The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1995 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES A review from the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 1' , - : ■’: : "M ■ ' i h Chicago's economic transform ation: Past and future Internal organization and economic performance: The case of large U.S. commercial banks FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO i Contents Chicago's economic transformation: Past and future................................................................ 2 G raham S chindler, P h ilip Israilevich, and G eo ffrey H ew ings Structural changes and shifts in exports have reduced Chicago’s sensitivity to macroeconomic fluctuations. Using a model of Chicago’s economy, the authors find that this trend is likely to continue into the future. Internal organization and economic performance: The case of large U.S. commercial banks............................................................................... 10 W illiam C. H unter This article provides new evidence on the impact of centralized versus decentralized strategic decisionmaking, product delivery systems, and back-office operations on commercial bank costs. ECONOMIC P ER SP E( Y Y IVES Septem ber/O ctober, 1995 Volum e XIX, Issue 5 P re s id e n t ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES is published by Michael H. Moskow the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors' and do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank. Single-copy subscriptions are available free of charge. Please send requests for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions, back issues, and address changes to the Public Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834, or telephone (312) 322-5111. Articles may be reprinted provided the source is credited and the Public Information Center is sent a copy of the published material. S e n io r V ic e P re s id e n t an d D ir e c to r o f R esearch William C. Hunter R esearch D e p a rtm e n t Financial Studies Douglas Evanoff, Assistant Vice President Macroeconomic Policy Charles Evans, Assistant Vice President Kenneth Kuttner, Assistant Vice President Microeconomic Policy Daniel Sullivan, Assistant Vice President Regional Programs David R. Allardice, Senior Vice President Adm inistration Anne Weaver, Manager Editor Janice Weiss Production Rita Molloy, Kathryn Moran, Yvonne Peeples, Roger Thryselius, Nancy Wellman ISSN 0164-0682 Chicago's economic transformation: Past and future G rah a m S c h in d le r, P h ilip Isra ile v ic h , and G e o ffre y H e w in g s A Hog butcher fo r the world, Tool maker, stacker o f wheat, Player with railroads and the nation’s freight handler; Stormy, husky, brawling, City o f the big shoulders. —Carl Sandburg, “Chicago” (1916) The charismatic city that Carl Sandburg depict ed in 1916 has since undergone a dramatic transformation. By the late 1970s, deep reces sions had all but eliminated much of the ro manticism associated with Chicago’s industrial economy. Indeed, the city and the entire Mid west seemed to produce almost daily reports of manufacturing plant closings and layoffs. The dire straits of those times appeared to portend only more gloom for the future. But during the same period, Chicago was fostering a growing service sector. By maintaining the growth of the industries in this sector, Chicago has recon structed itself into a strong, thriving economy. As several recent studies have shown, Chicago’s economic structure changed dramat ically during the 1970s and 1980s, with servic es coming to dominate both output and em ployment. In fact, by the early 1980s, service employment had surpassed manufacturing employment in the metropolitan area, foreshad owing a similar transformation nationally a few years later. Not only did Chicago lead the nation in this trend, but the relative degree to which services took over from manufacturing was more dramatic in Chicago than in the nation as a whole. Meanwhile, with manufac turers retiring old inefficient factories, the 2 relics of what some would call Chicago’s glory days, and replacing them with establishments featuring new highly efficient capital, manu facturing output exhibited little or no growth in real terms. With more efficient factories now in use, labor requirements were not as high as in the past; accordingly, between 1970 and 1992 manufacturing firms within Chicago cut over 280,000 jobs. Chicago’s new economic character has arisen because of two fundamental changes, each of which may have different policy impli cations. First, through the difficult transitional period of the 1970s and early 1980s, firms survived because they became more efficient and were able to compete in the increasingly globalized marketplace. Second, the growing dominance of the service sector has fundamen tally altered the composition of Chicago’s exports. These changes combined to reduce the importance of the pro-cyclical manufactur ing exports in favor of those from the less cyclically sensitive service industries. At the same time, Chicago’s interaction with other midwestern or national economies has also been affected. Despite the fall of man ufacturing’s share of total exports, Chicago’s Graham Schindler is a research associate, Philip Israilevich is the associate director, and Geoffrey Hewings is the director of the Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL). REAL is a cooper ative venture between the University of Illinois and the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Philip Israilevich is also a senior economist and research officer at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors thank David Allardice, Kathy Moran, and Janice Weiss for their comments and suggestions. ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES linkages with other economies have strength ened. This is due to three key developments: increased dependence on external markets for inputs in manufacturing, increased service sec tor trade, and altered consumption patterns as a result of increased residential mobility. In sum, Chicago’s economy has become less cyclical and more dependent on the rest of the nation. Stu d yin g C hicago A sketch of structural changes such as these prompts further questions: Which changes are likely in the future? Which industries were most important in engendering change, and will they continue to be prominent in future transfor mations? How will the recent changes affect the economy’s reaction to exogenous shocks? Is it reacting differently than in the past, and what might we expect in the future? How might these changes affect other midwestern econo mies? These are the types of questions that the Chicago Region Econometric Input/Output Model (CREIM) was designed to answer.1 Created by the Regional Economics Applica tions Laboratory, CREIM allows us to examine changes that have taken place in the past and to forecast those that might occur in the future. Additionally, it can estimate the direct and indirect impacts of these changes on various sectors of the economy. CREIM combines traditional input/output analysis with time-series analysis.2 The input/ output component enables a detailed analysis of purchases and sales between industries, while the time-series component allows for the analysis of intertemporal change in the transaction flows of goods and services. Together, these two compo nents produce a detailed analysis of structural change over time at the sectoral level.3 By taking into account transaction flows between industries, we are able to estimate the spillover or indirect effects within the economy that direct analysis cannot capture because it examines each sector irrespective of its effect on other sectors. For example, fabricated metals production requires machine tools and steel as inputs; machine tool companies require steel to build the tools. An increase in the demand for fabricated metals products will impact the steel industry in at least two ways: by increased direct consumption (from fabricated metals) and increased indirect con sumption (from machine tools). In this way, each sector of the economy is linked to all others, either directly or indirectly. FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF CHICAGO The exp erim en t To analyze the impact of Chicago’s struc tural change over time, we designed an experi ment to answer the question, how would a na tional recession affect the Chicago economy, and would the magnitude of this impact change over time? For ease of exposition, we decided to take the recession of 1982 as an example. Using CREIM, we estimated total exports from Chicago to the rest of the nation for both 1981 and 1982. We calculated that 1982 exports were 5.5 percent less than 1981 levels; we then used the magnitude of this export shock to simu late a national recession. The impact on exports from the region during the 1982 recession was largely concen trated in manufacturing industries, with durable goods hit particularly hard. We estimate that between 