View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

70

MONTHLY REVIEW, MAY 1962

The Prime Rate — Part II*
The first part of this article, which appeared in this
Review last month, reviewed the history of the prime rate
and its relation to other lending rates. We now turn to
changes in the prime rate and their causes. The behavior
of the prime rate is subject, of course, to a great variety
of influences, some essentially long run in nature, others
cyclical. To explain the timing of particular prime rate
changes, furthermore, one must take into account the
complex decision-making process in the banks that exer­
cise rate leadership and the competitive relations among
these institutions.
UNDERLYING SUPPLY AND DEMAND FACTORS

stages (February 1959 and June 1955) of the two pre­
vious business cycles.1
In order to obtain funds for lending, banks have had
to step up competition for deposits. In recent years, a
relatively large share of deposit gains has consisted of time
deposits on which, in contrast to demand deposits, banks
of course normally pay interest. In turn, the rates charged
by banks, including the prime rate, also have gone up.
The rise in the prime rate during the postwar years ap­
pears to have been of the same order of magnitude as the
increase in the yields on other outlets for bank funds.
However, just as bank loans often have special advantages
for borrowers, so lending to prime borrowers often yields
banks substantial returns, in the form of deposits or addi­
tional business, over and above the actual interest receipts.
The pressure of growing demand on relatively limited
supply has probably been more severe on the large banks
in New York and Chicago that “make” the prime rate
than on any other group of banks. The city banks have
traditionally taken the lead in servicing the national firms
that make up much of the prime borrower group. During
the 1950-60 period, total deposits at these banks have
increased only about 20 per cent, compared with a rise
of some 50 per cent at all other member banks. Over the
same period, the bank debt of large manufacturing cor­
porations (with assets of over $100 million) has more
than tripled.

Although it is only fourteen years since the first change
in the prime rate, the general pattern of the forces to
which it is subject seems fairly well established. The
basic trend of the rate during these years, like that of other
interest rates, has been upward. Demand for bank loans
has expanded greatly, reflecting the growth of the economy
and the drawing-down of liquidity reserves accumulated
during World War II. Moreover, although most prime
borrowers have access to other means of financing, bank
loans offer significant advantages in terms of the flexibility
of amounts, timing, and other arrangements. Even the
highly rate-sensitive national sales finance companies are
careful to maintain their bank credit lines at all times.
While demand for bank loans has been expanding, the
growth of funds has not kept pace. Throughout the post­
CYCLICAL FACTORS
war years, except during periods of cyclically slack de­
mand, loans have been replacing Government securities in
The direction and timing of changes in the prime rate
bank portfolios, with the total size of bank assets increas­ are determined largely by the ramifications of the cyclical
ing comparatively slowly. Each business upswing has seen behavior of loan demand and supply. The fact that the
loans rise to occupy a more prominent position in bank prime rate rises and falls later than most other businessportfolios than in the preceding expansion, and these cycle indicators seems due at least in part to the time it
increases have been only partly reversed during recessions. takes for shifts in the business situation and monetary
In December 1961, ten months after the February trough policy to be translated into changes in the loan supplyin the general business situation, the ratio of loans to total demand balance. Because of the nature of bank credit
deposits at large banks was 56.4 per cent, compared with and of the market in which it is sold, the prime rate
52.1 per cent and 44.1 per cent at the corresponding
♦Albert M. Wojnilower and Richard E. Spcagle had primary
responsibility for the preparation of this article.




1 The figures refer to the ratio, at weekly reporting member
banks, of total loans, excluding loans to securities brokers and
dealers and interbank loans, to total deposits less cash items in
process of collection.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Chart I

THE PRIME RATE AND VARIOUS CREDIT INDICATORS
Free reserves
in m illio n s of
d o lla rs , inverted

R a tio
in per cent

Interest rate in p er cent

1953

1954

1955

Interest rate in per cent

1956

1957

1958

1959

1960

1961

N o te: T rea sury b ill rates are m o n th ly a v e r a g e s of d a ily m arket yie ld s; free
reserves are three-m onth m o v in g a v e r a g e s of m o n th ly fig u re s. Sh a d e d
a re a s are b usine ss-cycle c o n tra ctio n s a c c o rd in g to the c h ro n o lo g y of the
N a t io n a l Bureau of Econom ic Research. A ste risk s m a rk the ap p a re n t
c y c lic a l turn in g p o in ts in the va rio u s series.
Source: B o ard of G o v e rn o rs of the Fed eral R e serve Syste m .

responds only to shifts in the credit situation that are un­
mistakable and are expected to persist.
The demand for new loans waxes and wanes roughly
in rhythm with the cyclical swings in private investment,
particularly investment in inventories. The supply of addi­
tional loans that a bank can extend, on the other hand,
depends primarily on the growth of its deposits and,
with a given deposit volume, the extent to which it is
willing to liquidate other assets to accommodate loans.
The aggregate of deposits for all banks is, of course,
largely determined by Federal Reserve policies, as a re­
sult of which the rate of growth of bank deposits has
tended, on the whole, to be faster in times of recession
and slower in times of boom. During recession periods,
in sum, loan demand is slack but the supply of bank
funds is growing; in boom periods, by contrast, peak loan
demands are pressing on a limited credit supply.
The ratio of loans to deposits, referred to earlier, is a
convenient summary measure of the shifting balance over
the cycle between loan demand and availability, and is
known to play a significant role in the formation of loan




71

policy by individual banks. Since in most large banks
the bulk of the deposit liabilities are payable on demand,
some margin must be invested in assets that, in contrast to
loans, can be quickly converted into cash. Consequentiy,
a high loan-deposit ratio, whether for an individual bank
or for the banking system, indicates a state of being
largely “loaned up” : considerations of liquidity then dic­
tate restraint in lending. Conversely, a low ratio suggests
that a bank may be having difficulty in finding acceptable
loans and is probably more receptive to new requests. Of
course, the loan-deposit ratio is only an approximate meas­
ure of liquidity, since loan portfolios may be more or less
liquid depending on the types and turnover rate of the
loans involved while the deposits themselves may be more
or less volatile.
As a result of the relationship between loan and de­
posit movements over the cycle, the loan-deposit ratio
shows pronounced cyclical swings (Chart I). The ratio
falls during recessions, when loan volume contracts while
deposits generally increase. The ratio rises during busi­
ness expansions, when loan volume is growing while de­
posits increase slowly or not at all. During the past de­
cade, as Chart II shows, the relation between the loandeposit ratio of city banks, indicating the pressure of loan
demand on supply, and the prime rate has been very close.
Largely similar results are obtained when the ratio of
short-term liquid assets to deposits is substituted for the
loan-deposit ratio (Chart III), as would be expected on
the basis of the close relationship of the two ratios (a high

C h art II

THE PRIME RATE AND LOAN-DEPOSIT RATIOS
W e e k ly r e p o r t in g m e m b er b a n k s
R a tio
in per cent

Prim e rate
in per cent

N o te: L o a n -d e p o s it ratio s e q u a l loans (a d ju sted ) less loa ns to b ro kers an d
d e a le rs as a p e rce n ta g e of total d ep o sits less cash item s in process of
c o lle ctio n . R a tio s a re b ased on a v e ra g e s of W e d n e sd a y fig u re s.
Source: Bo ard of G o v e rn o rs of the Fe d e ra l R e serve System .

72

MONTHLY REVIEW, MAY 1962

C h art III

THE PRIME RATE AND SHORT-TERM L5QUID ASSETS RATIOS
W e e k ly re p o rtin g merr.ber b an ks
Short-term
assets ratio ,
in v e rte d

Prim e rate
in per cent

N o te : Sh ort-term liq u id assets ratio s e q u a l v a u lt cash, b a la n ce s w ith dom estic
b an ks, loa ns to b ro kers a n d d e a le rs, a n d G o v ern m en t secu rities m a tu rin g
w ith in o ne y e a r less b o rro w in g s , as a p e rce n ta g e of total d ep o sits less
cash item s a n d reserves at the Fed eral Reserve Ban ks.
So u rce: Bo ard of G o v e rn o rs of the F e d e ra l Re serve System .

short-term assets ratio corresponds, in general, to a low
loan-deposit ratio).2
To the extent that the prime rate and loan-deposit
ratios are related, some of the “laggardness” of the prime
rate is explained. Loan-deposit ratios do not respond
immediately to changes in the direction of monetary policy
(Chart I). At least since 1953, turning points in the
cyclical course of loan-deposit ratios have in almost all
instances lagged several months behind turns in free
reserves, and often also behind Treasury bill rates. At
business-cycle troughs (and at the 1957 peak), turns in
loan-deposit ratios also have trailed behind the turning
points in business at large.
The effects on the prime rate of the cyclical fluctuations
in the balance of loan demand and supply are reinforced
by movements in the more sensitive, open market interest
rates. While the path of open market rates, like that of
loan-deposit ratios, reflects primarily the over-all credit
situation, each rate is also subject to forces and anticipa­
tions specific to its own market. As a result, differentials
among the various open market rates and loan rates are
by no means constant. Interviews with leading banks

indicate that the actual and anticipated standing of other
relevant interest rates, along with loan-deposit ratios,
plays a key role in decisions to change the prime rate.
Long-term rates, such as those on corporate bonds (in­
cluding rates on private placements with insurance com­
panies and other nonbank investors), are considered by
some banks to be more relevant than short-term rates.
When credit demand is expanding, rates on the various
instruments through which borrowers may obtain access
to nonbank funds—such as commercial paper and bond
issues—rise promptly, and further rises are normally an­
ticipated. With the prime rate still low, borrowing from
banks becomes more attractive and pressure develops on
the available supply of bank funds. At the same time, the
costs banks must incur to raise additional funds increase.
Rates on time deposits tend to rise toward the legal
maxima. Sales of securities, at rising rates (declining
prices), mean capital losses. Temporary reserve deficien­
cies become more frequent and must be offset at higher
Federal funds or Reserve Bank discount rates. Such con­
ditions appear ripe for the raising of the prime rate.
When credit demand is contracting, the sequence is
reversed. As open market rates fall, borrowing at the
established prime rate becomes less attractive. Some out­
standing loans may be prepaid with the proceeds of open
market financings. For the banks, the costs of attracting
new deposits, and the returns offered by other investment
outlets, decline. Sooner or later, the prime rate gives way.
INDIVIDUAL. BANK DECISIONS TO
CHANGE THE PRIME RATE

The preceding broad considerations describe the en­
vironment propitious to a change in the prime rate. They
are not sufficient, however, to predict with any confidence
the precise timing of rate changes. The changing of the
rate represents a major decision. A considerable time
interval may elapse between the conclusion by some
officials of a given bank that a rate change is appropriate
and the decision of its management to take action. Ele­
ments of “gamesmanship” are necessarily involved, both
among competing interests within a given institution and
with respect to efforts to anticipate the reaction of cus­
tomers and competitors.
Any actual change must be initiated by one particular
bank. This is a risky step, for if the others do not follow,
the lead bank faces a flood of loan requests perhaps in
2 Unlike the loan-deposit ratio, the proportion of liquid assets excess of lending capacity (if its rate is below the market)
does not show a pronounced longer term trend, reflecting the fact
that loans have displaced mainly long-term rather than short-term or a rapid exodus of customers to other banks (if its rate
securities. For a discussion of concepts and measures of bank is above the market). It is not surprising, therefore, that
liquidity, see “Recent Developments in Bank Liquidity”, Monthly
most prime-rate moves have been initiated by the two
Review, November 1961, pp. 185-88.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

largest New York banks, The Chase Manhattan and First
National City. These two banks have been particularly
prominent in initiating changes upward. Three of the four
rate reductions during the postwar period, on the other
hand, originated with other, somewhat smaller banks.
It is clear that a bank assumes leadership in a rate
change only upon considerable deliberation among its top
officials, whose views need by no means be unanimous.
In one instance studied, two and a half months intervened
between the initial proposal by a high official that the
rate be changed and the ultimate action. However, less
than two weeks elapsed in another case, in which con­
sideration of a rate shift was reportedly touched off by
a change in the Federal Reserve discount rate. At times
noneconomic motives, such as the desire for leadership
or publicity, appear to play an important part. When some
other bank has already announced a change, on the other
hand, the decision to follow along can normally be taken
promptly and with little travail.
There was some indication that, at times when the
existing rate seemed out of line, a move in the Federal
Reserve discount rate might be interpreted as calling for,
or giving sanction to, a changing of the prime rate. At
other than such pivotal times, however, judging from the
statistical record, discount rate changes have had little
influence.3

73

market. So far as the interest rate on such loans is con­
cerned, this view appears to be accurate: the extent and
timing of all types of business-loan rate changes is gov­
erned closely by changes in the prime rate. It is doubtful,
however, that the prime rate is a reliable indicator of
fluctuations in loan availability, which reflects, in addition
to rate, other credit terms, standards of credit-worthiness,
and the like.
Quite strikingly, the prime rate is among the last indexes
of the credit situation to register a change in the credit
climate. A number of reasons explain this. Because of the
many dimensions of a loan agreement, rate is probably
a less significant factor in a business-loan transaction than
in other large-sized credit transactions. Since every loan is
to some extent unique and since, as a related matter, there
is no secondary market in which existing loans may be
traded, there are no standard reference points or market
quotations to which rates on new loans can be mechani­
cally geared. Moreover, changes in the supply-demand
balance in the loan market, as reflected by loan-deposit
ratios, generally do not occur until after turning points in
reserve positions and short- and long-term rates. A further
lag is introduced by the necessarily cautious and complex
price-making procedure of a market in which leading
banks compete for the business of large national bor­
rowers.
In sum, changes in the prime rate do not normally
CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
occur ahead of, or even concurrently with, shifts in the
Bankers as well as the public tend to view the prime credit situation. Rather, a change in the prime rate may
rate as the principal index of conditions in the bank loan usually be interpreted as confirming that a sizable shift
has already taken place and that no early reversal is
3 It may be pointed out that in most advanced countries the rate expected.

structure of bank lending tends to be anchored in some key rate.
In continental Western Europe, the principal commercial bank
lending rates are in most cases set by consultation among the
banks. In many of these countries, such as France and Germany,
these rates are “linked” to central bank discount rates and are
changed more or less automatically by the same amounts as the
latter. (In France, however, full adjustment to changes in the
discount rate is made only when the latter is in the V/i-AVi per
cent range. Beyond these limits, only one half of any discount rate
change can be reflected in the minimum commercial bank lending
rate.) In the United Kingdom, the equivalent of the prime rate
by custom stands in a fixed relation to the Bank of England’s dis­
count rate. For prime private borrowers, the rate is set Vi per
cent above the discount rate (with a minimum of 5 per cent), but
most private firms pay 1 per cent above the discount rate. In
Canada, the prime rate is set by the chartered banks in consulta­
tion with each other and is changed quite rarely—partly because
in recent years it has been close to the 6 per cent legal maximum
on interest rates in general.




THE QUEST FOR BALANCE IN THE
INTERNATIONAL PAYMENTS SYSTEM

In response to requests, the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York has reprinted the seventeen-page sec­
tion of its 1961 Annual Report entitled “The Quest
for Balance in the International Payments System”.
Copies are available from the Public Information
Department, Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
33 Liberty Street, New York 45, N. Y.

74

MONTHLY REVIEW, MAY 1962

The Business Situation
The economy displayed more vigor during March and
early April than during the first two months of the year.
Most encouragingly, consumer spending— especially on
automobiles—picked up briskly. Residential construction
seemed to be moving out of its recent doldrums. There
were also signs of a somewhat faster growth in expendi­
tures for plant and equipment for the balance of the year
than had been indicated earlier.
Although the March gain in output helped to make
some small inroads on unemployment, the unemployment
rate was still significantly higher than at the comparable
stage of the two preceding business expansions. At the
same time, despite the drop in total unemployment the
number of persons out of work more than half a year
(the so-called “hard core” unemployment) increased
further and stood well above the level at the trough of the
recession in early 1961. And, despite the spurt in eco­
nomic activity in March, gross national product in the
first quarter of 1962 rose less than half as much as in the
preceding quarter.
The expansion in economic activity continued to be
accompanied by little change in prices. The wholesale
price index was stable in March, as it had been in Febru­
ary, and remained below year-earlier levels. The con­
sumer price index, after four months of stability, did
advance in both February and March, but at least part
of the rise could be attributed to increased food prices
brought on by freezing weather in the South and by
seasonally higher prices of apparel and used cars. The
prevailing noninflationary atmosphere, which has been
strengthened by the signing of the rather moderate steel
wage contract at the end of March (from which, sig­
nificantly, the cost-of-living escalation clause was elimi­
nated), was only briefly disturbed in early April by the
short-lived rise in the price of steel.

The slowing-down in the first quarter stemmed largely
from declines in consumer expenditures for durable goods,
primarily automobiles, and in outlays for residential con­
struction. In the comparable quarters of the two preceding
upswings, demand in these two areas had continued to
advance or had remained unchanged. In addition, the rate
of increase in business expenditures for fixed investment
slackened in the first quarter, whereas in the earlier expan­
sion periods such spending had advanced rather sharply.
Business investment in inventories, on the other hand, ac­
celerated in the first quarter, putting total inventory accu­
mulation in this expansion about midway between the two
earlier periods; and government spending, although not
increasing so sharply as a quarter earlier, continued to
move ahead of both the 1954-55 and 1958-59 upswings.
Consumer behavior in recent weeks raised hopes that
consumption spending in general may be on the rise.

C h art I

RECENT CHANGES IN GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
AND ITS COMPONENTS
S e a s o n a lly ad ju ste d a n n u a l rates
B illio n s of d o lla rs

B illio n s of d o lla rs

THE PATTERNS OF DEMAND

Through the final quarter of 1961 the growth in GNP
in the current expansion had roughly paralleled its per­
formance in the two preceding periods of upswing. How­
ever, with the relatively small advance of $6.8 billion to
a seasonally adjusted annual rate of $549.0 billion in the
first quarter of 1962 (see Chart I), the growth in GNP
fell slightly behind the pace set in the earlier expansions.




Sources'. U n ite d States D ep artm en t c f C o m m e rce; C cu n ci! of Econ o m ic A d v ise rs.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Total retail sales in March registered good gains for the
second month in a row, and more than regained last
November’s high. The advance in March centered on
automobile sales, which had been disappointingly weak
in the first two months of the year. In April, auto dealers
continued to chalk up sharp sales increases. Department
stores sales in April may have slackened somewhat from
the high March level, but the late date of Easter this year
complicates analysis of movements between these two
months. Taken together, the two months do represent a
good gain over January and February, reflecting higher
spending for both soft goods and household durables.
The home-building picture also appears to have im­
proved since the end of February. The first quarter’s
decline in residential construction outlays may, at least
in part, have resulted from adverse weather. While the
number of new housing units started had fallen for four
consecutive months through February, building permits—
which reflect intentions to begin construction and which
are less affected by weather—had moved generally up­
ward. With better weather in March, the number of non­
farm housing starts jumped by one fifth to a seasonally
adjusted annual rate of 1.4 million, only slightly below the
October 1961 high. In addition, FHA applications plus
VA appraisal requests rose for the second consecutive
month in March and the mortgage market eased further.
In the business sector, the latest indications of fixed
investment trends give some promise of a better showing
after the rather sluggish pace set in the first quarter. The
recent McGraw-Hill survey, taken in March and early
April, found businessmen planning to increase their spend­
ing for plant and equipment in 1962 by 11 per cent
above 1961 levels, somewhat more than the 8 per cent rise
indicated by the Commerce Department-Securities and
Exchange Commission survey taken two months earlier
(see March Monthly Review). In comparable stages of
previous cyclical upswings, the McGraw-Hill survey has
generally shown a higher percentage gain than the
Commerce-SEC survey, but both have tended to under­
state the volume of outlays actually rung up.
In contrast to consumer spending and business outlays
on fixed investment, business investment in inventories
rose more in the first quarter of 1962 than in the preced­
ing quarter. A significant portion of the faster inventory
build-up, of course, reflected steel stockpiling against the
possibility of a strike. Steel inventories probably rose
further in April, since the wage settlement at the end of
March allowed little time for cancellation of April ship­
ments. In the months following, however, steel users can
be expected to work off at least part of their inventories.
Government spending also rose in the first quarter, as it




75

C h art II

RECENT BUSINESS INDICATORS
S e a s o n a lly a d ju ste d
R a tio scale

116
Industrial production

/

1957=100

/

123.1

Output per man-hour

/

/

M a n u fa c tu rin g
1957=100

J

/

102
116.6

40.5

Hours worked per week
M a n u fa c tu r in g

39.3
M anufacturing employment
M illio n s of p ersons

16.7

16.0

F

I

I

M

A

I !
M

J

1

I

J
1961

A

1
S

1
O

1

1
N

C

>

J

1

F
1962

A*\

So u rces: B o a rd of G o v e rn o rs of the F e d e ra l R e se rv e Sy ste m ; U n ite d States
D ep artm en t of C o m m e rce ; a n d N a t io n a l Bureau of Econ o m ic R e search .

had a quarter earlier. More than half of the increased
spending in these two quarters was for national defense,
reflecting the military build-up that started with the Berlin
crisis last summer, and defense outlays are expected to rise
further at least through midyear. State and local expendi­
tures should continue their long-term upward trend.
PRODUCTION AND EMPLOYMENT

Industrial production in March advanced by 1 point
for the second month in a row, reaching 116 per cent of
the 1957 average (see Chart II). The March rise was
widespread with no major sector showing a decline. In
April, auto production was rising briskly and schedules
pointed to a substantial increase for the month as a whole.
The weekly figures for steel-ingot production in April,
however, suggested a more-than-seasonal decline, as out­
put was cut back following the steel wage settlement.
The further decline in March in new orders received
by manufacturers of durable goods partly reflected the

76

MONTHLY REVIEW, MAY 1962

special order situation in the steel industry. Since many
of the heavy December and January steel orders were
for shipments to be spread out over the whole first half
of 1962, the need to place new orders for steel during
February and March may have been somewhat reduced
from what it would have been under more normal cir­
cumstances. Moreover, the early start of the steel con­
tract negotiations may have dampened hedging demand
for steel during those two months.
Total employment in March rose imperceptibly on a
seasonally adjusted basis, the small increase being centered
in the manufacturing, service, and government sectors. At
the same time, the civilian labor force showed a slight de­
cline. As a result, the total number of unemployed fell
below 4 million for the first time since July 1960, and un­
employment as a percentage of the civilian labor force
edged off to 5.5 per cent; at the comparable stage of the
1958-59 and 1954-55 expansions, the unemployment rates
were 5.1 per cent and 4.1 per cent, respectively.
As is usual during the early periods of business ex­
pansion, the rather sharp increases that have occurred

during the past year in average hours worked and in
productivity have tended to hold down the gains in em­
ployment. In manufacturing industries, average hours
clocked by production workers in March rose close to
the previous cyclical high set last November (see Chart
II), when auto manufacturers were working overtime to
make up for production lost during the strikes in Septem­
ber and October. Output per man-hour in manufacturing
industries also rose in March, bringing the increase since
the recession trough to more than 5 per cent (see Chart
II). This is about in line with productivity gains in the
comparable period of the 1954-55 expansion, although
somewhat less than the gains experienced in 1958-59.
Neither hours worked nor productivity can be expected
to increase so rapidly in the months ahead as in the first
year of the expansion; future gains in output may there­
fore begin to have a greater impact on employment. How­
ever, the extent to which this may result in a decline in
unemployment will largely depend upon changes in the
total labor force, which over the past year has shown
almost no growth.

The Money Market in April
The money market was moderately firm during April,
as reserve needs of money center banks, while not extreme,
were fairly persistent throughout the month. New York
City banks made substantial purchases of Federal funds,
as their loans to brokers and dealers and their holdings of
United States Government securities expanded at a brisk
pace. Thus, except for three days, the effective rate on
Federal funds stayed within a range of 2% -3 per cent.
Similarly, rates at major New York City banks on loans to
Government securities dealers generally held within a 33Va per cent range. Fluctuations in Treasury bill rates
were minor during the month. An intermittent tendency
for bill rates to decline, under pressure of fairly widespread
demand, was offset in part by the continued additions of
$100 million to the weekly offerings of three-month bills.
Demand for long-term bonds increased further during
most of the month, as investors, apparently abandoning
expectations of higher interest rates in the near future,
placed a substantial volume of funds in new and out­
standing issues. Prices of longer term United States
Government obligations rose further to record levels for




the year, while the market readily absorbed the Treasury’s
cash offering on April 9 of $1 billion of 33A per cent
bonds due in August 1968. Prices of corporate bonds
also rose in April, with even those recently marketed
issues that were initially regarded as closely priced advanc­
ing notably. In the market for tax-exempt securities,
prices reached their highest levels in nearly four years,
despite somewhat less aggressive buying by commercial
banks. On April 26, the Treasury announced that it would
offer holders of 3 per cent certificates of indebtedness and
4 per cent notes, both maturing May 15, 1962, and of 2Va
per cent bonds maturing June 15, 1962, altogether total­
ing $11.7 billion, the right to exchange them for any of
the following securities, all dated May 15, 1962: 3V4
per cent Treasury certificates of indebtedness maturing
May 15, 1963, priced at par; 35/s per cent Treasury notes
maturing February 15, 1966, priced at 99.80 to yield 3.68
per cent; 3% per cent Treasury bonds maturing November
15, 1971, priced at 99.50 to yield 3.94 per cent. Subscrip­
tion books for the exchange would be open April 30
through May 2. Cash subscriptions would not be received.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

MEMBER BANK RESERVES

On balance, market factors absorbed reserves over the
four statement weeks of April. Reserve drains in the first
two weeks, stemming mainly from a seasonal increase in
currency in circulation and a decline in vault cash, were
only partly offset by gains in the final two statement
periods when float and vault cash expanded. System open
market operations more than offset the effects of market
factors, providing reserves over the four statement periods
as a whole. From the last statement week in March to the
final week in April, average System Account outright hold­
ings of Government securities increased by $231 million,
while average holdings under repurchase agreements rose
by $123 million. Between Wednesday, March 28, and
Wednesday, April 25, System holdings of securities rose by
$183 million, with holdings maturing within one year in­
creasing by $84 million and holdings maturing in more than
one year rising by $99 million.
Over the four statement weeks ended April 25, free

CHANGES IN FACTORS TENDING TO INCREASE OR DECREASE
MEMBER BANK RESERVES, APRIL 1962
In millions of dollars; (+ ) denotes increase,
(—) decrease in excess reserves
D aily averages—week ended
Factor
April
4
Operating transactions
Treasury operations* ................................
Gold and foreign account ........................

+
—
—
—
—

82
219
99
80
30

A pril

11
—
-f
—
—
+

56
127
224
32
19

A pril
18

—
4—
4-

+

20

April
25

— 39

N et
Changes

256
82
24
33

— 67
+
7

— 33
4-252
— 293
— 155
4- 29

4 - 88
4- 112

— 345

— 168

4 -212

4 -10 1

— 200

+ 345
4 - 126

+ 138
— 7

— 177
— 74

— 75
4- 78

4- 231
- f 123

— 11
—

— 15
—

4- 15
—■

+

10

— 1
—

— 2
—

—

— 1
—

—
+

2

+ 459

+ 115

— 237

+

12

4- 349

+ 114
— 99

— 53
— 103

— 25
4-203

+ 113
4- 54

4 -149
4 - 55

Effect of change in required! reservest . . .

-f- 15
+ 43

— 156
+ 82

4-178
— 124

4- 167
— 141

+ 204
— 140

Excess reservest ..............................................

+

58

— 74

-f

54

4 - 26

4 - 64

75
517
442

60
443
383

75
497
422

85
523
438

Direct Federal Reserve credit transactions
Government securities:
Direct market purchases or sales . . .
Held under repurchase agreements ..
Loans, discounts, and advances:
Member bank borrowings ....................
Bankers’ acceptances:
Under repurchase agreements ............

_

1

—
+

5
1

Member bank reserves

Daily average level of member bank:
Borrowings from Reserve Banks ..........
Excess reservest ..........................................
Free reservest ............................................

N ote: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
t These figures are estimated,
t Average for four weeks ended April 25, 1962.




741:
495$
421$

77

reserves averaged $421 million, compared with $376
million in the four statement weeks ended March 28.
Average excess reserves rose by $28 million to $495
million, while average borrowings from the Federal Re­
serve Banks decreased by $17 million to $74 million.
THE GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET

In the market for Treasury notes and bonds, the sus­
tained upward price movement that began in late February
and gained strength in March continued through most of
April as well, albeit at a lesser rate. Yields on most issues
fell to their lowest levels of the year (see chart). Un­
certainties regarding the vigor of the business expansion,
the absence of strong demand for business loans, and the
downward trend of stock prices continued to be significant
factors in the background of the price rise. The labor
agreement reached in the steel industry and the cancella­
tion of announced steel price increases, which apparently
were interpreted as diminishing the prospects for inflation,
also helped to strengthen the market.
On the opening days of the month prices rose steadily,
and by April 4 yields on all long-term Government securi­
ties were below 4 per cent. Demand for long-term bonds
by institutional investors and for intermediate-term issues
by commercial banks was augmented at times by profes­
sional demand, as dealers sought to maintain or rebuild
inventories. At the same time, offerings in the market
generally remained light. Prices declined fairly sharply on
April 5, however, largely on rumors of an impending
Treasury financing operation in either the intermediate- or
long-term maturity areas.
After the close of business on April 5, the Treasury
announced that it would offer for cash subscription on
Monday, April 9, $1 billion of 33A per cent bonds at par,
to be dated April 18, 1962 and to mature August 15,
1968, with commercial banks permitted to pay through
credit to Treasury Tax and Loan Accounts. Market
response to the announcement was enthusiastic, and the
entire market strengthened again, with the new bonds
ending their first day of “when-issued” trading, on April
10, at 10013/64 bid. The success of the financing was
later confirmed by the Treasury announcement that total
public subscriptions had amounted to $6.8 billion. Under
the terms of the allotment, subscriptions up to $50,000
were allotted in full and subscriptions over that amount
were allotted 15 per cent with a minimum allotment of
$50,000— about in line with market expectations.
Prices again declined temporarily in immediate response
to news of the steel-price increase after the close of busi­
ness on April 10, which was interpreted as possibly

78

MONTHLY REVIEW, MAY 1962

RECENT MOVEMENTS IN BOND YIELDS
AND TREASURY BILL RATES
P e r cen t

P e r cen t

N o te : Bo nd y ie ld s a re w e e k ly a v e r a g e s of d a ily fig u re s. T re a s u ry b ill rates
a re a v e r a g e issu in g rates. La te st d a ta p lo tte d : w eek en d ed A p r il 2 8 for
b on d s, a u ctio n h eld on A p r il 23 for T re a su ry b ills.

setting off new inflationary pressures. However, the bond
market began to recover even before the steel price rise
was rescinded, and further gains were recorded through
April 18. Over the next week, prices moved somewhat
lower in quiet activity as the market awaited the announce­
ment of the terms of the Treasury’s May refinancing.
The terms of the refinancing were quite well received,
and on April 27 prices of outstanding longer term Treasury
bonds rose from 1%2 to 1% 2 of a point, reflecting the
fact that the longest dated issue included in the refinancing
matures in 1971. However, the outstanding 4 per cent
bonds of 1971 also rose in price about x%2 of a point,
while the maturing issues continued to carry a “rights”
value. Over the month as a whole, prices of intermediateand long-term Treasury issues rose from % 2 of a point
to 1% points.
In the market for Treasury bills, rates fluctuated within
an unusually narrow range during the month. In the regular
weekly auction on Monday, April 2, average issuing rates
were set at 2.757 per cent and 2.875 per cent for the 91and 182-day bills, about 4 and 2 basis points, respectively,
above the previous week. Following the auction, rates
adjusted downward, mainly reflecting the relatively light
awards received by dealers.




On April 3, the Treasury announced that it would
auction, on April 10, $2.0 billion of 365-day bills, to be
dated April 15, 1962 and to mature on April 15, 1963.
These bills, which replaced a like amount maturing on
April 15, were sold at an average issuing rate of 2.943
per cent. After the announcement, rates on outstanding
Treasury bills moved slightly lower over the next several
days, as offerings contracted and demand broadened in a
somewhat easier money market. In the regular auction
on April 9, average issuing rates on the 91- and 182-day
issues were down 4 and 6 basis points, respectively, from
the preceding week, at 2.720 per cent and 2.814 per cent.
The spread of 9 basis points (shown in the chart) was
the narrowest of any auction since the six-month bill was
first offered in December 1958— apparently reflecting,
in part, the continuing weekly addition of $100 million
to the weekly offerings of three-month bills.
Bill rates rose fairly sharply in reaction to the announce­
ment of the increase in steel prices on April 10, as well
as to increased selling in a firmer money market. The
reaction was short-lived, however, as offerings tapered off
and a rather broad demand appeared. In the two regular
auctions on April 16 and 23, average issuing rates on both
three- and six-month bills were set at levels very close to
those established earlier in the month. A steady atmosphere
was maintained toward the close of the month, as dealers
were willing to hold large positions, partly in anticipation
of a reinvestment demand from the Treasury’s May refund­
ing. In the auction on April 30, average issuing rates were
2.748 per cent and 2.845 per cent on three- and six-month
bills, up about 3 basis points in each case from the rates
set in the auction on April 9.
OTHER SECURITIES MARKETS

Prices of seasoned coiporate and tax-exempt bonds
strengthened further in April, under the influence of
sustained investor interest in new and recent flotations.
Over the month as a whole, Moody’s average yield on
seasoned corporate bonds declined by 7 basis points
to 4.31 per cent while the average yield on similarly
rated tax-exempt issues fell by 8 basis points to 2.93 per
cent. New offerings in both sectors generally were well
received, despite the fact that the volume of publicly
offered new corporate and tax-exempt issues expanded
considerably. An estimated $870 million of state and local
securities reached the market in April, compared with
$599 million in March and $661 million in April 1961.
New corporate flotations totaled $640 million in April as
against $340 million in March and $711 million in April
1961. The Blue List of advertised dealer offerings rose

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

from $480 million at the end of March to $549 million
toward the close of April.
The largest new corporate flotation of the month was
a $90 million Aa-rated 4Vs per cent sinking fund deben­
ture maturing in 1987 and nonrefundable for five years.
Yielding 4.36 per cent to investors, the issue quickly sold

79

out. A large Aaa issue was reoffered during the month
at a yield as low as 4.225 per cent. The largest new taxexempt offering of the month was a $109 million A-rated
New York City various-purpose bond issue. Reoffered to
yield from 1.65 per cent in 1963 to 3.15 per cent in 1982,
the bonds were well received.

International Financial Cooperation
Legislation to authorize the United States to join nine
other countries in providing stand-by credits to enlarge
the International Monetary Fund’s potential resources1
was passed by the House of Representatives on April 2
and is now in the Senate. The following comments on the
significance of these new arrangements are taken from a
speech by Per Jacobsson, Managing Director of the Inter­
national Monetary Fund, before the Economic and Social
Council of the United Nations on April 6, 1962:
It is the great merit of these borrowing arrangements
that they make it possible to mobilize quickly large ad­
ditional resources for the defense of the international
monetary system. The need for such resources arises
not from any failure of this system, but, on the contrary,
from its success— from the broader convertibility of cur­
rencies and the increased freedom of the exchange mar­
kets. As so often in life, success creates its own prob­
lems. More widespread convertibility, which is so
important for the growth of world trade has, at the
same time, made possible sudden and substantial shifts
of funds from one country to another. Since large move­
ments of funds are most likely to occur between the
main industrial countries, it was not unnatural that it
was precisely those countries, in the first place, which
wanted to provide adequate safeguards against the un­
toward effects of these movements. The resources to be
provided under the borrowing arrangements will make
it possible to forestall or cope with the threat of any
impairment of the international monetary system cre­
ated by these movements or by any other circumstances.
Thus, the resilience of that system, as well as the liquid­
ity of the Fund, will be enhanced to the benefit of all
member countries.
At an early stage of the discussions which led to
the borrowing arrangements, it was found necessary to
clarify the extent to which the Fund’s resources may be
used to meet deficits in the balance of payments that
1 See Monthly Review, March 1962, p. 49.




are attributable in whole or in part to capital transfers.
By a decision adopted in July last year, the Executive
Directors eliminated any doubt which may have per­
sisted, despite the evidence of the established practices
of the Fund, that the Fund’s resources could be used to
offset the effects of capital transfers in accordance with
Article VI and other provisions of the Articles of Agree­
ment. If a country faced with an outflow of capital
turned to the Fund for assistance, such assistance would
be granted on the basis of the Fund’s accepted princi­
ples and practices, which would require, in the case of
a disequilibrating outflow, that appropriate measures
were being taken to arrest the outflow, so that the as­
sisted country would be able to repay the Fund within
a fairly brief period, and in any event not later than a
maximum period of three to five years after the drawing.
The borrowing arrangements are to be seen as a
manifestation of a growing tendency toward interna­
tional solidarity in the monetary field. But these ar­
rangements are not the only sign of such a tendency.
. . . The Federal Reserve System is now in a position
to undertake operations in the exchange market, and is
in fact doing so, which certainly represents a new de­
parture in postwar United States financial policies. The
concerted steps being taken to prevent disturbing move­
ments on the London gold market are also of interest
in this context. I should add that these methods of co­
operation are almost all still in the process of evolution,
and none of them will, of course, replace the necessity
for the authorities in the individual countries to safe­
guard their own position and sustain balance by pur­
suing appropriate policies. But these national policies
have to be worked out in relation to world-wide devel­
opments. It is a healthy sign that more and more dis­
cussions are taking place either in international organ­
izations or directly between interested countries, which
contribute both to the adoption of appropriate national
policies and to the harmonizing of these policies in the
international field. I think that this working together
has already met with a large measure of success.