The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
NO VEM BER/DECEM BER 19 93 ECONOMIC PERSPECTI1 ong-term earnings losses of high-seniority displaced workers lost effective control of urban smog: a report of a conference held at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 7-8, 1993 Index for 1993 (FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO Call for Papers 1994 Conference on Bank Structure & Competition Contents Long-term earnings losses of high-seniority displaced workers................................................................. 2 Louis S. Jaco b so n, R o b ert J. LaLonde, and D aniel G. Sullivan During the 1980s, many high-seniority workers lost jobs because of plant closings and mass layoffs. The authors examine the long-term earnings losses suffered by such workers and the extent to which assistance programs can offset those losses. Call for conference papers 21 Cost effective control of urban smog: a report of a conference held at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 7-8, 19 93..................................22 Richard F. Kosobud, W illia m A . T esta, and D onald A . Hanson With the move toward market-based incentives, public policy to control urban smog is headed in promising new directions. The authors give a brief overview of the issue and of a recent conference on the subject at the Chicago Fed. Index for 1993 25 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES N o vem ber/D ecem ber 1993 V o lum e X V II, Issue 6 Karl A. Scheld, Senior Vice President and ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank. Single-copy subscriptions are available free of charge. Please send requests for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions, back issues, and address changes to the Public Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834, or telephone 312-322-5111. Articles may be reprinted provided source is credited and the Public Information Center is sent a copy of the published material. Director o f Research Editorial direction Janice W eiss, editor David R. Allardice, regional studies Steven Strongin, economic policy and research Anne Weaver, administration Production Nancy Ahlstrom, typesetting coordinator Rita M olloy, Yvonne Peeples, typesetters Kathleen Solotroff, graphics coordinator Roger Thryselius, Thomas O ’Connell, Lynn Busby-Ward, John Dixon, graphics Kathryn Moran, assistant editor ISSN 0164-0682 Long-term earnings losses of high-seniority displaced workers Louis S. Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde, and D aniel G. Sullivan The recent recession and con tinuing slow employment growth have focused renewed attention on the plight of dis placed workers—workers whose job loss results from the plant closings and mass layoffs associated with economic restructuring. It has long been clear that such workers suffer short-term earnings losses if they are forced into unemployment while searching for new jobs.1 What has been less clear, howev er, is the magnitude of any long-term losses from reduced earnings on these new jobs. This article provides evidence that for displaced workers who had substantial seniority with their former employers, these long-term earnings losses are highly significant and, in fact, cumula tively much larger than the earnings losses they suffer while unemployed. Displacement is, of course, not limited to recessions. Rather, displacement is a normal feature of a dynamic economy in which techno logical progress and changing consumer tastes constantly necessitate economic restructuring. The Congressional Budget Office recently esti mated that during the 1980s, 20 million workers lost jobs because of plant closings and perma nent layoffs. Even in the relatively strong labor market that prevailed in 1988, 1.5 million work ers lost jobs in this way.2 The aggregate econo my benefits from this frequent restructuring. Nevertheless, many have shown a concern for the losses suffered by some of those who do not benefit—the displaced workers. Concern has been especially great for work ers who are displaced as a result of changes in government policy. For instance, trade liberal ization is almost certainly good for the country as a whole. In addition to lowering prices for consumers, it increases opportunities for exportproducing sectors of the economy and is likely to result in a net increase in jobs for U.S. work ers. Despite these benefits, however, some workers are likely to be displaced as a result of increased imports.3 Policymakers have tried to help such workers, either because they believe fairness requires it or because they believe such assistance is the only way to win enough politi cal support for freer trade. In either case, they have an interest in knowing the full losses suf fered by job losers. Assessing the full costs borne by displaced workers is even more important when the net benefits of policy changes that lead to displace ment are less clearly positive than those of freer trade. In such cases, policymakers need to be concerned not only with compensating the los ers, but also with determining whether the policy change should be made at all. For instance, from an economic perspective, additional environ mental regulations should only be imposed if the benefits of such regulations exceed their full costs, including the costs borne by any workers who lose their jobs. Similarly, much debate over appropriate monetary and fiscal policy can be cast in terms of a trade-off between inflation and 2 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES Louis S. Jacobson is senior economist with Westat Incorporated. Robert J. LaLonde is an associate professor in the University of Chicago Graduate School of Business. Daniel G. Sullivan is a senior research economist and research officer with the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. unemployment. If some of this unemployment takes the form of permanent job loss, then the net benefits of further reductions in inflation depend on the magnitude of any long-term earn ings losses experienced by affected workers. If workers’ skills were perfectly general in the sense that they were equally valuable to all employers and if earnings only reflected work ers’ accumulated skills, then displacement might not have any long-term consequences. Howev er, workers possessing skills that were especially well-suited to their old positions are likely to be less productive, at least initially, on their subse quent jobs. Such a fit between workers’ skills and the requirements of their old jobs could have resulted from on-the-job investment in firmspecific human capital or from costly search resulting in particularly good matches with their old firms.4 Moreover, workers losing jobs that paid wage premiums that didn’t merely depend on their accumulated skills are likely to have long term losses if their subsequent jobs pay standard wages. Such wage premiums could have arisen because of direct or threatened effects of unions, or because employers voluntarily chose to pay higher wages because doing so directly raised workers’ productivity.5 Finally, displaced workers’ long-term earn ings will be lower if, on their previous jobs, they had accepted wages below their level of produc tivity in return for higher earnings later in their careers. Economists have interpreted internal labor market phenomena and promotion-fromwithin policies as attempts by firms to imple ment such deferred compensation schemes. Workers might have accepted such earnings paths in order to enhance their employers’ incentive to invest in their human capital.6 These theoretical considerations suggest that displaced workers could suffer earnings losses after they find new jobs. They do not, however, tell us how large those losses are likely to be or how long the losses might persist. Empirical analysis is required to determine whether displacement is a relatively temporary setback from which workers quickly recover once they find new jobs or, alternatively, whether it is an essentially permanent blow to workers’ living standards. In this article, we examine the long-term consequences of displacement for workers who had accumulated substantial seniority with their former employers. Using newly developed data FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO from the administrative records of the state of Pennsylvania, we study the earnings histories of a group of workers who left declining firms between 1980 and 1986 after working for those firms since at least 1974. By observing these workers’ earnings for several years before and after their separations, as well as the earnings of workers whose employment relationships endured throughout our sample period, we are able to assess displaced workers’ long-term earnings losses much better than has previously been possible. Workers with seniority as high as those we study make up only a small portion of all lay offs. Nationally, we estimate that during the period 1980-86, approximately 350,000 such workers were displaced per year, about 18 per cent of all displacements. Nevertheless, highseniority workers are likely to account for a significant fraction of earnings losses because they are more likely to have accumulated firmspecific skills or to have been particularly well matched to their former employers. Likewise, because earnings premiums and deferred com pensation decrease quit rates, high-seniority workers are more likely than others to experi ence earnings losses due to displacement for these reasons as well. Our principal finding is that high-seniority workers suffer large, seemingly permanent earnings losses as the result of displacement. Even five years after their separations, the aver age annual losses of the workers we studied were approximately 25 percent of their 1979 earnings. We also observe several important patterns to the earnings losses. For instance, workers losing jobs in depressed labor markets and those formerly employed in highly union ized durable goods industries experience espe cially large losses. Nevertheless, we find that workers of nearly every description experi enced significant losses. Even workers who found new jobs in the same industry had major earnings losses, a finding that suggests the importance of highly firm-specific features in workers’ employment relationships. In the next section we describe the data that underlie our analysis. Next we discuss the specific definition of earnings losses due to displacement that is adopted in this article and present some simple estimates of those losses for the cohort of displaced workers who separated from their former firms in the fourth quarter of 1981. The subsequent section 3 presents results derived from our full data set showing how losses vary over time and across workers. This is followed by a discussion of some of the steps policymakers have taken to assist displaced workers. Finally, we offer some brief conclusions. T h e P e n n sylva n ia data The empirical work described in this article assesses the magnitude and temporal pattern of earnings losses suffered by workers displaced in Pennsylvania between 1980 and 1986. We have limited our analysis to these workers in order to take advantage of a rich set of administrative data on Pennsylvanian workers and their firms. By combining quarterly earnings histories for a 5 percent sample of the state’s workers with their firms’ employment data, we have created a data set that contains workers’ quarterly earnings from 1974 through 1986 as well as information about their firms, including employment levels and growth, geographic location, and four-digit SIC industry.7 By observing changes in the sources of earnings, we were able to date with high accuracy the quarter in which some work ers separated from firms experiencing substan tial employment declines. We also identified other workers who remained continuously em ployed by a single firm. These administrative data have several advantages for assessing the losses suffered by displaced workers. First, they track workers’ earnings over a relatively long period of time. This allows us to distinguish short-term from long-term losses and also to be more confident that our results are free of statistical biases.8 Second, they contain information on a large