1981 and 1982, exports of primary metals industries dropped by approximately 33 percent, exports of fabricated metals by about 20 percent. Despite the large export losses in some sectors, other sectors actually saw exports rise. Of the 36 sectors in the model, nine of them, including food and kindred products, petroleum products, and business services, ex hibited export growth between 1981 and 1982. Of these nine, all the resource and manufactur ing sectors saw exports subsequently fall from those levels by 1983. In order to ease interpretation of our results, we did not use the estimated sectoral export changes, which had varying signs. Rather, we distributed the total export change from 1981 to 1982—5.9 percent of 1982’s total exports— across all sectors, weighted by the size of their estimated exports in 1982. This gave all export changes the same sign and facilitated interpreta tion of the final results. We then used this new vector of export change to represent an economy wide export recession, with the overall magni tude equal to that of the 1982 recession, to shock CREIM. We introduced the recessions separately into CREIM as a fall in exports of 5.9 percent for the years 1975, 1985, 1995, and 2005. These four observations provided vectors of changes in output, employment, and so on, which would determine Chicago’s reaction to national downturns over time. For the simu lated recessions we assumed that only exports were shocked, not technology; thus, the esti mated changes in productivity and wage levels within Chicago occurred only in response to 3 the reduction in exports, not in FIGURE 1 some exogenous form due to the Manufacturing and service output recession. index, 1985=100 The recessions introduced into the model are constant through time in relative terms even though exports as a share of total output are increasing over time. From 1975 to 2005, ex ports’ share of total output is forecasted to increase from ap proximately 30 percent to 37 percent. Thus far, total manufac turing output—traditionally con sidered the source of most ex ports—has remained relatively constant, while service-oriented Note: Dashed lines indicate forecasts. output has grown and is expected Source: Authors' calculations, simulation using CREIM. to increase even further (see fig ure 1). In fact, manufacturing exports were between 29 percent and 34 per vealed by CREIM over time.6 For example, cent of total output during this time, while although the impact on total output exhibits a service exports grew from 35 percent of total downward trend, it shows increased sensitivity output in 1975 to 43 percent in 2005 (see fig in 2005 relative to 1995. ure 2). As a result of this forecasted rise in The relative impact on total service em total exports, the recession vector introduced ployment decreases during each period. Simi into the model as a change in export demand larly, from beginning to end, total service relative to total output increased in size from output change, manufacturing employment change, and manufacturing output change all 1.8 percent in 1975 to 2.2 percent in 2005. exhibit modest decreases in their respective This slight increase in the size of the shock will impact its nominal effect but not the re sizes, although in each of these cases the change is not monotonic over time. Within sults, because each sector’s share of the total impact is fixed. manufacturing, nondurable output seems to be The results of the four simula tions are presented in tables 1 and 2. Table 1 shows the percent change, due to a shock, in sectoral output and employment relative to their respective values from a base case simulation where there is no external shock.4 Table 2 shows each sector’s contribution to total output and employment change caused by the shock.5 Recession im p acts The two tables suggest many interesting observations. First, in table 1, for several sectors, the changes between one column and the next are not always in the same direction. This is because of the nonlinear movements of multipliers and input/output coefficients re 4 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES more sensitive to change than TABLE 1 durable output in each time peri Sectoral effect of shock relative to a base case od. Nonetheless, employment (percent change) sensitivity early on was higher for 1975 1985 1995 2005 durable sectors; in the later fore casted years, it is higher for non -5.21 -5.80 -5.31 CGRPa -6.33 durables. E m ploym ent The impact on total value -5.37 -4.67 -4.56 Total -5.09 added for the Chicago economy, as -3.72 -3.98 -3.11 -3.55 Resource measured by gross regional prod -5.87 -5.96 -5.89 Agriculture -5.69 uct, exhibits a continuous reduction Mining -5.10 -4.70 -4.73 -5.39 overtime. In the 1975 simulated -3.02 Construction -3.25 -3.56 -2.59 recession the economy lost 6.3 -5.38 -5.42 Manufacturing -5.68 -5.61 percent of gross regional product; -5.59 -5.48 -5.48 Nondurables -5.36 -5.87 -5.62 -5.30 -5.37 however, when we apply the reces Durables -4.64 Total services -5.22 -4.98 -4.50 sion impact in other years, that -5.65 -5.39 -5.13 -5.16 TCUb level drops continuously to 5.2 -5.64 -5.32 Trade -5.51 -5.29 percent in 2005, a reduction of FIREC -5.59 -4.73 -4.66 -4.76 nearly 18 percent.7 The size and -4.64 -4.67 -4.14 -4.32 Services direction of this fall are not so -5.02 -4.71 Government -5.50 -4.73 much an indication that Chicago’s O u tp u t economy is becoming more interre Total -5.45 -5.29 -4.99 -5.08 lated over time, but more a result -3.54 -3.71 -3.17 Resource -2.76 of the increased diversification of Agriculture -5.70 -5.96 -5.85 -5.85 exports away from the cyclically Mining -5.39 -5.10 -4.70 -4.73 Construction -3.25 -3.56 -2.59 -3.02 sensitive manufacturing sectors. Manufacturing -5.96 -5.96 -5.76 -5.93 Table 2 shows that over time, -6.09 -6.12 -6.34 Nondurables -6.31 the contribution of manufacturing -5.64 -5.42 Durables -5.88 -5.38 to total output change decreases -5.29 -5.09 -4.90 -4.92 Total services quite steadily from almost 47 per -5.64 -5.37 -5.09 -5.12 TCUb cent in 1975 to less than 35 percent -5.64 -5.29 Trade -5.51 -5.32 in 2005. Within manufacturing, -5.47 FIREC -5.56 -5.63 -6.01 -4.64 -4.37 -4.12 -4.02 nondurables seem to account for Services Government -5.50 -5.13 -4.83 -4.85 more of the change, trading places with durables after the first time aChicago gross regional product. period. Not surprisingly, durable b Transportation, communications, and utilities. output was greater than nondura cFinance, insurance, and real estate. ble prior to the early 1980s. Dur ing the 1980s nondurable output throughout the period. However, the gap levels began to match those of durables; by the between nondurables’ and durables’ contribu mid-1990s we expect nondurable output to tions to employment change shrinks, so that surpass durable output. This large increase of by 2005 they make relatively equal contribu nondurable output within the Chicago area tions to total employment change. This is results from strong nominal growth in its three largely due to the fall of durables’ share of largest sectors: food and kindred products, total manufacturing employment relative to petroleum and coal products, and chemicals that of nondurables. This switch is forecasted and allied products. Additionally, the rubber and plastic products sector, although only the to continue so that eventually, nondurable industries will constitute a majority of manu fifth largest nondurable manufacturing sector, facturing employment (see figure 3). The exhibits the most dramatic growth in percent gap between durable and nondurable shares age terms. of manufacturing employment is shrinking Despite the increased contribution of the despite the larger productivity gains within nondurable sectors to output change, their nondurable industries, specifically in the contribution to employment change diminishes FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 5 TABLE 2 Sectoral share of total change (percentages) 1975 1985 1995 3.94 1.00 0.17 2.76 29.20 9.95 19.25 66.87 7.12 22.92 10.98 24.71 1.14 4.62 1.12 0.14 3.36 22.13 8.84 13.30 73.24 6.33 22.40 9.85 33.47 1.19 5.02 1.41 0.13 3.49 16.20 7.42 8.77 78.79 6.60 20.09 9.69 41.16 1.25 4.74 0.28 0.68 3.78 46.90 19.15 27.75 48.37 9.09 12.81 11.30 14.11 1.06 5.43 0.32 0.30 4.81 39.02 19.90 19.12 55.55 9.00 13.61 16.17 15.73 1.04 4.95 0.38 0.18 4.39 37.63 20.49 17.14 57.41 9.40 13.85 15.40 17.71 1.05 E m ploym e nt Resource Agriculture Mining Construction Manufacturing Nondurables Durables Total services TCUa Trade FIREb Services Government O u tp u t Resource Agriculture Mining Construction Manufacturing Nondurables Durables Total services TCUa Trade FIREb Services Government transportation, communications, and utilities. bFinance, insurance, and real estate. petroleum and coal products and rubber and plastic products sectors. At the aggregate level, manufacturing’s contribution to total employment change falls from 29 percent in 1975 to 13 percent in 2005 (table 2), undoubt edly a result of manufacturing’s declining share of total employment (see figure 4). As the Chicago region’s exports are shocked by national economic movements, the transmission of the impact from the nation to the region involves simultaneous changes of both output and employment. Such effects can easily be analyzed with the elasticity of relative productivities: ( x ] - x b) . ^ N .