first quarter, banks could
lower their rates and still attract sufficient funds.
Toward the end of the quarter, however, as banks
began to market CD’s aggressively to help meet the
burgeoning demand for credit, rates rose dramatically. The rapid expansion of CD volume triggered

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

11

an expansion

of adjusted

ing substantial

acceleration

bank credit proxy.

Show-

over the previous quarter,

ABCP advanced at a seasonally adjusted annual rate
of 8.1 percent in the January-March
period.
All
components of the proxy, with the exception of Government deposits, showed gains.
Attempting

to continue

to satisfy

the expanding

loan demand, banks competed aggressively for CD’s
throughout the second quarter, to the extent that the
volume of CD’s outstanding grew at an astonishing
92 percent annual rate over the period.
This enor-

businesses have concentrated their short-term
borrowing at commercial banks, while others have preferred to rely on the commercial
paper market.
Although some shifting between these two sources of
funds has occurred in the past, the quantity and
extent of such shifts were unusually large on several
occasions during 1974 in order for businesses to take
advantage of changing interest rate spreads.
Following four consecutive months of sluggish
growth, total loans and investments of commercial

com-

banks expanded rapidly in the first quarter of 1974,
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 17.3 percent.

ponents to account for the 20.0 percent annual rate
of credit proxy growth between April and June.

The composition of bank credit shifted as the quarter
progressed.
Prior to a sharp jump in business loans

The growth of CD’s slowed sharply in the third
quarter from the explosive expansion of the previous
period. High interest rates and a moderation of the
demand for loans precipitated the decline in volume.
Even with the sharp third quarter decline in CD
volume, on a seasonally adjusted basis, the dollar
volume of CD’s outstanding rose more in the first

in March, bank credit growth was buoyed by substantial seasonally adjusted increases in bank holdings of U. S. Treasury securities.
The exceptional
late-quarter surge in business loans, however, provided the major thrust to the rapid expansion of
bank credit.
Much of the surge in business loans
was due, in part, to the need to finance large inventories at higher prices and also to finance some inventory accumulation in anticipation of rising material
prices, raw material shortages, and gloomier inflationary expectations.
Not all components of bank
loans advanced over the first quarter.
For example,
the growth of both real estate loans and consumer
loans continued to slide. The weakness of these latter
two loan categories reflected the declines in the consumer durables and residential construction markets
that accounted for much of the first quarter decline
in real GNP.
As measured by the sum of bank commercial and
industrial loans and nonfinancial commercial paper,
total short-term
business borrowing
surged from
January to March at an average annual rate of 22
percent. The requirements for financing inventories
and accounts receivables played a major role in the
exceptional business credit expansion.
Another fac-

mous surge

combined

with the other

ABCP

nine months of 1974 than in any preceding entire
year. Toward the close of the quarter, the 3 percent
marginal reserve requirement on CD’s with a maturity of more than 4 months was removed in an
effort to encourage banks to lengthen the maturity
of their liabilities.
The decline in the growth of CD volume, along
with slowed demand deposit growth, caused the rate
of growth of ABCP to decelerate to a 6.5 percent
seasonally adjusted annual rate in the third quarter.
Following on the heels of 8.1 and 20.0 percent ABCP
growth rates in the first and second quarters, respectively, this deceleration represented a significant turnaround in credit market behavior.
The adjusted

bank credit proxy expanded

at a 4.5

percent annual rate over the fourth quarter.
October
figures were slightly distorted due to the failure of
Franklin National Bank, which caused a brief inconsistency in the series. For November and December, the credit proxy expanded 6.1 and 7.6 percent,
respectively, resulting in a second half growth rate
of 5.5 percent.
Compared to the first half’s rapid
acceleration of 14.1 percent, the second half figures
represent a significant slowdown.
A decline in the
rate of growth of demand deposits and CD’s precipitated the decelerated credit proxy growth.
Bank Credit and the Money Market
In the market for short-term funds, a combination of circumstances developed that produced an alignment of
lenders and borrowers
somewhat
different
from
established historical patterns.
Traditionally,
certain
12

ECONOMIC

tor that put upward pressure on short-term credit
demands late in the quarter was the increased postponements and cancellations of planned bond issues
in the face of rising long-term rates. By late March,
as increases in the prime rate lagged behind commercial paper rate gains (Chart
1A), the weight of
business credit demand shifted out of the paper
market toward commercial banks.
This surge in
short-term credit demands worked to push rates on
short-term
instruments
toward 1973 peak levels.
During the first quarter most short-term rates moved
in a U-shaped pattern, declining 1¼ percentage
points in the first half of the period, then rising in
the latter half, with little net change over the period.

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

From early April through June, commercial

banks

continued to extend huge amounts of credit, as business loan demand showed continued strength.
The
volume of business loans outstanding advanced at a
23 percent annual rate over the quarter, with total
bank credit expanding only 11.8 percent.
Unsettled
conditions in the commercial paper market, combined
with a favorable spread between the commercial paper
rate and the prime rate in late April and early May
and again at the end of June, pushed the demand for
business loans to record levels, as borrowers withdrew from money and capital markets.
Market reaction to the financial difficulties of two large banks
-one
foreign and one domestic-and
a large public
utility company aggravated the shift of investor interest toward only the highest quality securities.
Borrowers with less than a prime rating found themselves unable to market new commercial paper or to
roll over existing debt. The new emphasis on quality
instruments worked to increase the already heavy
demand for business loans, precipitating sharp increases in the prime rate during the quarter.
Commercial banks raised their prime lending rates in ten
¼ percentage

point steps to a record level of 11.75

percent by late June.
A key factor contributing to
the prime rate increases was the need for banks to
raise offering rates on CD’s to obtain funds to cover
their burgeoning loan demands. Rates on most other
private short-term
debt instruments
also surged
sharply upward and by the end of the quarter most
short-term rates stood at record levels. Firm monetary policy, continued intense inflationary expectations, and the historically high level of business loan
demand combined to push rates up further.
The
news of isolated instances of liquidity problems also
aroused tensions throughout the short-term market.
For the period, the Federal funds rate rose over 2½
percentage points to close the quarter at nearly 12
percent (Chart lB), while the 3-month commercial
paper rate jumped 2¾ percentage points and ended
June at 25 basis points above the prime rate.
Conditions in the money market quieted somewhat
in the third quarter.
Bank credit expansion eased
considerably, expanding at only a 5.6 percent annual
rate compared to an 11.8 percent advance the previous quarter. Banks sold off heavy amounts of U. S.
Treasury securities during the quarter, while their
other investment holdings remained relatively stable.
The major factor influencing the slowed growth of
bank credit was a sharp fall in business loan demand.
On a seasonally adjusted basis, the volume of business loans rose less than 1 percent in September,
following a 21 percent gain in July and August. For

the quarter as a whole, business loans grew at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 14.2 percent, which,
though high by historical standards, was 10 percentage points off the growth rate for the first six months
of the year. A shift of borrowers out of the bank
credit market into the commercial paper market, as
paper rates fell below the 12 percent prime rate, nurtured the slowed business loan growth. Most private
short-term rates rose sharply at the beginning of the
third quarter as concern over inflation, firm monetary
policy, and the continued strong demand for funds
permeated short-term credit markets. In September,
however, several developments effected a dramatic
turnaround in rates.
First, the Federal funds rate
began to decline, indicating to market participants
that an easing of monetary policy was in progress.
Second, a reduction in the marginal reserve requirement on large CD’s of more than four months matur-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

13

ity was interpreted by the market as another sign of
an easing in policy.
Third, the excessively strong

After auctioning

$1.5 billion of tax anticipation

bills

business loan demand eased as the spread between the

(TABS)
on February 26, the Treasury next came to
market with a $4 billion new cash borrowing in late

paper rate and the prime rate returned to a more tra-

March, consisting

ditional alignment.

pation bills and $1.5 billion Z-year 8 percent

Reflecting

the

continuing

decline

in

short-term

market rates, the lagged response of bank prime
rates, and generally stringent bank lending policies,
total loans and investments at commercial banks were
unchanged in October and expanded at only a 4
percent annual rate in November.
The growth of
business loans continued to decline through November, as many prime borrowers shifted their interest
to the short-term securities markets to take advantage
of the favorable

spread between short rates and the

prime rate. Business loans grew at about a 6 percent
rate over the September-November
period, well
below the 14 percent third quarter expansion.
U. S. Government
and Agency Markets
In addition to the impact of corporate and municipal borrowers on long-term credit markets, the U. S. Treasury also had a substantial influence on market behavior during 1974.
The financial needs of the
Treasury in any given period are dictated by the
excess of current Federal expenditures over current
Federal

revenues.

Also, the Treasury

retire those previously-issued
maturity during the period.

must refund or

securities

that

reach

Early in 1974, the deficit for the fiscal year ending
in July was forecast to be in the $4 to $6 billion
range, with spending of about $273 billion and revenues in the neighborhood of $268 billion.
By May,
however, the budget deficit prediction was down to
between $3 and $4 billion with spending reduced to
just over $269 billion and receipts at $266 billion as
budget cuts accompanied the fight against inflation.
The final Federal budget deficit for fiscal 1974 was
$3.5 billion, substantially
cit a year earlier.

14

below the $14.4 billion defi-

ECONOMIC

of $2.5 billion of 85-day tax anticinotes.

The financing was well received, at least partly reflecting commercial banks’ ability to pay for the bills
by crediting

Treasury

Tax

and Loan

Accounts.

As the second quarter opened in April a cautious
atmosphere prevailed in the Treasury market, partially due to relatively

firm conditions

market, the announcement

in the money

of a sizable Agency offer-

ing, and the close proximity of the May Treasury
refunding. Terms of the refunding were designed to
refinance $5.6 billion of publicly held securities maturing May 15.
$4.1 billion would be retired by
auctioning three issues to the public.
$2 billion of
25½-month
notes and $1.75 billion of 4½-year notes
would carry a coupon rate of 8¾ percent, while $300
million of 25-year bonds would be placed at 8½
percent. The Treasury would use available cash balances to cover the remaining maturing issues.
The
terms of the refunding aroused substantial interest,
especially from the small investor in view of the
$1,000 minimum denomination.
In addition, the
Treasury announced plans to increase its weekly bill
auction by $200 million each week for five weeks
beginning mid-May.
Toward the end of the second quarter the Government securities market benefited from the growing
concern of market participants over liquidity problems that had recently come to light. Many participants were eager to shift part of their portfolios into
the “safer” Treasury securities ; thus, an $800 million
strip auction of bills to raise cash in late May was
well received by both large and small investors.
For
most of the remainder of the second quarter the
Treasury market was shielded from the inflationary
worries plaguing other sectors of the securities markets. Investors, including foreign official institutions
from oil producing countries, showed a strong preference for Treasury obligations, especially bills. By the
last half of June, S-month bill rates averaged a record
4 percentage points below rates on CD’s or commercial paper of the same maturity, considerably above
the normal 1 percentage point spread (Chart 1). A
substantial part of the demand for bills came from
foreign central banks, but continued interest from
individuals who found yields on bills more attractive
than those on alternative investments also contributed
to the strong demand.
The high level of short-term rates, bulging business
loan demand, and deteriorating
conditions in the

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

capital markets caused apprehension in the long-term
Treasury market at the start of the third quarter.
Yields on Treasury issues soared in August as new
bill offerings bulged and gloomy price statistics were
reported.
As the Treasury approached the August
refunding, the announced terms attracted intense interest from the small investor.
The offering was
structured to refund $4.3 billion of publicly held
notes and to provide $100 million to cover part of
the Treasury’s short-term cash needs. At the same
time the Treasury increased the regular weekly bill
auction of 3- and 6-month issues by $200 million to
$4.7 billion. Terms of the refunding included $2.25
billion of 9 percent 33-month notes, $1.75 billion of
9 percent 6-year notes, and $400 million of 8%
percent bonds maturing in 1999. Interest in the two
note issues, particularly from the small investor, was
unprecedented.
Noncompetitive
allotments for the
two issues accounted for 55 percent of the total
volume. Both the 9 percent rate and the availability
of $1,000 minimum denominations attracted the small
investor. Not since November 1970 when the Treasury started using the auction technique for note
issues had the noncompetitive
subscription been so
large.
Demand for the final $400 million of bonds
was dampened by a rapid rise in wholesale price
figures and the issue was sold at a price below par
to yield 8.63 percent.
As additional bills came to
market later in August, dealer inventories bulged and
bill rates soared until early September.
As the
month progressed, the continued strength of noncompetitive tenders at the weekly bill auctions combined with easing in the money market and continued
strong demand for bills by foreign official institutions
and other investors with a preference for high quality
issues to drive rates on auctioned bills well below
those on outstanding issues of comparable maturity.
By the end of September rates on 3-month bills had
dropped to the lowest level since May 1973 (Chart
1B).
Yields on Treasury coupon securities also fell
at the close of the third quarter in response to the
sharp declines in the short end of the market.
After a small upswing in short-term bill rates in
October, rates on most Treasury issues moved irregularly downward over the fourth quarter.
Even
though issue supplies were abundant throughout the
quarter, market expectations
of a broad decline in
interest rates buoyed investor sentiment, and demand
was generally strong.
Declines in both the Federal
funds and discount rates reinforced this belief.
Heavy financing activity dominated the Government securities market during the fourth quarter.

The Treasury raised $1 billion in new cash at the
regular weekly bill auctions in October.
In addition
the Treasury undertook a $2.5 billion cash refinancing program, auctioning $1.5 billion of 7½-month
bills and $1 billion of 4½-year notes at 7.93 and 7.89
percent, respectively.
Late in October the terms of
the quarterly refunding were announced with three
issues making up the package.
Treasury plans included refunding $4.3 billion publicly held notes and
bonds maturing November 15 and raising $550 million cash by auctioning $2.5 billion of 3-year notes,
$1.75 billion of 7-year notes, and $600 million of 8½
percent 25-year bonds.
The 3-year notes were restricted to a $5,000 minimum denomination in an
effort to reduce pressure
on thrift institutions.
Strong market interest in all three issues resulted in
yields of 7.85, 7.82, and 8.21 percent, respectively.
In addition to the refunding package and the extra
$200 million of bills auctioned weekly, the Treasury
came to market with bills on three occasions in
November.
$2.25 billion of April 1975 tax anticipation bills were priced to yield 7.43 percent ; $1 billion
worth of additions to outstanding short-term bill
series were offered November 21; and $1.25 billion
of June 1975 tax anticipation bills were auctioned at
7.52 percent.
Banks were not permitted to credit
their Treasury Tax and Loan Accounts as payment
for purchases in either of the TAB auctions.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

15

Throughout

the second quarter,

credit

agencies

marketed

bonds

with varying

the major

over $2 billion

maturities,

for the farming sector continued.

farm

worth

of

as strong

support

Although

investor

reaction was somewhat mixed around mid-quarter,
most issues sold out well.
On the housing front,
support operations picked up over the quarter as
evidence
mounted.

of withdrawals
from thrift institutions
Federal home loan banks came to market

with a total of $3.5 billion of bonds in two separate
issues.
Of this total, $2.5 billion was new capital,
and both issues met enthusiastic
A factor that must be dealt with in any discussion
of the Government

securities

market,

especially

in a

year such as 1974, is the market for Federal Agency
securities.
Although active in the past, the Agency
market blossomed during 1974 as pressures in a wide
variety of market sectors, particularly
the farming
and construction markets, caused increased demand
for Agency funds to be used in support operations.
As investors became nervous over the liquidity problems that came to light around mid-year, Agency
issues began to look even more attractive because of
their high quality status.
The market for Agencies
benefited from and reacted to many of the same pressures and stimuli that affected the Government market throughout the year.
A good tone or moderate
investor resistance in either market permeated the
other, so the prevailing pressures will not be reiterated in this discussion.
It is helpful, however, in
understanding
the impact of Agency financings to
look at some specific issues that came to market.
The Agency market in the first quarter was dominated by farm and mortgage related issues.
There
were offerings by three major farm credit agencies
during January and February.
Federal Land Banks
came to market with $300 million of 5-year bonds at
7.10 percent, $360 million 30-month bonds at 7.05
percent, and $389 million 5½-year
7.15 percent
bonds.
The Banks for Cooperatives
and Federal
Intermediate
Credit banks marketed bond issues of
$556 million and $753 million, respectively, in January and came back to the market in March with
$251 million and $608 million bond issues. Around
mid-quarter,
a $600 million Federal
home loan
bank issue was offered and met with enthusiastic
investor response.
The offering represented a net
pay down of $650 million of debt, reflecting reduced
dependence of S&L’s on Federal home loan banks as
a source of advance funds as the growth of savings
deposits resumed and mortgage demand slackened.
16

ECONOMIC

The
Federal
National
(FNMA)
also marketed

investor

response.

Mortgage
Association
a large package totaling

$1.5 billion and consisting of three separate debenture offerings. $750 million of this was to raise new
cash as the mortgage market tightened.
At the start of the third quarter, in late July, the
Federal Financing Bank held its first auction, selling
$1.5 billion of 8-month bills at 8.05 percent. Bearing
all the characteristics of Treasury bills, the bills were
auctioned with full tax and loan account privileges.
By coordinating the borrowing activities of several
Federal agencies, the Financing Bank hoped to reduce
financing costs.
The proceeds of this first offering
repaid $1.4 billion of advances from the Treasury
and covered some current advances to the agencies.
In addition to this marketing, farm credit and
housing related agencies continued their high level of
offerings throughout the third quarter.
In July
Federal Land Banks, Federal
home loan banks,
Banks for Cooperatives, and Federal Intermediate
Credit Banks came to market with $3.6 billion worth
of bonds with varying maturities, mostly intermediate-term.
During August a whopping $4.6 billion
housing and farm credit related debt was marketed.
Expectations of future heavy financings coupled with
already large dealer inventories and the surge in
Treasury yields weakened the Agency market somewhat during August.
Prices of Agency securities
moved up at the close of the third quarter with new
issues generally well received.
Housing and farm
credit agencies continued their heavy volume of offerings, with the Federal home loan banks raising $1.7
billion of new capital.
The Agency market was characterized
by strong
investor interest and declining yields during the
fourth quarter. Both housing and farm credit agencies continued to come to market with large offerings,
some of which were to raise new cash. On November 26, the Federal National Mortgage Association
sold $1.2 billion of debentures in a three-part pack-

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

age, raising

$500

million new cash.

Yields

ranged

from 7.50 percent on the debentures maturing September 1976 to 7.95 percent on the 9¾-year
debentures.

The

three offerings
bonds varying
yielding

Federal

home loan banks marketed

over the quarter : (1) $1.5 billion of
in maturity from 2 to 7 years and

an average 8.63 percent ; (2)

$500

million

of 2¼-year 8.05 percent bonds and $500 million of
5-year 8.15 percent bonds, representing a net redemption of $216 million ; and (3) $500 million of 5-year
bonds for new cash at a yield of 7.5 percent.
The farm credit agencies came to market in each
month of the quarter with a total of $4.2 billion consisting of several issues of varying maturities.
The
offerings raised about $580 million of new cash, were
generally well received, and carried steadily lower
yields as the quarter progressed.
Corporate and Municipal Securities
The volume
of securities offered by corporations during 1974 far
exceeded the 1973 level (Chart 3).
The average
monthly volume of new corporate debt securities
issued during 1974 was $2,111 million ; for all of
1973, new issue volume averaged $1,075 million per
month. On the other hand, the average monthly voltime in the tax-exempt sector was only slightly more
expansive at $1,879 million than in 1973 when the
average monthly offering was $1,865 million.

short-term rates, caused many investors to resist all
but the most creditworthy issues, greatly increasing
spreads

between

yields

on high

and

low quality

bonds. Rates on lower quality debt rose to unacceptable levels and issues were postponed or canceled.
Corporations
as conditions

turned increasingly to banks for funds
in the market deteriorated at the close

of the second quarter. In addition, new stock issues
dropped to the lowest seasonally adjusted quarterly
volume since 1968, with stock prices falling to their
lowest point in 3 years.
In contrast, the volume of
tax-exempt
issues remained high throughout most
of the quarter with good investor reception in spite
of higher interest rates. A record-sized New York
City bond issue artifically inflated municipal bond
volume figures for the second quarter, but even without this issue, volume remained near a record high
level. Late in the quarter some cutbacks in offerings
were announced as the available rate terms exceeded
statutory ceilings.
Corporate bond volume dropped only slightly over
the third quarter.
The new issue volume that was
lost through postponement of utility issues was offset
by 10 floating-rate note offerings.
A newcomer to
the capital market, these notes offered a fixed return
for a specific period after which the rate was equal

Yields on long-term bonds increased on balance
over the first quarter of 1974. By the end of March,
yields in the corporate sector were at their highest
level in more than 3 years.
Seeking to finance
capital outlays and improve liquidity ratios, corporations placed heavy demands on the capital market
during the first quarter, issuing $5.9 billion in debt.
Offerings
would have been even higher if some
scheduled issues had not been canceled as interest
rates rose in late February and March.
State and
local governments were also heavy borrowers in the
first quarter, although the $6.2 billion of municipal
bonds offered was down somewhat from the large
fourth quarter 1973 volume.
Rates on municipals
did not rise as noticeably as corporate rates.
As
sharp price rises pushed individuals into higher tax
brackets, tax-exempt
issues became more popular
thereby holding rates down.
Capital market new issue volume remained high
into the second quarter.
Yields were up 70 to 90
basis points, with the sharpest gains experienced in
June.
After showing continued strong investor demand in the early part of the quarter, the long-term
market firmed around mid-May.
A large public
utility’s liquidity problems, combined with rising
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

17

new issue volume was up only slightly over the previous quarter

at $5.9

billion.

fairly steady over the quarter,

Investor

interest

with selectively

was
better

response to the high quality issues.
Equity markets improved gradually and irregularly
from the start of the fourth quarter through midNovember.
The downward slide in the Dow Jones
index that began the third week in November

ended

with the index closing December 6 at 577.50, its
lowest level in 12 years.
A steady improvement in
the index followed and by year-end it was above 600
at 602.16.
The cost of equity funds remained relatively high, however, so no dramatic upsurge in stock
issuance occurred.
Thrift
Institutions
and the
Over the first quarter, thrift

to the 3-month Treasury bill rate plus a premium.
The notes offered good call protection along with
periodic redemption opportunities at par after a set
period of time.
Throughout all of the quarter, long-term market
participants showed preferred interest in high-quality,
intermediate-term
credit issues. Volume in the taxexempt market dropped off sharply through September as a large number of issues were postponed because rate ceilings precluded acceptance of any bids.
Yields in both sectors of the capital markets rose, on
balance, over the quarter.
Buffeted by the ill winds
of inflation and investor pessimism, the equity market
skidded through the third quarter as uncertainty over
the future course of the economy continued to pervade investor outlooks.
Stock prices fell nearly 25
percent over the quarter with the volume of margin
credit outstanding moving down to the lowest point
since 1971.

Mortgage
institution

Market
deposits

continued to grow at a moderate pace. Deposits at
savings and loan associations and mutual savings
banks grew at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of
8.7 percent between December and March, essentially
the same rate of gain as in the previous 3-month
period. Higher yielding certificate deposits accounted
for all the deposit gains as passbook account balances remained substantially below early 1973 peaks.
Early in the quarter, during January and February,
thrifts were able to decrease their debt and increase
their liquid asset holdings, thus halting a year-long
downswing in mortgage commitments
outstanding.
As market rates began to rise sharply in March, net
inflows of savings slackened and borrowing from the
Federal home loan banks picked up.
The higher
interest rates on market instruments attracted individual savers, as indicated by the expansion in the
number of noncompetitive
tenders at the weekly
Treasury bill auctions.
The volume of such tenders
rose to its highest level since 1970.
Net mortgage debt formation remained near the
reduced rate of the previous quarter when measured

In the fourth quarter tax-exempt yields rose on
net while corporate yields fell (Chart 4). The Bond
Buyer 20-bond index reached a record 7.15 percent
for the week of December 13 before declining slightly
by year-end.
A lack of demand for tax exempts by
institutional
investors
and a net decline in tax
exempts at weekly reporting banks during the quarter
were two factors that contributed to the yield disparities.
Both corporate and municipal bond markets suffered from a congestion of new offerings
throughout the fourth quarter.
Corporate volume
rose to an astounding $8.5 billion while tax-exempt
18

ECONOMIC

* FHLBB series for
Source:

Board

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

of

effective

rate on purchase

Governors,

1975

Federal

of newly

Reserve

built

System.

homes.

on a seasonally
in mortgage

adjusted

holdings

annual basis.
in most

Table III

The increase

of the first

quarter

FEDERAL

reflected a run-off of some of the heavy mortgage
commitments made during the first half of 1973 when
housing demand was quite strong.
The relative

NATIONAL
TOTAL

MORTGAGE

MORTGAGE

ASSOCIATION

ACTIVITY

($ millions)

strength of deposit flows at thrift institutions early
in the quarter helped to cushion mortgage rates from
the impact of sharply rising market rates. In recognition of the eventual rise in mortgage rates, however,
ceiling rates on FHA and VA mortgages were raised
¼ percentage point to 8½ percent in April.
Reflecting the continued rise in interest rates on
most market instruments, deposit growth at nonbank
thrift institutions slowed sharply during the second
quarter.
Total deposits at savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks grew at a seasonally
adjusted annual rate of 4.2 percent from April to
June. Mutual savings banks bore most of the burden
of slowed deposit expansion, experiencing only a 1
percent deposit expansion over the quarter and a net
deposit outflow during May.
Under pressures of
disintermediation,
savings and loans covered their
mortgage commitments by borrowing from the Federal home loan banks, reducing their liquid asset
holdings, and tapping established credit lines at commercial banks.
Net mortgage debt formation at thrift institutions,
however, rose substantially over the second quarter
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 9.9 percent,
reflecting the eased money market conditions and
strong deposit flows of the first quarter.
The rise
in mortgage debt formation was also spurred by
direct and indirect financing from Federally sponsored credit agencies.
The advance in mortgage
lending was accompanied by rising interest rates.
The average effective rate on conventional mortgages,
as reported by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board,
climbed to a record 8.85 percent by the end of the
second quarter.
To align FHA and VA mortgages
with the prevailing market, ceiling rates on such
mortgages were raised in two steps from 8½ percent
in April to 9 percent in early July.
Following the trend established in the second quarter, thrift institution deposit growth decelerated further in the third quarter.
Slowing to a seasonally
adjusted annual rate of 2.6 percent, deposit growth
was down 1½ percentage points from the rate of
deposit expansion in the second quarter.
Such factors as the keen interest in the Treasury’s August
refunding, the initially well-received
new floatingrate securities, purchases of money market mutual
funds, a decline in personal savings, and the continued high level of market interest rates combined

Source:

Board

of

Governors,

Federal

Reserve

to aggravate declining deposit flows.

System.

Mutual savings

bank deposits grew more slowly than deposits of
S&L’s. For the g-month period ending in September,
MSB deposits expanded at a seasonally adjusted
annual rate of 2.2 percent, while S&L deposits grew
at a 6.4 percent rate.
Although below the growth
experienced in the final half of 1973, thrift institution
deposits showed more rapid growth through the first
three quarters of 1974 than during the periods of
slow deposit growth in 1966 and 1969.
Moreover,
the base of deposits is currently more than double
that in either 1966 or 1969. The third quarter level
of deposits at savings and loans stood at nearly $240
billion compared to $110 billion in 1966 and $134
billion in 1969.
Another factor to be considered,
however, is that the level of mortgage commitments
at S&L’s ranged around $12 billion through the first
9 months of 1974, against only $2 billion in 1966 and
$4 billion in 1969. Even with the substantial deceleration in the growth of mortgage holdings over the
third quarter, it still exceeded the growth of deposits
over the same period. To finance the lending thrifts
borrowed heavily from Federal home loan banks.
Interest rates well below late summer and early
fall highs precipitated increased savings inflows at
thrift institutions throughout the fourth quarter. Preliminary data indicate that total thrift institution
deposits closed the year at $341.1 billion on a seasonally adjusted basis, with the fourth quarter posting
the sharpest rate of expansion.
The tone of the
mortgage market improved as the fourth quarter
progressed ; however, net mortgage debt formation
continued to slacken throughout the quarter with no
apparent upswing in commitments evident.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

B. Gayle Ennis
19

FORECASTS 1975
Will the “Year of the Hare” Outrun the Hounds?
The

process

of economic

forecasting

misunderstood

and often maligned

large.

year

Each

Richmond

compiles

the

Federal

various

is usually

by the public at
Reserve

forecasts

Bank

of

of the econ-

omy’s performance for the coming year. These forecasts, published by leading business and academic
economists,
future.

are

not really

Professional

attempts

forecasters

to foresee

the

can only evaluate

the implications of current trends, and-given
certain assumptions about future events-extend
these
trends into the future.
If unforeseen events occur,
the “prediction” does not come about, and, unfortunately for the forecasters, the one certainty in forecasting is the unforeseen events always occur. The
economic forecast of the 1974 economy could not have
incorporated the effect of a Presidential resignation.
Even astrologers missed on that one. Nor could the
economist have been expected to foresee another
relatively poor crop year, skyrocketing sugar prices,
and the full extent of the liquidity crises both here
and abroad.
There is a legitimate area for debate about forecasting performances
if the forecasters
seemed to
miss the implications of development that were in
existence when they made their forecasts.
For example, the 1973 forecasts underestimated the rate of
increase of prices in 1974 by a large margin. Viewing 1974 from hindsight, the inflationary trend, which
was well entrenched by the time that the forecasters
made their forecasts, might have been expected to
worsen considerably.
In late 1973 and January 1974,
however, when the forecasts were published, the
economy was slowing; and forecasters expected this
slowing to affect the rate of price increase much more
than it did. Thus, debate about their price predictions should revolve around the question of whether
they were justified in expecting a slowing in prices
based upon their knowledge at the time.
Last year the forecasters underestimated the actual
GNP total for 1974 by only $2.4 billion. They were
considerably off target, however, for real GNP, or
GNP

measured

in constant

1958 dollars.

mate was for a rise in the aggregate
instead, it fell approximately
20

The esti-

of 1.2 percent;

2.1 percent.
ECONOMIC

This year the principal

forecasting

problems have

been whether the economy will recover in 1975, and
if so, when and by how much?

The forecasters

not able to take account of the President’s
package.

Nevertheless,

the

consensus

were

economic
that

was

reached is that recovery can be expected in the
second half of the year.
Some of the reasons that
have been advanced to explain the second half upturn
have been :
1)
2)
3)
4)
5)
6)

A reduction in the rate of inflation,
A decline in the price of oil,
Recovery in productivity,
Recovery in automobile sales,
A rebound in housing starts, and
The inventory correction ending by midyear.

The reduction in the rate of inflation is expected
to have a favorable impact upon the financial sector
of the economy, leading to lower interest rates and
generally easier credit conditions.
Also, it is expected to stop the deterioration
in real spendable
earnings for consumers.
As employers have already
begun to lay off hitherto unproductive workers, output per man-hour should improve substantially, leading to more slowing in price pressures.
Automobile
sales are expected to recover by midyear, if only
because of the aging of the current stock. Housing
starts are expected to begin their recovery in the
spring, because of easier credit conditions and improving real incomes for consumers.
Many forecasters view the current sharp downturn
as an inventory correction.
Fueled by the boom,
many industries, not only automobile and related,
but also consumer durables in general-textiles,
ap
parel, and furniture-and
housing saw increases in
their inventories in 1974 as their unit sales fell off.
The forecasters think that these excess inventories
will have been worked off by the middle of next year,
and firms will cautiously begin to rebuild their stocks.
The consensus of our for-casters is that current
dollar GNP will increase 8.3 percent in 1975. Price
increases, however, are expected to account for the
entire gain, so real GNP is expected to remain approximately the same as it was in 1974.
The con-

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

sensus has the unemployment
rate averaging
percent for the year, an increase of approximately

7.3
1.7

percentage points from the 1974 average.
The consensus of our quarterly forecasters also
shows recovery in the second half.
Gross national
product measured in 1958 dollars is projected to
decline in the first quarter by $1 billion, increase in
the second by $3 billion, followed by increases of $7
billion in the third and $9 billion in the fourth.
This

article

attempts

to convey

and pattern of some 50 forecasts
Research Department of this Bank.

the general

tone

received by the
Not all of them

are comprehensive forecasts, and some incorporate
estimates of future behavior of only a few key economic indicators.

The consensus

of the annual fore-

casts differs from the consensus drawn from the
quarterly forecasts, since different forecasters were
applying their skills.
Since there were varying assumptions in the individual forecasts regarding events
in 1975, the general tone and pattern may not necessarily be based upon the more accurate assumptions,
but only the most prevalent.
This Bank publishes
also a Business Forecasts
booklet,
which is a compilation
of representative
business
forecasts
with names and details
of the
various estimates.
No summary article can begin to
be as informative as the actual forecasts themselves,
so serious readers are urged to look at the individual
forecasts in more detail in Business Forecasts
1975.
The views and opinions set forth in this article
are those of the various forecasters.
No agreement or endorsement
by this Bank is implied.
1974

FORECASTS IN PERSPECTIVE

close to the mark.

However,

far away from the target
increasing

the forecasters

on real GNP.

1.2 percent as they predicted,

dollar measure
have fallen

of output

is currently

by 2.1 percent.

performance

the constant
estimated

with their
made their

deflator,

the rate of price increase.

which is the price

items included in the GNP,

was forecast

The large underestimate

understandable,

index for
to increase

forecasters,

almost unthinkable.

nevertheless,

10.2 per-

of price increases

for double digit inflation

at least until recently,
performance

to

Consistent

6.4 percent during 1974 ; in fact, it increased
cent.

of

in past years, the forecasters

mistake in underestimating
The implicit

were

Instead

is

has been,
But the

worsened their already poor

in predicting

price changes.

The consensus of quarter-by-quarter
forecasts for
1974 was for current dollar GNP to rise by approximately $19.8 billion in the first quarter, $19.0 billion
in the second quarter, $24.5 billion in the third quarter, and $28.1 billion in the fourth.
The realized
increases came to $14.8 billion, $25.0 billion, $32.5
billion, and $7.7 billion for the four quarters, respectively. The quarterly projections for real GNP were
for changes of -$0.9
billion, -$0.5
billion, +$4.0
billion, and +$5.6 billion. For the four 1974 quarters, however, GNP in constant dollars actually fell
by $15.2 billion, $3.4 billion, $4.0 billion, and $19.2
billion, respectively.
Thus, the consensus path forecasted for the economy in 1974 turned out to be inaccurate.
The recovery that was forecast for the

RESULTS
TYPICAL

FOR

1974

FORECAST

AND

FOR

1975

The consensus forecast for 1974 GNP, published
in last year’s March/April ECONOMIC REVIEW called
for an increase of 7.6 percent over 1973. The forecasts for increases in GNP ranged from a low of 5.6
percent to a high of 9.3 percent.
Using the revised
1973 GNP figure of $1,294.9 billion, the consensus
forecast for 1974 GNP would have been $1,393.3
billion and the range, from $1,367.4
billion to
$1,415.3 billion. Increasing prices were predicted to
account for most of the 7.6 percent gain in GNP.
GNP measured in constant dollars, or real GNP,
was expected to rise by only 1.2 percent.
Latest estimates by the Department of Commerce
indicate a 1974 current dollar GNP total of $1,395.7
billion, which is only $2.4 billion higher than the
consensus forecast of business and academic economists.

Historically

speaking,

this forecast

was very

* Figures are constructed from the typical percentagechange forecast for 1975.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

21

second half of 1974 did not materialize.
In fact, the
recession deepened. The rate of price increase, which
the forecasters also expected to improve in the second
half of the year, also worsened.
The consensus 1974 forecast projected personal
consumption expenditures for the year to increase
7.0 percent to $861.0 billion. Current estimates place
personal consumption expenditures much higher, at
$377.1 billion. Gross private domestic investment, on
the other hand, forecast to increase 4.8 percent to
$219.4 billion, actually fell 0.4 percent to $208.3
billion.

Thus,

1974 had considerably

dollar consumption

more current

than the forecasters

expected and

considerably less fixed investment.
One of the principal reasons for the overestimate of investment was
the forecasters’ failure to anticipate the severity of
the decline in construction activity in 1974. Residential structures were expected to decline somewhat,
from the $57.2 billion total in 1973 to $52.1 billion in
1974.
Actually residential
structures totaled only
$45.8 billion.
The seers were relatively accurate in
predicting Government
expenditures,
however, anticipating a 10 percent growth in Government purchases versus an actual increase of 11 percent.
Net
exports were expected to total $5 billion, but they
actually amounted to only $1.2 billion.
All-in-all, it would appear that few kudos should
be extended to last year’s forecasters for their relatively accurate forecast of current dollar GNP, since
the forecasts for the components of GNP were so
far off target.
The GNP estimate came close only
because the errors in estimating the components
tended to offset one another.
Surprisingly,
forecasters’

however,

tendency

and not consistent

with the

to predict a better performance

from the economy in 1974 than the one that actually
materialized,

they predicted the rate of unemployment

quite accurately.
to average

The unemployment

rate, estimated

5.5 percent in 1974, actually averaged

5.6

percent.
In other areas, the 1974 forecasters
the index

of industrial

production.

overestimated
The

index fell

0.9 percent for the year, against

a forecast

percent

before

predicted
actually

gain.

Corporate

to fall slightly
rose

a whopping

billion in dollar terms.
like the implicit
stantially
expected

profits
to $122.4

price

percent

price index,
was sub-

prices

were

they actually

9.5 percent.
22

were

but they
to $140.9

for GNP,

Consumer

6.8 percent;

taxes

billion,

The consumer
deflator

underestimated.
to increase

14.9

of a 1.1

ECONOMIC

rose

1975

Gross

National

FORECASTS

Product

IN BRIEF

Forecasts

for 1975 cur-

rent dollar GNP center around $1,511.5 billion. This
consensus forecast represents an approximate
8.3
percent yearly gain, which is slightly more than the
7.9 percent increase registered in 1974. Prices, however, are expected to increase by 9.1 percent and
thus to account for more than the entire rise in current dollar GNP. GNP measured in constant dollars,
or real GNP, is expected to fall in 1975, but only
0.6 percent, compared to a 2 percent fall in 19.74.
Estimates for increases in current dollar GNP ranged
from a low of 6.2 percent to a high of 10.8 percent.
The typical

quarterly

consensus

this year indicates

that a recovery will begin in the second quarter and
pick up steam throughout the year.
The typical
quarterly estimates indicate that GNP should increase $26.0 billion in the first quarter of 1975 and
$31.0 billion in the second.
The recovery is then
expected to accelerate, and the increases in the third
and fourth quarters are expected to be $38.0 billion
and $40.0 billion, respectively.
Personal consumption expenditures
are expected
to total $963.1 billion for 1975, up 9.8 percent from
1974.
Forecasters
estimate that expenditures
for
durable goods will increase least rapidly, showing an
increase of only 5.3 percent for 1975, but expenditures for nondurables and services will increase 9.1
percent and 11.2 percent, respectively.
The slower
rate of expansion of durable goods expenditures is
expected to stem primarily from a sluggish pickup
in purchases of big-ticket items.
The increases in
nondurables and services expenditures are expected
to reflect price increases, in large measure, but to
allow for some increases in unit sales.
Government purchases of goods and services are
projected to total $341.8 billion. This estimate represents a 10.9 percent increase over the 1974 total,
which is somewhat smaller than the large 11.5 percent gain of the previous year.
The 1975 forecasts
range from increases of 7.5 to 12.2 percent.
Gross private domestic investment is expected to
rise by about 1.4 percent in 1975. This estimate is
somewhat higher than the 0.3 percent decline in
1974.
Both are considerably slower than the 13.0
percent 1973 pace.
Residential construction is expected to decline from the 1974 average,
but only
modestly.
Inventory
investment, however, is expected to decline by more than $10 billion. Business
fixed investment, the only source of relative strength
in the investment sector, is expected to increase 8.2
percent.
The forecasters are predicting a recovery

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

starts closed the year at a 1.0 million unit annual
rate, 1.52 million units in 1975 is a significant improvement.
The recovery is expected to come about
mainly because financing is expected to become easier
and less costly for home buyers.
The easier conditions in the mortgage markets are expected because
the slowing economy is supposed to exert downward
pressure

on interest

rates.

Corporate
Profits
The concensus
forecast indicates that this year should be considerably less profitable for corporations
than 1974, with pretax corporate profits expected to decline 9.7 percent to
$127.3 billion. Considering their forecasts for a 9.1
percent increase in the price deflator, a decrease in
profits of 9.7 percent is a sizable decline.
The 18.4 percent increase in 1974 corporate profits,
however, resulted in large measure from changes in
inventory valuation. In an inflationary period, firms

L

for residential construction in the second half of the
year, so it seems somewhat surprising at first glance
that they are predicting the year’s performance to
average out as a 4 percent decline. It is important to
remember that residential construction at year-end
1974, however, was in considerably worse straits than
the average
1974 figure would indicate.
The forecasters were, as is often the case, less consistent in
their investment forecasts than in any other aggregate. The predictions for residential structures range
from a 14.9 percent decline to a 10.5 percent increase.
Those for business fixed investment range from increases of 3.0 percent to 12.4 percent.
And investment in business inventories, which had a consensus
of $3.0 billion, had a range of forecasts
billion to $10.5 billion.

from -$4.3

Industrial
Production
The typical
forecast
for
the Federal Reserve index of industrial production
(1967=100)
is 123.9, a fall of 0.3 percent, which is
approximately equal to the 1974 performance.
The
index of industrial production ended the year, however, at 118.3, so a 1975 average of 123.9 indicates
some improvement over that level. Anticipated gains
are in the production of heavy machinery, automobiles, and construction related items.
Housing
The construction
industry is expected
to recover somewhat from its dismal 1974 performance. It will remain sluggish, however, compared to
1972 and 1973. Private housing starts, which totaled
2.38 million in 1972, slowed to 2.04 million in 1973
and 1.39 million in 1974, are expected to amount to
1.52 million units in 1975. Considering that housing

can profit on the value of the inventory held, although the profit is largely illusory because firms
must pay the higher price to replace the inventory.
Some industry spokesmen have argued that it is not
fair for them to be taxed on such inventory gains and,
in order to avoid such taxes, have advocated changing to the lifo method of valuing their inventory.
This method-last
in, first out--causes the inventory
valuation to more nearly reflect replacement cost.
Many firms in fact have recently adopted lifo, which
has the effect of lowering their reported or accounting profits by removing the “illusory” inventory
gain.
The forecasters
took this changeover into
account in making their 1975 profit projections, so
the predicted profit drop in 1975 is not as large an
actual turnaround as it might seem to be from a
cursory examination.
The most pessimistic forecaster expects a 25.9 percent profit decline; the most
optimistic a 9.8 percent decline.
Unemployment
Most forecasters
are predicting
a large increase in the rate of unemployment for 1975.
The typical forecast for the year is around 7.3 percent, which is 1.7 percentage points above the 5.6
percent average for 1974.
Most of the projections
had already been completed before the 7.1 percent
figure for December 1974 was announced.
Prices
This year the forecast indicates a slight
decline in the rate of advance of prices. The implicit
GNP deflator, which rose 10.2 percent in 1974, is
expected to increase 9.1 percent. The consumer price
index is also expected to increase less rapidly, 9.5
percent compared to 11.0 percent in 1974.
The
wholesale price index, still expected to increase at

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

23

Federal

Reserve

Bank

of Richmond

P. O. Box 27622
Richmond,
Address

Virginia

Correction

23261

Requested

double-digit rates, is expected to rise by 12.0 percent,
which is considerably less than the 18.9 percent rate
of advance registered in 1974 but still phenomenal.
Net Exports
The nation’s trade position, which
showed a $2.2 billion surplus in 1974, is expected to
be in deficit in 1975 (-$5
billion).
The forecasters,
however, were not able to evaluate President
energy package in making their projections.
estimates for net exports ranged between -$7.8
lion and +$20

Ford’s
The
bil-

billion.

Quarter-by-Quarter
Forecasts
Fifteen
forecasters made quarter-by-quarter
forecasts for 1975. As
indicated by the accompanying
table, these forecasters generally expected a slow economy in the first
half of the year and recovery during the second. To
illustrate the diversity of the quarterly estimates,
however, the typical forecast for real GNP in the
first quarter, a decline of $0.1 billion, was drawn
from forecasts that ranged from a decline of $10.0
billion to a rise of $4 billion. Only two of the fifteen
forecasters predicted two consecutive quarters of negative growth in real GNP, and only one failed to
predict
consistently
increasing
rates
of growth
By the fourth quarter, they
throughout the year.
were predicting

real growth ranging

to $15 billion.
The quarterly consensus for the unemployment rate is considerably different from the
annual consensus.
This divergence results in part
from different expectations on the part of the forecasters, but mainly from the fact that the quarterly
forecasts are less current and the forecasters were
less able to evaluate the November and December
1974 unemployment figures.
Summary
According
to the majority
of forecasters, the economy should begin to recover from its
downturn late in the second quarter of the year.
Moreover, the rate of price increase should subside
throughout the year. Price advances will continue to
be high, by historical standards, but double-digit inflation should be behind us, at least at the consumer
level. Thus, barring further adverse energy developments and poor crop yields, the stage should be set
for a healthy and growing economy in 1976. Thus
1975, which is the “year of the hare” according to
the Chinese calendar, is predicted to be milder than
1974, which was the “year of the tiger.”
Also,, it
will be characterized by improving, albeit sober, expectations on the part of consumers, investors, managers, and workers.
William

from $5 billion

BUSINESS FORECASTS 1975
The Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond is pleased to announce the publication
of Business Forecasts
1975, a compilation of representative business forecasts with
names and details of estimates for the coming year. The booklet is available free
of charge from this Bank.
Please address requests to Bank and Public Relations.
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, P. O. Box 27622, Richmond, Virginia 23261.

24

ECONOMIC

REVIEW, JANUARY/FEBRUARY

1975

E. Cullison