number of displaced workers. This allows us to provide useful results for relatively narrowly defined groups of workers. Third, they include information on employment changes in workers’ firms. This allows us to identify workers who separated from distressed firms. Such workers are likely to have been displaced rather than to have quit or been dismissed for cause. Finally, they contain information on a large number of nondisplaced workers. This allows us to borrow statistical techniques from the program evalua tion literature in order to obtain more reliable estimates of the cost of displacement, including the loss of earnings growth that would have occurred in the absence of job loss. Our Pennsylvania data set also allows us to avoid two problems inherent in the use of stan 4 dard survey-based data sets. First, earnings in data such as the Current Population Survey (CPS) and Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) are reported by workers with significant error, while our data are based on firms’ reports that are used to calculate tax liabilities and are presumably virtually free of measurement error.9 Second, workers in data sets such as the Dis placed Worker Supplements (DWS) to the CPS are less likely to report instances of job loss the longer ago the displacement occurred. If, as seems likely, the less severe setbacks are the ones not reported, it becomes difficult to use this data to determine the rate of recovery from job loss. By contrast, our administrative data allow us to identify all of workers’ separations. There are also some disadvantages to using these data. Most obviously, they report only on Pennsylvanian workers. Although we cannot be sure that their experiences reflect the experienc es of displaced workers generally, it is worth noting that Pennsylvania is a large state with a diverse industrial base. Further, during the peri od covered by this study, the economic perfor mance of the eastern half of the state, which shared in the growth experienced by the other Middle Atlantic states and New England, was considerably better than that of the western half, which experienced double-digit unemployment rates.1 This variation in labor market conditions 0 allows us to assess the impact of such conditions on earnings losses, which in turn helps us assess the importance of our restriction to Pennsylva nian workers. Another disadvantage of our data is that demographic information on workers is limited to their sex and year of birth. By comparison, data sets such as the CPS and the PSID include a wider array of characteristics including, work ers’ educational attainments, occupations, and marital and union statuses. The statistical tech niques that we employ account for unobserved heterogeneity in ways that ensure that our lack of such information does not lead to any biases in our estimates of average earnings losses.1 1 However, lack of data does limit our ability to measure differences in earnings losses across demographic groups. Similarly, lack of data prevents us from decomposing earnings losses into those due to lower wages and those due to reduced hours. However, even given these limitations, we are able to provide a substantially more complete assessment of the determinants ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES of long-term earnings losses than has previously been possible. Another possible shortcoming of our data is that they do not explicitly identify whether workers’ separations resulted from quits, dis charges for cause, or displacements.1 The fact 2 that the former two reasons for separation are likely to have quite different consequences for workers’ earnings motivates our focus on work ers separating from distressed firms. Specifical ly, we limited our analysis to a mass-layoff sample that includes separators whose firms’ employment in the year following their depar ture was 30 percent or more below their maxi mum levels during the late 1970s.1 This defini 3 tion encompasses firms that closed around the time of workers’ separations as well as firms with large employment declines. Although some workers from this sample may have quit or been discharged for cause, the vast majority probably were displaced from their firms for economic reasons. Finally, our data’s most important disadvan tage is that they do not allow us to distinguish between workers who left Pennsylvania’s wage and salary work force and those who remained unemployed for long periods of time.1 In these 4 data, both groups of workers have zero earnings. For the unemployed, those earnings are their actual earnings. But for workers who moved out of state, became self-employed, or worked under a different Social Security number, zero clearly understates their actual earnings.1 Therefore, to 5 avoid overstating workers’ earnings losses, we have eliminated from our sample the approxi mately 25 percent of high-tenure separators who subsequently never showed positive earnings in our data. Because some of the workers we eliminate probably were unemployed, we believe that this decision biases downward our displacement cost estimates. Without this sample restriction, our estimates of losses would be approximately 15 percentage points larger. Alternatively, with this sample restriction, we might overstate losses if the most resilient workers are significantly more likely to move out of state. However, we dis count this possibility because before their sepa rations, the excluded workers had characteristics similar to the rest of the sample. Moreover, in results not reported in this article, we find that displaced workers who move within Pennsylva nia actually experience somewhat larger-thanaverage losses. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO To summarize, to construct the specific sample analyzed in this article, we first included only those workers with six or more years of tenure by the beginning of 1980. Second, we restricted our sample to workers for whom we had information on age and sex and, to avoid complications associated with early retirement, to workers bom between 1930 and 1959. Third, we selected those workers who separated from firms that had experienced employment declines of 30 percent or more from their 1974-79 peaks, as well as those workers who maintained a stable employment relationship through at least 1986.1 6 Finally, to reduce biases due to workers’ disap pearing from the sample, we included only workers who had received some wage or salary earnings during each calendar year. Table 1 displays some characteristics of the age and earnings distributions of the displaced workers that we study, as well as of workers who continued working for a single employer through at least 1986. The median displaced worker was 37 years old in 1979, only one year less than the median nondisplaced worker. In addition, 80 percent of all workers were within ten years of the median age for their group. The earnings figures in table 1 indicate that the median displaced worker earned $23,593 (1987 dollars) in 1979, about 5 percent less than the median stably employed worker’s earnings of $24,867. A similar gap between displaced and nondisplaced workers’ 1979 earnings holds within each of the groups displayed in the table. It is also worth noting that, on the one hand, displaced workers were more likely to be male, to come from the manufacturing sector, and to work in western Pennsylvania, characteristics associated with higher earnings. On the other hand, they were somewhat more likely to work for smaller firms, a characteristic associated with lower earnings. T he nature o f e a rn in g s lo sse s Our concept of the losses caused by dis placement focuses on the consequences to the worker. Specifically, we define the loss as the difference between workers’ actual earnings and their expected earnings in the absence of the events that led to their job loss. We derive esti mates of this quantity from a statistical model (see box) that represents the dependence of workers’ earnings on a number of factors includ ing the event of displacement. 5 TABLE 1 Sample characteristics Displaced workers % 1979 age 10th percentile'1 Mean Stably employed workers 90th Median" percentile" 27 37.1 37 Mean 28 % 10th percentile" 37.7 38 48 $38,879 47 90th Median* percentile' 1979 earningsb $12,037 $24,461 $23,593 $36,805 $13,643 $26,321 $24,867 Males 77.3 16,658 27,253 26,201 38,207 75.1 17,956 29,349 27,594 40,960 Females 22.7 7,827 14,975 14,282 22,834 24.9 9,005 17,199 16,435 26,045 38,361 Total M anufacturing 76.3 12,386 24,346 23,774 36,250 60.1 14,047 26,197 24,768 Nonm anufacturing 23.7 10,203 24,834 22,665 39,624 39.9 13,080 26,509 25,033 39,599 Eastern Pennsylvania 53.4 11,477 23,354 22,329 35,474 59.5 13,071 25,994 24,352 39,037 Western Pennsylvania 46.6 12,859 25,733 25,226 37,950 40.5 14,742 26,803 25,524 38,762 1979 firm size < 2,000 49.7 10,047 22,085 20,621 34,149 47.1 11,942 24,459 22,552 37,304 1979 firm size > 2,000 50.3 15,544 26,814 26,617 38,027 52.9 16,564 27,982 27,188 39,975 “Values represent the level below which 10%, 50%, or 90% of the respective group falls. bln 1987 dollars. Before examining such estimates, however, it is useful to discuss a number of subtleties in our definition of earnings losses that can be more easily appreciated in the context of the simple earnings history data displayed in figure 1. That figure shows the mean earnings over the sample period of the group of displaced workers that separated from their former employers in the fourth quarter of 1981 as well as the mean earnings of workers who remained stably em ployed throughout the sample period. Figure 1 illustrates a number of characteris tics that proved to be general features of the experience of displaced workers: 1) From the beginning of the sample period until a year or two before workers’ separations, there was a relatively constant gap between the earnings of displaced and nondisplaced workers. relatively constant, but larger than at the beginning of the sample period. To estimate the losses suffered by displaced workers, we track the earnings growth of nondis placed workers to infer by how much displaced workers’ earnings would have changed if they had not been displaced. Because the gap be tween the two groups’ earnings was relatively constant for several years prior to the period surrounding separation, it is reasonable to as sume that gap would have remained constant throughout the sample period if the one group of workers had not been displaced. This assump- FIGURE 1 Earnings histories of workers displaced in 1981: Q4 and workers stably employed through 1986 thousands of 1987 dollars, quarterly I 2) During the year or two immedi ately prior to workers’ separa tions, this gap began to widen. 3) Displaced workers’ earnings took a sharp drop when they separated from their former firms. 4) During the next few quarters, displaced workers’ earnings recovered somewhat relative to nondisplaced workers. 5) Finally, for the rest of the sample period, the earnings gap remained 6 1981 :Q4 ■x/iK Stably employed workers Displaced workers I ... i ... i ... i ... i ... i 1974 77 '80 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES '83 '86 tion in turn implies that the increase in the earn ings gap is a reasonable estimate of the effect of displacement on earnings. For example, the losses suffered during 1986 by the workers displaced in the fourth quarter of 1981 (1981:Q4) could be estimated by ( y S6D - y 86S ^ ' - ^ b a s e D - y baseS ^ ^ 8 6 D ~ ybaseD baseS ^ where y8 = mean earnings of displaced workers 6D in 1986, y8 = mean earnings of stably employed 6S workers in 1986, ybaseD = mean earnings of displaced workers in the base period, and ybaseS = mean earnings of stably employed workers in the base period. mediately prior to separation. Table 2 suggests that such a measure could misrepresent the im portance of displacement to workers in two ways. First, the events that eventually lead to job loss may decrease workers’ earnings even before their final separations. This can occur through reduction in overtime hours, temporary layoffs, or real wage decreases. Table 2 presents evidence of such pre-separation earnings de clines for the 1981 :Q4 cohort. In particular, the difference-in-differences estimator of losses in 1981 is $2,138. Using 1981 earnings as the base in a calculation of earnings losses would de crease loss estimates for subsequent years by this same amount. The second reason why the simple change in displaced workers’ earnings from levels im mediately prior to separation may fail to capture the importance of displacement to workers is that it does not account for the loss of earnings growth that would have occurred in the absence of displacement. Such losses of potential earn ings reduce workers’ welfare just as meaningful ly as do actual declines in earnings, and thus ought to be included in any measure of lost earnings. Lost earnings growth is not a signifi cant factor in the estimation of losses in the first Table 2 presents such difference-in-differ ences estimates.1 7 Over the period 1974-79, the displaced workers who separated in 1981:Q4 had average annual earnings of $21,868. This was $2,804 less than TABLE 2 the average earnings of the nondisEarnings means for workers displaced in 1981:Q4 placed workers. By contrast, in and stably employed workers 1986 the displaced workers earned (in 1987 dollars) an average of $19,759, which was Stably Workers Difference: $8,008 less than the average for employed displaced in displaced workers 1981 :Q4 stable nondisplaced workers. Thus the gap between the two groups’ earnings Earnings level increased by $5,203. Alternatively, Annual average in this estimate of the earnings loss -$ 2 ,8 0 4 $21,868 $24,672 base period (1974-79) (514) (505) (98) caused by displacement is equal to -4 ,9 4 2 1981 20,258 25,200 the difference between displaced (649) (106) (658) and nondisplaced workers’ earnings 1982 15,669 24,748 -9 ,0 7 9 growth from the base period (1974(684) (693) (111) 79) to 1986. For the displaced 27,767 1986 19,759 -8 ,0 0 8 (761) (139) (774) workers, earnings growth was -$2,108 and, for the nondisplaced Earnings changes workers, it was $3,095. Again, the 1981-base -1 ,6 0 9 529 -2 ,1 3 8 (477) (474) (51) difference was $5,203. Similar -6 ,1 9 9 -6 ,2 7 5 1982-base 76 calculations yield an estimated loss (540) (59) (543) during the first year after separation 1986-base -2 ,1 0 8 3,095 -5 ,2 0 3 (1982) of $6,275. (87) (612) (618) Some studies define the losses Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. due to displacement as the decline in workers’ earnings from levels im FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 7 year after the 1981:Q4 cohort’s separation be cause the annual earnings of nondisplaced work ers’ had grown by only $76 dollars from the base period. Over the five years following sepa ration, however, the picture changes consider ably. Ignoring the $3,095 earnings growth expe rienced by nondisplaced workers for the period ending five years after the 1981 :Q4 cohort’s separation reduces the estimated losses of the latter group by more than half. A final point to note is that we have inferred the growth in displaced workers’ earnings that would have occurred in the absence of displace ment from the average experience of all nondis placed workers. An alternative would be to make this inference only on the basis of the BOX 1 Statistical models for estimating earnings losses Our estimates of earnings losses are derived from a statistical model that represents the dependence of workers’ earnings histories on displacement and other factors.' This model exploits two of the prin cipal strengths of our data set—that it covers a long period of time and that it contains data on many individuals—so as to yield a detailed picture of the pattern of earnings losses across time and across workers. To produce such a detailed picture, we pool information for all workers displaced between 1980 and 1986. A convenient way to do this is by introducing a series of dummy variables for the number of quarters before or after workers’ separations. We let D*= 1 if, in period t, worker i had been displaced k quarters earlier (or, if k is negative, worker i was displaced -k quarters later). Otherwise, D*= 0. By restricting attention to these dummy variables, we formalize the idea that a worker displaced in 1982 was in much the same position in 1985 as a worker displaced in 1981 was in 1984. Our specification assumes that workers’ earnings at a given date depend on displacement through the set of previously defined dummy variables and on some controls for fixed and time varying char acteristics: ( 1) y. = a.i + Y + xi t r(3 + £ D* 5, + 8.. h * a k it J it k > -m In this equation, the dummy variables D*, k = -m, -{m - 1 ) , . . . , 0, 1 , 2 , . . . jointly represent the event of displacement. In particular, 8; is the effect of displacement on a worker’s earnings k quarters after its occurrence. In the empirical work described in this article, we allow displacement to affect earnings up to 20 quarters before separation.2 The vector xjt consists of the observed time-varying char acteristics of the worker, which in this article are limited to the interactions among sex, age, and age squared. The parameter y, is the coefficient of a dummy variable for the quarter t in the sample period; these quarter dummies jointly capture the general time pattern of earnings in the economy. The “fixed effect,” a., summarizes the impact of permanent differences among workers in observed and unob served characteristics. Finally, the error term e.( is assumed to have constant variance and to be uncor related across individuals and time. We estimate the parameters of equation 1, including the fixed effects, by least squares. Thus, no matter how workers’ permanent characteristics are related to their displacement status, our estimates of the displacement effects are unbiased. This estimation approach generalizes the “difference-in-differences” technique which uses a comparison group to estimate the earnings changes that would have occurred in the absence of displacement, by accounting for the effects of time-varying variables and by allowing the effects of displacement to vary by the number of quarters relative to separation. The foregoing model describes the temporal pattern of displaced workers’ earnings losses in a highly flexible manner. It must, however, be modified to summarize how this pattern varies among different groups of workers. The most straightforward such modification interacts each displacement dummy variable, D*, with variables indicating workers’ sex, age, industry, or region. The problem with this approach is that it leads to a very large number of parameters. Fortunately, after examining such estimates, we observed that differences among groups in the time pattern of earnings losses occurred 8 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES experiences of nondisplaced workers who were highly similar to the displaced workers. In fact, the estimates presented in the next section do allow workers’ expected earnings growth to depend on their age and sex. It is possible to go still further and compare displaced workers only to others who kept jobs in their former industries or firms. But our interest is in the full effects of the events that lead to displacement. A compari son of displaced workers’ earnings only to those of workers retaining jobs in firms or industries affected by displacement does not capture these full effects if those same events cause those who retain their jobs in affected firms or industries to mainly along just three dimensions: the rate at which earnings dip in the period before separation, the size of the drop that occurs at the time of separation, and the rate of recovery in the period following separation. To construct a more parsimonious representation of losses across time and workers, we use the fact that differences in the losses among groups can be summarized by three magnitudes. Specifically we define FI = t - (5 - 13), if worker i is displaced at time s and s - 12 < t < s, and F!f = 0 otherwise; P = 1, if worker i is displaced at time s and t > s + 1, and Fr = 0 otherwise; and P = t - (5 + 6), if worker i is displaced at time s and t > s + 7, and P.t - 0 otherwise. Then, if c. is a vector of characteristics of individual 1, our parsimonious model takes the form (2) v 7 y. = a 1 + y + x.it rB + h J it L D* 8. + F'c.cp, + Pi t cm 2 -1- Pitc mp, -1 £., cp, i 3 - ir u k i t 1*1 k>-m where cpp cp,, and cp3 are parameter vectors giving the effect of workers’ characteristics on the dip, the drop, and the recovery, respectively. To implement this specification we include the full set of displace ment dummies but only allow for interactions between worker characteristics and the three variables F\t, P , and P . Specification 2 forces the gap between the estimated losses of two workers to 1) be zero in the period more than three years before separation, 2) grow or decline linearly during the period from three years before separation until the quarter of separation, 3) be constant during the period from one to six quarters after displacement, and 4) grow or decline linearly from its value six quarters after separa tion until the end of the sample period. Accordingly, the losses k quarters after separation for a worker with characteristics c. take the following form: 5^ if k < -1 3 ; bk + c (p,(& + 13) i f -12 < k < 0; 5; + c.cp2 if 1< k < 6; and 5, + c (p2 + c.cp3 - 6) if k < 7. (/c The loss estimates presented in table 3 are derived from model 2 for the cases in which c consists of dummy variables for sex, birth cohort, industry, and firm size, and for the case in which c. summariz es local labor market conditions by including a region’s unemployment rate, its trend growth rate of employment growth, and the deviation of its employment from trend in the quarter in which the worker was displaced. 'Similar statistical models are often used to evaluate the earnings impact of public sector training programs. See Ashenfelter (1978), Heckman and Robb (1985), and LaLonde (1986). 2To identify the parameters of model 1, we must observe the earnings o f at least some displaced workers more than m quarters prior to their displacement. The choice o f m - 20 presents us with no problems o f identification, for even our first cohort of displaced workers, who separated from their firms in the first quarter o f 1980, have six years o f pre-displacement data. 3Elsewhere we consider models that allow for a worker-specific time trend in addition to the worker-specific constant in model 1. (See Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan [1993a].) Estimated displacement costs are slightly higher under this alternative specification. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 9 suffer their own earnings declines. Instead, it captures only the effects specifically associated with the separation. We have chosen to focus here on the work ers most affected by their firms’ distress—the workers who actually lost jobs. Yet workers who kept jobs in distressed firms and whose earnings declined relative to those who kept jobs in nondistressed firms suffered meaningful losses too. Elsewhere we estimate that these earnings losses are about 20 percent as large as those suffered by workers who lost their jobs.1 8 Thus the choice of comparison group, while significant, is not crucial; even when it is limit ed to workers who remained employed in dis tressed firms, the estimated earnings losses due to displacement are still 80 percent of those reported here. E stim a ted ea rn in g s lo sse s In this section we present our estimates of the earnings losses associated with displacement as derived from the statistical model described in the box. Like the difference-in-differences esti mates computed in the previous section, these estimates account for the loss of earnings growth that displaced workers experience and allow for permanent differences in the level of earnings across workers. They extend the difference-in differences estimates by 1) pooling information from all cohorts of work ers displaced from 1980 to 1986; 2) allowing individual workers’ earnings growth to vary by age and sex; 3) making the base period, in which displacement effects are assumed to be absent, end five years before workers’ actual separations; 4) allowing the effects of displace ment to vary by length of time since separation; and after their separations. To facilitate the exposi tion, we plot these estimated effects against the number of quarters before or after workers’ separations. We also show 95 percent confi dence bounds for each quarter’s estimate. As figure 2 shows, high-tenure prime-age workers endured substantial and persistent earn ings losses when they were displaced from firms with substantial employment declines. Even in the fifth year after separation, their quarterly earnings remained $ 1,600 below expected lev els. This loss corresponds to approximately 25 percent of their 1979 earnings.1 Further, be 9 cause the estimated losses do not decline signifi cantly following the third year after separation, there is little evidence that displaced workers’ earnings will ever return to expected levels. Clearly, displacement is a major setback for experienced workers. We also found evidence that the events which led to job loss caused workers’ earnings to depart from their expected levels well before these workers actually left their firms. In fact, their quarterly earnings began to diverge mean ingfully from expected levels approximately three years before separation. That divergence accelerated as separation approached, so that by the quarter immediately before separation, these workers’ quarterly earnings were approximately $ 1,000 below expected levels. Although we cannot determine from our data whether these pre-separation earnings losses resulted from cuts in real wages or in weekly hours, elsewhere we FIGURE 2 Overall earnings losses of displaced workers by time relative to separation thousands of 1 9 8 7 dollars, qua rte rly 5) allowing the magnitude of work ers’ losses to vary by sex, birth cohort, former industry, former firm size, and conditions of the local labor market at the time of their separation. We begin by reporting estimates of the average effect of displacement on displaced workers’ earnings for each quarter beginning with the twentieth quarter prior to, and end ing with the twenty-sixth quarter 10 years since disp la c em e n t ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES present evidence that temporary layoffs for which workers received unemployment insur ance benefits can account for about half of these pre-separation losses.2 0 The average present discounted value of workers’ earnings losses during the period from three years before to six years after their separa tions amounted to approximately $50,000.2 If, 1 as seems likely, these workers’ earnings losses remain at about $6,000 per year until their retire ment at age 65, their losses’ present value rises to approximately $80,000. Workers’ average earnings losses during the period up to six quar ters after their separations were approximately $20,000. Virtually all workers had found stable employment by this time. Even during this period, far from all of these losses are attribut able to workers’ unemployment. But, even if unemployment was responsible for all of these losses, it would still account for only about 25 percent of workers’ cumulative earnings losses. Table 3 displays estimates of earnings loss es for several categories of workers. Each group of estimates corresponds to a version of model (2) of the box for a particular choice of the vec tor c 2 Losses are shown for the first and fifth 2 years after separation. The former reflect both lower earnings on workers’ initial jobs after separation and earnings losses due to unemploy ment. By the fifth year after separation, howev er, workers have had a significant amount of time to adjust to their displacement. Losses at that time reflect almost exclusively lower earn ings on jobs that those workers are likely to hold for some time. To aid interpretation, losses are presented in 1987 dollars and as a percentage of workers’ 1979 earnings. Table 3 indicates that men had larger dollar losses than women. However, because their pre displacement earnings were much less than those of men, women’s smaller dollar losses actually were larger percentages of their pre-displace ment earnings. In the first year after job loss, men’s earnings were more than $10,500 less than expected and even in the fifth year were still $7,100 less than expected. These figures are 39 percent and 26 percent, respectively, of their 1979 earnings. For women, the losses were $6,700 and $4,700 in the first and fifth years after job loss, or 45 percent and 32 percent of 1979 earnings. On the one hand, the lower dollar losses for women suggest that before displacement, they possessed fewer firm-specific skills or were less likely to have been receiving FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF CHICAGO wage premiums. On the other hand, their higher percentage losses suggest that a greater fraction of women’s earnings were attributable to firmspecific skills or wage premiums. The birth cohort estimates in table 3 indi cate that workers of widely different ages had remarkably similar long-term losses. In the first year after separation, workers bom in the 1950s had losses more than $1,000 higher than those of workers bom earlier. By the fifth year after separation, however, their losses were less than $600 higher than those of the older workers. The modest narrowing of the differences in losses across age cohorts may reflect a greater willingness of younger workers and their new employers to invest in obtaining new skills. This greater willingness, in turn, is consistent with the longer time they will have to recoup the benefits of such investments. Table 3 also indicates that long-term losses due to displacement are substantial for workers in almost every industry. However, losses were especially large in the primary metals industries. In the first year after separation, workers in these industries were earning $17,600 less than ex pected. Five years after separation their losses were still $12,100, or 40 percent of their 1979 earnings. These workers’ large losses may re flect the loss of union wage premiums that kept earnings on their old jobs especially high. How ever, loss of union premiums cannot be the whole explanation of earnings losses among displaced workers. Even workers in the whole sale and retail trade industries, where unioniza tion rates are relatively low, experienced long term losses equal to approximately 29 percent of their 1979 earnings. The only industry group for which long term losses were not a significant fraction of previous earnings was finance, insurance, and real estate, where losses five years after separa tion averaged only 3.5 percent of 1979 earn ings.2 Experienced workers in these industries 3 may have skills that are more easily transferred from one employer to another. Another possi bility is that because employment in these indus tries was growing relatively rapidly, displaced workers may have found it easier to find new jobs with similar firms. However, we show below that returning to the same industry did not, in general, shield workers from losses. Another indication that losses are somewhat higher for unionized workers is the larger losses experienced by workers displaced from very 11 TABLE 3 Earnings losses by worker characteristics (in 1987 dollars) Number 1979 earnings First year after separation Loss Percent* Fifth year after separation Loss Percent* 6,435 $24,461 $9,676 (70) 39.6 (0.3) $6,575 (125) 26.9 (0.5) Male 4,972 27,253 Female 1,463 14,975 10,555 (76) 6,734 (118) 38.7 (0.3) 45.0 (0.8) 7,143 (132) 4,744 (184) 26.2 (0.5) 31.7 (1.2) 1930s 2,599 25,605 1940s 2,584 24,742 1950s 1,252 21,509 9,209 (94) 9,662 (92) 10,663 (121) 36.0 (0.4) 39.0 (0.4) 49.6 (0.6) 6,672 (159) 6,352 (151) 6,927 (188) 26.1 (0.6) 25.7 (0.6) 32.2 (0.9) 247 31,570 Nondurable manufacturing 1,206 18,989 Primary metals 1,354 30,160 Fabricated metals 436 23,653 Nonelectrical machinery 632 25,489 Electrical machinery 421 21,368 Transportation equipment 419 25,320 Other durable manufacturing 441 22,108 Transportation, communication, and public utilities 348 28,666 11,589 (243) 7,104 (124) 17,562 (117) 7,156 (189) 5,577 (168) 8,447 (197) 7,912 (196) 7,499 (184) 9,000 (206) 36.7 (0.8) 37.4 (0.7) 58.2 (0.4) 30.3 (0.8) 21.9 (0.7) 39.5 (0.9) 31.2 (0.8) 33.9 (0.8) 31.4 (0.7) 8,434 (352) 5,052 (188) 12,074 (210) 4,936 (301) 4,644 (284) 5,318 (300) 6,508 (291) 4,570 (262) 9,392 (321) 26.7 (1.1) 26.6 (1.0) 40.0 (0.7) 20.9 (1.3) 18.2 (1.1) 24.9 (1.4) 25.7 (1.1) 20.7 (1.2) 32.8 (1.1) Wholesale and retail trade 545 20,604 Finance, insurance, and real estate Professional, business, and entertainment services 183 24,604 203 21,635 8,809 (167) 4,352 (291) 2,184 (282) 42.8 (0.8) 17.7 (1.2) 10.1 (1.3) 5,927 (235) 855 (369) 3,093 (378) 28.8 (1.1) 3.5 (1.5) 14.3 (1.7) 50-500 1,704 21,284 501-2,000 1,497 22,997 2,001-5,000 1,381 24,378 >5,000 1,853 28,630 8,238 (107) 7,635 (112) 6,760 (115) 11,896 (147) 38.7 (0.5) 33.2 (0.5) 27.7 (0.5) 41.5 (0.5) 5,404 (163) 5,540 (176) 5,571 (179) 10,151 (190) 25.4 (0.8) 24.1 (0.8) 22.9 (0.7) 35.5 (0.7) Pittsburgh-1982 214 26,232 Philadelphia-1985 189 25,859 13,075 (116) 7,349 (89) 49.8 (0.4) 28.4 (0.4) 8,889 (267) 4,947 (158) 33.9 (1.0) 19.1 (0.6) Overall Sex Decade of birth Industry Mining and construction Firm size Local labor market aLoss as a percentage of 1979 earnings. Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. 12 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES large firms. Workers from firms TABLE 4 with over 5,000 employees in 1979 Earnings losses of displaced workers by had fifth year losses of 36 percent of sector of new job their 1979 earnings. By contrast, (in 1987 dollars) average losses of workers in smaller First year after Fifth year after firms were at most 25.4 percent.2 4 separation separation Finally, table 3 indicates that Loss Percent" Loss Percent" the size of earnings losses depended Manufacturing substantially on the state of the local workers labor market when workers were Same SIC $6,700 27.5 $4,020 16.5 (212) (0.1) (281) (0.1) displaced. We divide Pennsylvania Same sector 8,188 33.6 4,702 19.3 into 13 distinct regions and summa (186) (0.1) (258) (0.1) rize local labor market conditions in Different sector 12,538 51.5 9,280 37.8 (168) (0.1) (239) (0.1) those regions with three variables: 1) Nonmanufacturing the trend rate of employment growth workers 5,214 Same SIC over the sample period, 2) the devia 21.0 5,098 20.5 (276) (0.1) (416) (0.2) tion of employment growth from Same sector 8,288 33.4 6,510 26.2 that trend in the quarter in which the (243) (0.1) (305) (0.1) Different sector 10,436 42.0 7,791 31.4 worker separated, and 3) the unem (549) (0.2) (694) (0.3) ployment rate in the quarter in which the worker separated. “Loss as a percentage of 1979 earnings. Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. We further summarize these effects by presenting estimates of losses for a particularly weak labor market As table 4 shows, in the fifth year after separation, (Pittsburgh in 1982) and a particularly robust the losses of those who left the manufacturing labor market (Philadelphia in 1985). Losses sector were 38 percent of their 1979 earnings.2 6 were 13 percentage points higher in the weaker However, for those who found new jobs in the labor market. Even in the robust market, how manufacturing sector, it did not matter as critically ever, losses still averaged over 19 percent of whether they found a job in their old four-digit 1979 earnings. Therefore, while labor market SIC industry. In the fifth year after their separa conditions are a significant determinant of dis tions, manufacturing workers’ losses were 17 placed workers’ losses, even those who separate percent of 1979 earnings if they found new jobs in from distressed firms in prosperous times experi the same four-digit SIC industry, compared with ence large losses. 