(xs- x b ) (xs - x b . ) ,(ns- n b) (ns -_ i' . ) ' i_ n b ) '(ns- n br i 'ZN .(Xs- x h/i' i=l' ) 6 - nb ) where x. and /? are respectively the output and employment of sector i. The variable £ is the ratio of sector Vs share of total 2005 output change divided by its share of total employment change. If £ > 1, which indi 5.37 cates transmission reduction, 1.58 then a change in output of sector 0.13 3.67 i will translate to a relatively 13.04 smaller change in employment; 6.43 the transmission mechanism will 6.61 dampen the impact of an output 81.59 shock on employment. Con 6.68 17.41 versely, if £ < 1, which is a 8.47 transmission magnification, then 47.64 a change in output of sector i 1.38 will translate to a relatively larger change in employment; 4.84 that is, the transmission mecha 0.40 nism will amplify the impact of 0.11 an output shock on employment. 4.33 34.59 Table 3 contains the elasticities 20.48 of relative productivities for all 14.11 the sectors through time. 60.57 For total services, the elastic 10.25 ity of relative productivities rises 14.56 15.39 from 0.72 to 0.74; for manufac 19.25 turing £ grows from 1.61 to 2.65. 1.12 Thus while manufacturing is becoming less sensitive to output changes, so are services; in that sector, employment is becoming less sensitive to changes in out put, although it still exhibits transmission mag nification. Since manufacturing is cyclical, the reduced sensitivity of manufacturing employ ment to output means that the Chicago economy will be less sensitive to cyclical changes. Fur thermore, although the services sector is less cyclical, its reduced employment-to-output sensitivity will further reduce Chicago’s overall vulnerability to cyclical fluctuations. This transformation is largely due to the significant productivity advances in manufacturing, which have yielded such large gains that the econo my’s total productivity is growing faster than that of services. Similar analysis can be made of changes within manufacturing. Both the durable and nondurable sectors show significant productiv ity growth, but that of nondurables is 30 per cent to 50 percent higher, accounting for large ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES FIGURE 3 Total manufacturing employment percent Note: Dashed lines indicate forecasts. Source: U.S. Department of Commerce (1995) and authors' calculations, simulation using CREIM. competitiveness of Chicago firms have set the economy in a much stronger position. Within manu facturing, significant productivi ty advances seem to account for most of the decreased sensitivity to the economic downturns of the early 1990s. This trend is ex pected to continue into the near future, with nondurables eventu ally dominating both manufac turing output and employment. In total, the service transmission magnification should be strongly outweighed by the transmission reduction of the manufacturing industries, thus reducing Chica go’s vulnerability to exogenous macroeconomic shocks. Interregional linkages As older inefficient manufacturing estab lishments have been either closed or re-tooled, firms have lost the deep roots that formerly held them to the relatively centralized industri al areas of Chicago. Thanks to advances in computers and communications, service indus tries no longer need to remain in the central business district. The allure of lower taxes and the opportunity to reduce other overhead costs has led many firms to relocate to suburban areas in order to cut costs and increase compet itiveness. As firms move, people move. In 1990, 62 percent of the six-coun ty region’s total population lived FIGURE 4 outside Chicago proper; in 1970 Manufacturing share of total employment the number was 52 percent. Dur ing this time, the city’s total percent population fell by almost 590.000 while its suburbs gained 875.000 people. As the popula tion and work force of Chicago’s six-county region have grown and spread out, a large portion of economic activity has moved into the suburbs and surrounding regions. This occurred as geo graphic consumer spending zones were pushed across region al boundaries. Accompanying this has come an increase in the number of people who work Note: Dashed lines indicate forecasts. Source: U.S. Department of Commerce (1995) and authors’ calculations, within the Chicago region but do simulation using CREIM. not live within its borders. output gains despite the continued reduction in overall employment. The overall effect becomes obvious in e/. For nondurables, eI grows from 1.93 to 3.19, while for durables it increases from 1.44 to 2.14. Thus while Chi cago will become less sensitive to exogenous manufacturing shocks, durable employment will still remain more susceptible to output variations than will nondurable employment. Thus, it appears that the thinning out of underperforming manufacturing firms in the 1970s and 1980s and the overall increased FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 7 TABLE 3 Elasticity of relative productivities 1975 Resource A g ricultu re M ining C onstruction M anufacturing N ondurables Durables Total services TCUa Trade FIREb Services G overnm ent 1985 1995 1.203 0.275 3.931 1.368 1.606 1.925 1.442 0.723 1.277 0.559 1.029 0.571 0.933 1.175 0.289 2.177 0.988 0.273 1.462 1.260 2.323 2.760 1.953 0.729 1.425 0.689 1.590 0.430 0.843 1.430 1.763 2.252 1.438 0.758 1.420 0.608 1.641 0.470 0.877 “Transportation, communications, and utilities. b Finance, insurance, and real estate. Between 1980 and 1993 the number of people who held jobs within the six-county area but who lived outside the area increased by approximately 32,000. We estimate that by 2010 this figure will increase by an additional 30,000. This means that the regions surround ing Chicago, including northern Indiana and southern Wisconsin, are becoming more de pendent on Chicago for their own economic growth as people earn money in Chicago but spend most of it in their home communities. Such a development affects the Chicago econo my in several ways. Our estimates suggest that between 1969 and 1992, those people who lived outside the Chicago area but held jobs within it had average annual wages and salaries of approximately $2 billion (in 1982 real dol lars), most of which would be spent outside Chicago. This has obvious tax consequences for the six-county region’s local governments, especially when multiplier effects are consid ered. Additionally, the growing number of nonresident employed raises the pressure on Chicago firms to increase their relative com petitiveness as they are forced to compete for quality labor. As a result, local issues such as taxes or transportation will have magnified impacts on the region as a whole. The links between Chicago, these commu nities, and other parts of the country have increased in another way as well. As men tioned, both exports from and imports into Chicago, as a percent of total output, have 8 increased. Thus Chicago has become more reliant on those regions to purchase its goods, 2005 while those regions rely on Chi cago’s products to produce their 0.900 own goods, a portion of which 0.251 will then be purchased in Chica 0.901 go. For example, a survey of 1.178 fabricated metals establishments 2.653 revealed that in 1992, 23 percent 3.186 of intermediate goods purchases 2.135 0.742 came from other midwestern 1.535 states, and 21.7 percent of sales 0.837 were made to the same region. A 1.816 further 28 percent of sales were 0.404 made to the rest of the United 0.807 States.8 This two-pronged strengthening of interregional linkages becomes important because Chicago’s economic transformation has fundamental ly changed the way the city reacts to economic stimuli, and this change will now affect other communities much more than ever before. Conclusions Chicago’s economy is not glamorous. It is not dominated by high-tech businesses or manufacturing behemoths. Its recent eco nomic performance has not been spectacular; economic growth in the 1980s lagged that of the United States, although Chicago did see less of a downturn in the early 1990s. But during the past 20 years Chicago’s economy has exhibited significant structural change, the implications of which are now beginning to surface. These structural changes appear to have yielded benefits for both Chicago and the Midwest. We have shown that Chicago has been transformed into an economy highly depen dent on the service sector for its growth and vitality. Service exports have grown relative to service output as well as to total output. This relative movement away from manufac turing exports helps reduce exposure to man ufacturing fluctuations on the macro level, thus cushioning Chicago from some macro shocks. But the overall increase of exports as a percentage of total output means that Chica go is now potentially more dependent on the rest of the Midwest and nation to provide a demand base for locally produced goods. This implies an increased exposure to macro ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES fluctuations. But within manufacturing, pro ductivity increases have been dramatic, re sults of a newly updated capital stock and a possible shift of intermediate purchases from other firms within the region to more compet itive lower-cost providers outside Chicago. This effect has strengthened manufacturing’s transmission reduction effect, the decreased sensitivity of employment to changes in out put, thus decreasing Chicago’s exposure to the highly cyclical manufacturing sectors. The economic connections between Chica go, the Midwest, and other regions have been intensifying, with local firms increasingly relying on external markets to supply interme diate goods and to purchase final goods and services. Other changes have come about on the consumer side. As population has grown in the suburbs and other outlying areas dispropor tionately to Chicago’s central business district, more people living outside Chicago have come to depend on Chicago to supply their jobs. This implies that neighboring regions now depend more heavily on Chicago to supply the funds for consumer demand. In sum, these findings suggest that Chica go’s economy is becoming less sensitive to exogenous shocks. The combined health of services and manufacturing seems to be the largest contributing factor, even though inter regional linkages are now obviously much more important than they once were. This should indicate that although Chicago’s econo my seems strong, the economic health of other midwestern economies now becomes much more significant to our own. NOTES 'We define the Chicago region as the six-county metro politan area containing Cook, DuPage, Kane, Lake, McHenry, and Will counties. (xs - x 1 . ’) ’Sector f s share of total output change is c ' = ------------'■--' yv /«..«_ rb \ The impact is similar on employment, n. ^i=i' < -V fiSee Schindler et al. (1994) for a complete discussion. 2CRE1M, defined in real 1982 dollars, forecasts output, employment, and income for 36 roughly two-digit SIC sectors, as well as many other final demand and demo graphic variables up to 25 years into the future. ’See Israilevich et al. (1994) and Schindler et al. (1994) for further details. JLet x denote output, b denote the base case, and s denote the shocked case. Then the impact of the shock on output in percentage terms for sector i, i = 1... N, is (xs~ x 1 . ;) m '= ----- -— . The impact is similar on employment, n. ’Although we present results for only four years, the general results do not change if we examine the data on an annual basis. Annually, though not continuously, the same downward trend is clear. Additionally, for the sectoral results, the tabular information is representative of annual trends. “See Carter (1994) for further details. Yh REFERENCES Carter, K.L., “The fabricated metals industry in Chicago,” University of Illinois at UrbanaChampaign, manuscript, 1994. Israilevich, P.R., and R. Mahidhara, “Chica go’s economy: Twenty years of structural change,” Economic Perspectives, Federal Re serve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 14, No. 2, March/ April 1990, pp. 15-23. ___________ , “Hog butchers no longer: 20 years of employment change in metropolitan Chicago,” Economic Perspectives, Federal Re serve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 15, No. 2, March/ April 1991, pp. 2-13. Israilevich, P.R., G.J.D. Hewings, M. Sonis, and G.R. Schindler, “Forecasting structural FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO change with a regional econometric input-output model,” Regional Economics Applications Labo ratory, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, discussion paper no. 94-T-l, 1994. Schindler, G.R., P.R. Israilevich, and G.J.D. Hewings, “Three-dimensional analysis of eco nomic performance,” Regional Economics Ap plications Laboratory, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, discussion paper no. 94-P6. 1994. U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Regional Economic Mea suring Division, “Regional economic informa tion systems report,” CD-ROM, May 1995. 9 Internal organization and economic performance: The case of large U.S. commercial banks W illiam C. Hunter Organization theorists have long been aware of the proj ductivity ramifications of firms’ organizational strucI tures and innovations. Indeed, some have asserted that if changes in business procedures and practices were patentable, their contributions to the economic growth of the nation would be as widely recognized as the influence of mechanical inventions. More recently, economists have come to realize that questions about the efficiency of production, marketing, and finance are bound up with social questions about organizational structure and change, culture, and management style and practice. As is well known, the recent deregu lation (and re-regulation) of the U.S. commer cial banking industry has had a dramatic im pact on the way in which banks produce, price, and manage their financial services—from consolidation of operations through mergers, to the more recent unbundling of traditional pack aged services, to the phenomenon of loan sales. What is less well known, particularly among academic economists studying the industry, is the dramatic set of parallel changes taking place in banks’ internal decisionmaking and organizational structures. Changes in these areas will likely have a significant impact on how efficiently banks produce their financial services, how effectively they interact with their customers, and how successfully they compete in their product markets. If the tenets of organizational economics that relate elements of internal organizational structure to the productive efficiency of firms 10 are robust across industries, then managerial and public policy prescriptions drawn from empirical studies of bank production and cost functions that take account of these influences should be better informed than those that ig nore them. Such knowledge takes on added importance given the current debate over whether universal banking as practiced in many European countries is the most appropri ate organizational structure for insuring the long-term competitiveness of U.S. banks. This article reports empirical evidence on the impact of management decisionmaking characteristics on the productive efficiency of banks. Specifically, I examine the impact on bank costs of centralized versus decentralized decisionmaking, product delivery systems, and back-office operations. The analysis is based on data from a sample of 118 large U.S. com mercial banks. The results show, first, that centralized decisionmaking tended to increase costs. Second, centralized product delivery systems either increased or had an insignificant impact on costs. In no case did centralized product and service delivery systems reduce costs as envisioned by proponents of central ization. Third, centralized back-office opera tions significantly reduced costs. This latter result is consistent with the existence of scale economies in back-office operations. W illiam C. Hunter is senior vice president and director of research at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The author owes an enorm ous debt to Stephen T im m e and thanks John Curran, Trey H o lling sw orth, Lynn W oosley, and Carolyn Keyser fo r excellent research assistance. A ny re m aining errors are the a u thor's responsibility. ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES Organizational stru c tu re and firm performance Organizational economics concerns itself with the study of organizations and organiza tional phenomena using concepts taken from contemporary organizational theory, organiza tional behavior, and microeconomics.1 The fundamental factor distinguishing organiza tional economics from traditional microeco nomic analysis of the firm is that the former views the firm as an organization that com petes with the market as a mechanism for allo cating resources, as opposed to an abstract entity characterized by a production function and an objective of profit maximization. Un der this view, firms and markets represent alternative mechanisms for providing the coor dination, control, and monitoring required for the efficient allocation of resources. For a given organizational form to survive in the long term, it must provide higher net returns than alternative institutional arrangements. Among internal organizational structures, the ones tending to predominate over time are those that tend to minimize transaction costs. According to Alfred Chandler (1977) and Oliver Williamson (1967, 1975), the optimal structure from this point of view is the multidivisional form (M-form) as opposed to the older and more traditional unitary form (U-form).2 The U-form is a centralized multifunction al organizational structure in which the major active units are functional divisions. That is, there is specialization by function such as pro duction, sales, finance, and research and devel opment, with decisionmaking responsibilities located at the top levels of the organization. The U-form favors the realization of econo mies of scale and the internal specialization of labor, but as the firm expands this form creates the following set of problems: 1) bounded rationality—managers cannot act optimally because they cannot process large volumes of information; 2) opportunism—the tendency for managers and employees to engage in behavior bene fiting themselves as opposed to stockhold ers; and 3) subgoal pursuit—placing short-term non profit-maximizing goals ahead of long-term value-maximizing goals. FEDERAL http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ RESERVE Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis BANK OF CHICAGO These problems make it difficult for the firm to achieve global profit maximization. Compared with decentralized structures, the Uform favors a less efficient pyramidal and bureaucratic hierarchy within which capital, labor, and information are allocated. In con trast, the M-form substitutes quasi-autonomous operating divisions for the functional divisions of the U-form. These operating divisions are organized mainly along product, brand, mar ket, or geographic lines. Each of the divisions may subsequently be divided along functional lines to ensure its autonomy or independence from heavy-handed decisionmaking within higher levels of the organization. Under the M-form, strategic decisionmaking occurs in the general or head office, while operating deci sions are assigned to the divisions. This struc ture thus affords the divisions a large degree of autonomy, allowing them to take their own risks in much the same way that an indepen dent firm would. Each division constitutes a quasi-firm (profit center) managed to achieve a specific objective. The M-form combines the best features of centralization (such as realization of economies of scale) and decentralization (such as provid ing proper incentives for profit maximization). As such, it creates a superior organizational structure compared to the U-form and the ex ternal market. Williamson's hypothesis essen tially states that the M-form organizational structure favors goal pursuit and least-cost behavior that is more closely associated with the neoclassical profit maximization hypothesis than does the U-form. Not surprisingly, Williamson’s hypothesis has been subjected to numerous empirical tests. Studies by Armour and Teece (1978), Burton (1988), Cable and Dirrheimer (1983), Cable and Hirohiko (1985), Norton and Pittman (1988), Steer and Cable (1978), Riordan and Williamson (1985), Roberts and Viscione (1981), Teece (1981), and Thompson (1981) are only a few of those providing empirical support. The results favoring the M-form as the least-cost organizational structure have generally proved robust not only across indus tries, but across countries as well.3 However, with the exception of the article by Roberts and Viscione, which examines captive finance companies, all of the above studies examined nonfinancial firms. The following sections 11 lay out a test of aspects of the hypothesis among large U.S. commercial banks. The internal stru c tu re of large U .S . banks Prior to the early 1970s, large banks oper ated predominantly with U-form organizational structures. Functional units at the top reported directly to the chief executive officer, whose responsibilities included reconciling functional subgoals and determining strategic directions. Since the U-form performs best in a stable and predictable environment, it is understandable that the U-form was dominant among large banks during this period when the economic and regulatory environments were stable and predictable. Since the 1970s, changes in these econom ic and regulatory environments have eroded many of the advantages of the U-form. As a consequence, large U.S. commercial banks have to some extent paralleled the transition from U-form to M-form observed in nonfinancial firms during earlier years.4 The natural response to the increased competition from nonbank firms and the geographic and product deregulation occurring during this period was for banks to develop explicit marketing func tions, thus moving toward the market-oriented structure observed in most large banks today. This market-oriented structure is similar in many respects to the M-form of organization. The principal characteristic of the marketoriented structure is the elevation of customerand market-based departments to top organiza tional levels. Departments are organized around groups of customers rather than around banking functions; all products and functions necessary to serve a particular group of cus tomers tend to be housed in one department. Examples of such departments include corpo rate or commercial banking, retail and private banking, and real estate banking. All of these departments report to the chief executive offic er. The strategy of the market-oriented bank is essentially to be in the right markets with the right products at the right time. Compared with the U-form, the marketoriented structure is less centralized, less spe cialized, and somewhat less formalized.5 Con flicts are resolved according to the objectives of the bank instead of those of the individual functions, and managers have profit responsi bilities. Thus, difficulties in coordination and 12 control are corrected by means of a more effec tive incentive system and by the elimination of competition between functional units. These characteristics make decisionmaking in the market-oriented structure more decentralized than it is in the U-form. As banks shifted to market-oriented struc tures during the 1980s, they switched from decentralized to more centralized delivery systems. In the centralized delivery system, an agent (i.e., account representative) handles all of the needs of the customer with respect to product and service delivery. That is, the ac count representative acts as an intermediary between the customer and members of the bank’s functional areas producing such servic es as lending, cash management, and trust, among others. Conversely, in a decentralized delivery system, employees from each func tional area call on and service the customer directly. The switch to centralized delivery systems was motivated by several factors. First, under decentralized systems, banks often did not know overall customer profitability since there was generally limited communication and coordination between functional areas. Sec ond, it was believed that the switch to a cen tralized delivery system would increase cus tomer perceptions of service quality, since in centralized delivery systems service problems are handled by one individual as opposed to several functional-area specialists. Finally, centralized delivery systems were thought to be a more cost-effective way to service customers. As noted earlier, the market-oriented structure described above is similar in many respects to the multidivisional M-form. Both of them separate strategic decisionmaking from the decisionmaking of operating divisions (i.e., decentralization), and both have internal controls and incentives that eliminate the prob lems of opportunism, loss of control, and bounded rationality that characterize the Uform.6 Thus, the recent transformation in the banking industry parallels that which occurred earlier in other industries. The data The data on internal organizational struc ture used in the analysis were obtained from a survey and follow-up telephone interviews conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES Atlanta with the chief operations T A B LE 1 officers of the 145 largest U.S. Structure of 118 sample commercial banks commercial bank holding compa A . Decisionmaking nies for the period October 1990 through July 1991, as listed on the N um ber of banks Percent of to ta l BANK COMPUSTAT tape. Of the 145 banks surveyed, complete data 50.85 60 Centralized were collected for 118 banks, ap 58 49.15 Decentralized proximately an 81 percent response rate. The remaining 27 companies B. Delivery systems either provided incomplete organi Percent of to ta l Num ber of banks zational data or were in the process of changing their internal organiza 64.41 73 Centralized tional structure. 35.59 45 Decentralized For each bank in the sample, information was obtained on 1) C. Operations whether the bank(s) within the Percent of to ta l N um ber of banks holding company operated with internal structures organized 86.44 102 Centralized around customer or market groups 16 13.56 Decentralized versus functional areas; 2) whether decisions regarding credit adminis tration and the pricing of fee-based services PUSTAT tapes. Financial data on each sample were centralized at the level of the holding bank for fiscal years 1989 through 1991 were company or at the lead bank headquarters; collected. The average sample bank had ap 3) whether the delivery of services to customer proximately $16.0 billion in total assets and or market groups was centralized within a $1.6 billion in total costs (total non-interest single customer contact unit and provided by costs plus allocated interest expense). account representatives, or provided on a de To facilitate the analysis, I grouped all of centralized basis by all units producing the the sample banks into seven categories accord services; and 4) whether back-office operations ing to their organizational characteristics (see (accounting, computer facilities, advertising, table 2). Table 3 presents selected summary etc.) were centralized or decentralized. statistics for the sample. Note that there were The survey revealed that all respondents no banks with organizational form C, and only were organized around either customers or one with organizational form D. Data from the markets. Hence, all sample companies exhibit latter bank were used in the estimation of the ed some characteristics of the M-form organi cost function but not in the hypothesis tests. zational structure. Table 1 summarizes other results of the survey. As panel A shows, deci T A B LE 2 sions regarding credit administration and the Bank organizational forms pricing of fee-based services were centralized in approximately 51 percent of the banks. That D ecision Delivery is, these decisions were made at the holding Form m aking system s O perations company or lead bank headquarters level, not A c c c at the division or non-lead-bank level. Central B c d c ized product and service delivery systems were d c C c employed at 64 percent of the banks (panel B). D d d c Back-office operations were centralized at 86 c c E d percent (panel C). This finding is consistent d d c F with the notion that such centralization yields c d d G significant scale economies. Note: c = centralized; d = decentralized. Other data needed to conduct the empirical analysis were taken from the BANK COM FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 13 Th e econometric model where To examine the impact of internal organi zational structure on bank cost and productive efficiency, I used the following cost function: where TC is the bank’s total cost of production, Q is a vector of the products or services pro duced, P is a vector of input prices, and ORG is a vector of inputs that describe the bank’s organizational structure. Three binary organizational variables— DEC, DEL, and OPER (the elements in ORG in equation 1)—were constructed for each sample firm. The variable DEC was assigned a value of 1 if a bank used centralized decision making regarding credit administration and the pricing of fee-based services, zero if these decisions were decentralized. The variable DEL was assigned a value of 1 if the delivery system within a customer or market group was centralized and provided through an intermedi ary agent, zero if it was decentralized and pro vided by agents from functional areas. Finally, the variable OPER was assigned a value of 1 if back-office operations were centralized, zero if decentralized. To estimate the cost function in equation 1, the following second-order translog approxi mation to a multiproduct bank cost function was applied: (2) InTC = a 0 + I m a m InP + 1/21m I n a m.n InP InP m m n + Z,P,lnQ, + \l2Zl.fi.JnQtlnQk + I j I m T j.m ip '*“ '7 InQlnP+ d,,.,DEC D EC m + + \ S DKJnPDEC + SoaDEL + Zj Sm InO DEL DEL.J + I m SnF m InPm DEL I DEL, + S ^O P E R + Z S ^ ln Q O P E R + ^■APmJnPOPER + ^P E C -D E L + ^ c.oKSDEC‘OPER + S ^ fiE L -O P E R + for m, n = L, K, and j, k = C&I, Consumer, R/E, and Other, 14 = total costs (non-interest costs plus interest expense allocated to loans), ecll (1) TC = i(Q,P,ORG), TC = dollar volume of commercial and industrial loans, ^ C o n su m e r = dollar volume of consumer loans, ^ R/E = dollar volume of real estate loans, ()ther = other bank output, = price of labor (L) Labor PCapital = price of capital (K) P, Interest = interest rate on deposits (I) DEC = decisionmaking dummy vari able, which equals l if central ized and zero otherwise. DEL = system of service delivery dummy variable, which equals l if centralized and zero other wise, OPER = back-office operations dummy variable, which equals l if centralized and zero otherwise, and £ = an error term. In estimating the model in equation 2 ,1 imposed the usual symmetry (a = a and Pjk = Pk) an<^ adding-up and homogeneity conditions ( I m a = 1 and Irn '0 = X am,n = x m j,m n I S =I 8 =X 8 = 0). D e fin itio n o f outp uts All bank cost studies encounter the diffi culties associated with the definition of output, the appropriate level of aggregation of output, and costs. It is beyond the scope of this article to resolve whether various categories of depos its should be treated as outputs or inputs.7 For this study, I treated the dollar volume of all deposits as an input. In addition, using a proxy variable, I treated clearing balances and other deposit-related activities as outputs. Regarding the specific definition of the outputs in equation 2 ,1 used the criterion of value added employed by Berger, Hanweck, and Humphrey (1987) to determine the compo- ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES T A B LE 3 Summary statistics for 118 sample banks A. 60 banks with centralized decisionmaking O rganizational fo rm N um ber of banks Total assets Total costs (-— billion dollars-— ) A B 35 $11.59 24 10.49 C 0 D 1 n.a.a 45.60 $0.96 0.80 n.a.a 3.06 Input prices B. 73 banks with centralized delivery systems O rganizational fo rm N um ber of banks Total assets Total costs (— billion dollars-— ) A 35 C 0 E F 26 21.91 2.22 12 24.30 2.01 $11.59 n.a.3 $0.96 n.a.a C. 102 banks with centralized operations O rganizational form N um ber o f banks T otal assets Total costs (-— billion dollars-— ) A B E 35 $11.59 24 10.49 26 21.91 G 17 18.45 a Not applicable. sition of the various output categories. Whole sale loans (<2Citl) were defined as the dollar volume of all commercial and industrial and security loans. Consumer loans (Qr. ) were defined as the dollar volume of credit cards and other personal loans excluding loans se cured by residential real estate. Real estate loans ((2r/h) were defined as all loans secured by real estate. Other bank output (Q0ther) was included in an attempt to capture off-balancesheet activities such as loan sales, letters of credit, securitization, and swaps—activities that are becoming increasingly important at U.S. commercial banks. The proxy Q was set equal to annual non-interest income includ ing service charges received on transaction and nontransaction deposit accounts. Finally, secu rities were excluded from the definition of output, since in markets exhibiting low infor mation costs, banks add only negligible if any value to these assets. The choice of these four FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO output measures was tempered by the objective of examining multi product cost attributes within an econometrically tractable model of the banking firm. Hence, it was a maintained hypothesis that for a given output category, a single cost function adequately characterized the production of each of the activities aggregated within that category. $0.96 The price of labor (P ) was defined as salaries plus bene fits divided by number of em ployees. The price of capital (Pn ,) was defined as the ratio of occupancy and fixed asset expense to net bank premises. The interest rate on deposits (P, ) was calculated as the interest rate paid on all deposits divided by the sum of all inter est-bearing deposits outstanding. To ta l costs Total costs (TC) were defined as total non-interest costs plus 1.46 allocated interest expense. Inter est expenses are included since data limitations require that the output metric be defined in terms of dollars of loans and deposits instead of by the number of accounts. Allocated interest equaled the product of the ratio of total loans to earning assets times total interest expense. The allocation of interest was necessary be cause securities are not specified as outputs, and many banks incur substantial interest costs in financing their securities portfolio. The output/cost specification described above is consistent with the intermediation approach to examining bank costs; it is preferable when the issues being examined concern the economic viability of banks. 0.80 2.22 Hypotheses regarding organizational fo rm The variables DEC, DEL, and OPER were used to test several hypotheses regarding the impact of organizational form on costs (effi ciency). The first question was whether organiza tional factors help explain bank cost structures. 15 Testing this hypothesis involved determining if the coefficients associated with the organiza tional structure variables in equation 2 were jointly equal to zero. That is, for each organiza tional variable i, (i = DEC, DEL, and OPER): (3) 8 = 8 =8 = 8 , =0. The second hypothesis related to the im pact of centralization on costs. With the pa rameter estimates from equation 2, the hy pothesis can be stated as (4) dlnTC/dORG = 8 + X < InQ + X < InP 5 5 + ORGh = 0. This equation measures the percentage increase in total costs (TC) resulting from centralization of the ith organizational variable holding out puts, prices, and other organizational variables constant. For the multiproduct firm, ray scale econo mies (RSCE) were measured by (5) RSCE = 'LdlnTC(Q)/dlnQr where TC{*) is the cost function, (9 represents the outputs specified in equation 2, and Q is the vector of outputs. If RSCE equals 1.0, production of Q exhibits constant returns to scale, whereas RSCE less than (greater than) 1.0 indicates increasing (decreasing) returns to scale. The third hypothesis concerned the impact of centralization on scale economies and can be stated as (6) dRSCE/dORG‘ = X < . = 0. 5 j ij This equation measures the impact of central ization of the ith organizational variable on scale economies holding outputs, prices, and other organizational variables constant. Em pirical re su lts and im plications Full information maximum likelihood (FIML) was used to jointly estimate the model in equation 2 with factor input share equations. Using Shepard’s lemma, the share equations are given by dlnTC/dlnPm= Sm for m = L, K, , and /, where Smis the mth input’s share of total costs. Since the coefficients in the share equa tions are a subset of those in the cost function 16 in equation 2, joint estimation should result in more efficient estimates. However, since X;Sm= 1, the capital share is dropped from the joint estimation to avoid singularity.8 Likelihood ratio tests were conducted to test the hypothesis given in equation 3 regarding the significance of the organizational variables in explaining total costs. The chi-square statis tics for DEC, DEL, and OPER were 28.41, 46.42, and 32.54, respectively. All test statistics were significant at the .01 level. These results suggest that the organizational variables were significant in explaining the structure of bank costs as specified in equation 2. Impact o f centralization on costs Table 4 reports the tests of the hypotheses in equation 4. For each test, the impact of centralization with respect to a given organiza tional variable was evaluated holding constant quantities, prices, and other organizational variables. Quantities and prices were set equal to their geometric means for the overall sam ple. In this way, variations in costs were at tributed to differences in organizational forms. For each test, the organizational forms associ ated with the null and alternative hypotheses are given. Because some groups lacked suffi cient membership, two out of four tests were conducted for centralized decisionmaking, two out of four for centralized delivery systems, and one out of four for centralized back-office operations. D ecisionmaking The results in table 4, panel A suggest that a change to centralized decisionmaking significantly increased costs relative to decen tralized decisionmaking. For a bank with cen tralized delivery systems and operations, a change from decentralized to centralized deci sionmaking increased costs by 3.68 percent (significant at the .10 level). For a bank with decentralized delivery systems and centralized operations, a change from decentralized to centralized decisionmaking increased costs by 9.57 percent (significant at the .01 level). In no case did a switch to centralized decision making decrease costs. Both of these findings appear to be economically significant consider ing that the average bank’s costs equal $1.4 billion and assets equal $16 billion. For the average sample bank, a 3.68 (9.57) percent increase in total costs would be associated with ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES TABLE 4 Impact of centralization on total costs A. Impact on total costs from centralized decisionmaking Organizational structure underlying null hypothesis (Organizational structure underlying alternative hypothesis) Test number Centralized decisionmaking Centralized delivery systems Centralized operations Number of firms Test statistic 1 yes (no) yes (yes) yes (yes) 35 26 3.68%* (2.07%)a 2 yes (no) no (no) yes (yes) 24 17 9.5 7% *** (2.64%)a B. Impact on total costs from centralized delivery systems Organizational structure underlying null hypothesis (Organizational structure underlying alternative hypothesis) Test number Centralized decisionmaking Centralized delivery systems Centralized operations Number of firms Test statistic 3 yes (yes) yes (no) yes (yes) 35 24 0.68% (2.36%)a 4 no (no) yes (no) yes (yes) 26 17 6.5 3% *** (2.27%)a C. Impact on total costs from centralized operations Organizational structure underlying null hypothesis (Organizational structure underlying alternative hypothesis) Test number Centralized delivery systems Centralized operations Number of firms Test statistic 5 | Centralized decisionmaking no (no) yes (yes) yes (no) 35 24 -3.97% ** (1.85%)a Standard error. * * * * * * Significant at the .10, .05, and .01 levels, respectively. a reduction in return on assets of 21 (55) basis points, using a marginal tax rate of 34 percent. Given that the average sample bank's return on assets averaged approximately 60 basis points from 1989 to 1991, these effects are of great economic significance. Delivery of services The results in table 4, panel B indicate that for banks with centralized decisionmaking and operations, a change from a decentralized to a centralized service delivery system had no significant impact on costs. For banks with decentralized decisionmaking and centralized operations, centralization of the service deliv ery system increased costs by approximately 6.53 percent (significant at the .01 level). In neither case did the results suggest a reduction FEDERAL http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ RESERVE Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis BANK OF CHICAGO in costs. This is in contrast to the notion dis cussed above that centralizing a service deliv ery system will produce cost savings. Howev er, these results and those above should be interpreted with caution, since other motiva tions for centralizing (such as improving the analysis of customer profitability or the quality of service) may be at work. Back-office operations The results in table 4, panel C suggest that for a bank with decentralized decisionmaking and centralized service delivery systems, cen tralizing back-office operations reduced costs by approximately 4 percent (significant at the .05 level). This finding is consistent with pre vious research which reports fairly large scale economies for back-office operations (see 17 Hunter and Timme 1986, for example). Hence, one would expect banks to centralize backoffice operations in order to capture these scale economies. Impact o f centralization on scale economies Using the parameter estimates from equa tion 2, the estimated scale economies for a bank with decentralized decisionmaking, deliv ery systems, and back-office operations equalled 0.945 (significant at the .05 level). This indicates increasing returns to scale, on average, for this class of bank. This result is consistent with the findings of Hunter and Timme (1986) and Hunter, Timme, and Yang (1990). Those studies examined scale econo mies for large U.S. banks but did not include organizational variables of the type included in this study. Table 5 reports tests of the impact of cen tralization on scale economies, the hypothesis given by equation 6. The test statistics for a bank with centralized decisionmaking, delivery systems, and operations were -0.0040, 0.0260, and -0.0023, respectively. None of the test statistics was significant at standard confidence levels. These results imply that centralization did not have a significant impact on scale econ omies, although it did have a significant impact on bank costs. It appears, then, that cost ineffi ciencies dominate the effects of scale econo mies in explaining variations in bank costs. Conclusions This article provides empirical evidence on the impact of internal organizational struc ture on bank costs. Specifically, I examined the impact of centralized versus decentralized decisionmaking, product and service delivery systems, and back-office operations on bank costs and productive efficiency. The analysis used average data from a sample of 118 large U.S. commercial banks for the years 1989 through 1991. The results can be summarized as follows. First, centralized decisionmaking tended to increase costs. Second, centralized service delivery systems either increased or had an insignificant impact on costs. In no 18 T A B LE 5 Impact of centralization on scale economies Test num ber O rganizational stru ctu re 6 Centralized decisionm aking 7 Centralized delivery systems 8 Centralized operations Test s ta tis tic -0.0040 (1.29) 0.0260 (2.27) -0.0023 (1.41) Note: Standard errors in parentheses. case did centralized service delivery systems reduce costs as envisioned by proponents of centralization. Third, centralized back-office operations significantly reduced costs. This latter result is consistent with the existence of scale economies in bank back-office opera tions such as accounting, computing, and advertising. These results provide new insights into the determinants of bank cost and efficiency char acteristics, highlight the importance of organi zational variables in financial firm production, and point to the need to incorporate these vari ables into future bank efficiency studies. The results do not, however, answer numerous questions as to why a bank would adopt an organizational form which (according to the evidence) increases costs. In this regard, sev eral further approaches would appear promis ing. First, it may be useful to examine the impact of organizational structure on other measures of performance (such as profits, return on assets, or risk-adjusted holding peri od returns) and on bank risk. Second, insight can be obtained from examining the effects of organizational forms in a dynamic framework. Since this article examines data covering only three years, we cannot know if the results char acterize banks in a state of transition, where the full benefits of the selected organizational forms would not be fully recognized, or banks operating in steady state. ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES NOTES 'Among the many noted contributors to the field of orga nizational economics, I draw heavily on the works of Beckmann (1960), Chandler (1977), and Williamson (1967. 1975). 'Williamson actually describes a range of organizational forms in his 1975 book. These include the corrupted H-, U-, and M-forms, and variations of these. 'In these studies, firm internal organizational structure is classified into categories such as the U-form or M-form, among others. This classification is entered as a regres sor in an equation relating some performance character istic (profitability, efficiency, etc.) to firm and market characteristics generally thought to be determinants of performance. 4The discussion in this section draws heavily on Channon (1986) and Donnelly and Skinner (1989). 'Certain activities may remain centralized where definite economies of scale are thought to exist, such as account ing or computing. Thus, movement towards less special ization among employees, i.e., requiring that they have knowledge of various functional areas as well as the needs of the customer, does not necessarily imply that the organization loses much in the way of productive efficiency. h While the market-oriented structure has essential fea tures of the M-form, the two are not exactly equivalent. This is because the M-form evolved in the manufactur ing sector. Perhaps the best way to describe the marketoriented structure is as the financial-sector equivalent of the M-form. 'Hunter, Timme, and Yang (1990), examining the largest U.S. commercial banks, provide separate estimates of bank cost characteristics, treating deposits first as outputs and then as inputs. Holding product mix constant and treating deposits as outputs, they observe returns to scale which are roughly constant for the average sample bank, generally mild diseconomies of scale for the larger banks ($3 billion to $25 billion in total assets stated in 1986 dollars), and rather large diseconomies for the largest banks (more than $25 billion in assets) when analyzed on a subgroup basis. Holding product mix constant and treating deposits as inputs, they find significantly increas ing scale economies for banks up to $5 billion in assets and constant scale economies for banks with assets be tween $5 billion and $10 billion. Banks with assets between $10 billion and $25 billion are found to exhibit mild diseconomies, while the largest banks with more than $25 billion in assets exhibit significantly large dis economies of scale. 8Maximum likelihood estimates are invariant to which one of the share equations is dropped from the joint estimation. REFERENCES Armour, H. O., and David J. Teece, “Organi zation structure and economic performance: A test of the multidivisional hypothesis,” Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 9, Spring 1978, pp. 106-122. Cable, John, and Manfred J. Dirrheimer, “Hierarchies and markets: An empirical test of the multidivisional hypothesis in West Germa ny,” International Journal of Industrial Orga nization, Vol. 1, 1983, pp. 13-62. Beckmann, Martin J., “Some aspects of re turns to scale in business administration,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 74, August 1960, pp. 464-471. Cable, John, and Yasuki Hirohiko, “Internal organization, business groups and corporate performance: An empirical test of the multidi visional hypothesis in Japan,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 3, December 1985, pp. 101-120. Berger, P., G. Hanweck, and R. Humphrey, “Competitive viability in banking: Scale, scope, and productivity mix economics,” Jour nal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 20, No. 2, December 1987, pp. 501-520. Burton, Richard, “Opportunism, incentives, and the M-form hypothesis: A laboratory study,” Journal o f Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 10, July 1988, pp. 99-119. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO Caves, Richard E., “Industrial organization, corporate strategy, and structure,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 18, March 1980, pp. 64-92. Chamberlain, Edward H., The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962. 19 Chandler, Alfred, Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of Industrial Enter prise, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1962. v ______________ , The Visible Hand, Cam bridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977. Channon, Derek F., Bank Strategic Manage ment and Marketing, New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1986. Coase, Ronald H., “The nature of the firm,” Economica, Vol. 4, November 1937, pp. 386405. Donnelly, James H., and Steven J. Skinner, The New Banker, Homewood, IL: Dow JonesIrwin, 1989. Hirshleifer, Jack, Price Theory and Applica tions', Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1980. Hunter, William C., and Stephen G. Timme, “Technical change, organizational form, and the structure of bank production,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 18, No. 2, May 1986, pp. 152-166. Hunter, William C., Stephen G. Timme, and W.K. Yang, “An examination of cost subaddi tivity and multiproduct production in large U.S. banks,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 22, November 1990, pp. 504-525. Norton, Edgar, and Russell Pittman, “Mform organization and firm profitability,” Re view of Industrial Organization, Vol. 3, Spring 1988, pp. 1-14. Roberts, Gordon, and Jerry A. Viscione, “Captive finance subsidiaries and the M-form hypothesis,” Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 12, Spring 1981, pp. 285-295. Steer, Peter, and John Cable, “Internal orga nization and profit: An empirical analysis of large U.K. companies,” Journal of Industrial Economics, September 1978, pp. 13-30. Stigler, George J., The Theory o f Price, New York: Macmillan, 1966. __________________, “Management produc tion functions in the theory of the firm,” Jour nal of Economic Theory, Vol. 14, February 1977, pp. 1-18. Teece, David J., “Internal organization and economic performance: An empirical analysis of the profitability of principal firms,” Journal of Industrial Economics, December 1981, pp. 173-199. __________________, “Towards an economic theory of the multiproduct firm,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 3, 1982, pp. 39-63. Thompson, R. S., “Internal organization and profit: A note,” Journal of Industrial Econom ics, Vol. 30, December 1981, pp. 201-211. Williamson, Oliver E., “Hierarchical control and optimum firm size,” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 75, April 1967, pp. 123-138. _________________, Markets and Hierar chies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York: Free Press, 1975. Riordan, M., and Oliver Williamson, “Asset specificity and economic organization,” Inter national Journal o f Industrial Organization, Vol. 3, 1985, pp. 365-368. ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES B U L K RATE P ublic In fo rm a tio n C en ter Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago P.O. Box 834 C hicago, Illinois 60690 -0 8 3 4 U .S . P O S TA G E PA ID C H IC A G O , IL L IN O IS P E R M IT NO. 1942 Do n o t fo rw a rd A d d ress c o rre c tio n re q u es ted R eturn p o s tag e g u a ra n te e d M a ilin g la b e l c o rre c tio n s or d e le tio n s Correct or mark Delete from mailing list on the label and fax it to 312-322-2341, or send to: Mail Services Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago P.O. Box 834 Chicago. Illinois 60690-0834 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO