View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICH M ON D

MONTHLY
REVIEW
Antitrust and the New Bank
Holding Company Act
Forecasts 1971
The Supply of Money in the
United States




FEBRUARY

1971

Antitrust and the New Bank Holding
Company Act: Part I

Until 1956, the regulation of bank holding com ­

trust and administrative techniques.

The first part

of controlling

traces the separate development of antitrust and bank
holding company regulation along their different

monopolies and monopolistic tendencies commercial

paths until 1956 and reviews the milestones that led

banking was considered a special case not subject to

to their recent integration.

federal antitrust laws.

pear in the next tw o issues, survey current bank

panies remained substantially independent of anti­
trust enforcement.

For

purposes

A s a matter of fact, the

Subsequent parts, to ap­

Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935 did much to dis­

holding com pany regulations as they apply to

courage competition in commercial banking, deny­

acquisitions of com m ercial banks and entry into

ing to commercial banks many forms of competitive

nonbank businesses.

conduct encouraged in other lines.
W ith the enactment of the Bank Holding Company

The Antitrust Approach to Business Regulation

A ct of 1956, however, the competitive criterion be­
came explicitly relevant to acquisitions of commercial
banks by bank holding companies controlling 25 per­
cent or more of the stock, or the election of a ma­
jority of the directors, of each of two or more banks.
Thereafter, antitrust principles— themselves in pro­
cess of rapid change— became increasingly important
in the regulation of bank holding companies. This
trend was due in part to judicial decisions applying
the antitrust laws to banking generally and in part
to amendments to the banking and bank holding
company laws themselves.
Now, with the passage in December 1970 of farreaching amendments to the Bank H olding Company
Act, a substantial integration of traditional antitrust
policy and bank holding company regulation in the
commercial banking industry has occurred. All types
of bank holding companies, whether they control a
single bank or more than one, and all forms of bank
holding company expansion, as regards both bank­
ing and permissible nonbanking functions, are now
subject to the administrative authority of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System acting
under general guidelines embodying the substance of
antitrust doctrine, as modified to conform to the
particular conditions of the commmercial banking
industry.
This article discusses the background and present
status of bank holding company regulation by anti­
2




Comprehensive antitrust regulation in the United
States dates from the Sherman A ct of 1890.

This

short statute declares unlawful (1 ) every combina­
tion, contract, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or
commerce,

(2 )

every monopolization of trade or

commerce or any part thereof, and (3 ) every at­
tempted

monopolization

or

combination

or

con­

spiracy to monopolize such trade or commerce.
As the Supreme Court has noted, it was
• .. enacted in the era of “ trusts” and of “ combina­
tions” of businesses and of capital organized and
directed to control of the market by suppression of
competition in the marketing of goods and services
the monopolistic tendency of which had become a
matter of public concern. The end sought was the
prevention of restraints to free competition in
business and commercial transactions which tended
to restrict production, raise prices or otherwise
control the market to the detriment of purchasers,
or consumers of goods and services, all of which
had come to be regarded as a special form of public
injury.1

Congress, however, failed to define the character­
istics of illegal restraint of trade and monopolization,
thus leaving to the courts the task of interpreting the
statute in the light of its legislative history and the
particular practices at which it was aimed.
The vague and general nature of the Sherman A ct’s
prohibitions was not the only difficulty confront­
ing Federal courts called upon to construe and ap­
1 A p e x H osiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U .S . 469, 492-493 ( 1 9 4 0 ).

ply them. There was little common law precedent to
guide the courts in shaping the new antitrust policy,

century Supreme Court decisions that fostered a
widespread belief among lawyers that money trans­

and as the Supreme Court soon came to realize, even
this body of law was not relevant to the public issues
raised by Federal antitrust policy.
Faced with the reality that all contracts and com ­

actions in and of themselves were not “ commerce”
subject to Federal jurisdiction under the commerce
clause of the Constitution. These 19th century de­
cisions relied upon an entirely different constitutional

binations among businessmen necessarily restrain the

basis to justify Federal regulation in the areas of

trade of the contracting or combining parties to some

banking and currency.

extent, even if only by restricting their power to deal
with others, and that most such arrangements are
essential to the functioning of a free enterprise
economy, the Supreme Court concluded in 1911 in
its epochal Standard Oil and American Tobacco de­
cisions2 that it had no alternative but to be guided by
the “ rule of reason” in adjudicating alleged anti­
trust violations.

Not all restraints of trade would

be regarded as illegal.

Only restraints deemed “ un­

reasonable” by the courts would be proscribed.
From these beginnings antitrust jurisprudence
evolved gradually on a case-by-case basis over a
period of 60 years, although from time to time the
Sherman A ct has been supplemented by legislation
defining particular forms of illegal practices. Am ong
this legislation was the Clayton Act of 1914,3 focus­
ing particularly upon price discrimination, tying con ­
tracts, exclusive dealing, full line forcing, corporate
stock acquisitions, and interlocking directorates; the
Robinson-Patman A ct of 1936,4 replacing the inef­
fectual price discrimination provisions of the Clayton
A ct with complex provisions applicable to differential
pricing and other discriminatory practices in dis­
tribution

arrangements; and the Celler-Kefauver

Antimerger Act of 1950,5 designed to prevent eco­
nomic concentration by means of corporate mergers,
consolidations, and acquisitions of assets. Even as
regards these last three Acts, however, the substance
of illegal conduct today is largely the result of judicial
interpretation and application of the law and not of
the statutory language itself.
But the body of unique national antitrust law that
emerged gradually between 1890 and 1960 was not
applied to commercial banking generally until the
past decade (although one ill-fated proceeding, dis­
cussed later, was undertaken in 1948).

Partly re­

Commerce, Banking, and Antitrust

Legal au­

thority for Federal antitrust legislation is found in
the commerce clause of the Constitution, investing
Congress with power to “ regulate Commerce with
foreign Nations and among the several States, and
with the Indian tribes. . . .”

Some of the first Su­

preme Court antitrust decisions after 1890 limited
the scope of Federal jurisdiction to cases involving
actual transportation of physical commodities across
state lines. This approach was soon abandoned, how­
ever, and by the end of W orld W ar II it was clear
that any significant effect upon interstate or foreign
commerce attributable to challenged conduct would
sustain antitrust jurisdiction.6
Nevertheless, this turnabout in judicial thinking
did not affect the application of antitrust legislation
to the commercial banking industry, as it (along
with the insurance industry) continued to occupy a
unique, immune status under such legislation.

As

noted, the Supreme Court had ruled on several o c­
casions in the 19th century that transactions in money
did not constitute “ trade or commerce” for con ­
stitutional purposes.

In Paid v. Virginia/ an 1867

decision, the Court concluded that writing a contract
of insurance was not “ commerce,” relying heavily on
its earlier 1850 decision in Nathan v. Louisiana.8
There the Court stated that the “ individual who uses
his money and credit in buying and selling bills of
exchange . . . is not engaged in commerce but in
supplying an instrument of commerce.”
These decisions, which predated the Sherman A ct
by many years, continued in full force and effect
until the 1944 decision in United States v. SouthEastern Underwriters Association ,9 Moreover, they
were supported by a line of decisions dating back
to McCullough v. Maryland,10 which had affirmed

sponsible for the long delay was a succession of 19th

2 Standard Oil Co. v. U .S ., 221 U .S . 1 (1 9 1 1 ); U.S. v. A m erican To­
bacco Com pany, 221 U .S . 106 (1 9 1 1 ).
3 A c t o f October 15, 1914, 38 Stat. 730.

6 See, for example, Mandeville Islands Farm s v. A m erican Crystal
Sugar Co., 334 U .S . 996 (1 9 4 7 ).
7 8 W all. 168

(1 8 6 8 ).

8 8 Howard 73 (1 8 5 0 ).

4 A ct o f June 19, 1936, 49 Stat. 1526.

9 322 U . S. 533 (1 9 4 4 ).

5 A c t o f December 29, 1950, 64 Stat. 1125.

10 4 W heat. 316 (1 8 1 9 ).




3

United States. In that landmark case, as well as in
subsequent decisions upholding the National Bank­

enactment of the Bank Holding Company A ct of
1956.12 Prior to this legislation, bank holding com ­
panies cou ld acquire banks both within the

ing Act of 1864, the Court had not relied upon the

state in which the holding company itself was in­

power of Congress over interstate commerce to sup­

corporated and in other states as well.

port Federal regulation.

Instead, it had grounded

of nonbanking businesses were equally free from

its decision on the Constitutional power of Congress
It

Federal regulation. A s of December 31, 1950, 20
known bank holding companies owned various kinds

was therefore generally assumed that Congress did

of businesses including life insurance, home finance,

not intend commercial banking to be subject to anti­

automobile insurance, fire and marine insurance, and

the constitutionality of the Second Bank of the

to “ coin money and regulate the value thereof.”

trust control.

This assumption found support in the

real estate.

Acquisitions

Although South-Eastern Underwriters

much more detailed, specific legislation applicable to

and Transamerica had clearly established the ap­

commercial banks as represented by the National

plicability of the Sherman and Clayton Acts to bank

Banking Act, the Federal Reserve Act, and existing

holding company acquisitions, in reality not one anti­

state legislation.

trust proceeding had been brought against a bank

W h atever jurisdictional questions m ight have

holding company by the Antitrust Division of the

existed regarding applicability of the Sherman Act

Department of Justice in the entire history of the

to commercial banking were swept away with the

antitrust laws.

1944 South-Eastern

This

to bring its proceeding under the Clayton A ct after

decision reversed the earlier position and indicated
. . the trans­

receiving advice from the Department of Justice that
there was inadequate evidence of abuse of power by

mission of great quantities of money, documents and

Transamerica to support a Sherman A ct charge.13

Underwriters decision.

clearly the Court’s conclusion that

communications across . . . state lines” is interstate
commerce for antitrust purposes.

Beginning as early as 1927, rising concern over
the growth of bank holding companies led to nu­

Soon thereafter, in 1948, the first antitrust pro­
ceeding directed against corporate acquisitions of
stock in commercial banks was instituted under the
Clayton Act by the Board of Governors of the Fed­
eral Reserve System.

In fact, the Board had only decided

The defendant was Trans-

america Corporation, a large diversified bank hold­
ing company based on the W est Coast. The Board’s
complaint alleged that Transamerica controlled 41
percent of all commercial banking offices, 39 percent
of total commercial bank deposits, and about 50 per­
cent of commercial bank loans in the states of A ri­
zona, California, Oregon, Nevada, and Washington,
as a result of systematic and continuous acquisitions
of bank stocks. Although Transamerica successfully
defended the action, the opinion of the United States
Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit held that

merous legislative proposals for their direct regula­
tion.

A t first, the principal thrust of these pro­

posals was to restrict acquisitions of banks by hold­
ing companies. This emphasis was closely related to
the bitter struggle over branch banking that raged in
Congress throughout the decade of the 1920’s. The
Banking A ct of 1933 settled this issue, at least for a
time, by restricting branching by national banks to
the same geographical limits permitted to statechartered banks. A s a result, no national bank
could branch across state lines. Even within the
state where its head office was located, a national
bank could establish branches only if state banks
within such state were authorized to have branches,
and then only within the same geographic areas per­
mitted to the state banks.

commercial banking was, indeed, interstate com ­
merce subject to antitrust regulation.11

Neverthe­

less, the failure of the Board’s antitrust proceeding
in this factual context raised serious questions as to
the probable effectiveness of the antitrust laws in
controlling acquisitions by bank holding companies.
Regulatory Approach of the Bank Holding Com­
pany Act The Transamerica case led directly to
11 Transamerica Corporation v. Board o f G overnors o f the Federal
R eserve S ystem , 206 F.2d 163 (3rd Cir. 1953 ).

4 FRASER
Digitized for


12 12 U .S .C . 1841 et seq., as amended.
13 Fischer, A m erican Banking Structure ( 1 9 6 8 ), p. 279. The Board’s
action was brought under “ old” Section 7 o f the Clayton A c t, as
originally enacted in 1914.
W hile the Board’s case was pending,
Section 7 was extensively revised in 1950 to prohibit any form of
corporate merger, acquisition or consolidation which m ight sub­
stantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any
line o f commerce in any section o f the country.
The amended
statute is entirely different from the earlier revision, which had
been largely emasculated by hostile Supreme Court interpretations
in the 1920’s and 1930's, long before the Transamerica proceeding.
Especially notorious were the decisions in S w ift & Co. v. F .T .C .,
272 U .S . 554 (1 9 2 6 ), and A rrow -H a rt and H egem an Electric Co.
v. F .T .C ., 291 U .S . 587 (1 9 3 4 ).
A changed antitrust environment
and a receptive Supreme Court have made amended Section 7 into
an extrem ely effective deterrent to corporate concentration by mer­
gers or by corporate acquisitions involving competitors and com­
panies standing in the relationship o f actual or potential customer
and supplier, as discussed in Part II o f this article.

But bank holding com panies were under no
similar restrictions and could lawfully acquire banks
— at least insofar as Federal law was concerned—
both within the states where they were located and
in other states as w ell; and they continued to do so
throughout the 1930’s and 1940’s.
In addition,
Transamerica and certain other bank holding com ­
panies began broadening their penetration into non­
banking areas by means of acquisitions, thus bring­
ing extensive banking and nonbanking businesses
under common control.

industrial and manufacturing concerns.
It is
axiomatic that the lender and borrower or potential
borrower should not be dominated or controlled by
the same management. In the exceptional case the
corporate device has been used to gather under one
management many different and varied enterprises
wholly unallied and wholly unrelated to the con­
duct of a banking business. . . . The Board believes,
therefore, that it is necessary in the public interest
and in keeping with sound banking principles that
the activities of bank holding companies be re­
stricted solely to the banking business and that
their activities be regulated, as are the activities of
the banks themselves.16

In 1938, President R oose­

Between 1945 and 1956 a number of bills to bring

velt sent a special message to Congress calling for

bank holding companies under direct Federal con­

creation of a Temporary National Economic Com­

trol were introduced in Congress.

mittee to undertake

flected the Board’s recommendations; others took

. a thorough study of the

Some of these re­

concentration of economic power in American in­

different approaches.

dustry and the effect of that concentration upon the

sion and debate the position of the Board on the

decline of competition.”

question of permissible activities of bank holding

The measure included the

following recommendation:

companies moderated somewhat.

. . . that the Congress enact at this session legisla­
tion that will effectively control the operation of
bank holding companies; prevent holding companies
from acquiring control of any more banks, directly
or indirectly; prevent banks controlled by holding
companies from establishing any more branches;
and make it illegal for a holding company, or any
corporation or enterprise in which it is financially
interested, to borrow from or sell securities to a
bank in which it holds stock.

Roosevelt also recommended that the proposed legis­
lation include a provision “ for the gradual separation
of banks from holding company control or owner­
ship____ ” 14
Congress never seriously considered this so-called
“ death sentence.”

Only two bills to regulate bank

holding companies were introduced between the 1938
special message and the end of W orld W ar II, and
no hearings were held on either of them.15
The Federal Reserve System and Bank Holding
Companies

During these years of discus­

Then in 1943, a new factor was in­

Whereas in 1943

it had advocated that “ the activities of bank holding
companies be restricted solely to the banking busi­
ness,” in 1952 the Board advised the House Com­
mittee on Banking and Currency as follow s:
. . . the Board believes that the principal problems
in the bank holding company field arise from two
circumstances: (1) The unrestricted ability of a
bank holding company group to add to the number
of its banking units, thus making possible the con­
centration of a large portion of the commercial
banking facilities in a particular area under single
control and management; and (2) the combination
under single control of both banks and nonbanking
enterprises, thus permitting departure from the
principle that banking institutions should not en­
gage in businesses w holly unrelated to banking
because of the incompatibility between the business
of banking which involves the lending of other
people’s money and other types of business enter­
prises.17

By 1952, therefore, the Board had moved away
from the view that bank holding companies should
be restricted “ solely” to the business of banking and

The Annual Report of

had adopted the position that banking institutions

the Board of Governors to Congress called attention
to the use of the bank holding company device as a

should not engage in businesses “ wholly unrelated to
banking.” A s will be seen, this was a subtle change,

means of evading restrictions on branch banking,

but an important one, for the future evolution of

and for the first time the Board expressed concern

bank holding company legislation.

troduced into the situation.

over the possible growth of conglomerate bank hold­
ing companies with extensive ownership of nonbank
businesses.

The report stated, in relevant p art:

The Bank Holding Company Act of 1956

As

finally enacted, the Bank Holding Company Act of
1956 accomplished the two objectives sought by the

Accepted rules of law confine the business of banks
to banking and prohibit them from engaging in ex­
traneous businesses such as owning and operating

16 Annual R eport o f the Board o f Governors o f the Federal R eserve
S ystem (1 9 4 3 ), pp. 34-36 (emphasis added).

14 Senate Document N o. 173, 75th Cong., 3rd Sess. (1 9 3 8 ), pp. 8-9.
15 Fischer, Bank Holding Companies (1 9 6 1 ), p . 65.

17 “ Control and Regulation o f Bank Holding Companies,” Hearings
Before the Committee on Banking and Currency, House o f Rep­
resentatives, 82nd Cong., 2d Sess., on H .R . 6504 (1 9 5 2 ), pp. 9-10
(emphasis added).




5

Board.

A “ bank holding company” was defined as

any corporation, business trust, association or similar
organization controlling 25 percent or more of the
voting shares or the election of a majority of di­
rectors of each of two or more banks.

Any com ­

pany meeting this definition was required to divest
its interest in every business other than that of

In determining whether to approve any acquisition
. . . consideration shall be given to the financial
history and condition of the applicant and the
banks concerned; their prospects; the character of
their management; the convenience, needs, and
welfare of the communities and the area concerned,
and the national policy against restra in t o f trade
and undue concentration o f econom ic p ow er and in
fa v o r o f the m aintenance o f com petition in the
field o f banking.™

managing or controlling banks, with certain limited
In addition, every such company was

Although the Senate Banking and Currency Com­

required to register with the Board and to obtain

mittee reported the 1947 bill out favorably, no fur­

its prior approval before acquiring control of more

ther action was taken.

than five percent of the voting shares of any bank.18

“ Declaration of Policy” was introduced in 1950, and

The Federal and state branch banking statutes

the italicized portion quoted above referring to na­

were supplemented by a provision written into the

tional antitrust policy was omitted. In its place were

exceptions.

A similar bill without the

Act prohibiting the Board from approving any ac­

substituted the words “ . . . whether or not the effect

quisition of any interest in any bank outside of the

of such acquisition may be to expand the size and

state in which the acquiring bank holding company

extent of a bank holding company system beyond

maintains its principal place of business or conducts

limits consistent with adequate and sound banking

its principal operations unless specifically authorized
by statute in the acquired bank’s home state.19 Ten

and the public interest. . .

years later this provision was further restricted by
an amendment limiting an acquiring bank holding

guide the Board in ruling upon proposed acquisitions

company to acquisitions within the state in which

same ones incorporated into the 1947 bill, as modi­

the operations

fied in 1950.

of

its banking subsidiaries

were

The criteria finally selected in the 1956 A ct to
of banks by holding companies were substantially the
It turned out, however, that this sub­

principally conducted on the date on which it be­

stitute was unsatisfactory and unworkable in practice,

came a bank holding company or on the date of the

as the Board recognized in a report to Congress in
1958 only two years after the A ct went into effect.

amendment, whichever is later.20
Criteria for Approving Bank Acquisitions

P re­

facing a proposed 1947 bank holding company bill
was a “ Declaration of Policy” asserting, among other
things, that
. . . all of the provisions of this Act shall be in­
terpreted to control the creation and expansion of
bank holding companies; to separate their business
of managing and controlling banks from unrelated
businesses; and g en erally to maintain com petition
am ong banks and to minimize the d anger inherent
in concentration o f econom ic pow er through cen­
tralized control o f banks . . . .

T o further the objectives of this policy declaration,
the following standards were written into the Act to
guide the Board of Governors in considering pro­
posed acquisitions of banks by bank holding com ­
panies :
18 Exceptions to this prohibition were written into the A ct for voting
shares of banks held by a bank (1 ) in a fiduciary capacity, unless
held for the benefit of the shareholders o f the fiduciary bank, (2 )
to collect a debt previously contracted in good faith, provided the
shares were disposed of within two years from the date on which
they were acquired, and (3 ) for additional shares acquired by a
bank holding company in a bank in which such bank holding com­
pany owned or controlled a m ajority o f voting shares prior to such
acquisition.
19 70 Stat. 115

(1 9 5 6 ).

20 80 Stat. 237 (1 9 6 6 ).

6




Commenting on its experience in attempting to dis­
tinguish

permissible from

prohibited

acquisitions

during the first two years, the Board told Con­
gress, in p art:
As guides for the exercise of the Board’s judg­
ment in passing on applications, the first three of
these statutory factors present little difficulty
. . . . To a large extent this is also true of the
fourth factor, relating to the convenience, needs
and welfare of the communities and area con­
cerned. The factor which has given rise to the
greatest difficulty is the fifth— that relating to
whether the proposed transaction would expend
the “ size or extent” of the holding company system
“ beyond limits consistent with adequate and sound
banking, the public interest, and the preservation
of competition in the field of banking.”
The
major problem has been the difficulty of balancing
considerations affecting competition and the public
interest under the fifth factor and those affecting
convenience and needs under the fourth factor.

Even so, and although they were substantially re­
placed in 1966, the 1956 standards at least provided
an interim statutory framework for regulating bank
21 “ Providing for Control and Regulation o f Bank Holding Com­
panies,” Hearings Before the Committee on Banking and Currency,
United States Senate, 80th Cong., 1st Sess. on S. 829 (1 9 4 7 ), p. 9
(em phasis added).

holding company growth during a decade of rapid

relationship

and profound antitrust change.

mercial banking.

N o one, except per­

to

the

traditional

business

of

com ­

haps the Supreme Court, could have said with any
confidence just how much lessening of competition

Congress reacted in 1970 with important new
legislation brin gin g one-bank h olding com panies

would be required for a bank acquisition to violate

under regulation. In addition, antitrust prohibitions
applicable to reciprocity and tying arrangements

either the Sherman or the Clayton Act prior to the
As for conglomerate acquisitions of

were specifically applied to all insured banks and to

nonbank businesses by bank holding companies,

bank holding companies. A t the same time, the pro­

early 1960’s.

antitrust tests simply did not exist at that time.
But by 1966, as a result of a series of Supreme

visions of the Bank Holding Company Act govern­
ing entry by all types of such companies into new

Court decisions beginning with the Philadelphia

areas were substantially changed.

Bank22 opinion in 1963, a different antitrust environ­

1966, antitrust principles governing corporate mer­

Meanwhile, in

ment had come into being. And by 1968, a changed

gers and acquisitions had been substituted for the

economic environment caused hundreds of leading

original five “ banking factor” criteria for approving

commercial banks with billions of dollars in deposits

bank acquisitions written into the Act in 1956.

These or­

The 1966 and 1970 amendments, which have had

the restrictions of the

the effect of substantially merging antitrust and bank

Bank Holding Company Act, immediately began

holding company methods of regulation in the com ­
mercial banking industry, will be discussed in the

to organize one-bank holding companies.
ganizations, exempt from

entering or announcing plans to enter a variety
of new business areas, some having little direct

next two parts of the article, to appear in the March

2- U .S . v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U .S . 321

and April issues of the Monthly Review.
William F. Upshaw




(1 9 6 3 ).

7

FORECASTS 1971
Recovery in Sight?

Forecasting the economy’s performance for the
coming year is a difficult task, and all too often the
forecasts prove to be less accurate than the predictor
may have desired. For example, in the waning
months of 1969, few if any of the seers incorporated
a protracted automobile strike in their projections.
But, as is well known, the strike had widespread and
significant effects upon the economy. The estimates
of the quarter-by-quarter change in G N P had been
reasonably accurate until effects of the General
Motors strike began to appear, but then the fore­
casting error began to mount.
In general, last year’s forecasts might be summed
up as having been accurate with respect to the di­
rection of the economy, if not to the magnitude of
its changes. The only exception to this evaluation is
the rate of price increase, which was expected to
slow. The forecasters thought that slackening con ­
ditions in labor and product markets would be re­
flected in a smaller rate of increase in prices. Some
slowing of price inflation did occur in the second
half of 1970, but the implicit price deflator— the
price index for G N P — in 1970 ended up showing a
higher growth rate than in 1969.
This year forecasters are aware of the possibility
of some major strikes during 1971, and most note
that the threat of a steel strike will affect the
economy even if the strike does not materialize.
Many expect an abatement of inflationary forces
during 1971 notwithstanding the continuation of
strong cost-push pressures. Also, 1971 is expected
to be a year of significant recovery for the construc­
tion industry. The impetus to general economic re­
covery is expected to come from that industry, from
state and local government spending, and from con­
sumer spending. Capital outlays and Federal Gov­
ernment expenditures are expected to contribute
little to economic growth in 1971.
The consensus of forecasts examined in this article
indicates a 1971 G N P of around $1,050 billion.
Based upon current Department of Commerce esti­
mates for 1970 G N P, this figure would represent a
gain of approximately 7.5% , which is greater than
the 4.9% rate in 1970. Economists are predicting a



rather large jump in current dollar G N P during the
first quarter of 1971. This gain is expected to result
partly from consumer purchases of durable goods
deferred from the last quarter of 1970 because of
the automobile strike. Also, adding to the gain will
be business inventory accumulation because of a re­
plenishment of automobile dealer stocks and a build­
up of steel stocks in anticipation of a possible strike
in that industry. None of the forecasters expects an
end to inflation in 1971, but many think that its rate
of growth will be slightly less in the fourth quarter
than in the first.
The 1971 forecasts summarized here represent the
best efforts of business and academic economists
during the autumn and winter of 1970 to predict the
performance of the U. S. economy in 1971. This
article attempts to convey the general tone and pat­
tern of some 50 forecasts reviewed by the Research
Department of this Bank. Not all of them are com ­
prehensive forecasts, and some incorporate estimates
of the future behavior of only a few key economic
indicators. Several represent group rather than in­
dividual efforts.
The views and opinions set forth in this article
are those of the various forecasters. ATo agreement
or endorsement by this Bank is implied.
1970 Forecasts in Perspective A year ago m ost
projections of current dollar G N P for 1970 centered
around $986.5 billion, an increase of 5.8% over 1969.
The forecasts ranged from a low of $966 billion to a
high of $990 billion. After allowing for expected
price increases, the growth of real G N P was pre­
dicted to account for about one-third of the 5.8%
rise. Latest estimates by the Department of Com­
merce indicate a 1970 G N P total of $976.8 billion,
which is well within the range of our forecasters.
Compared to 1969, wrhen the seers had predicted a
G N P of around $912 to $915 billion and the eco­
nomic aggregate actually totaled $931.4 billion, 1970
was a banner year for forecasters. The most fre­
quent estimates for 1970 G N P, however, were a good
deal larger than the actual G N P recorded; so 1970
could only be called a “ banner year” when compared

RESULTS FOR 1970 A N D TYPICAL FORECAST FOR 1971

Unit or
Base

Estimated Forecast
1971*
1970

Percentage
Change
1969/ 1970/
1971
1970

Gross national product _________________________
Personal consumption expenditures _________
Government purchases of goods and services ....
Gross private domestic investment ___________
Net exports of goods and services ___________

$
$
$
$
$

billions
billions
billions
billions
billions

976.8
617.2
220.5
135.4
3.7

1,049.6
663.4
233.9
145.0
4.5

6.9
6.9
3.9
— 3.1

7.4
7.5
6.1
7.1

....

....

New plant and equipment expenditures _________
Change in business inventories ________________
Corporate profits before taxes __________________
New construction put in place _________________

$
$
$
$

billions
billions
billions
billions

80.4
3.2
82.6
91.4

80.8
5.2
89.2
98.7

6.6

0.5

— 9.4
0.5

8.0
8.0

Private housing starts _________________________
Domestic automobile sales _____________________
Rate of unemployment _________________________

millions
millions
per cent

1.43
7.2
5.0

1.70
8.5
5.5

— 2.7
— 14.9

19.0
18.0

Industrial production index _____________________
Wholesale price index __________________________
Consumer price index _________________________
Implicit price deflator __________________________

1957-1959
1957-1959
1957-1959
1958

167.6
117.1
135.3
134.8

173.5
119.4
140.5
139.6

— 3.0
3.6
6.0
5.3

_

—

—

3.6
2.0
4.0
3.6

* F igures are con stru cted from the typical percentage ch ange foreca sted for 1971.

with the poor 1969 performance. If there had been
no automobile strike during the fall, 1970 might
indeed have been a memorable forecasting year.
The consensus of the quarter-by-quarter forecasts
for 1970 was that G N P was expected to rise by ap­
proximately $10 billion during the first quarter.
$10.5 billion in the second, $14 billion in the third,
and $16 billion in the fourth. G N P actually in­
creased $7.8 billion in the first quarter, $11.6 billion
in the second, $14.4 billion in the third, and between
$5 billion and $6 billion in the fourth. The average
predicted increase for the first three quarters of 1970
was $11.5 billion, compared to an actual average
increase of $11.3 billion.
Compared to past per­
formances, therefore, their estimates for current dol­
lar G N P were close indeed.
Unfortunately, the forecasts for G N P measured
in 1958 dollars were less accurate. The predictors
thought that prices would rise from 4 % to 4.5%
over the year. In fact, the implicit price deflator
for G N P rose 5.3% over the course of the year.
In contrast to the predicted moderate slowing from
the 4.7% increase during 1969, the inflation rate
for the year was moderately higher than in 1969.




In any event, G N P measured in 1958 dollars is
now expected to total $724.7 billion for 1970. This
figure represents a decrease of 0.4% from the 1969
total. It might be noted that the forecasters have
rather substantially underestimated the rate of price
increase in each of the last three years.
The estimates of the various components of G N P,
as well as other important economic indicators which
were projected for 1970, generally reflected a ten­
dency to underestimate the slowing of the economy
from its 1969 pace. The rate of unemployment, pre­
dicted to average 4.3% to 4.5% for the year, was
actually 5.5% . Gross private domestic investment
was expected to increase by 4 % to about $145 or
$146 billion ; it actually fell by approximately 3% to
$135.4 billion. The estimators’ over-optimism with
respect to the 1970 performance of construction and
inventory investment accounted for most of their
error in the investment sector.
On the consumer side, 1970 personal consumption
expenditures were expected to be around $614 bil­
lion, but they appear now to have totaled $617.2
billion. Personal consumption was one of the few
aggregate series that was underestim ated. T he
9

underestimate cannot be easily rationalized since d o­
mestic automobile sales, which account for a signi­
ficant proportion of consumer expenditures, were
substantially overestimated. They were expected to
total around 8 million units in 1970, but current
indications are that they will total 7.2 million.
The consumer price index rose over 6 % from its
1969 average, which was higher than the average
forecast of a 5% rise. The forecasters also tended
to underestimate the slowing of the business sector
of the economy. The index of industrial production,
which was predicted to average between 172 and 173
for the year, actually dropped to an average of 167.6.
Corporate profits before taxes dropped 9.4% to
$82.6 billion in 1970— again well below the estimated
range of $90 to $91 billion.
Apparently, almost all of last year’s forecasters
underestimated the extent of the downturn in the
economy and expected inflation to subside more
than it did. W ith respect to the two economic goals
of price stability and full employment, it is un­
fortunate that the predictions were not realized.
THE 1971 FORECASTS IN BRIEF
G ro ss N ation al Product Forecasts for 1971 G N P
are concentrated around $1,050 billion. This esti­
mate represents an approximate 7.4% yearly gain,
somewhat more than the 4.9% advance registered
for 1970. The forecasts range from a low of $1,031
billion to a high of $1,059 billion. Price rises are
expected to account for about half of the anticipated
increase in current dollar G N P. Most of those who
made quarterly forecasts expect G N P, measured at
seasonally adjusted rates, to increase by almost $30
billion during the first quarter, $20 billion in the
second, $17 billion in the third, and $18 billion in
the fourth quarter.
As a rule, personal consumption expenditures are
estimated around $663.5 billion. This represents an
increase of 7.5% , which is somewhat more than the
6.9% increase registered during 1970. Government
purchases of goods and services are expected to total
$234 billion. This increase of approximately 6 % is
again projected to be larger than the 1970 gain of
3.9% . The forecasters expect a further decline in
defense spending, but they think that other Federal
Government expenditures will rise enough to offset
the decline.
State and local government expendi­
tures, on the other hand, are predicted to be one of
the strongest sectors of the economy in the coming
year, mainly because of anticipated improvements
in the capital markets.
Gross private domestic investment is expected to
rise by about 7.1% to $145 billion, which is a sub10FRASER
Digitized for


TYPICAL* QUARTERLY FORECAST FOR 1971
Q u a rte r-b y -Q u a rte r

Ch anges

in

B illio n s

U n le s s O t h e r w is e

of

D o lla r s

N o te d

I

II

III

IV

G ross N ational P rod u ct

29.5

20.0

17.0

18.2

P erson a l C on su m p tion
E xp end itu res

18.5

10.9

12.0

11.0

G ross Private D om estic
In vestm en t

7.1

3.4

0.0

4.0

N et E x p orts

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.2

G overn m en t P u rch ases

3.2

3.0

3.5

3.3

3.9

3.5

3.4

3.1

Im p licit P rice D e fla t o r f

* M edian.
f P ercen ta ge ch anges at annual rates.

stantial improvement over the 3.1% decline during
1970. Plant and equipment spending is projected to
remain almost unchanged, but the overwhelming ma­
jority of forecasters expect construction spending to
show a rapid recovery from the depressed conditions
of the past two years. Construction, therefore, will
combine with increased business inventory invest­
ment to offset the rather lackluster spending pace
predicted for producers’ durable goods.
It should be mentioned that no clear consensus
emerged for investment spending. In the case of
gross private domestic investment, the estimates most
often clustered between 6.6% and 7.4% , but the
median estimate was that it would rise by 7.4% .
Moreover, the estimates ranged widely from a 4.3%
to an 11.4% rate of increase.
Likewise, even
though more plant and equipment spending forecasts
fell in the zero to 1% range than in any other range
of equal magnitude, the median estimate called for
an increase of 2 % .

The predictions ranged widely,

from a decline of 4% to an increase of 7.7% .

Esti­

mates for inventory investment show even less of
a consensus.

It was most often estimated to be be­

tween $5 and $5.5 billion. The median estimate was
$6 billion, however, and the figures cited by our
group of forecasters ranged between $3 billion and
$11.1 billion.
In d u strial Production

M ost predictions call for

the Federal Reserve index of industrial production
(19 57 -5 9= 10 0)
during 1971.

to

average around

173

or

174

This estimate represents a 3.5% in­

crease in the index, compared to the actual decline
of 3% on record for 1970.

The forecasters expect

a recovery in automobile production from the strikeaffected conditions of 1970 as well as an expansion
in the production of other consumer durables.
Several of the forecasters think that the threat
of a steel strike will cause forward building of steel
inventories during the first half of 1971. Many of
them, however, seemed to believe that a major work
stoppage in that industry would be avoided.
Construction The value of new construction put
in place is expected to total $98 to $99 billion in
1971, an increase of around 8 % over 1970. Both
residential and nonresidential construction outlays
are expected to show the effects of the recovery in
the construction industry. Private housing starts are
commonly expected to rise almost 20% to a total of
1.7 million units. Forecasters usually base their pre­
dictions for a recovery in the construction industry
upon greater availability of funds in the mortgage
market combined with pent-up demands engendered
during the last couple of years.
New Plant and Equipment

M ost of the fore­

casts indicate that firms will spend $80.8 billion for
plant and equipment during 1971.

This forecast is

for almost no increase in expenditures over the $80.4
billion totaled in 1970 and represents a substantially
smaller growth rate than the 6.6% recorded during
1970. The low estimate for 1971 seems to stem from
the generally bearish investment plans of private
businesses.
Corporate

Profits

Forecasters

are

far

from

unanimous about the future for corporate profits,
and the predictions for the growth of profits before
taxes range from 5% to 15%.

Most of the esti­

mates, however, are in the neighborhood of 8 %
growth, which would raise the total to $89.2 billion
for the year.

Such a growth of corporate profits

would suggest a sizeable increase over the 9.4% de­
cline which corporate profits recorded in 1970.
Profits after taxes are also expected to show an 8 %
growth rate to $48 billion.

Since most forecasters

estimate either before-tax profits or after-tax profits,
very little can be inferred about their assessment of
corporate tax liabilities in 1971.

Unemployment T h e unem ploym ent rate is pro­
jected to average 5.5% by most of the observers of
the 1971 scene, and the forecasts range between 4.8%
and 6.1% . Since the unemployment rate reached a
high of 6 % in December to average 5% for the year,
our forecasters are predicting some downward move­
ment in the unemployment rate during 1971.
Prices This year nearly all o f our forecasters
are predicting some moderation in the rate of in­
flation. The most common prediction is that the
implicit price deflator for G N P will increase by only
3.6% — well below the 5.2% increase of last year.
The most pessimistic of our forecasters predicts an
an increase of only 4 % . The consumer price index
is generally expected to rise by almost 4 % during
the year. Estimates for the increase in this index
ranged from 3% to 4.6% . Wholesale prices are ex­
pected to increase by a smaller amount, approxi­
mately 2 % , during the year.
Quarterly Forecasts Eleven of our forecasters
made quarter-by-quarter predictions for the 1971
econ om y; the details of their forecasts are sum­
marized in the quarterly table.
They call for a
relatively rapid rate of growth for G N P during the
first quarter attributable mainly to recovery from the
automobile strike, some slight tapering off during the
second and third, and a slight acceleration again
during the fourth quarter. Prices are expected to rise
somewhat less in the fourth quarter than in the other
three, but always at a more moderate annual rate
than in 1970.
Summary The econ om y slow ed considerably
more than anticipated during 1970. This slowing,
however, was accompanied by a faster rate of infla­
tion than had been anticipated. Prices actually ac­
counted for the entire increase in current dollar G N P
during 1970.
The 1971 consensus is for a resumption of growth
in real G N P, some abatement of inflation, and a
decline in the unemployment rate from its fourth
quarter 1970 level. This year the forecasts might
be called “ cautiously optimistic,” and most of the
experts think that 1971 will be a better year for
business than 1970, but not startlingly so.
William E. Cullison

A compilation of forecasts in booklet form, with names and details of estimates,
may be obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.




11

The Supply of Money in the United States
Part II — The Monetary Framework

Part I of this essay sum m arized som e o f the
principal institutions and events that have been in­
strumental in shaping control over the money supply
in the United States. This section examines the
more important technical factors and processes that
generate change in the U. S. money stock at the
present time.1
High-Powered Money T h e units of m oney in
common use are the final products of a refined
technical operation. Tw o different industries com ­
bine and coordinate resources and raw materials to
generate the dollars that compose this product. The
primary industry is the central bank. It produces
what is sometimes known as high-powered money
( H P M ) , which consists of (1 ) currency and (2 )
commercial bank reserve accounts in the central
bank. These components make up the base on which
the actual money supply of hand-to-hand currency
and demand deposits is formed. Most currency is
a part of the actual money supply, but it also may
be held by banks as reserves on which demand de­
posits are expanded.2
Tw o institutions, other than the gold and silver
industries, have furnished the monetary system with
H P M in the past. First, the Treasury Department
at various times printed paper currency (e.g., U. S.
notes, Treasury notes, and silver certificates) when
authorized to do so by Congress. During the late
nineteeth and early twentieth centuries it also ma­
nipulated its deposit balances in national banks as
a part of deliberate policy to increase and decrease
bank reserves at different seasons of the year.
Since 1914, the Federal Reserve System has been
the more prominent institution for furnishing H P M .
It issues Federal Reserve notes and maintains the
reserve (or deposit) accounts of member banks. The
Treasury still has some outstanding currency in the
1 Much o f the following discussion on high-powered money and the
two determining ratios are presented in greater depth in Philip
Cagan, D eterm inants and E ffe c ts o f Changes in the Stock o f M oney,
1875-1960, N B E R , Columbia U niversity Press, 1965.
2 The total stock of H PM as of June 30, 1970 was $80.0 billion.
This total consisted of (1 ) member bank reserve accounts with Fed­
eral Reserve Banks— $22.2 billion; (2) Federal Reserve notes out­
standing— $50.6 billion; and (3 ) Treasury currency outstanding-—
$7.2 billion.
The defined narrow stock o f money was $222 billion,
consisting of $172 billion private demand deposits adjusted for inter­
bank holdings and $50 billion o f currency held outside commercial
banks and the Federal government.

12




form of silver certificates and fractional coin, and it
still has substantial balances (tax and loan accounts)
with commercial banks. However, the Federal R e­
serve System has taken over most of the currencyissuing job, and member bank deposits in Federal
Reserve Banks have been substituted for the specie
reserves that used to be held by the banks themselves.
Both the central bank and the Treasury may
carry out seasonal policies with H P M but only the
central bank can provide year-to-year (secular) in­
creases in this basic stock. W here the Treasury
must rely on bank reserves already in existence to
change its balances at commercial banks, the Federal
Reserve System creates H P M from scratch by buy­
ing government securities or acquiring other assets.
The final payment for the securities takes the form
either of an issue of Federal Reserve notes or of a
new credit to the reserve accounts of member banks.
Both of these items are counted as liabilities of Fed­
eral Reserve Banks, and both of them are H P M .
Once H P M has been created by the central bank,
its final monetary effect depends on its route through
the second of the two money-generating industries
— the commercial banking system.
Most Federal
Reserve notes are channeled through commercial
banks to become a part of hand-to-hand currency.
However, commercial banks keep about 10 percent
of these notes as reserves in addition to their deposit
reserve accounts in the central bank.
The Currency-Deposit Ratio In addition to the
quantity of H P M , two ratios have an important
influence in determining the ultimate quantity of
money. One is the ratio of currency to demand
deposits expressed as

that households and business firms wish to maintain.
This ratio is a function of technical factors, such as
checking facilities available to the nonbank public.
It also depends on such behavioral factors as trust
or mistrust of banks, desire to avoid inflation or
evade taxes, black market activities, and the extent
of personal travel.

Given the total amount of the

H P M base, the narrow money supply (defined in
footnote 2 ) is larger when the currency-deposit ratio
is smaller, and vice versa. For example, let this ratio
be one-to-five at some point in time. Then assume
that households and business firms experience some
change in preferences that prompts them to main­
tain a ratio of only one dollar in currency to six
dollars in checkbook balances, and let them deposit
some of their currency in commercial banks in order
to achieve this new ratio. The net effect of currency
deposited in the banks is to give the banks excess
reserves.
If the central bank holds constant the
stock of H P M , that is, if it does nothing to offset
the additional currency in the commercial banks,
these banks now have the means to expand credit on
the asset side and deposits on the liability side. The
volume of deposits then increases by the amount of
excess reserves times the inverse of the average ratio
of reserves to demand deposits maintained by the
commercial banking system. Thus, a unit of H P M
held as hand-to-hand currency by the nonbank public
has much less monetary influence than the same
dollar held as a reserve unit in a commercial bank.
The Reserve-Deposit Ratio T h e second of the
two determining ratios is largely a function of central
bank policy. It is the ratio of all banks’ reserves to
their total demand deposits. It may be expressed as

where R is the dollar volume of commercial bank
reserves held against demand deposits and Da is the
dollar value of demand deposits. Generally, the banks
make loans and investments until the actual ratio
is reduced to the legal minimum ratio required by
law. By increasing earning assets and thereby re­
ducing this ratio, banks maximize the earnings po­
tential of their portfolios.
The minimum required ratio varies from one bank
classification to another and between state banks and
member banks of the Federal Reserve System. R e­
serve requirements for state chartered banks are
subject to state laws. W hile these laws may be very
different one from another, they generally specify
reserve requirements in terms of vault cash (cur­
rency), deposits in “ other” banks— usually member
banks of the Federal Reserve System— and “ ap­
proved” government securities. The “ approved” se­
curities are limited issues of state or Federal govern­

imposed by the Federal Reserve System on member
banks indirectly restrict creation of state bank de­
posits as well.
For the commercial banking system as a whole,
some ratio of total reserves to total deposits exists
at any given moment. If the quantity of H P M and
the value of the currency-deposit ratio mentioned
above are already determined, the volume of demand
deposits (and also the total stock of money) is
greater when the reserve-deposit ratio is lower and
smaller when this ratio is higher.
These three basic parameters define an unadjusted
money stock.
However, several factors involving
monetary accounting and classification must be
disposed of before the narrow stock of money is
obtained.
Accounting Issues in Classifying the Stock of
Money One item to be considered is interbank
demand deposits— deposits to the credit of one bank
and accounted as a liability by another bank. A c ­
cording to current Federal Reserve regulation, a
commercial member bank that makes such a deposit
in another member bank may deduct this amount
from the total of its own demand deposits subject
to reserve requirements. Even though the recipient
bank must keep reserves against these deposits, the
net effect is to exempt the member banking system
as a whole from maintaining reserves against inter­
bank deposits. If this allowance were not made— if
reserve requirements were in full force against inter­
bank deposits— an increase in this item would di­
minish the measured narrow money supply even
though gross demand deposits remained constant.
A s it is, the reserve allowance permits an increase
in interbank deposits with no corresponding decrease
required in deposits held by the nonbank public,
foreigners, or the government. Member interbank
deposits, therefore, neither absorb reserves nor are
a part of a classified money stock.
Another difficulty, one which cannot be handled
so readily, is the fact that both time and demand
deposits require reserves. Therefore, reserves held
against time deposits in commercial banks must be
deducted from total reserves in order to count the
amount of reserves that can be used to expand de­
mand deposits.
Time deposits raise yet another problem. Since
interest is paid on them, they are in competition with
a whole complex of interest-earning assets in fi­

ment securities bearing relatively low rates of in­

nancial markets.

terest.

mercial banks is subject to interest rate effects and

Most of the reserves maintained by these

Therefore, their creation by com ­

banks, however, are interbank deposits with mem­

interactions of demands and supplies of other fi­

ber banks; so the reserve requirement limitations

nancial assets.




These feedbacks may alter the re­
13

serves available for demand deposit creation, so that
interest rates on financial assets may have some in­
direct bearing on the volume of demand deposits.
This influence is so roundabout that it is difficult
to measure. The opinion here is that it is visible
but of low significance.
Dollar demand deposits held by foreigners in U. S.
commercial banks also require an accounting pigeon­
hole. These deposits absorb reserves just as any
other deposits do. Since they may be used to buy
goods and services produced in the United States
and are largely behavioral, they are included in the
narrowly defined money supply.
The Federal government also has demand de­
posit balances in commercial banks, as well as vault
cash (currency) in government offices, and deposit
accounts with Federal Reserve Banks. The latter

two of these three items remain relatively constant,
but the tax and loan accounts at commercial banks
are another matter. W hile subject to reserve re­
quirements, they are not usually counted as a part
of the narrowly defined stock of money. The gov­
ernment is assumed to carry out policies and make
decisions that require spending without regard to its
cash balance holdings. Only money held by private
households and business firms can influence (or be
influenced b y )

individual behavior.

H ow ever,

classifying the money supply to include or exclude
government balances is purely arbitrary. It can be
done either way. The way it is done should depend
on the function of the money supply so classified.
Short-Run Effects of Treasury Balances

T he

ability of the Treasury to create H P M has become

GENESIS OF THE M O N EY SUPPLY
TOTAL D E M A N D DEPOSITS
H A N D -T O -H A N D
CURRENCY

Demand deposits held by households
and business firms
r "'1 i i i

Seasonal
fiscal
policies

ii

ii

i i

i r~ i i*' *i i 1 i i i i

Currency
deposit
ratio

i i—

Treasury deposits

Currency held by
households and
business firms

Foreign deposits
I

Interbank deposits

<&:**_ j

TIME DEPOSITS
Member bank reserves (deposits) with
Federal Reserve Banks
Currency issued by Treasury and
Federal Reserve System
Other reserves of nonmember banks
ALL C O M M ERCIA L BA N KS

7
Interest rate
complex

\

Mem ber bank deposits in Federal
Reserve Banks
Treasury currency outstanding
Federal Reserve notes outstanding
HIGH-PO W ERED M O N E Y

14




negligible. Its fiscal powers of taxing and spending,
however, cause the balances it keeps in commercial
banks to fluctuate widely. These balances average
about $6 billion, but their month-to-month variation
is often $2 billion and is sometimes more than $4
billion due to a lack of synchronization between
federal tax receipts and disbursements.

Since none

of the government’s cash holdings is created by the
Treasury, increases and decreases in government
balances must be reciprocated by corresponding de­
creases and increases in the money holdings of house­
holds and business firms in the private economy.
Sometimes, the change of the month-to-month money
supply in the private economy from this source is
larger than the annual secular change due to Federal
Reserve policy effects either on H P M or on the
reserve-deposit ratio.

This datum emphasizes that




the Treasury’s short-run influence on the private
money stock is frequently massive.
Figure 1, in which some nonmonetary details are
condensed, gives a schematic view of the whole
money-generating process. H P M originating in the
Federal Reserve System (and to some extent in the
Treasury) is channeled through commercial banks
to become either hand-to-hand currency or bank re­
serves.
The currency-deposit and reserve-deposit
ratios establish the ultimate amounts of deposits and
currency that will be generated as well as the total
of both. Offstage, a complex of interest rates in the
money market has some possible effects on total
time deposits created, and thus on the total of de­
mand deposits. Seasonal fiscal policies, finally, are
seen defining the short-run volume of Treasury de­
posits held in the aggregate of total demand deposits.
Richard H . Timberlake, Jr.

15