19 percent if they found new manufacturing jobs Our data also allow us to assess the impor in different four-digit SIC industries. tance of the sector of workers’ post-displace The findings for displaced nonmanufacturing ment jobs for the size of their losses.2 If the 5 workers are similar, though the dependence on skills required on two jobs are more similar new industry is less pronounced. For those who when the jobs are in the same industry, and if the found new jobs in the same four-digit SIC indus loss of specialized skills is an important determi try, earnings losses in the fifth year after separa nant of workers’ losses, then displaced workers tion were 21 percent of 1979 earnings. That figure returning to the same industry should experience rose to 26 percent when the new jobs were in smaller losses than those whose new jobs lie in a different four-digit SIC industries but still in the different industry. Accordingly, we examined same sector. For those who found new jobs in the the earnings losses of workers whose new jobs manufacturing sector, fifth-year earnings losses were 1) in the same four-digit SIC industry as were 31 percent of 1979 earnings. their old job, 2) in the same sector (manufactur It is clear, then, that among both manufactur ing or nonmanufacturing) but in a different four ing and nonmanufacturing workers, even those digit SIC industry, or 3) in a different sector. who found jobs in the same four-digit SIC indus The earnings losses of manufacturing work try experienced large and persistent losses. This ers depended crucially on whether those workers finding suggests that something intrinsic to the obtained new jobs in the manufacturing sector. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 13 employment relationship itself is lost when workers are displaced. If it is workers’ skills that are lost, these skills must be firm-specific, not merely in dustry-specific. Alternatively, such earnings losses may result from the workings of internal labor markets. Though a number of interesting patterns appear in tables 3 and 4, work ers’ earnings losses appear to be more similar than different. Large long-term losses appear to be the rule when expe rienced workers are forced to leave declining firms. FIGURE 3 Earnings losses and losses in total income including UI and TAA benefits thousands of 1987 dollars, quarterly P u b lic p o lic ie s to a ssist d isp la ce d w o rk e rs Assistance for displaced workers comes in several forms.2 Unemploy 7 years since displacement ment insurance (UI) provides income replacement while workers are unem ployed. For some workers, these benefits are figure 3 demonstrates, UI and TAA do relative supplemented by Trade Adjustment Assistance ly little to reduce displaced workers’ cumula (TAA), which provides additional benefits to tive losses. Figure 3 compares losses in earn workers whose job loss is the result of import ings as shown in figure 2 with a measure of competition. Other programs aim to speed dis displaced workers’ losses in income including placed workers’ return to work and raise their UI and TAA benefits. Clearly, UI significant skills so that they will have higher earnings in ly reduces losses in the period when they are the future. For instance, the Economic Disloca most severe but has no impact on workers’ tion and Worker Adjustment Act (EDWAA) long-term welfare. provides certain displaced workers with exten Of the displaced workers we study who sive job search assistance, counseling, and class did receive UI benefits, many received them for room training. Unfortunately, as we shall argue, long periods. Nearly two-thirds received 26 or the existing assistance programs do not and probably cannot eliminate FIGURE 4 more than a small fraction of the losses suffered by workers such as Earnings losses for workers not collecting UI, collecting fewer than 26 weeks, and collecting 26 weeks or more those we report on here. In the previous section we ob thousands of 1987 dollars, quarterly served that most of the cumulative losses experienced by displaced workers occurred after they had become re-employed. This finding obviously implies that a benefit such as UI, whose receipt is tied to being unemployed, cannot eliminate a large fraction of workers’ losses. In any case, only a little over 40 per cent of the displaced workers we study in this article received any UI payments in the quarter of their separation or the one thereafter.2 8 Thus it is not surprising that, as years since displacement 14 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES The fact that these workers’ losses are so large and persistent, Distribution of weekly UI benefits relative to weekly however, makes providing that earnings before and after displacement help in the form of longer maxi (in 1987 dollars) mum benefit durations potentially 75th 25th costly to the economy because Median8 percentile' percentile9 doing so may substantially delay the beneficiaries’ return to work. Did not collect UI $575 $314 $433 Previous weekly earnings In order to give unemployed work 277 411 560 Subsequent weekly earnings ers strong incentives to find new 15.5% -17.1% -1.5% Percentage change6 jobs, policymakers have limited UI Less than 26 weeks of UI benefits to a little less than half $264 $382 $520 Previous weekly earnings their previous earnings. Yet even 447 321 197 Subsequent weekly earnings such benefit levels may represent a -11.5% 9.6% -36.6% Percentage change6 $121 $185 $201 substantial fraction of the earnings UI weekly benefit Benefit relative to that workers can eventually expect 41.6% 51.6% 31.6% previous earnings6 to get on their new jobs, since new Benefit relative to jobs tend to be lower-paying than 67.8% 35.3% 48.5% subsequent earnings6 previous ones. 26 or more weeks of UI $522 $414 Previous weekly earnings $293 Table 5 compares estimates 122 211 330 Subsequent weekly earnings of workers’ weekly earnings on -41% -12.5% -67.3% Percentage change6 pre- and post-displacement jobs $167 $190 $199 UI weekly benefit with their weekly UI benefits. Benefit relative to We estimated weekly earnings on 44.7% 53.0% 35.8% previous earnings6 new jobs by dividing by 13 work Benefit relative to 135.2% 77.4% 53.5% subsequent earnings6 ers’ earnings in the second quarter a Values represent the level below which 25%, 50%, or 75% of the after their separations in which respective group falls. they had positive earnings and bEntries are the respective percentiles of the distribution of individual percentage changes, not the percentage difference between the received no UI benefits. We corresponding percentiles of the distributions of previous and subsequent estimated weekly earnings on old earnings. cEntries are the respective percentiles of the distributions of individual jobs in the same manner from benefit-to-earnings ratios, not the ratio of the percentiles. workers’ earnings in the last quar ter before their separations in which they received no UI payments. more weeks of UI in the four years surrounding The table shows that workers who collected their separations. This finding is not unique to 26 or more weeks of UI generally had much our data. Other researchers have noted an in larger drops in weekly earnings than other work creased tendency for certain groups of workers ers and that UI benefits were a significantly to exhaust 26 weeks of UI eligibility. This fact larger fraction of subsequent than of previous has prompted a number of policymakers and earnings. For workers collecting fewer than 26 analysts to advocate substantially lengthening weeks of UI, the median ratio of benefits to the standard maximum duration of benefits.2 9 earnings was 42 percent for previous earnings Figure 4 displays estimates of losses sepa and 49 percent for subsequent earnings. For rately for workers who workers collecting at least 26 weeks of benefits, 1) received no UI benefits, however, the two median ratios were 45 percent 2) received fewer than 26 weeks of benefits, and and 78 percent. Indeed, for more than a third of 3) received 26 or more weeks of benefits.3 0 the latter group, benefits exceeeded their earn As can be seen, workers who collected ings on post-displacement jobs.3 1 many weeks of UI had especially large earnings It seems possible, then, that providing long losses. Indeed, in the fifth year after separation er periods of eligibility for UI benefits will their losses averaged nearly $10,000. Clearly, increase unemployment durations not only be workers who collect many weeks of UI are cause appropriate jobs for such workers are among those who policymakers should most scarce, but also because many workers will have want to help. TABLE 5 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO 15 relatively little incentive to take those jobs. For many displaced workers, lengthening the dura tion of benefits might simply postpone the inevitable—taking a job at substantially lower earnings. Elsewhere, we suggest that assistance could be better provided to such workers by offering an earnings subsidy that would replace a fraction of the difference between earnings on their pre- and post-separation jobs. Such a sub sidy would direct the most assistance to those suffering the largest losses without at the same time eliminating displaced workers’ incentives to return to work.3 2 Because UI has an obviously limited capaci ty to reduce displaced workers’ long-term losses, policymakers have also designed programs to raise these workers’ earnings once they are re employed. These include training programs that upgrade workers’ skills and job search assistance programs that better match workers’ existing skills with the needs of employers. Unfortunate ly, a good deal of research suggests that these efforts historically have not raised workers’ earnings by enough to come close to compensat ing for losses of the size we estimated.3 This 3 lack of success in raising workers’ earnings may reflect the relatively modest duration and inten sity of traditional subsidized training programs.3 4 There is also reason to question whether the resources that are available for assisting displaced workers are allocated wisely. Eligibil ity for EDWAA services theoretically extends to millions of workers per year. In reality, how ever, funding constraints have limited participa tion to about 120,000 workers annually.3 Thus 5 in determining the mix of services provided under this program, policymakers face an inevi table choice between breadth and depth. More specifically, they can provide large numbers of workers with relatively basic and inexpensive job search assistance, or they can provide a smaller number of workers with job training which, while relatively modest in duration and intensity, is still several times more expensive. Presumably, the decision should depend on two considerations: 1) the respective rates of return that these two choices offer in the form of in creased earnings on workers’ subsequent jobs, and 2) their respective implications for equity among workers. Our reading of the available evidence sug gests that job search assistance has a substantial ly higher rate of return than the kind of training that has been traditionally provided to displaced workers. In a recent survey of research on train ing and job search assistance programs for the displaced, Leigh (1990) concluded that job search assistance strongly improves a variety of labor market outcomes, including earnings. Given its low cost per worker, it also appears to be cost effective.3 Later, however, Leigh notes 6 that “classroom training fails to have a sizable incremental effect on earnings and employment above that of job search assistance only. In particular, it certainly does not appear that the additional affect of classroom training is large enough to offset the higher cost of these servic es.”3 Concentration on job search assistance 7 would also allow more workers to be served and hence seems more equitable as well. Thus, the stipulation in EDWAA’s enabling legislation that half of all funds be spent on classroom train ing may be unfortunate. The results of the recent New Jersey Unem ployment Insurance Re-employment Demonstra tion are typical of the evidence on the relative rates of return to training and job search assis tance.38 This demonstration used an experimen tal design to study whether mandatory job search assistance and referrals for retraining raised displaced workers’ earnings. The demonstration targeted UI claimants over 25 years old, with at least three years’ tenure with their former em ployer, and who had been laid off without a recall date for more than four weeks. A random sample of this group was required to participate in a two-week job search assistance workshop. Afterwards, a random sample of these partici pants was referred to training. The evaluation indicated that job search assistance raised participants’ earnings by $450 during a one-year period some months after the programs ended. However, the earnings gains of those who received both job search assis tance and retraining referrals were not signifi cantly larger than the gains of those who re ceived job search assistance alone. To make the case for retraining even worse, job search assistance cost only a few hundred dollars per participant, whereas training cost at least $2,300 per participant. As we noted, the evidence suggests that traditional subsidized training programs have not significantly reduced displaced workers’ earn ings losses. Nevertheless, it is instructive to ask how much it might cost for a hypothetical, well 16 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES functioning training program to eliminate dis placed workers’ $6,000 annual long-term earn ings losses. Suppose that such a program were able to generate a 12 percent rate of return on its investment—a high rate compared to invest ments in other forms of human capital such as schooling. Even such a program could generate a permanent earnings gain of $6,000 per year only at a cost of $50,000. For this price, one could allow participants to spend two years out of the labor force and forego $15,000-$ 19,000 per year in earnings in a full-time retraining program with direct costs of $6,000-$ 10,000 per year. This would be equivalent to paying the tuition, books, and other expenses for a dis placed worker with a high school diploma to go back to school full time to acquire an associ ates degree. To date, policymakers have not been willing to commit this level of resources to retraining displaced workers; typical pro grams last only a few months and cost a few thousand dollars. In summary, the existing programs designed to aid displaced workers provide modest short term relief but do little to reduce long-term loss es. No existing program provides the costly, long-lasting assistance that might come close to offsetting these losses fully. Although current programs could probably be substantially im proved through reorganization and in some cases additional funding, it is doubtful whether they could ever fully restore workers’ lost earnings potential. It may be more efficient to introduce some form of earnings subsidy that would re place a fraction of the difference between work ers’ earnings on their pre- and post-displacement jobs. Such a program might effectively provide substantial assistance to those most severely affected by job loss without at the same time creating strong disincentives to work. C o n c lu s io n Displacement clearly has substantial long term consequences for high-seniority workers. Even several years after separation, such work ers’ losses are still approximately 25 percent of their pre-displacement earnings. Losses vary in important ways across groups of workers; they are larger for workers in highly unionized dura ble goods manufacturing industries and for those losing jobs in depressed labor markets. But workers from almost every industrial sector and in every labor market condition appear to suffer FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO significant losses. Even workers returning to the same industry experience significant losses. Current programs to assist displaced work ers offset only a small fraction of the losses of high-seniority workers. Even so, the current structure of the UI system may delay significant ly displaced workers’ return to work, since bene fit levels for those most adversely affected by job loss are often relatively close to earnings on post-displacement jobs. Job search assistance appears to be highly cost effective, but our find ing that even workers who return to the same industry suffer large losses suggests that these programs are limited in their capacity to aid workers. The job training traditionally offered to displaced workers does not appear to come close to eliminating their losses and may not even be cost effective. Whether more ambitious training programs would have larger effects is an open question. Given the current resources devoted to assisting displaced workers, however, shifting resources from training to job search assistance would probably contribute to both greater equity and greater efficiency. If policymakers wish to offset a substantial portion of displaced workers’ losses, they will almost certainly have to commit substantially more resources than they have done heretofore. Whether they should make this commitment is obviously a political question. But when dis placement is the result of policies such as trade liberalization, whose net benefits to society are likely to be large, it may be worth insuring that those who suffer losses receive assistance if for no other reason than to insure the political via bility of the policy. When policies that entail job loss are less clearly beneficial, as in some cases of proposed environmental regulation, policymakers will need to weigh carefully the full consequences of the resulting dislocation. Similarly, if lower inflation can be achieved only at the cost of permanently displacing workers, then the magni tude of the long-term losses documented in this article suggests caution in evaluating the net gains from further reductions in inflation. Only a small fraction of workers’ total losses occur while they are actually unemployed. The major ity of their losses occur in the form of lower earnings on subsequent jobs. Thus the trade-off is not strictly between inflation and unemploy ment, but between inflation and a more compre hensive measure of labor market disruption that includes the long-term effects of displacement. 17 FOOTNOTES 'See Chapter 2 o f Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b) for a review o f some o f the previous empirical literature documenting displaced workers’ earnings losses. 2See Congressional Budget Office (1993). 3In the case o f the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), a widely quoted estimate from the Institute for International Economics is that 150,000 jobs will be lost in the ten years after ratification. This figure is easily offset by the 325,000 new jobs predicted to be created as the result of the treaty. See Congressional Budget Office (1993). 4For example, on the former possibility see Becker (1975) and on the latter possibility see Jovanovic (1979). 5For example, on the former possibility see Lewis (1986) and on the latter possibility see Stiglitz (1974). l4The wage and salary work force consists o f those covered by the unemployment insurance system. The primary group of workers excluded are those that are self-em ployed. Potential sample selection problems are not unique to studies using administrative data. For example, in the 1984 DWS, wage data were unavailable for the approxi mately 40 percent o f the sample that was not employed at the survey date. See Flaim and Seghal (1985). l5Tannery (1991) used U.S. Social Security Administration data to study the rates at which workers left the Pennsylva nia wage and salary work force between 1979 and 1987. Although his sample is not restricted to high-tenure work ers, he found that among those who left the Pennsylvania wage and salary labor force for reasons other than retire ment, 60 percent had earnings outside the state. However, among those who left the state by 1987, over one-half had 1979 earnings less than $3,000 and less than 8 percent had earnings above $20,000. 6See, for example, Lazear (1981). 7For details on how we constructed our data, see Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b). 8The statistical issues associated with estimating earnings losses due to displacement are similar to those involved in the estimation o f the impact o f programs such as those providing subsidized training to workers. One interpretation o f the exchange between LaLonde (1986) and Heckman and Hotz (1989) is that reliable nonexperimental estimation of such programs’ impacts requires data on workers well before the time o f their participation. 9See Duncan and Hill (1985) and Bound and Krueger (1991). l0See Jacobson (1988). "See Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993a) and Chapter 4 o f Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b) for discus sion o f statistical issues in the estimation of earnings losses, including a description o f circumstances under which our earnings loss estimators could possibly be biased. 1 Workers who separated from firms that did not experience 5 large employment declines or who worked for firms with fewer than 50 employees in 1979 were not used in the analysis described in this article. "The difference-in-differences technique has been fre quently employed in the program evaluation literature. See, for example, Ashenfelter (1978), Ashenfelter and Card (1985), Heckman and Robb (1985), LaLonde (1986), and Card and Sullivan (1988). l8See Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b). l9Although not shown, the quarterly employment rates of the displaced workers in our sample differ only slightly from their expected levels except in the year after separa tion. This is not surprising because our sample excludes workers with extremely long spells without wage and salary earnings. Thus the substantial earnings losses shown in figure 2 are largely due to lower earnings for those who work, rather than to an increase in the number o f workers without quarterly earnings. 20See Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b). l2In related research, Jacobson (1991) found that between 1977 and 1987, the rate o f separations for workers from Allegheny County (Pittsburgh) was 80 percent for workers with less than one year of tenure, 43 percent for workers with one year o f tenure, 24 percent for workers with two to three years o f tenure, and 13 percent for workers with four or more years o f tenure. For those with four or more years o f tenure, he estimated that one-half were retirements and one-third were displacements. Thus the quit rate for that group would be about 2 percent per year. l3This categorization is less sensible for workers in small firms. Accordingly, we further restricted our sample to workers whose firms had at least 50 employees in 1979. We have experimented with other, similar definitions o f mass layoff and obtained results similar to those presented here. 18 2lThis assumes a 4 percent real discount rate. “ Elsewhere we explore the relative importance o f the various factors displayed in table 3 in determining workers’ losses, for instance, the extent to which the differences in men’s and wom en’s earnings losses are explained by differences in the industries in which they work. See Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993a). 23The variation in losses across industries is significantly less when the alternative comparison group discussed at the end of the previous section is used to estimate losses. For instance, the earnings losses o f displaced primary metals workers and displaced finance, insurance, and real estate ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES workers are both about 25 percent when the comparison group is limited to workers in the displaced workers’ former industries. This convergence in loss estimates reflects the relatively rapid earnings growth o f workers who remained employed in finance, insurance, and real estate and the significant earnings reductions experienced by workers who remained employed in primary metals. See Chapter 6 o f Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b). 24In Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993a) we show that the large losses o f workers from large firms remain even after we control for other factors such as the industrial makeup o f these firms. 25In keeping with this study’s focus on displacement’s long term impact, we would like to assess the relationship between earnings losses and the industry of workers’ new jobs several years after separation. For workers displaced in 1985 and 1986, however, such an assessment is impossi ble because we have post-separation data for only a few quarters. Accordingly, we examined the relationship between earnings losses and industry o f new job for work ers separating from distressed firms between 1980 and 1983. Industry o f new job refers to the workers’ primary employer in 1986, or three to six years after separation. 26This finding showing greater losses when displaced workers switch sectors does not result because workers with jobs in the nonmanufacturing sector have been dis placed for a shorter period of time. The mean quarter of separation for those who switch sectors is the same as for those who remain in the manufacturing sector. 27For a fuller discussion o f assistance policies see Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b). 28Most of these workers appear to have found new (lowerpaying) jobs relatively quickly. Very few o f them had even a single quarter without earnings. 29See, for example, Topel (1991). 30The estimates in figure 4 were obtained from a model that interacted dummy variables for the three categories of workers with dummies for the number o f quarters relative to separation and thus do not satisfy the constraints im posed by the parsimonious model described in the box. 3'Moreover, for most of the period covered by our study, unemployment insurance benefits received favorable tax treatment. Note that the figures given are medians o f the distributions of the ratio o f benefits to earnings. This is not necessarily the same as the ratio of the medians. 32See Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993b). 33See Leigh (1990) for a comprehensive survey o f research on the effectiveness o f training programs for displaced workers. 34Such programs, which are often run through community colleges, seldom last more than six months. 35A recent Congressional Budget Office study (1993) notes that funding levels have recently risen to levels consistent with participation of around 200,000 workers per year. 36Leigh (1990), p. 102. 37Leigh (1990), p. 103. “ See Corson et al. (1989). REFERENCES Ashenfelter, Orley, “Estimating the effect of training programs on earnings,” Review o f Eco nomics and Statistics, Vol. 60, February 1978, pp. 47-57. Card, David, and Daniel Sullivan, “Measuring the effects of CETA participation on movements in and out of employment,” Econometrica, Vol. 56, No. 3, May 1988, pp. 497-530. Ashenfelter, Orley, and David Card, “Using the longitudinal structure of earnings to estimate the effect of training program, ” Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 67, No. 4, November 1985, pp. 648-660. Congressional Budget Office, Displaced work ers: trends in the 1980s and implications fo r the future, Washington, DC, 1993. Becker, Gary, Human Capital, New York: Na tional Bureau of Economic Research, second edition, 1975. Bound, John, and Alan Krueger, “The extent of measurement error in longitudinal earnings data: Do two wrongs make a right?,” Journal o f Labor Economics, Vol. 9, No. 1, January 1991, pp. 1-24. FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF CHICAGO Corson, Walter, Shari Dunstan, Paul Decker, and Anne Gordon, “New Jersey Unemploy ment Insurance Re-employment Demonstration Project,” unemployment insurance occasional paper, No. 89-3, U.S. Department of Labor, 1989. Duncan, Greg J., and Daniel H. Hill, “An investigation of the extent and consequences of measurement error in labor-economics data on 19 earnings,” Journal o f Labor Economics, Vol. 3, No. 4, October 1985, pp. 508-532. Flaim, Paul, and Ellen Seghal, “Displaced workers of 1979-83: How well have they fared?” U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bulletin, No. 2240, 1985. Heckman, James, and V. Joseph Hotz, “Choosing among alternative nonexperimental methods for estimating the impact of social programs: the case of manpower training,” Jour nal o f the American Statistical Association, Vol. 84, No. 408, December 1989, pp. 862-74. Heckman, James, and Richard Robb, “Alter native methods for evaluating the impact of interventions,” in Longitudinal Analysis o f La bor Market Data, J.J. Heckman and B. Singer (eds.), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985, pp. 156-245. Jacobson, Louis, “Structural change in the Pennsylvania economy,” W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, MI, 1988. ____________ , “The dynamics of the Pittsburgh labor market,” W.E. Upjohn Institute for Em ployment Research, Kalamazoo, MI, 1991. Jovanovic, Boyan, “Job matching and the theo ry of turnover,” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 87, No. 6, December 1979, pp. 972-90. LaLonde, Robert, “Evaluating the econometric evaluations of training programs with experi mental data,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 4, September 1986, pp. 604-20. Lazear, Edward, “Agency, earnings profiles, productivity, and hours restrictions,” American Economic Review, Vol. 71, No. 4, September 1981, pp. 606-20. Leigh, Duane E., Does Training Work fo r Dis placed Workers?: A Survey o f Existing Evi dence, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, MI, 1990. Lewis, H. Gregg, Union relative wage effects: a survey, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986. Stiglitz, Joseph, “Alternative theories of wage determination and unemployment in LDs: the labor turnover model,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 88, No. 20, May 1974, pp. 194227. Jacobson, Louis S., Robert J. LaLonde, and Daniel G. Sullivan, “Earnings losses of dis placed workers,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 4, September 1993a, pp. 685-709. Tannery, Frederick J., “Labor market adjust ments to structural change: comparisons be tween Allegheny County and the rest of Pennsylvania 1979-87,” unpublished working paper, Economic Policy Institute, University of Pittsburgh, 1991. ____________ , The Costs o f Worker Disloca tion, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, MI, 1993b. Topel, Robert H., “Unemployment and insur ance,” testimony before the U.S. Senate Finance Committee, April 1991. 20 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES The 30th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition May I 1-13, 1994 Call for Papers 7 .'phdifflyf T h e Role of Banking The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago invites the sub mission of research and policy-oriented papers for its 30th annual Conference on Bank Structure and Compe tition which will be held at the Westin Hotel in Chicago, Illinois, May 11-13,1994. The theme of the conference is the widely held but debatable perception that the commercial banking industry is in a state of decline. By some measures, including employment and inflation-adjusted assets, this decline has been absolute as well as relative. On the other hand, the decline is less obvious when more comprehensive measures are used that take account of banks’ enormous expansion into off-balance-sheet ac tivities. Moreover, the importance of banking in the implementation of public policy may be largely inde pendent of the size of the industry. Whatever its magnitude, the perceived decline has raised a plethora of questions on the part of bank ers, their nonbank competitors, and public officials. For example, does the performance of many tradition al banking services by nonbank competitors expose the economy to disturbances that previously would have been absorbed by the bank safety net? Is the de cline a consequence of overregulation that could be eliminated without significant adverse effects on finan cial stability? Or is it the result of inefficient manage ment and inappropriate strategies on the part of the banks? What if anything should public policy do to slow down or reverse the decline? What can bank management do? What do banks’ declining shares of assets and deposits portend for the Federal Reserve’s ability to affect money and credit and, therefore, total spending in the economy? Although much of the program will address is sues related to the primary theme of the conference, we also welcome papers on the following topics: ■ the impact of regulatory changes in FDICLA; ■ the consolidation movement in banking, with an emphasis on interstate expansion; ■ depositor preference legislation; ■ risk management and derivative financial instruments; ■ financial issues associated with community development; and ■ other topics related to the structure and regulation of the financial services industry. If you would like to present a paper at the confer ence, please submit three copies of the completed paper or an abstract with your name, address, and telephone number, and those of any coauthors, by December 15, 1993. Correspondence should be addressed to: Conference on Bank Structure and Competition Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 230 South LaSalle Street Chicago, Illinois 60604-1413 For additional information, call Douglas Evanoff 312-322-5814 or Larry Mote 312-322-5809. Cost effective control of urban smog: a report of a conference held at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 7-8, 1993 Richard F. Kosobud, W illia m A. Testa, and D onald A . Hanson recent years have seen the emergence of two apparently opposing trends: a heightened inter est in reducing urban smog concentrations, which remain high, and a growing apprehension that improved air quality will require increasing costs per unit of improvement. What explains this shift from optimism about having achieved certain environmental goals to the more recent apprehension of an environment-prosperity trade-off? Perhaps some of the more tractable environmental prob lems have been solved and the less costly pollu tion abatements have been achieved, leaving those complex environmental problems that will be very costly to remedy. One of the remaining problems is the quantity of low-level airborne ozone, perhaps the most important component of urban smog. After twenty years of efforts such as modifications to automobiles, many urban areas still fail to meet national standards for ambient ozone. Given the difficulties in attaining national ozone standards, it is natural to ask whether the goals of current ozone legislation can be justified within a cost-benefit framework. In the minds of many of the conference participants was an earlier and influential study by the economists Alan Krupnick and Paul Portney (1991), which estimated that the costs of a one-third reduction The new environmental man dates set forth in the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 (CAAA ‘90) are expected to cost the nation $20 to $30 billion annually through the end of the decade. These costs will fall particularly hard on Seventh District metropolitan areas such as Chicago, Milwaukee, and Muskegon, Michigan, which are classified as severe nonattainment areas. Responding to these expectations, a group of academics, business people, government regulators, and environmentalists gathered on June 7 and 8, 1993, for a conference at the Fed eral Reserve Bank of Chicago sponsored by the Chicago Fed, the Workshop on Market-Based Approaches to Environmental Policy of the University of Illinois at Chicago, and the Chica go Council on Foreign Relations. The confer ence was designed to evaluate the promise and the potential shortcomings of urban smog con trol strategies from various perspectives, ranging from the impact on human health to the potential effects on regional economies. The conference proceedings reflect this diversity of topics and explore ways of crafting environmental policy that will improve air quality while minimizing the extent of economic disruption. During the past twenty-five years, most regions of the United States have experienced both growing per capita standards of living (as measured by national income) and improved air quality. Environmental policy measures have brought about reduced atmospheric concentra tions of lead, particulate matter, and sulfur diox ide. In contrast to this improvement, however, R ic h a rd F. K o s o b u d is p r o fe s s o r o f e c o n o m ic s a t th e U n iv e r s ity o f Illin o is a t C h ic a g o , W illia m A . T e s ta is a re s e a rc h o ffic e r a n d s e n io r re g io n a l e c o n o m is t at th e F e d e ra l R e s e rv e B a n k o f C h ic a g o , a n d D o n a ld A. H a n s o n is m a n a g e r o f th e E n e rg y P o lic y S e c tio n at A r g o n n e N a tio n a l L a b o ra to ry . T h e a u th o r s w is h to th a n k th e ir a s s o c ia te e d ito rs , P a m e la P in n o w , J e n n ife r Z im m e r m a n , a n d J e ff C a m p . 22 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES of volatile organic compounds, a precursor of ground-level ozone, far exceeded the benefits associated with this reduction—by a factor of eight or more.1 Calculations for the Los Angeles area, that “superbowl” of smog, reduced the factor but left the ratio above three. These find ings were consistent with those of earlier re search. Yet the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 (CAAA ‘90) set new and even more strin gent goals for the nation that could require more expensive control measures. Recent research suggests that the benefits of reducing smog are greater than previously esti mated. This shift in thinking is due to new dis coveries about the health impacts of ozone, as well as its adverse effects on agriculture and material contamination—primarily vehicle tires. Moreover, as new market-based approaches to controlling emissions are tried, the smog cleanup costs, both for volatile organic compounds and nitrogen oxides, appear to be decreasing or in creasing less rapidly per unit of improvement. If this is true, the new legislation might be even closer to the mark than previously thought. Some observers view Title I of CAAA ‘90 as a renewed effort by the federal government to attain cleaner urban air, but in the most costefficient fashion so as to allow continued im provement in both living standards and air quali ty. The legislation sets more stringent require ments for reducing ozone concentrations, yet it provides for new, flexible, market-based ap proaches to controlling those ozone precursors generated by human activity. Such approaches hold out the promise of more cost effective and innovative control of air pollution. Among the responses to the legislation are programs that allow firms to trade rights to emit prescribed levels of the precursors of urban ozone, and “cash-for-clunkers” programs that offer bounties to car owners who scrap their high-emitting, often older, automobiles. Incentive systems such as these have long appealed to economists. In theory, given cost variability within and among firms, market incentives allow firms to realize significant cost savings by choosing the cheapest, most efficient methods of reducing their own emissions. In addition, programs of tradeable emission credits give firms an incentive to search out-of-house for the most cheaply reduceable emission sourc es to control first, such as motor vehicles. But perhaps the most significant benefit of incentive systems is that they stimulate advances in en FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO vironmental control technologies and promote practices that lead to additional cost savings and emissions reduction. Clearly, incentive systems hold out the promise of substantial savings in resources that would be welcome in an era of increasing de mands. The only hitch is that they are relatively untried and untested. A heavy load of program design, institution creation, monitoring, and enforcement problems remains to be resolved before the promise of incentive systems can be fulfilled. Additionally, many of the parties con cerned with environmental policy are uneasy with market-based approaches. This includes not only some environmental groups, but also segments of the business and government regu latory communities. An important objective of the June confer ence, therefore, was to contribute to a full airing of these disparate views. Several contributions to the conference bear on this point. The direc tor of the Illinois Environmental Protection Agency and the president of Commonwealth Edison Company announced the initiation of a new market-based program whereby emitters in the Chicago region can trade nitrogen oxide emission credits. A senior economist with the Environmental Defense Fund voiced support for this program, illustrating the potential for coop eration among groups previously in opposing environmental camps. Such signs of cooperation are welcome at this time. The debate leading up to CAAA ‘90, both inside and outside Congress, revealed a dramatic widening of the range of interest groups demanding a say in the legislative pro cess. Groups with differing points of view and conflicting historical positions on environmental policy—particularly, the business and environ mental communities— seemed to be modifying previous positions and opening up tentative new lines of communication and cooperation. At the local and regional level, such cooperation will be needed if these innovative policies are to be sucessfully designed and implemented. The conference aimed to nurture the development of these new cooperative relationships, which can ultimately fashion the most cost effective poli cies for solving the ozone abatement problem. FOOTNOTE 'A la n J. K ru p n ick and P au l R. P o r tn ey , “ C o n tr o llin g urban air p o llu tio n : a b e n e fit -c o s t a s s e s s m e n t ,” Science, V o l. 2 5 2 , 1 9 9 1 , pp. 5 2 2 -2 8 . 23 Proceedings of the Conference on Cost Effective Control of Urban Smog Preface David R. Allardice, F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ic a g o Ed ito rs' in tro d u ctio n Richard F. Kosobud, U n iv e r s ity o f I llin o is a t C h ic a g o ; William A. Testa, F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ic a g o ; a n d Donald H. Hanson, A r g o n n e N a tio n a l L a b o r a to r y Special address Samuel K. Skinner, C o m m o n w e a lth E d is o n C o m p a n y The challenges fa c in g Illinois: achieving b alance b etw ee n a clean er en viro n m e n t and econ o m ic g ro w th Mary A. Gade, I llin o is E n v ir o n m e n ta l P r o te c tio n A g e n c y The urban ozone a b a te m e n t problem George Tolley, U n iv e r s ity o f C h ic a g o a n d R C F , In c .; Jeffrey Wentz, H a r d in g - L a w s o n A s s o c ia te s ; Steven Hilton, R C F , In c .; a n d Brian Edwards, R C F , Inc. Discussion Karl A. McDermott, I llin o is C o m m e r c e C o m m is s io n The status o f th e m o d elin g o f ozone fo rm a tio n and geographic m o ve m e n t in th e M id w e s t Stephen L. Gerritson, L a k e M ic h ig a n Discussions Mark E. Femau, S ig m a R e s e a r c h Peter A. Scheff, U n iv e r s ity o f I llin o is A i r D ir e c to r s C o n s o r tiu m a t C h ic a g o C ost e ffe ctive n e ss o f re m o te sensing o f vehicle em issions Winston Harrington, R e s o u r c e s f o r th e F u tu re ; a n d Virginia D. McConnell, U n iv e r s ity o f M a r y la n d a n d R e s o u r c e s f o r Discussions Wynn Van Bussmann, C h r y s le r C o r p o r a tio n Thomas R. Wallin, I llin o is E n v ir o n m e n ta l P r o te c tio n A g e n c y James D. Boyd, C a lif o r n ia A i r R e s o u r c e s B o a r d th e F u tu r e Incen tives and th e car Daniel J. Dudek, E n v ir o n m e n ta l D e f e n s e F u n d Discussions Thomas F. Walton, G e n e r a l M o to r s C o r p o r a tio n Elmer W. Johnson, K ir k la n d & E llis H ealth im p acts o f ozone John D. Spengler, H a r v a r d U n iv e r s ity Discussions Victoria W. Persky, U n iv e r s ity o f I llin o is a t C h ic a g o Richard A. Wadden, U n iv e r s ity o f I llin o is a t C h ic a g o Emissions o ffs e t tra d in g program s in th e N o rth ea st and M id -A tla n tic states Bruce S. Carhart, O z o n e T r a n s p o r t C o m m is s io n M o b ile source em issions redu ctio n cred its as a cost e ffe c tiv e m easure fo r co n tro llin g urban a ir p ollution James D. Boyd, C a lif o r n ia A i r R e s o u r c e s Discussion Tom Tietenberg, C o lb y C o lle g e B oard Regional econ o m ic im p acts o f m a rk etab le p erm it program s: th e case o f Los A ngeles Kelly Robinson, R u tg e r s U n iv e r s ity T itle I o f th e Clean A ir A c t A m en d m en ts o f 1 9 9 0 and im p licatio n s fo r m arket-b ased strategies John Calcagni, E 3 V e n tu r e s I n c o r p o r a te d For a complimentary copy of these proceedings, write or phone P u b lic A f f a ir s D e p a r tm e n t, F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ic a g o , P .O . B o x 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , I llin o is 6 0 6 9 0 - 0 8 3 4 , te le p h o n e 3 1 2 - 3 2 2 - 5 1 1 1 . 24 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES E C O N O M IC PERSPECTIVES— IN D E X FOR 19 93 Issue Pages B A N K IN G , CREDIT, A N D FIN ANC E Reducing credit risk in over-the-counter derivatives John P. Behof.............................................................................................................. .Jan/Feb 21-31 Consumer debt and home equity borrowing Francesca Eugeni........................................................................................................ . Mar/Apr 2-14 Recent trends in corporate leverage Paula R. Worthington.................................................................................................. May/Jun 24-31 Capital shocks and bank growth— 1973 to 1991 Herbert L. Baer and John N. McElravey.................................................................... .Jul/Aug 2-21 Why the life insurance industry did not face an “S&L-type” crisis Elijah Brewer III, Thomas H. Mondschean, and Philip E. Strahan............................. Sep/Oct 12-24 E C O N O M IC C O N D IT IO N S Assessing global auto trends Paul D. Ballew and Robert H. Schnorbus..................................................................., Mar/Apr 15-26 Economic development policy in the 1990s—are state economic development agencies ready? Richard H. Mattoon.................................................................................................... .May/Jun 11-22 Long-term earnings losses of high-seniority displaced workers Louis S. Jacobson, Robert J. LaLonde, and Daniel G. Sullivan................................. Nov/Dec 2-20 M O N E Y A N D M O N E T A R Y POLICY Indicators, performance, and policy in the 1930s and today Robert D. Laurent....................................................................................................... .Jan/Feb 2-11 REG IONAL E C O N O M IC S NAFTA: a review of the issues Linda M. Aguilar........................................................................................................ .Jan/Feb 12-20 Trends and prospects for rural manufacturing William A. Testa........................................................................................................., Mar/Apr 27-36 How lean manufacturing changes the way we understand the manufacturing sector Thomas H. Klier......................................................................................................... . May/Jun 2-9 Shaping the Great Lakes economy: a conference summary Richard H. Mattoon and William A. Testa.................................................................. Jul/Aug 22-27 Tracking Midwest manufacturing and productivity growth Philip R. Israilevich, Kenneth N. Kuttner, and Robert H. Schnorbus........................ ..Sep/Oct 2-11 Cost effective control of urban smog: a report of a conference held at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 7-8,1993 Richard F. Kosobud, William A. Testa, and Donald A. Hanson............................... . Nov/Dec 22-24 To order copies of any of these issues, or to receive a list of other publications, telephone 312-322-5111, or write to: Public Information Center Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago P.O. Box 834 Chicago, IL 60690-0834 ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES P u b lic I n f o r m a tio n C e n te r Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago P.O. Box 834 Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834 BULK RATE U.S. POSTAGE PAID CHICAGO, ILLINOIS PERMIT NO. 1942 Do N o t Forw ard Address C o rrec tio n Requested R eturn Postage G uaranteed M a ilin g label c o rre c tio n s o r d eletio n s: M a k e c h a n g e s or m ark Delete From Mailing List o n th e la b e l and fax th e la b el to: 3 1 2 -3 2 2 - 2 3 4 1 , o r m a il to: A T T N : M a il S e r v ic e s , F ed e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k o f C h ic a g o , P .O . B o x 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , I llin o is 6 0 6 9 0 - 0 8 3 4 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO