View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Call for Papers
Federal Reserve Ban
of Chicago

2002 Conference on
Bank Structure and
Competition
Fourth Quarter 2001

perspectives
2

Electronic bill presentment and payment—
Is it just a click away?

17

Liquidity effects in the bond market

38

Countering contagion: Does China’s experience
offer a blueprint?

53

Growth in worker quality

75

Index for 2001

Economic .

perspectives

President
Michael H. Moskow

Senior Vice President and Director of Research
William C. Hunter
Research Department
Financial Studies
Douglas Evanoff, Vice President

Macroeconomic Policy
Charles Evans, Vice President
Microeconomic Policy
Daniel Sullivan, Vice President
Regional Programs
William A. Testa, Vice President

Economics Editor
David Marshall

Editor
Helen O’D. Koshy
Associate Editor
Kathryn Moran

Production
Julia Baker, Rita Molloy,
Yvonne Peeples, Nancy Wellman
Economic Perspectives is published by the Research

Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The
views expressed are the authors’ and do not necessarily

reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
or the Federal Reserve System.
Single-copy subscriptions are available free of charge. Please
send requests for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions,
back issues, and address changes to the Public Information
Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834,
Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834, telephone 312-322-5111
or fax 312-322-5515.
Economic Perspectives and other Bank

publications are available on the World Wide Web
at http://www.frbchi.org.
Articles may be reprinted provided the source is credited
and the Public Information Center is sent a copy of the
published material. Citations should include the following
information: author, year, title of article, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, Economic Perspectives, quarter, and
page numbers.

& chicagofed. org
ISSN 0164-0682

Contents

Fourth Quarter 2001, Volume XXV, Issue 4

Electronic bill presentment and payment—Is it just a click away?
Alexandria Andreeff, Lisa C. Binmoeller, Eve M. Boboch, Oscar Cerda,
Sujit Chakravorti, Thomas Ciesielski, and Edward Green

This article addresses the following questions about electronic presentment and payment
(EBPP) in the business-to-consumer marketplace: Why aren’t electronically presented
bills always paid electronically? And, if EBPP does aid in the migration to fully electronic
end-to-end payment, what are the barriers to its adoption?

17

Liquidity effects in the bond market
Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau
The authors find that supply risk in the market for Treasury bills adds between 10 basis points
and 40 basis points to the standard deviation of the T-bill interest rate. The risk will probably
increase unless the Fed expands the set of assets that it uses to conduct open market operations.

Call for Papers
Countering contagion: Does China’s experience offer a blueprint?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald, and Prakash Loungani
China did not succumb to the Asian crisis of 1997-99, despite two apparent sources of
vulnerability: a weak financial system and increased export competition from the Asian crisis
economies. This article argues that both sources of vulnerability were more apparent than real.
China’s experience (especially its use of capital controls) does not offer a blueprint for other
countries, because other countries would not want to replicate China’s inefficient, non-marketoriented financial system.

53

Growth in worker quality
Daniel Aaronson and Daniel Sullivan
This article shows that increases in the educational attainment and labor market experience of
the U.S. work force have led to an advance in labor productivity of more than 0.2 percentage
points per year since the early 1960s. Estimates show, however, some deceleration in the pace
of labor quality improvements toward the end of the 1990s. Forecasts call for a continued
decline over the remainder of the current decade.

Index for 2001

Electronic bill presentment and payment—
Is it just a click away?
Alexandria Andreeff, Lisa C. Binmoeller,
Eve M. Boboch, Oscar Cerda,
Sujit Chakravorti, Thomas Ciesielski,
and Edward Green

Introduction and summary
This article concerns electronic bill presentment and
payment (EBPP) in the business-to-consumer (B2C)
marketplace and, more specifically, remote bill payments (as opposed to payments made at the point of
sale). B2C EBPP applications are plausibly among
the most promising innovations to shift U.S. consumer
payments from checks to electronic alternatives. By
EBPP, we mean the electronic bill presentment to the
consumer and the electronic initiation of payment by
the consumer. Some analysts have suggested that electronic delivery of bills will increase the use of electronic
payments. Our research attempts to answer the following two questions: Why aren’t electronically presented bills always paid electronically? And, if EBPP
does aid in the migration to fully electronic end-toend payment, what are the barriers to its adoption?
While the U.S. continues to lead the world in technological advancements such as the development and
widespread use of the computer and Internet technologies, Americans still rely on checks to make most
payments. The U.S. has higher check usage per capita than any other industrialized country. Humphrey,
Pulley, and Vesala (2000) state that U.S. consumers
and businesses write around 20 checks per month. This
is more than 2.8 times the number of checks written
per person in Canada, France, or the UK and at least
20 times more per person than in Germany, Japan, Italy,
Belgium, the Netherlands, Sweden, or Switzerland.
In 1999, U.S. businesses and consumers issued a
total of 68 billion checks (BIS, 2001). The proportion
of check usage is highest for remote payments. Of the
15 billion to 17 billion consumer bills issued every year,
over 80 percent are paid by check (Kerr and Litan,
2000). If EBPP were to capture the whole consumer
market and convert all check payments into electronic ones, the number of checks written by consumers
would be reduced by over 40 percent.

2

Today, most consumers still receive their bills
via mail. With today’s technology, bills may be presented via the Internet, mobile phone, or personal digital assistant anywhere in the world, allowing for greater
convenience to consumers. However, how much, if
anything, most consumers are willing to pay for such
a service remains unclear. Greater convenience, along
with value-added services such as better customer service, account aggregation, and other incentives may
be required to achieve the number of consumers necessary for billers to provide EBPP services.
In the next section, we explore how most traditional bills are presented and paid. Then, we discuss the
various EBPP models and what enhancements to existing payment choices may be necessary for Internetand e-mail-initiated transactions. Next, we consider
the various payment options available for EBPP;
and finally, we outline barriers to market adoption
of EBPP services.
Traditional bill presentment and payment
Below, we discuss the costs and benefits of the
traditional bill presentment and payment process. Industry participants estimate that billers issued between
15 billion and 17 billion consumer bills in 2000. Over
80 percent of these bills were originated by one of four
industry groups: finance, insurance, telecommunications, and utilities. Billers and consumers pay $80
Alexandria Andreeff is project leader and Lisa C. Binmoeller
is project manager of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s
EBPP Leadership Assignment. Eve M. Boboch, assistant
vice president, and Thomas G. Ciesielski, vice president in
the Financial Services Group, are project directors of the
EBPP Leadership Assignment. Oscar Cerda is a regulatory
associate economist, Sujit Chakravorti is a senior economist,
and Edward Green is senior policy advisor at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors would like to extend
a special thank you to Elizabeth Knospe and Ann Spiotto
for their legal assistance.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

billion annually for bill presentment and payment.1
Internal operations for bill and payment processing
cost billers $45 billion yearly, with almost two-thirds
($30 billion) of that going to technology vendors for
hardware and software implementation and support.
The remaining $35 billion comprises $10.7 billion
for postage; $8 billion for account fees at financial
institutions; $7.5 billion for insufficient fund fees;
$5.7 billion for outsource bill/payment processing;
$2.2 billion for check clearing fees; and $0.9 billion
for ACH (automated clearing house)/credit card processing and settlement fees (Whaling, 2000a).
Bill presentment
Traditional consumer bill presentment and payment is a paper-based process that involves presenting the consumer with a paper bill for goods or services
previously rendered, which the consumer pays by
check. The bill presentment process involves billing
operations, such as generating, printing, mailing, and
delivery of bills to consumers.2 The cost of processing,
printing, and sending bills can range from $.70 to $1.50
(PayAnyBill, 2000). In other words, billers spend between $10.5 billion and $25.5 billion each year to
present bills.3
The traditional bill presentment process involves
not only the biller generating a periodic report from
its billing systems, but also the subsequent notification of the bill to the consumer for goods or services
previously rendered. Paper-based billing is an intricate and time-consuming process that involves printing
account statements, stuffing them into envelopes (along
with appropriate advertising inserts and other marketing material), and sorting for mailing. Depending upon
the level of automation, the creation and processing
of bills can take anywhere from one to three days
(Doculabs, 1999). In the traditional bill payment world,
notification and presentment of a bill occur simultaneously when the consumer receives the bill in their
mailbox. For most bills today, the post office serves
as a notification and presentment network by delivering each statement from each biller individually to
each customer. The average bill takes three to five
days to reach the consumer.
Most billers have streamlined and improved their
paper-based billing operations as much as possible.
However, the traditional billing process still faces issues of convenience, timeliness, cost, and reliability.
Traditional billing does not allow consumers to receive
their bills anytime and anywhere. Furthermore, errors
in customers’ addresses (which are common when
customers relocate) may lead to significantly longer
delivery times. The process of printing bills, assembling bills, and delivering bills is time-consuming

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

and costly to billers since it is resource intensive. Traditional billing also lacks reliability because paperbased billing systems offer no guaranteed delivery
mechanism. Furthermore, lost bills result in customer
service problems and late fees for consumers.
Bill payment
The bill payment process involves at least five
main participants: the consumer, the consumer’s financial institution, the biller, its financial institution, and
a payment network (see figure 1). The consumer will
ultimately use funds on deposit at their financial institution to settle the monetary obligation. In the case of
check, debit card, or ACH payments, the consumer
will have to deposit the funds into their account before
initiating payment to the biller.4 The biller’s financial
institution will present the consumer’s payment obligation through a payment network that processes
checks, ACH payments, credit cards, or debit cards.
The consumer’s financial institution will send funds
via the network to the biller’s financial institution if
sufficient funds are in the payee’s account (or if the
payee has a sufficient line of credit). The advantages
and disadvantages of each network are well known.5
Electronic bill presentment and payment
In contrast to the traditional model, EBPP no
longer uses the mail system as a delivery mechanism
for bill presentment and payment initiation. Instead,
it uses the Internet as a speedier and less expensive
delivery infrastructure to present bills electronically.6
With the percentage of U.S. households with Internet
access having increased from 26.2 percent to 41.5 percent between December 1998 and August 2000 (U.S.
Department of Commerce, 2000), Internet access to
bill presentment and payment options is on the rise.
Consumer and biller expectations
Compared with the traditional bill delivery and
payment methods, EBPP seeks to meet or exceed the
sometimes competing expectations of consumers and
billers.
Consumer expectations
■ Convenience—Consumers do not view the traditional payment methods as overly burdensome
and would expect any new bill payment procedure
to meet or improve on this convenience before
switching.
■ Time/cost savings—Consumers would expect to
have costs that are just as low (or even lower)
than their current bill paying costs.
■ Control over payments—As with the use of checks,
with EBPP consumers would expect to have control over the timing and amount of payments.

3

FIGURE 1

Bill payment

Consumers
Billers

Payment network

Consumer's
financial
institution

■

■

Universal payment mechanisms—Because electronic payments are replacing the check, consumers
would expect to have a wide range of electronic
payment options that meet their specific payment
needs or wishes.
Privacy and security—Consumers must be confident that any bill payment process will protect
their privacy and funds by securely transferring
billing information and payments.

■

Reliability—Consumers must trust the accuracy of
their electronic bills and feel confident that their
payments will be delivered accurately and on time.

■

Dispute resolution—Consumers need reliable and
accessible customer service options to resolve any
questionable transactions.

Biller expectations
■ Cost reductions—Billers want a bill creation and
payment process that is less costly or, at least, no
more costly than the current paper-based billing
process.
■

4

Dispute resolution mechanism—Billers require an
accessible and cost-efficient dispute resolution
procedure.

Biller's
financial
institution

■

Reliable delivery mechanism—Billers want a fast
and reliable delivery mechanism for both presentment and payment.

■

Ability to up-sell and cross-sell—Billers want to
employ specialized, targeted marketing techniques,
rather than general paper statement stuffers that
may not be suitable for each consumer.
Control over customer data—Billers want to protect and safeguard their most valuable data.

■

■

Broad distribution/reach—Billers require a broad
delivery and payment medium to gain maximum
customer use.

EBPP presentment models
The two primary EBPP models are the biller-direct model and the consolidation/aggregation model.
There are a number of variations of the consolidation/
aggregation model, including e-mail-based EBPP, the
use of personal financial management software, screen
scraping, and scan and pay methods. The notification
procedure for both the biller-direct and the consolidation/aggregation models involves the biller notifying
the customer of a pending bill, generally via e-mail, and
the customer subsequently logging onto either the biller’s or consolidator/aggregator’s website (see figure 2).

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Biller-direct model
In the biller-direct model, once a consumer has
enrolled for EBPP services, the biller generates an
electronic version of the consumer’s billing information. The biller may outsource this responsibility using
a bill service provider (BSP). These BSPs act as agents
on behalf of the biller and provide such services as
electronic bill translation, formatting, data parsing, and,
at times, hosting the biller’s website. Next, the biller
notifies the consumer of a pending bill, generally via
e-mail, and the consumer is directed to log onto each
biller’s website (or to a BSP’s website), where the biller presents the consumer with an electronic version
of the billing statement (see figure 3). After viewing
the online bill, the consumer can initiate payment directly from the website. From the time of enrollment
to the time of initiating payment, there are no other
parties that come between the biller (or its BSP) and
consumer. Thus, the biller (or its BSP) is responsible
for interfacing with the customer to enroll, access
electronic billing information, and make payments.
Biller-direct advantages
For the most part, the biller-direct model exceeds
the biller’s basic expectations. It provides the biller
with an electronic method of creating and notifying

the consumer of pending bills in a cost-efficient manner. It is estimated that the electronic creation of all
consumer bills would significantly reduce bill statement production costs.
The model also provides a more reliable, faster
delivery mechanism for both bill delivery and payment
receipt, compared with traditional bill presentment
and payment (Kerr and Litan, 2000). Delays and interruptions can have negative effects on the biller’s
cash flow. The model also has the potential to reduce
costs through the use of electronic consumer dispute
resolution mechanisms. It is estimated that 70 percent
of calls to telephone-based customer service centers
concern billing statements (IBM, 2000). Online resolution could reduce the labor and overhead costs associated with customer service centers.
The biller-direct model is also advantageous for
the biller in that it maintains direct contact with the
consumer. Since the biller controls how the bill is visually presented through its website, it can maintain
its brand identity. The biller-direct model can also lead
to better cross-sell and up-sell opportunities. It attempts
to integrate bill presentment with specialized, targeted marketing techniques, rather than broad-based
advertising that may not apply to all consumers. Since

FIGURE 2

Notification

Co

ns

Biller A

um

Co

er

ns

um

Co

er

ns

um

er

C

B

Ab

m
Fro

ill

bil

er
bill

l

Consumer B bill

From

l

n

Co

er

B

m
su

on

C

Biller C

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

C

From

l
bil

er

um

s
on

Consumer B

From biller C

il
Ab

su

C

From biller B

E-mail

Consumer C bill

r
me

er

bill

From biller A

Consumer A bill
Biller B

bill

m
Fro

l

B

er

m
Fro

bil

Consumer A

A

C

l
bil

From

bille

rA

bille

rB

bille

rC

Consumer C

5

FIGURE 3

Biller-direct presentment

Biller A
website

Consumer A

Biller B
website

Consumer B

Biller C
website

the biller controls the consumer’s demographic data
(captured during the enrollment process) and purchasing habit data (through billing data), it can more easily
target different market segments.
Finally, since the biller relies on its own (or its
BSP’s) processing systems, it does not risk third-party integration problems seen in other EBPP models
(Doculabs, 1999). In its survey of consumer highvolume billers (over 250,000 bills a month), Gartner
Group estimated that by year-end 2000, 74 percent
of e-billers would be presenting on their own company’s website (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
From the consumer’s perspective, the biller-direct model meets many of the basic expectations seen
in the traditional mailing system model. Customers
expect EBPP costs that are just as low (or even lower)
than their current bill paying costs. Under the billerdirect model, the customer saves on mailing and
check writing costs when submitting payments. In
addition, biller-direct applications are usually offered
free of charge.
The majority of consumers perceive the U.S. Postal Service to be a secure, private, and reliable way of
transporting bills and payment (Whaling, 2000a). EBPP

6

Consumer C

offerings utilizing the biller-direct model use login
IDs, passwords, and encryption technology to provide
sufficient protection for privacy of consumers’ bill
records, as well as the actual payments. Biller-direct
providers are relying not only on the 128-bit RC4 encryption in the consumer’s browser, but also on additional encryption and secure channels for all messages
sent between the biller, financial institution, and consumer. In addition, consumers may be more comfortable establishing EBPP arrangements directly with
billers with whom they have existing relationships—
rather than with unknown third parties. Using the
Internet as a reliable delivery mechanism also results
in a reduction of potential late fees due to lost mail or
misplaced payments.7
Finally, consumers benefit from the biller-direct
model from a customer service perspective. Consumers
have the ability to access current or real-time information since billers are able to update customer data
more frequently. The biller-direct model also allows
for simpler and faster dispute resolution online versus
current telephone contacts. Market research indicates
that direct billers have a tendency to provide better
customer service than third parties (Robinson, 2000).

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Biller-direct disadvantages
The biggest disadvantage of the biller-direct approach is that consumers must take the initiative to
visit multiple billers’ websites to view and pay their
bills. Even if some billers use the same BSP, it is currently unlikely that all of a consumer’s billing information can be received from a single site. This can
be time-consuming and potentially confusing if all
billers do not use similar processes or interfaces for
presenting bills and accepting payments, in addition
to the multiple usernames and passwords the consumer must remember. While this model was acceptable
to the early adopters, it may be too cumbersome for
the broader consumer market.
Another disadvantage for consumers utilizing the
biller-direct model is that not all billers provide a wide
range of electronic payment options for each consumer’s payment needs. In the traditional model, all consumers have access to one universal payment option,
the check.8
For billers, the largest disadvantage to implementing the biller-direct model is that it is expensive
to establish, design, host, and maintain an in-house
application (Doculabs, 1999). In a survey of highvolume billers building or buying software for inhouse EBPP, first year expenditures in EBPP programs
averaged nearly $570,000 (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
Consolidation/aggregation model
The consolidation model was introduced to address
consumers’ desire to have one destination to access
and pay their bills while reducing the cost to billers
of implementing EBPP. In this model, the biller sends
the customer’s billing information to a third party
called a bill consolidator. The consolidator, operating
on behalf of the biller (or the aggregator operating on
behalf of the consumer) combines data from multiple
billers and consolidates the information at a single
destination. Although some consolidators present bills
at their own websites, most support the aggregation
of bills by consumer service providers (CSPs) such
as Internet portals, financial institutions, and brokerage websites (see figure 4).
Thick consolidation
Two variations of the consolidation model have
emerged, thick and thin consolidation. Under thick
consolidation, the consolidator maintains both the summary and details of the customer’s billing information.
The customer does not need to have one-on-one contact with the original biller to view the full detail of
bills due.
Thick consolidation advantages
In the thick consolidation model, the biller can
offer EBPP services to its customers without having

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

to implement its own costly infrastructure. Smaller billers lacking financial resources can still enter the EBPP
arena quickly. In fact, Gartner Group found that 41 percent of current consolidation users cited the ability to
start e-billing quickly as the top reason for using the
thick consolidation model (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
For consumers, having a third party offer EBPP
services may be to their advantage if the third party
is able to offer numerous electronic payment options
not supported directly by the biller. Depending on the
consolidation site chosen, convenience may be increased by allowing consumers to access their billing
data at popular Internet sites where they can perform
other tasks (such as online banking or online shopping).
Financial institutions could potentially garner
several benefits if they choose to host a bill consolidation site. In contrast to the traditional and biller-direct models, with this model banks are no longer forced
into the background performing simple payment processing. Banks’ entry into hosting an EBPP consolidation site could help drive the use of other online
banking services, thus maintaining customer relationships (McPherson, 2001).
Thick consolidation disadvantages
Under the thick consolidation model, billers
generally lose branding, marketing, and cross-selling
capabilities as consolidators eliminate direct contact
between billers and customers. In addition, billers
risk losing control over consumer data once it moves
to the consolidator.
For consumers, unlike providers offering the
biller-direct EBPP model, providers of the third-party
consolidation/aggregation model typically charge a
fee of approximately $4–$12 per month. This is problematic given that 59 percent of consumers are not
willing to pay for online bill payment and only 6 percent are willing to pay more than $5 (Kerr and Litan,
2000). In addition, customer service levels may be
reduced as consumers are directed to different contacts for different problems.
Thin consolidation
Under the thin consolidation model, the biller
maintains the details of the customer’s billing information while a summary is forwarded to the consolidator. Customers can view a summary of their bills
on the consolidator’s site, while those desiring to view
the details are linked to the original biller’s website.
Thin consolidation advantages
The thin consolidation model allows billers a
greater opportunity to provide online customer service, cross market products, and gain greater control
of their e-billing process, particularly by maintaining
control over consumer data (Kerr, 2000). Furthermore,

7

FIGURE 4

Consolidation/aggregation

Co

ns

Biller A

um

Co

er

ns

um

Co

er

ns

um

er

C

B

Consumer A

s
iew
A v bills
r
me ed
nsu at
Co solid
con

Ab

ill

bil

l

bil

l

Consumer A bill
Biller B

Consolidator/
aggregator
website

Consumer B bill
Consumer C bill

ill

r
me

su

n

Co

Ab
er

um

s
on

r
me

C
Biller C

B

l
bil

similar to the biller-direct model, the thin consolidation model provides consumers with the perceived
security and comfort of knowing that their billing
information is stored by the biller, an entity with
which they already have an established relationship.
Thin consolidation disadvantages
While this model may be advantageous for marketing purposes, billers still lose the marketing channel if customers choose not to view the full details of
their bills. In addition, the biller must bear the cost of
hosting a website where consumers can view the details of their bills. Finally, issues with technology,
standards, and security increase between the consolidator’s and the biller’s website, as they must be more
closely integrated than in the thick consolidation model.
Because the consolidation models involve the transmission of more data and the number of parties involved increases, the potential for errors also increases
if the industry lacks a universal message standard for
data exchange. Several groups are currently working
on a universal open standard that would allow billers
to present bills to any customer, anywhere, at anytime.
Two industry standards have been introduced
over the last few years, the Open Financial Exchange
(OFX) and Interactive Financial Exchange (IFX).

8

Consumer B

Con
con sumer
soli
date C views
d bi
lls

u

ns

Co

ill

Cb

Consumer B views
consolidated bills

Consumer C

Both of these standards are in their infancy. While OFX
has the widest acceptance, it is a very basic standard
that supports HyperText Markup Language (HTML)
and lacks the depth to support any level of complexity in a billing statement for consumers.9 Meanwhile,
IFX is being aggressively pursued by industry workgroups and EBPP software providers. Since IFX is
Extensible Markup Language (XML) based, it is
more robust than OFX, with mechanisms for richer
payment information and customer transaction tracking functionality (West, 2001). However, given that
the industry has yet to adopt one standard for data exchange, integration issues in the consolidation/aggregation models persist.
Consolidation preferences
Larger billers are beginning to show a preference
for the thin consolidation model. In its survey of highvolume billers, Gartner Group found that in 1999, 59
percent of billers that adopted the consolidation model
used the thick model. In contrast, nearly 63 percent
of billers planning to implement EBPP services in the
future intended to use the thin consolidation model
by year-end 2000. In fact, 64 percent of billers currently
utilizing the thick model intended to switch to the
thin consolidation model within the next three years.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

It was also estimated that 75 percent of high-volume
billers will use the thin consolidation model by yearend 2002 (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
According to Gartner Group, the consolidation
model’s high fees, lengthy and confusing enrollment,
and fragmented customer service have kept enrollment
low (Litan, 2000). The challenge inherent in both variations of the consolidation model is the coordination
between the different parties involved in the process.
Once these issues are resolved, growth of the consolidation model is expected to increase. As the number
and type of sites that aggregate multiple bills continue to grow, use of the consolidation model is expected to outpace that of the biller-direct model by 2004.
Financial institutions, brokerages, Web portals, and
now the U.S. Postal Service have all added EBPP to
their online offerings (Kerr, 2000).
Although industry experts suspect that consumers will ultimately prefer to have all of their bills
presented at one location, the disadvantages of the
consolidation models (namely, security, customer
service, high fees, and cumbersome enrollment procedures) may perpetuate the use of the biller-direct
model. Given the advantages and disadvantages of
each model, it is not surprising that many billers
currently use both the direct model and variations of
the consolidation models. In its 2000 survey of highvolume billers, Gartner Group indicated that by yearend 2000, 74 percent of e-billers would be presenting
on their own company’s website, while 73 percent
would have contracted with third-party bill consolidators (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
Alternative consolidation/aggregation models
Other variations of the consolidation/aggregation
model exist. These mainly consist of differences in bill
delivery or creation methods. Next, we provide a brief
summary of the alternative aggregation EBPP models.
Total bill consolidation
This is the only model that currently enables
customers to view all their bills at a single point via
the Internet. Total bill consolidation providers require
customers to redirect their bills to the provider’s data
center, which serves as a lockbox operation where
bills are scanned and transformed into electronic format (usually in a portable document format or PDF).
After bills are converted to electronic format, they
are presented at a consumer service provider (CSP)
(Jeffrey, 2000).
The primary advantage of the total bill consolidation model is that there is no need for standard systems and there are no complicated issues regarding
thick versus thin hosting. In addition, scan and pay

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

companies can provide customers with all of their
bills electronically, regardless of whether the biller
provides its bills electronically.
One of the limitations of this model is the reliance of the bill scanner on printing and mailing checks
to the biller after the customer has authorized payment.
In fact, it is estimated that over 50 percent of bills
presented electronically via the total bill consolidation
method are settled with the biller via check (Glossman
et al., 2000). In addition, consumers do not receive
bills any faster (in some cases more slowly) and the
value of the bill is improved little over the paper version, since it has no interactive capabilities. For billers, direct contact with the customer is lost. In fact,
the biller may not even be aware that the customer
has redirected statements to a total bill consolidator.
Screen scraping
Screen scrapers are companies that capture customer data from multiple billers’ websites with the
use of customer supplied IDs and passwords. Once
captured, the data is presented at the screen scraper’s
aggregation website or other CSP aggregation website. Screen scraping companies provide the software
used for screen-scraping purposes.
In the past, screen scraping was primarily a unilateral procedure initiated by the screen scraper acting on behalf of the consumer. A major disadvantage
of this model to billers was that they were not involved
in the process. Billers were unaware that their customers’ information had been screen scraped. This raised
concerns about security, privacy, and data accuracy,
as well as liability and regulatory issues. With resistance to screen scraping fading within the past year,
there has been a more collaborative approach between
billers and screen scrapers. Major consolidators and
major financial institutions have embraced screenscraping technology. Although this approach fulfills
a customer’s desire for aggregation, it has yet to be
seen if screen scraping will adequately address the
issues of liability, security, privacy, and data accuracy
(Gillespie, 2000).
One attempt to decrease the use of screen scraping in data aggregation is being headed by the Financial Services Technology Consortium (FSTC). Its goal
is to test methods of account aggregation, whereby
financial institutions and aggregators work together
to facilitate accurate display of customer data without screen-scraping or without the customer’s surrender of financial institution access codes to third-party
aggregators (Gram, 2001).
Consumer consolidation model
In the consumer consolidation model, electronic
bills are delivered directly to the customer’s desktop.

9

The biller maintains control of bill details until delivery to the customer is complete. The customer is then
able to control and store bills and can integrate them
into offline programs, such as personal financial management software. When payments are initiated via a
personal financial management software program, the
payments are facilitated through a consolidator. As a
result, payments may be made via check, ACH, credit,
or debit card payments.
The major advantage of the consumer consolidation model is that the consumer is able to work offline.
One of its less attractive features is that consumers
are required to download or purchase special software
to view bills rather than using a standard browser
(Chandler, 1998).
E-mail consolidation
In the e-mail-based billing model, companies enable the full detailed billing statement to be sent directly
from the biller to the consumer in HTML format. To
the consumer, the billing data received resembles a
Web page and can contain graphics, advertisements,
links to the biller’s website, links for immediate bill
payment, and a link to customer service (Kille, 2001).
The major advantage of the e-mail-based model
is that consumers are comfortable using e-mail. It also
allows for personalized electronic exchanges from
biller to consumer (Rini, 2000). As in the biller-direct
model, the biller maintains complete control over the
bill delivery process. For the consumer, there is no need
to download or learn any special software or device.
Disadvantages of this mode of bill delivery are
that the billing information is not interactive and there
is no guarantee that the consumer’s e-mail post office
will properly deliver the e-mail.
EBPP payment options
The payment mechanisms used by consumers in
the EBPP process are essentially the same as those
used in a traditional bill payment environment:
check, ACH, credit card, and debit card. Consumers
often authorize payments online rather than in paper
form. These payments are sometimes fulfilled in an
electronic fashion; however, many EBPP providers
still issue payments via check on behalf of the consumer. Currently, bill payment service providers process an estimated 40 percent of bill payments via
check, with less than 60 percent of the remaining bill
payments processed electronically, predominantly
through the ACH (Whaling, 2000b). Regardless of
how the payments are ultimately made, payment instructions are most often provided online in EBPP
applications—introducing concerns about the privacy
of consumers’ information, the security of payment

10

data being transmitted, and the authentication of parties to the transaction.
Privacy of information is one of the most critical
issues in an online environment. This is made more difficult by the fact that EBPP providers may be subject
to different rules and requirements protecting consumers’ information, depending on whether the provider
is a financial or nonfinancial institution. To make matters more complex, state privacy laws vary greatly in
terms of the protection provided to consumers.10
The security of the billing information presented
and the payment instructions received are also of
concern in an online environment. For an EBPP
solution to be effective, it must protect the integrity
of billing data presented and payment instructions
received through the entire process. Hackers, disgruntled employees, fraudulent billers, or insufficient data
security procedures can threaten the security of the
process. Also, since EBPP is relatively new, there is
little (if any) legal precedent identifying the responsible parties in the event that billing or payment data
are compromised.
Due to the electronic nature of EBPP transactions,
authentication of the parties involved is essential. In
a traditional environment, consumers receiving bills
via the mail generally assume that these bills are legitimate if they follow the biller’s conventional format.
On the payment side, the legal framework is well established to provide parties to a transaction with protection from fraud—largely based on paper-based
signatures. When bills are presented online, the consumer has little way of knowing whether the biller
really issued those bills, unless the consumer uses the
biller-direct model or has some kind of guarantee of
authenticity from the service provider.
Conversely, the identity of the consumer must be
authenticated to ensure that payment instructions being provided are not being initiated fraudulently. In
an online environment, it is unclear what constitutes
“authentication”—particularly from a regulatory
standpoint. Progress is being made in this area, with
the approval of the Uniform Electronic Transactions
Act (UETA) and its adoption in more than 20 states.
The federal Electronic Signatures in Global and National Commerce Act (the “E-Sign Act”), part of
which became effective in October 2000, considers
and promotes electronic signatures as an appropriate
means of authenticating identity. Per a March 29,
2001, press release, the Federal Reserve Board of
Governors is currently modifying Federal Reserve
Regulation E, which applies to electronic payments,
to reflect certain provisions of the E-Sign Act.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Each of the four primary payment mechanisms
used for bill payment has advantages and disadvantages in conjunction with electronic bill presentment.
To some extent, consumer choice will drive the popularity of the payment mechanisms. In many electronic transactions, though, the way in which the
payment is made is unknown to the consumer. Ultimately, this means that billers’ and financial institutions’ preferences for one financial instrument over
another could have a significant impact on the mechanism that ultimately dominates EBPP.
Check
The payment component of EBPP is sometimes
accomplished via paper check if a biller participating
in an electronic transaction cannot receive electronic
payments. In these cases, the consumer often provides electronic payment instructions to the service
provider, but the service provider executes the payment by writing a check to the biller. Consumers are
often unaware that a check payment has been made
to the biller because their portion of the transaction is
entirely electronic.
Checks provide important benefits in the EBPP
process in that they can be used to pay virtually anyone—even billers that are unable to receive electronic
payments. However, there is a unique disadvantage
for some billers receiving checks in an EBPP environment. Service providers sometimes consolidate (by
biller) multiple consumer payments initiated electronically in a check-and-list format. A biller receiving a
check-and-list payment receives a single check payment with a list of the consumers’ payments included
in the lump sum. The biller then must use a manual
process to reconcile the payments received in its billing system, which can be labor-intensive and introduces
yet another opportunity for error into the reconciliation of bills. Electronic payment options streamline
this process, and would seem to be preferable from a
biller’s perspective for use in conjunction with EBPP.
From the perspective of payment system efficiency, though, the check-and-list process does reduce
the total number of checks that would have to be processed if each consumer paid those bills by check. In
addition, the check and list removes authentication
issues between the biller and the EBPP service provider; the service provider essentially assumes responsibility for authenticating the identity of consumers
initiating payments.
ACH
ACH is the most common electronic payment
option used for consumer bill payments. In a traditional environment, ACH transactions are sometimes

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

perceived negatively by consumers citing a need for
greater control over the timing and amount of their
bill payments. However, EBPP applications can often
provide consumers with greater control over their
ACH payments. Consumers have the option to pay
bills through one-time ACH credit transactions initiated through their financial institutions, through onetime ACH debit payments authorized online (that is,
click to pay), or through the more traditional automated recurring debit transactions (direct debit) authorized online or via paper.
Though online bill payment applications appear
to remove some of the barriers to consumer use of
ACH payments, there are still some obstacles that
must be overcome. Many billers (particularly smalland medium-sized organizations) do not initiate or
receive electronic payments. The reasons for this are
uncertain and require further investigation as discussed
in the “Barriers to EBPP” section of this article. In
addition, the consumer enrollment and authentication
process for ACH payments is not standardized—
partly due to the fact that the regulatory environment
surrounding ACH debit is still evolving to accommodate online initiation of payments. This poses challenges for those educating consumers about electronic
payments and for EBPP providers wanting to offer
ACH as a payment option. Lastly, the consumer protections associated with unauthorized ACH transactions are not as robust or well known as they are for
other payment options, which may be preventing
greater usage.
Credit card
Credit card payments are another electronic payment option sometimes available to consumers participating in EBPP arrangements. From a biller’s
perspective, credit card transactions are generally
more costly than other electronic payment alternatives and are not accepted by all billers, which may
limit their use in the electronic payments arena. It is
important to note, though, that some credit cards now
feature embedded micro chips that store information
useful in authenticating the identity of the consumer.
If these cards can increase the reliability of authentication of the consumers, billers may be more receptive to them due to the reduced risk that a bill payment
transaction will be fraudulent (although it is unclear
whether fraud related to consumer bill payment is a
significant issue for billers).
Credit card usage is prevalent among consumers
in an online environment. Since EBPP applications
are typically available via the Internet, consumers
may pressure more billers to accept credit card payments.11 Some billers that allow consumers to pay their

11

bills via credit card are now charging a special fee for
their use. It is not clear whether billers are charging
this fee to cover the increased cost of the transaction,
to discourage widespread use of credit cards for bill
payment, or due to other reasons. If this becomes a
common, accepted practice, more billers may be encouraged to accept credit cards for bill payments.
Debit card
Debit card transactions are also sometimes used for
the payment of electronically presented bills. Offline
debit cards are most commonly used because these
transactions can be processed offline through the credit
card networks. Online debit transactions have not been
used on a widespread basis, which may be because
there is no standard industry model for authenticating
consumers’ identities and for connecting with the ATM
networks to obtain the instant verification of funds
availability that is needed to process online debits.
Online debit card transactions are currently being piloted on the Internet. One such pilot, launched
in February 2001 by BillMatrix Corporation in conjunction with Star Systems, Inc., allows consumers to
pay their utility bills using a debit card. In addition,
NACHA, the Electronic Payments Association, sponsored a pilot which concluded in March 2001 of consumer debit card use on the Internet; the NACHA pilot
combined use of the debit card with a digital signature for authentication purposes. The success of both
of these pilots remains to be seen, but interested parties are working to ensure that the debit card plays a
role in Internet-based payment transactions.
Barriers to EBPP
In the introduction to this article, we asked the
question: What barriers are preventing widespread
adoption of electronic presentment and payment?
Initial research has uncovered a number of barriers:
1. Lack of incentives for participants,
2. Lack of standards for enrollment and data exchange,
3. Concerns over security and privacy of financial
information, and
4. Legal issues surrounding industry regulations, liability, dispute resolution, and consumer protections.
Lack of incentives for consumers
EBPP services need to save consumers money
and time compared with traditional bill payment. Consumers appear reluctant to use EBPP until more of
their bills are available electronically. Checks are perceived to be free and relatively easy to use. Industry
analysts agree that consumer adoption would grow
more rapidly if EBPP services were offered for free

12

or at a fee lower than current costs associated with
check payments. Gartner Group reported that a majority of consumers, 59 percent, say they do not
want to pay anything for account and bill payment
aggregation services, and 51 percent feel other payment types, including checks, cash, and debit cards,
are easier to use (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
A cumbersome set-up process and long lead time
for electronic payments may also need to be addressed
to entice further usage. Consumers often have to wait
one billing cycle to set up credit card, debit card, or
ACH payments for their bills. Some consumers may
also experience a three- to five-day delay between the
time their account is debited and the merchant is paid.
Consumers may not change existing bill payment
habits until they perceive a strong value proposition
with EBPP. One approach may be to price paper presentment and payment more directly so as to encourage consumers to utilize electronic alternatives. An
alternative potential solution may be to attract consumers to adopt electronic payments through financial incentives.
Incentives for financial institutions
EBPP could result in lost revenue for financial
institutions operating retail lockboxes (the service of
financial institutions processing remittance information from a post office box and depositing them directly into an account) and check-processing operations.
Some institutions struggle with the inherent conflict
of reducing check revenue when promoting electronic payment usage. Furthermore, current pricing policies for electronic and check payments may discourage
the use of electronic payment alternatives.
However, pressure from EBPP providers has resulted in financial institutions entering the marketplace either directly with more user friendly and less
costly EBPP options or by partnering with consolidators. In addition, service providers are targeting financial institutions by offering network switches that utilize
open architecture for settlement of EBPP transactions.
Incentives for billers
The initial costs associated with implementation
of e-billing programs for high-volume billers are estimated to average $570,000 (Kerr and Litan, 2000).
High implementation costs and the need to operate
multiple, complex, billing systems concurrently have
likely discouraged biller adoption. The lack of standards and the uncertainty surrounding future EBPP
solutions introduce additional disincentives for billers
considering participation.
While 32 percent of all large volume billers
(greater than 250,000 bills a month) (Kerr and Litan,

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

2000) are presenting electronically, adoption rates
drop considerably for small to medium-sized billers
for both electronic presentment and payment. However, adoption by the largest billers may generate the
critical mass required to convince consumers of the
benefits of EBPP because, as noted earlier, the largest billers generate 80 percent of bills.
However, the adoption of EBPP has not necessarily led to end-to-end electronic payments. Virtually all consumer bills are paid electronically when
they are presented electronically and the consumer
has initiated payment online (click and pay). A majority of these payments are completed via the
ACH.12 However, consumer-initiated online recurring bill payments that are not presented electronically (primarily the pay-anyone model) are often
completed via check. Additional research is needed
to investigate if online-initiated check payments are
driven by the billers’ inability to accept electronic
payments or if other barriers are also contributing to
the use of paper payments in EBPP.
Incentives for third-party service providers
The dominance of several providers, lack of
open systems, and lack of universally accepted standards may serve as deterrents to new entrants. While
larger providers may have the financial resources to
develop solutions for multiple standards, the lack of
standards may limit smaller providers’ capabilities. It
is also unclear if third-party pricing policies for electronic and check payments discourage the use of
electronic methods.
Lack of standards for enrollment
The multitude of models, payment options, and
providers require consumers to use various cumbersome, inconsistent enrollment methods to establish
EBPP services. The method of enrollment may vary
depending on the biller and/or the model. The fragmented enrollment process has historically been a
major barrier for the traditional ACH direct payment
product. In the direct payment enrollment process,
the onus is typically on the consumer to contact each
biller to enroll, change, or cancel automatic deductions. This same type of problem is apparent in the
initial EBPP enrollment process, where the burden is
again on the consumer to search for billers offering
EBPP services. The pay-anyone model tries to alleviate this burden by allowing consumers to initiate
payments online to anyone regardless of how the bill
is received. While this model begins to address some
of the barriers to EBPP, it also appears to introduce
paper payments into the process.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Standards for data exchange
The lack of universal message standards for data
exchange continues to hamper growth in EBPP. Several standards have been introduced over the last few
years, including OFX and IFX. Industry adoption has
been slow, and participants continue to use different
formats for the exchange of presentment data, hindering interoperability between various provider and
biller systems.
Security and privacy concerns
Consumers are concerned about the security and
privacy of the financial information required for the
EBPP process. Gartner Group surveyed consumers
and determined that of Internet users who do not pay
bills online, 52 percent are concerned about privacy
and 48 percent are concerned about security and
fraud (Barto, 2001).
Some security and privacy concerns regarding
electronic data transfer for bill presentment include
data confidentiality and integrity, billing statement
issuer authentication, and nonrepudiation of statements (Whaling, 2000a). Specifically, the issues include the protection of the data that is transferred
between biller, service provider, and consumer from
being read or modified; verification that the billing
statement received by the consumer was sent from
the biller or service provider; and proof of the exact
contents of the billing statements.
Legal issues
When the EBPP provider is a financial organization, this raises a number of legal and regulatory considerations that might not be relevant to a typical
commercial provider. The question of which state’s
or country’s laws control an Internet relationship is
still developing (Spiotto and Mantel, 2000). States
have adopted different consumer protection laws,
which may be applicable to EBPP services.
Consumers may be exposed to differing protection rights and liabilities. The dispute resolution process may vary depending on the players, models, and
payment options. The current legal and regulatory
environment is still primarily designed for a paper
environment.
Conclusion
In recent years, commercial use of the Internet
has changed the way consumers and billers interact.
Traditionally, consumers received paper billing statements for products or services rendered; most consumers then forwarded a check to the biller via mail
to pay the amount due. As an information delivery
channel, the Internet has provided a new alternative

13

for billers and consumers to complete these transactions. Today, some billers are leveraging the Internet
to facilitate EBPP, in which billing statements are delivered to consumers and consumers provide bill payment instructions via e-mail or on the Internet.
In this article, we addressed two important questions: What barriers are preventing widespread adoption of EBPP?, and Will the electronic delivery of
bills increase the use of electronic payments? Industry analysts have heralded EBPP as the “killer application” enabled by the Internet, and some have claimed
that electronic presentment of bills will be the key
driver leading to the electronic payment of bills. However, we find that in spite of extremely optimistic predictions of growth for EBPP, actual use of EBPP is
estimated at less than 1 percent of consumers’ electronically paid bills (Kerr and Litan, 2000). Furthermore,
upon closer look at the industry, we find that checks
are still predominately used to pay consumer bills—
including bills that are presented electronically.
We have uncovered several barriers to greater use
of EBPP and electronic payments. The most critical
barrier is that key parties have insufficient incentives

to use EBPP and/or electronic payments instead of
traditional presentment and payment methods. Another inhibiting factor is the lack of standards in several areas of the industry: The enrollment process is
inconsistent among service providers, and there are
no universally accepted standards for the presentment
of bills, thus hindering greater interoperability in the
industry. As with other Internet-based applications,
security and privacy concerns may be slowing the
adoption of EBPP, as are uncertainties and obstacles
in the legal and regulatory environment.
It is unclear whether increased EBPP usage will
truly drive the use of electronic payments among consumers—and if so, what their electronic payment
method of choice will be. This article identifies the
key barriers to EBPP and suggests some areas in which
incentives could be provided to encourage greater
use of EBPP and electronic payments. Some, but not
all, of these areas represent potential opportunities
for both the private and public sector in facilitating
the migration from traditional paper-based payments
to electronic payments.

NOTES
1
Admittedly, this cost estimate overstates the real resource cost
of bill payment, because some of the cost represents transfers
among various participants and third-party providers.

7
Industry participants hope that the Internet will prove reliable;
however, there are some reliability concerns relating to e-mail delivery and website hosting.

2
These operations may be done internally by the biller or outsourced
to third parties.

8
A consumer does not necessarily need a single electronic payment option, but rather various payment options with flexibility
to meet their needs and wishes.

3
This assumes 15 billion bills at $.70 and 17 billion bills at $1.50.
The wide range in cost may reflect differences in unit cost for
large and small billers and differences in the way the cost estimates were made.

9
As of mid-2000, OFX had achieved broader industry support
with the release of OFX 2.0, an XML compliant version.

It can be argued that a provider of bills to customers in several
states must satisfy the privacy expectations in each state, and the
various requirements might conflict.

10

The consumer may have access to overdraft facilities that would
allow them to make payment without having funds in their transactions account.
4

This is in part because all four of the major credit card networks
limit consumer liability for unauthorized use to zero if proper
processing rules are followed.

11

For further information regarding the advantages and disadvantages of each payment mechanism, see Chakravorti, 1997;
Chakravorti and Shah, 2001; Federal Reserve Board, 1996;
Federal Reserve System, 1997; Flatraaker and Robinson, 1995;
Humphrey and Berger, 1990; Humphrey, Kim, and Vale, 1998;
and Wells, 1996.
5

6
Cost comparison is done at the margin and does not include transition costs.

14

Consumers may also choose to only view electronically presented bills and write checks rather than initiate online payments.
These types of transactions are not currently tracked and are
therefore not included in this discussion.

12

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

REFERENCES

Bank for International Settlements, 2001, Statistics on Payment Systems in the Group of Ten Countries: Figures for 1999, Basel, Switzerland: Bank for
International Settlements.
Bank Network News, 2000, “While online debit
grows, offline’s reign remains,” Bank Network News,
Vol. 19, No. 5, July 24, p. 5.
Barto, George L., 2001, “EBPP consumer trends,”
Gartner Group Interactive, available on the Internet
at www3.gartner.com/Init.

Federal Reserve System, 1997, “Payments primer:
Traditional payments,” Federal Reserve System Traditional Payments, December, No. 7.
Flatraaker, D., and P. Robinson, 1995, “Income,
costs, and pricing in the payment system,” Economic
Bulletin, Norges Bank, Vol. 76, pp. 321–332.
Food Marketing Institute, 1998, EPS Costs, A Retailer’s Guide to Electronic Payment Systems Costs,
Washington, DC: Food Marketing Institute.

Chakravorti, Sujit, 1997, “How do we pay?,” Financial Industry, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,
First Quarter.

Gillespie, Penny, 2000, “Financial aggregation—
Alternatives to screen scraping,” GIGA Information
Group, available on the Internet at
www.gigaweb.com, August 1.

Chakravorti, Sujit, and Alpa Shah, 2001, “A study
of the interrelated bilateral transactions in credit card
networks,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Public
Policy Series, policy paper, No. EPS-2001-2.

Glossman, Diane B., Richard H. Repetto, Scott A.
Smith, and Kenneth M. Usdin, 2000, “The electronic bill presentment and payment (EBPP) handbook,” Lehman Brothers Industry Reports, March 14.

Chandler, Dawn, 1998, “Electronic billing: Understanding the road to adoption,” Output Technology
Solutions, El Dorado Hills, CA, white paper, available on the Internet at www.output.net/docs/
newsroom/whitepapers.html.

Gram, William H., 2001, “FSTC’s phase two fast
aggregation pilot,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
report, April.

CheckFree, 2001, “CheckFree: The way money
moves on the Web,” homepage, available on the
Internet at www.CheckFree.com.
Credit Card News, 2001, Credit Card Issuers’
Guide, North Palm Beach, FL.
Doculabs, Inc., 1999, “Reference on electronic bill
presentment and payment, second edition (2.0),”
A Doculabs Report, available on the Internet at
www.doculabs.com.
Dove Associates and American Bankers Association, 1999, Study of Consumer Payment Preferences,
Washington, DC: American Bankers Association.
EDocs, 2001, “EDocs: Online account management
& billing,” homepage, available on the Internet at
www.eDocs.com.
Federal Reserve Board, 1996, Check Fraud Study,
Washington, DC.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Green, Paul H. (ed.), 1998, “1998 United States
check study,” The Green Sheet Quarterly, Vol. 1, No. 3.
Humphrey, David B., and Allen N. Berger, 1990,
“Market failure and resource use: Economic incentives to use different payment instruments,” in The
U.S. Payment System: Efficiency, Risk, and the Role
of the Federal Reserve, David B. Humphrey (ed.),
Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 45–86.
Humphrey, David B., Lawrence B. Pulley, and
Jukka M. Vesala, 2000, “The check’s in the mail:
Why the United States lags in the adoption of costsaving electronic payments,” Journal of Financial
Services Research, Vol. 17, No. 1, pp. 17–39.
Humphrey, David B., Moshe Kim, and Bent Vale,
1998, “Realizing the gains from electronic payments:
Costs, pricing, and payment choice,” Bank of
Norway, working paper, No. 1998/1.
IBM Global Services, 2000, “Electronic bill presentment and payment: A strategic advantage,”
IBM Corporation, available on the Internet at
www.ibm.com/services/files/emea_final.pdf.

15

Jeffrey, Andrew W., 2000, “Electronic bill payment
and presentment: Jump-starting the next great Webenabled consumer empowerment engine,” Robertson
Stephens eProcessing Research, April 11.
Kerr, K., 2000, “E-billers make strategic move to
thin consolidator model,” GartnerGroup Interactive,
May 1.
Kerr, Ken, and Avivah Litan, 2000, “Trends in
business-to-consumer electronic bill presentment and
payment,” GartnerGroup Interactive, August 25.
Kille, Steve, 2001, “Leveraging electronic statement
delivery,” MessagingDirect, available on the Internet
at www.messagingdirect.com/publications/IC-6112.pdf.
Litan, A., 2000, “E-bill consolidation is attractive,
but vendors must do more before consumers agree,”
GartnerGroup Interactive, November 13.
McPherson, Aaron, for International Data Corporation (IDC), 2001, “Electronic bill presentment and
payment—Checkered past, hopeful future,” presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, March 5.
National Automated Clearing House Association,
2000, “The 2000 accredited ACH professional handbook: An overview,” National Automated Clearing
House Association, Herndon, VA: NACHA.
Nilson, Spencer, 1997, The Nilson Report, No. 646.
PayAnyBill, 2000, “EBPP: Why, what, where—and
How it works,” white paper, No. 1, available on the
Internet at www.linkata.com/open/info/
whitepapers.jsp, May 26.
Power, Carol, 2000, “While others quail at ‘screen
scraping,’ FleetBoston will embrace it on new site,”
American Banker, February 1.
Radecki, J. Lawrence, and John Wenninger, 1999,
“Paying electronic bills electronically,” Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, Vol. 5, No. 1, January.

16

Rini, Nick, 2000, “Paperless billing: What’s the
payoff?,” Wireless Review, No. 18, September 15,
pp. 64–70.
Robertson, Elizabeth, 2000, “E-payments: The latest initiatives,” TowerGroup, report, September.
Robinson, Teri, 2000, “Bill presentment and payment—Time to e-pay the bills,” InternetWeek, available on the Internet at www.internetweek.com,
October 23.
Roth, Andrew, 2001, “CheckFree says it will use
screen scraping,” American Banker, March 22.
Spiotto, Ann, and Brian Mantel, 2000, “Electronic
bill presentment and payment,” Federal Reserve
Bank Chicago, report, June.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the
Census, 2000, “Falling through the Net: Toward digital inclusion,” Economic and Statistics Administration and the National Telecommunications and
Information Administration, available on the Internet
at www.ntia.doc.gov/ntiahome/digitaldivide/
index.html, October.
Wells, Kirstin E., 1996, “Are checks overused?,”
Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Vol. 20, No. 4, pp. 2–12.
West, Tim, 2001, “A standard will speed business:
Which standard will lead the way?,” e.bill Magazine,
April.
Whaling, Jonathan, 2000a, “Travel the road from
paper-based to electronic bill presentment and payment: Drivers and inhibitors,” TowerGroup, available
on the Internet at www.towergroup.com/, January.
, 2000b, “U.S. consumer bill payment
market analysis: When will we say goodbye to 15
billion checks?,” TowerGroup, January.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Liquidity effects in the bond market
Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau

Introduction and summary
Is money neutral? Most economists would now say
that it is not, at least not in the short run. This belief
derives partly from the results of studies done decades
ago. In their book on monetary history, Friedman and
Schwartz (1963) argued that the Federal Reserve may
have caused or prolonged the Great Depression by a
policy of tight money. And in another study, Phillips
(1958) found a negative relation between wage inflation and unemployment. In the two decades that followed, other studies confirmed the view that money
growth raises output in the short run.
Since the 1970s, however, the Phillips-curve relation seems to have broken down, and money seems
to have no clear effect on real interest rates either. Only
if we assume that some part of money responds to real
variables can we conclude that the exogenous part of
money does move interest rates. Evans and Marshall
(1998), for example, describe several scenarios—identifying assumptions—under which some part of the
money supply can plausibly be said to move real interest rates. In other words, what we infer about a liquidity effect on interest rates depends on what we believe
the Fed reacts to when it sets the money supply.
But, if we wish to estimate the liquidity effect on
interest rates, or even if we wish to study the interest
rate channel of monetary policy, is money the right
measure of policy? The rate of interest is the return on
bonds, which depends most directly not on the supply
of money but on the supply of bonds. Using bonds,
one can find a liquidity effect without introducing a
host of other variables.
Whether we measure money by nonborrowed reserves or more broadly, injections of money are not
the same as withdrawals of, say, Treasury bills (T-bills).
This is because the Fed sometimes injects money by
buying long-term bonds, and this will affect short-term
rates less than would a purchase of T-bills. Indeed,
table 1 shows that, since 1961, the correlation between

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

the real per capita supply of outstanding Treasury
securities (T-secs) and nonborrowed reserves (NBR),
which one might expect to be negative, has been
slightly positive at .048.1 The table also shows that,
at least since 1980, growth in nonborrowed reserves
has reduced short-term rates, but not as strongly as
a contraction of T-secs. Over the whole period, however, growth in both nonborrowed reserves and T-secs
is positively correlated with short-term rates—which,
for nonborrowed reserves, is the wrong sign.
These conclusions do not change if we look instead
at surprises, as implied in models like Lucas (1990)
and Christiano and Eichenbaum (1995). Table 2 presents the correlations of interest rates with surprises
in the growth of NBR and T-secs.2 For the 1980–99
period, surprises to nonborrowed reserves come in
with the wrong sign, whereas T-sec surprises have the
positive correlation that a liquidity effect implies. Both
correlations have the wrong sign for the 1961–99 period, but the correlation between surprises to growth in
the bond supply and real rates is tiny.
Tables 1 and 2 suggest that, at least in recent decades, bonds have been the better measure of policy.
The remainder of our analysis uses this measure more
systematically to estimate the degree of risk that unpredictability in their supply imposes on the investor.
A nominal bond carries two kinds of risk. First, its
Boyan Jovanovic is a professor of economics at the University
of Chicago and New York University, a research associate
of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER),
and a consultant to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Peter L. Rousseau is an assistant professor of economics
at Vanderbilt University and a faculty research fellow
of the NBER. The authors thank the National Science
Foundation (NSF) for financial help, Fernando Alvarez
and Robert Lucas for useful comments, and Timothy Daniels
for assistance in obtaining data. Special thanks go to
David Marshall and Helen Koshy for many detailed
comments on earlier drafts.

17

TABLE 1

Correlations among monthly growth rates
Variable

1961–99

1980–99

1-month real return on T-bills
and previous month’s real
growth in NBR

.046

–.063

1-month real return on T-bills
and previous month’s real
growth in T-secs

.137

.107

Real monthly growth in NBR
and T-secs

.048

–.007

Notes: NBR = real per capita value of nonborrowed reserves;
and T-secs = real per capita value of outstanding Treasury
securities.
Sources: See note 1 on p. 33.

real return erodes with inflation, which may be uncertain. Second, unexpected changes in the supply of
bonds may cause the value of a bond to change. If a
large bond issue causes bond prices to fall, then the
return on existing bonds is reduced and the cost of
purchase is lowered for investors who are about to
buy bonds. The bond issue therefore transfers wealth
from existing bondholders to future bondholders. If
such issues are not foreseen, they give rise to what
we call bond-supply risk.
Supply risk can lead to an uncertain price, or
(when prices do not clear markets) an uncertain availability. The Fed creates both kinds of risk in the primary market, where it acts as the Treasury’s agent in
the regular Dutch (that is, single-price) auctions of
bonds. The Fed’s current actions affect not only the
current auction-price results, but also the number of
bonds that will become available in later auctions. The
Fed probably also contributes to price variability in
the secondary bond markets, where it conducts open
market operations. In this article, we find that bondsupply risk remains as important as ever, even though
Fed policy has rendered the price level more and more
predictable.
The lessons from the data that we highlight are
the following:
1. Surprise sales of T-bills raise real rates: Unanticipated (month-to-month) positive shocks in the
supply of T-bills or total Treasury securities available to the public have always had a large positive
effect on the ex post real returns earned by these
instruments.
2. Interest rates and stock returns: Popular wisdom
holds that cuts in the federal funds rate raise
stock prices. This seems to derive from the view

18

that bonds and stocks are close substitutes so that
when the Fed, say, cuts interest rates, stock prices
will rise in order to allow price–earnings ratios to
rise and, therefore, stock returns to fall. Yet the opposite seems to be true. Overall, if anything, T-bill
rates are negatively correlated with stock returns.
3. The decline of Treasury finance: The supply of
T-bills has decreased steadily over time, but this
has been neutral in its effect on asset prices, including bond prices.
4. Lessons for policy: Supply risk stems from unpredictability in the growth rate of T-secs in the hands
of the public—that is, by the unpredictability of
changes in this supply relative to the amount outstanding. But the amount of T-secs has been declining relative to the unpredictable rollover demands
for them at auction by foreign monetary authorities and financial institutions. If the inclusion of a
broader range of short-term securities in the Fed’s
portfolio were to reduce unpredictability in the
growth rate of T-secs, supply risk would decline.
This is because the risk would be spread across a
wider range of assets, many with deep markets, so
that an unexpected change in the Fed’s overall securities holdings would impact any one of these markets minimally relative to the amount outstanding.
In the next section, we provide more detail on how
T-bills are sold and how open market operations work.
Then, we assess the effects that bond-supply risk has
had over the past 80 years on the ex post real returns
obtained by purchasing a new three-month T-bill and
holding it until maturity and compare them to the effects of bond-supply risk on real stock returns. We then
consider the role of supply risk under an investment
strategy of purchasing a seasoned three-month T-bill
TABLE 2

Correlations among growth-rate surprises
Variable

1961–99

1980–99

Unexpected components of:
1-month real return on T-bills
and previous month’s real
growth in NBR

.056

.138

1-month real return on T-bills
and previous month’s real
growth in T-secs

–.008

.142

Real monthly growth in NBR
and T-secs

–.060

–.118

Sources: See note 1 on p. 33.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

with two months until maturity and selling it one
month later. Next, we document the recent decline of
Treasury finance in the context of the Fed’s history
and show that supply risk is unrelated to this decline.
What causes bond-supply risk?
Bond-supply risk arises when agents commit funds
to the bond market before they know the price at which
they will buy the bonds or the price at which they will
be able to sell them afterwards. Such risk arises because asset markets are incomplete and, in the sense
of Grossman and Weiss (1983), segmented. Some
agents and some fraction of their resources are ready
to trade in the bond market and this exposes them to
the risk that comes from randomness in the supply of
bonds. Buyers are in luck when a bond-supply shock
is positive because bond prices are then lower than
expected and the rate of return is higher than expected. These agents get a good deal, and any real consequences are distributional because the shock has
favored some agents at the expense of others.
To take part in the bond market, institutions must
commit liquid assets to the new-issue and secondary
markets. Primary dealers, who make competitive bids
in the course of their direct interactions with the New
York Fed in the conduct of Treasury auctions, pay for
their winning bids when the new bonds are issued on
the Thursday following the Monday auctions. Certain
depository institutions and other broker/dealers may
also pay for their winning bids on the date of issue.
Other competitive bidders pay at the time of submission and are either refunded excess balances or called
upon to remit additional funds based upon the final
auction price and security allocations. A majority of
secondary dealers, however, acquire new issues from
primary dealers, and presumably pay for them upon
delivery, though the bonds trade actively prior to their
issue in a “when-issued” market. Noncompetitive tenders, or offers to purchase bonds at the final auction
price, whatever that may be, are paid upfront on the
auction day.3 Noncompetitive bids at T-bill auctions
are currently limited to $1 million per account, and they
have accounted for only 10.4 percent of total auction
sales since July 1998.4 Thus, even though many bidders can delay payment until issue, they must be ready
to purchase their entire bid if won, and, in the event
of an unsuccessful bid, must act quickly to reinvest
liquid assets that had been set aside. A closer look at
how these markets work shows how the winning bids
can become quite uncertain.
By “supply risk,” in some cases, we mean “residual supply risk.” A large chunk of the demand for
T-bills comes from the decisions of foreign financial

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

institutions and international monetary authorities
(FIMA) regarding whether to roll over their substantial and various holdings of bonds, and these rollover
decisions affect the residual supply that will be available to the remaining traders because they count against
the issue quantity stated in the auction announcement.
Further, when FIMA make rollovers, they do so at the
single auction price as noncompetitive bidders.5 Many
individuals also bid noncompetitively, but, as mentioned above, the quantities of such bids are restricted and thus more predictable. All of this means that
supply risk can arise at the auction stage, even though
the Treasury announces the face value of the T-bills
that it intends to issue. Since the public knows only the
maturing quantity and not the rollover plans, the randomness in these plans, from the perspective of the
dealer, makes the final auction price less predictable.
The Fed itself must also decide whether to roll over
portions of its own portfolio of maturing bonds at the
final noncompetitive price. The securities that the Fed
rolls over do not count against the total offered to the
public in that week’s auction and, thus, have at best a
minimal impact on the final auction price, but they will
affect the size of subsequent auctions. For example,
if the Fed rolls over only half of the bills that it could
have in a given auction, to maintain a constant debt
level the Treasury would need to arrange a larger issue for the next week. It seems, however, that the Fed’s
rollovers, at least in recent years, have been quite predictable—the Fed rolls over its entire holdings unless
that would exceed its self-imposed limit on individual
securities holdings, in which case it redeems enough
to meet that limit.
The Treasury has changed its usual procedures
twice recently with regard to foreign rollovers, and
the nature of these changes suggests that it may be
trying to reduce supply risk. In early 1999, auction
announcements still specified that the Treasury could,
at its discretion, issue additional securities for foreign
accounts whenever the total of new bids from these
sources exceeded their total holdings of maturing bills.
Beginning with the T-bill auctions of March 29, 1999,
however, the Treasury usually placed an explicit limit of $3 billion on the amount of foreign rollovers that
would be counted against the public’s total, agreeing
to make additional issues automatically if rollover bids
were to exceed this amount. This practice became more
common as 1999 progressed. The change signaled a
more accommodative stance by the Treasury that would
have reduced residual supply risk by limiting the degree to which unexpected noncompetitive rollover
decisions could affect the final auction price. As of
February 1, 2001, however, the Treasury has allowed

19

only $1 billion in total foreign noncompetitive tenders,
and that limit cannot be exceeded.6 Foreign institutions seeking to purchase large amounts of T-secs at
auctions must now bid competitively. Even though
this change might ameliorate disturbances that would
impede the systematic paying down of the federal
debt, it is also likely to raise residual supply risk.
Cammack (1991, p. 110) reports that the Fed
and FIMA combined to buy 43 percent of all T-bills
that were sold at auction between 1973 and 1984. By
examining the press releases of auction results, we have
found that this portion has risen to 44.8 percent since
mid-1998. The risk associated with rollover decisions
exceeds both the spread in the distribution of bids
and the time-series variation of the winning bids,
because the losing bidders (of which there are more
either immediately or in future auctions when the Fed
absorbs its limit) must end up holding cash or a lowerreturn substitute.
Bond-supply risk and interest rates
How much do bond supplies vary from month to
month? Figure 1 shows the standard deviation of the
monthly per capita real growth of the monetary base,
T-bills and T-notes, and all marketable T-secs, including bills, notes, bonds, and certificates of indebtedness
since 1920.7 The Treasury quantities reflect securities
that are outstanding and in the hands of the public
(that is, excluding the Fed’s holdings).8
The striking feature of figure 1 is the high monthto-month variability of total T-secs in the hands of the
public. This variability was particularly high in the
early 1940s due to large issues of securities of all maturities to finance the Second World War. We also observe large rolling standard deviations for the T-bills
and T-notes subset in the midst of the Depression and
again from 1942 to 1947. Interestingly, variability in
the supply of T-secs is much larger than that of the
monetary base itself, which suggests that a considerable portion of what we call supply risk may have
served to stabilize money growth.
How strongly do bond-supply surprises affect the
real rate of interest? We use the effects of inflation surprises as a standard of comparison and compare the two
kinds of risk, first for the entire 1920–99 period and
then for three subperiods. Here is how we proceed:
The nominal return at date t on a one-period zerocoupon bond maturing at date t + 1 is

¥1
´
Rt, t 1  ¦  1µ ,
§ Pt
¶

20

FIGURE 1

Standard deviation of monthly growth
of T-secs and monetary base
percent
12

T-bills and T-notes

9

Marketable T-secs

6
3
0

Monetary base
-3
1920

’30

’40

’50

’60

’70

’80

’90

’00

Note: Figure displays rolling standard deviations of monthly
growth rates of real per capita supplies of T-secs and the
monetary base, 1920–99.

where Pt is the price of the bond at date t. The ex post
real return on this bond is

¥1¨ 1 · ´
©
¸  1µ ,
§ Pt ª©1  Q t, t 1 ¹¸ ¶

rt, t 1  ¦

where Q t, t 1 is the rate of inflation of goods prices
between dates t and t + 1. Rearranging and taking logs,
ln(1  rt, t 1 )   ln Pt  ln(1  Q t, t 1 ),

for any small number F
ln 	1  F 
 z F Using this, we
approximate the above equation by
rt, t 1 z it, t 1  Q t, t 1 ,

where it, t 1 y 1/ Pt  1.
Let the superscript e denote an expected value
given information from the previous period, which
we shall denote It–1, so that, for instance,
rt,et 1  E \rt, t 1 I t 1 ^ . 9

Let the superscript u denote the surprise component of a random variable so that, for instance,
rt, t 1  rt,et 1  rt,ut 1 and so on. Then to a first
approximation,

1)

rt,ut 1  itu, t 1  Qut, t 1 .

The first term is the bond-supply risk and the second
is inflation risk.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Now assume a liquidity effect of bond-supply
surprises on the price of bonds as in, say, Lucas
(1990). That is, assume that

2) itu, t 1  Bgtu1, t ,
where, once again, gtu1, t is the surprise growth in
the number of bonds at t given It–1. Substituting into
equation 1 leads to

3)

rt,ut 1  Bgtu1, t  Q ut, t 1 .

The notation may suggest that the surprises in the
above three variables are formed at different dates and
are based on different information sets, but this is not
the case. The dependent variable and the regressors
all derive from the information set It–1 that we describe
in note 9 on page 33. To reiterate, at the start of date
t, agents know the realization of pt–1,t. But the presence of bond-supply risk means that the agents do not
know the date t supply of bonds when they form their
expectations of Pt and, hence, of it,t+1. This means that
they cannot yet know gt–1,t, since its realization comes
too late to be included in the date t information set.
Therefore, in spite of the dating differences in the
subscripts, rˆt,ut 1 , gˆ tu1, t , and Qˆ ut, t 1 , are surprises based
on the same information set, It–1.
We estimate equation 3 with the regression

4) rˆt,ut 1  a0  a1 gˆ tu1, t  a2 Qˆ ut, t 1 ,
where rˆt,ut 1 , gˆ tu1, t , and Qˆ ut, t 1 are surprises of the three
variables. In practice, we obtain these surprises using
de-seasonalized monthly observations as the one-step
ahead forecast errors from a set of vector autoregressions (VARs) with a rolling estimation window. To
be more precise, the variables in the forecasting
equations are:
1. g, the growth rate of real per capita T-secs in the
hands of the public,
2. r, the ex post real return on T-bills,10
3. p, the rate of growth of the consumer price index,11 and
4. the ex post real return on the S&P 500.12
Thus, all four variables in the system are dimensionless. We then pool the forecasts and errors from the
VARs over the sample period and use them to estimate
equation 4.
The monthly data represent the highest frequency that is available continuously for the past 80 years
of Fed history. The T-bill return is the monthly average of daily rates for the current (that is, “on the run”)

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

three-month T-bill, from which we subtract realized
inflation over the next three months. The returns that
we consider first, and the only ones that can be constructed going back to 1920, correspond to an investment strategy of buying the current three-month T-bill
and holding it until maturity. Later we consider onemonth holding period returns on seasoned T-bills since
1961. Box 1 describes in detail the methods we used
to prepare the data for analysis and to compute the
surprises.
Supply risk 1920–99
Using monthly data from January 1920 through
December 1999 and forecasting equations with a
36-month rolling window and three lags, figure 2
shows the effects of one-standard-deviation surprises
to both the price level and the supply of marketable
T-secs available to the public on the annualized ex
post real return on T-bills.13 Pooling the surprises
across periods, we obtain the following estimates
for equation 4 (with t-statistics in parentheses):

5)

rˆt,ut 1  .0001  .0274 gˆ tu1, t  1.082 Qˆ ut, t 1  et .
(0.60)

(7.45)

( 17.31)

The superscript u in equation 5 denotes a variable’s
deviation from its one-step-ahead forecast from the
rolling VAR.
As limited participation models would suggest,
gˆ tu1, t raises ex post real T-bill returns because a release
of T-bills lowers T-bill prices. This in turn contributes
to better-than-expected returns for those who have
committed funds to the T-bill market. Unanticipated
inflation enters with, essentially, a unit coefficient,
which suggests that Qˆ ut, t 1 is indeed a true surprise.
To obtain the series plotted in figure 2, we
multiply the coefficients gˆ tu1, t and Qˆ ut, t 1 by the
centered values of their rolling 12-month standard
deviations and compound the result over 12 months
to annualize. This measures the effects of the surprises on annualized real T-bill returns.14 The figure indicates that both sources of risk have always mattered,
with inflation risk at times quite large, especially at
the height of the Great Depression in 1933 and in the
year immediately following the end of the Second
World War. The relative importance of inflation risk
has declined dramatically over the past two decades,
however, as the price level has stabilized.
The effect of supply risk in three subperiods
The method used to construct figure 2 assumes
that the seasonal adjustment coefficients applied to
the raw data and the responses of the T-bill rate to
unexpected inflation and T-sec growth are stable
across the 1920–99 period. One way to examine the

21

BOX 1

Estimating the impact of price and T-sec supply risk on real T-bill returns
The methodology underlying figures 2–9 begins with
adjusting the raw data to make the timing of monthly
observations consistent across variables. Since the
nominal quantity of T-secs in the hands of the public
(Xt) is available at the end of each month, while the
consumer price index (CPIt) and population (popt)
are computed as annualized monthly averages, we
derive the real quantity of Treasury securities at the
end of month t as:

xt  4 s

Xt
,
	CPI t 1  CPI t 
 s ( popt 1  popt )

which amounts to averaging the consumption deflator and population across periods to center them
with Xt.
To approximate the ex post real return on T-bills
(rt,t+1) associated with the buy-and-hold strategy discussed in this article, we start with the annualized
yields to maturity on three-month (91-day) T-bills that
are computed by the Fed as averages of daily yields
over the course of a calendar month (Rt) and subtract
the annualized inflation rate implied by the change
in the CPI over the next three months. Since the CPI
is a monthly average and Rt is annualized, we have

Before using the series derived above (as well as
CPI inflation itself), we de-seasonalize by regressing
each on monthly dummy variables and an adequately
high-order polynomial in time. We include the time
polynomial to reduce the degree to which the estimates
of the monthly effects reflect cyclical and trend components. After subtracting the coefficients on the
monthly dummy variables from the raw series, we
add the mean of the detrended series back in to complete the seasonal adjustment. See Johnston (1984,
pp. 23–49) for a clear exposition of this method
along with its advantages and drawbacks.
The VAR equations used to compute the surprises to growth in the supply of T-secs (g) and inflation
(p) have the form

gt 

¤ c g  ¤ d Q ¤ f
¤ h s  t  e
k

k

i 1

1, k

t k

k

i 1

1, k

t k

i 1

r

1, k t  k

k

i 1

Qt 

1, k t  k

1, t

¤ c g ¤ d Q ¤ f
¤ h s  t  e ,
k

k

i 1

2, k

t k

k

i 1

2, k

tk

i 1

r

2, k t  k

k

1
12

¨ ¥
¨¥ CPI  CPI ´ 4 ·´ ·
t 3
t
¸
rt, t 1 z ©1 ¦ Rt  ©¦1 
µ¶  1¸¸µµ ¸  1.
© ¦§
CPI t
§
©
¶
ª
¹
ª
¹
This is the monthly real return that an investor would
receive by buying a three-month T-bill and holding it
until maturity, assuming that the inflation rate is
steady across the three months.
The nominal return on the S&P 500 (St) covers
an actual calendar month, so we derive an ex post
return by subtracting the growth rate of the consumer
price index (CPIt),

¨¥ CPI t 1  CPI t ´ ·
 1¸ ,
st  St  ©¦
§ CPI  CPI µ¶
ª

t

t 1

¹

which amounts to computing inflation as the growth
in the CPI after averaging across periods.

robustness of our results to these assumptions is to
repeat the analysis over subperiods. We do this for
1920–46, 1947–79, and 1980–99, and display the results in figures 3–5. We split the postwar period into
pre-1980 and post-1979 segments because of the shift
in Fed targeting policy that occurred in 1979. To
accommodate the shorter sample periods, we limit

22

i 1

2, k t  k

2, t

where k is the lag length and t is a linear time trend.
The time subscripts refer to the information sets It–k
from which the variables derive. To allow the forecasts to reflect recent economic conditions, we allow
the VAR samples to roll with time, choosing estimation windows of 36 months (figure 2) or 30 months
(figures 3–9). This implies that each successive onestep ahead forecast and forecast error is computed
with an information set that overlaps the previous
one in all but the latest and earliest periods. Using
the coefficients from the time t regression, we compute the forecasts for time t + 1 as fitted values obtained with the information set from time t.
In estimating equation 4, we pool the monthly
surprises across the sample period to obtain a single
set of regression coefficients.

the underlying VAR models to two lags and shorten
the length of the estimation periods to 30 months.
Table 3 includes regression results for equation 5.
Figure 3 reaffirms the importance of inflation
risk in the pre-1947 period, including the 1933 and
1946 episodes. The effects of supply risk on T-bill
returns rise at these same times and average 0.36

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 2

Effect of surprises in T-sec supply
on T-bill returns, 1920–99
percentage points
18

46.2% in 1946

15
12
9

Inflation risk

6
3
0

Supply risk

-3
1920

’30

’40

’50

’60

’70

’80

’90

’00

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the supply
of T-secs on annualized real T-bill returns.

percent over the 1920–46 period, but are always less
important than the effects of inflation risk, which average 5.31 percent. In figure 4, the narrower scaling reflects the overall decline in inflation risk that occurred
from 1947 to 1979, during which it averaged only 1.35
percent. Even though supply risk also fell to 0.12 percent over this same period, the decline is considerably
less in percentage terms than that of inflation risk.
Figure 5, on the other hand, shows that supply risk
has if anything become more important over the past
20 years, averaging to 0.14 percent, while inflation
risk has continued to decline, averaging 0.99 percent.

By 1980, the Treasury had completed a long-term
shift in financing away from T-bonds and into shorterterm T-bills and T-notes (see figure 15 on page 30).
It is therefore possible that fluctuations in the quantity of T-bills and T-notes are more precise measures of
supply risk for the post-1980 period than the total of
outstanding marketable T-secs. To see if this preference shift has influenced our results, we compute
supply shocks to T-bills and T-notes only after 1980,
and in figure 6 once again display their effects on real
T-bill returns. The results are similar to those observed
for all T-secs, with average real effects of 0.16 percent and 1.0 percent, respectively. Once again, supply risk grows in relative importance over time.
That bond-supply risk, which arises from committing funds to the T-bill market before supply is revealed,
should even approach inflation risk in importance is
quite striking. After all, if inflation surprises are measured over the entire term of the T-bill, they should
affect ex post yields virtually point for point.15
To generate bond-supply risk, however, it is necessary for open market operations or variations in auction quantities to have large effects on interest rates,
and this in turn suggests some degree of market segmentation. Otherwise, in the absence of segmentation,
investors could offset T-sec supply shocks with transactions in the markets for substitute assets.
Bond-supply risk and real stock returns
Theory leads us to expect a positive relation between stock returns and real bond returns. If stocks
and bonds were perfect substitutes and if they traded

TABLE 3

Interest rate regressions for buy-and-hold strategy
g

= Marketable T-secs

g = T-bills
and notes
1980–99

1920–99

1920–46

1947–79

1980–99

Constant

.0001
(0.60)

.0002
(1.04)

.0000
(0.01)

–.0000
(–0.24)

–.0000
(–0.29)

gˆtu 1,t

.0274
(7.45)

.0140
(1.97)

.0069
(1.42)

.0100
(2.37)

.0104
(2.66)

Qˆ ut,t  1

–1.082
(–17.31)

–.9963
(–9.43)

–.3837
(–6.04)

–.3446
(–6.54)

–.3537
(–6.79)

.361
(1.98)

.255
(1.19)

.092
(1.70)

.206
(1.81)

.216
(1.77)

919

290

370

205

205

R2/(DW)

N

u
t ,t 1

Notes: The dependent variable is the unanticipated real return on a three-month T-bill, rˆ . The table presents coefficient
estimates for equation 5 over the subperiods included in figures 2–6, with T-statistics in parentheses. The R2 and Durbin-Watson
(DW) statistics and number of observations (N) for each regression appear in the final two rows.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

23

in the same market, their real rates of return would
always be equal. In such a world, an open market
operation of the Fed or, indeed, any other event that
changed the return on bonds would change the return
on stocks by the same amount. For example, a cut in
the federal funds rate would cause bond prices and
stock prices both to rise and the holding rate of return
on each asset to fall. The presence of inflation risk
on bonds and dividend risk on stocks would, perhaps,
weaken the contemporaneous correlation between
the ex post real returns on the two assets, but would
not eliminate it entirely.
One implication of this logic is that if the Fed’s
actions can affect the stock market, we should expect
to find a positive correlation between bond returns

and stock returns. Surprisingly, we find no evidence
of a positive correlation between the two ex post returns. We proceed as we did with T-bill returns, but
now the dependent variable in equation 5 is the unanticipated component of the real return on the S&P
500, sˆu:

6) sˆtu, t 1  a0  a1 gˆ tu1, t  a2 Qˆ ut, t 1  et .
Table 4 presents our findings using surprises
from the same VAR models that we used to examine
T-bill returns. Interestingly, T-sec surprises never affect real stock returns. Inflation surprises, on the other
hand, enter with the expected negative and significant
coefficients in the 1947–79 and 1980–99 subperiods,

FIGURE 3

FIGURE 5

Effect of surprises in T-sec supply
on T-bill returns, 1920–46

Effect of surprises in price level and
T-sec supply on T-bill returns, 1980–99

percentage points

percentage points

18

2.0

15

1.6

12

Inflation risk

1.2

9

0.8

Inflation risk

6

0.4

3

0.0

0

T-sec supply risk

T-sec supply risk

-3
1923

’27

’31

’35

’39

’43

’47

-0.4
1982

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the
supply of T-secs on annualized real T-bill returns.

’85

’88

’91

’97

FIGURE 4

FIGURE 6

Effect of surprises in T-sec supply
on T-bill returns, 1947–79

Effect of surprises in supply of T-bills
and T-notes on T-bill returns, 1980–99

percentage points

percentage points

5

2.4

4

’00

1.8

3

Inflation risk

1.2
2

Inflation risk
0.6

1

0.0

0

T-bill and T-note supply risk

T-sec supply risk
-1
1950

’55

’60

’65

’70

’75

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the
supply of T-secs on annualized real T-bill returns.

24

’94

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in the price level and T-sec
supply on annualized real T-bill returns.

’80

-0.6
1982

’85

’88

’91

’94

’97

’00

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the
supply of T-bills and T-notes on annualized real T-bill returns.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

but with a positive and significant coefficient for
1920–46. The latter result may be driven by a few
extraordinary events, such as the sharp deflation and
decline of equity values associated with the Great
Depression and the inflation and rising market values
of the immediate postwar period. In all, the evidence
suggests that the stock market has been relatively unaffected by Fed policy.
In table 5, we report contemporaneous correlations among the variables in our VARs (that is, the
variables themselves and not their surprises) and for
the monetary base over the 1920–99 period and the
three subperiods.16 Once again, links between stock
returns and growth in bond supplies are weak and inconsistent across subperiods. For example, correlations between real growth in the T-sec supply and
stock returns never exceed 0.05 and have the expected
negative sign only for 1980–99. T-bill returns vary
inversely with stock returns in all but the 1947–79
period, but in all cases the correlations are small. As
it turns out, the most consistent correlations are positive ones between growth in T-sec quantities on the
one hand and real T-bill returns on the other. This is
true for the full 1920–99 sample period and for all of
the subperiods. It is also as we might expect, since
more T-secs in the hands of the public require higher
interest rates to induce investors to hold them.
Since a rise in T-bills and T-notes in the hands of
the public usually implies bond sales and, hence, a
monetary tightening, it is surprising that growth in the
real monetary base—a monetary loosening—seems
to go hand in hand with bond sales (and the higher

interest rates that they imply) in all but the 1980–99
period. To explore this further, we compute the correlations using growth in real per capita nonborrowed
reserves, which is probably a closer indicator of policy
stance than growth in the monetary base, for 1959–
99—the period over which we have a series for nonborrowed reserves. We find in this case that a monetary
loosening, as measured by growth in nonborrowed
reserves, also has an unexpected positive correlation
with T-bill returns and T-sec growth, and that this result obtains for both the 1959–79 and 1980–99 subperiods.17 This may again reflect important differences
between indicators of policy stance that are based on
monetary aggregates and our bond supply measures.
An alternative measure of real T-bill returns
Until now, we have considered the effects of bondsupply risk on T-bill returns under a buy-and-hold
strategy. This, of course, is only one strategy that a
T-bill investor might follow, as it is easy for an investor to liquidate a T-bill, and in particular after a supply
or price shock has been realized. To analyze such a
holding strategy, we now estimate equation 5 using
surprises to the ex post real one-month holding period
return on a seasoned T-bill as the dependent variable.
The effects of supply risk should be different under this shorter-term strategy. This is because the investor now faces two sources of supply risk—one that
occurs just before the bond is purchased and another
that occurs over the holding period. A positive shock
after commitment but before purchase will lower the
bond price and raise the real return, yet a similar

TABLE 4

Stock return regressions
g

g = T-bills
and notes
1980–99

= Marketable T-secs

1920–99

1920–46

1947–79

1980–99

–.0014
(–0.55)

–.0033
(–0.50)

.0014
(0.57)

–.0002
(–0.06)

–.0008
(–0.19)

gˆtu 1,t

.1085
(1.20)

–.0851
(–0.42)

–.0558
(–0.36)

–.2390
(–0.76)

–.1476
(–0.503)

Qˆ ut,t  1

0.2446
(0.16)

5.753
(1.92)

–5.571
– (2.81)

–6.013
(–1.53)

–6.296
(–1.61)

.002
(1.76)

.014
(1.96)

.022
(1.84)

.013
(1.78)

.014
(1.77)

919

290

370

205

205

Constant

R2/(DW)

N

u

Notes: The dependent variable is the unanticipated real return on a one-month investment in the S&P 500 portfolio, sˆt ,t 1 .
The table presents coefficient estimates for equation 6, with T-statistics in parentheses. The R2 and Durbin-Watson (DW)
statistics and number of observations (N) for each regression appear in the final two rows.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

25

TABLE 5

Correlations of real asset returns and real per capita quantities
S&P 500

T-bills

T-bills
and notes

T-secs

1920–99
Real return on S&P 500
Real return on T-bills
Growth in real T-bills and notes
Growth in real T-secs
Growth in real monetary base

1.00
–0.034
0.046
0.006
0.067

1.00
0.071
0.110
0.235

1.00
0.669
0.040

1.00
0.142

1.00

1920–46
Real return on S&P 500
Real return on T-bills
Growth in real T-bills & notes
Growth in real T-secs
Growth in real monetary base

1.00
–0.075
–0.022
0.040
0.064

1.00
0.108
0.048
0.161

1.00
0.680
0.067

1.00
0.145

1.00

1947–79
Real return on S&P 500
Real return on T-bills
Growth in real T-bills & notes
Growth in real T-secs
Growth in real monetary base

1.00
0.028
0.040
0.003
0.011

1.00
0.096
0.185
0.470

1.00
0.575
0.017

1.00
0.112

1.00

1980–99
Real return on S&P 500
Real return on T-bills
Growth in real T-bills & notes
Growth in real T-secs
Growth in real monetary base

1.00
–0.032
–0.061
–0.050
0.102

1.00
0.188
0.208
0.064

1.00
0.962
–0.065

1.00
–0.003

shock over the holding period will lower the resale
value of the bond. Thus, it is deviations of resale
values from investor expectations that were formed
prior to purchase that impart risk to the strategy.
To derive the equivalent of equation 4 for multiperiod bonds, we again define the cost of such a bond
1

at date t as P units of real consumption. The bond’s
t
nominal return over the holding period is

it*, t 1 

Pt 1  Pt
,
Pt

where we introduce asterisks to reflect the change
from the buy-and-hold investment strategy discussed
earlier to the seasoned one-month holding strategy
considered here. The ex post real return is again
rt,*t 1  it*, t 1  Q*t, t 1 , and as in equation 1,
u*
t, t 1

r

i

u*
t, t 1

Q

.

Now we need to be quite precise about the dating of
information. Let t 1 z u y the surprise component of a
random variable z given It–1, and suppose that

26

u

¥ Pt 1 ´
 1  B 	 t 1 gtu*1, t 
  b* 	 t 1 gtu, *t 1 
 .
§ Pt µ¶

7) itu, *t 1  t 1 ¦

The right-hand side of equation 7 is based on the logic behind equation 2. The first term deals with the
denominator of the left-hand side; it is the one-stepahead surprise and is the same as in equation 2. The
second term deals with the numerator, Pt +1, and is a
two-step-ahead surprise to growth in the bond supply. We compute this term as a VAR forecast using
I t*1 . Isolating the return surprises on the left-hand
side, we have the holding-period analog of equation 3:
*u
t 1 t, t 1

r

z B 	 t 1 gtu*1, t 
  b* 	 t 1 gtu, *t 1 
  	 t 1 Qtu,*t 1 
 ,

or, roughly, the linear relation that we estimate:

8)
u*
t, t 1

Monetary
base

*u
t 1 t, t 1

rˆ

z a1* 	 t 1 gˆ tu*1,t 
  a2* 	 t 1 gˆ tu, *t 1 
  a3* 	 t 1 Qˆ ut,*t 1 
 .

The final term in equation 8 is inflation risk over
the holding period.
Under the buy-and-hold strategy that we considered earlier, we subtracted realized inflation over the
three-month term of the T-bill and, assuming monthly

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

compounding, converted to a monthly return. The result there reflected an average of inflation over the next
three months. Here we proceed slightly differently:
For the one-month holding strategy, we subtract the
one-month inflation rate that corresponds to the actual holding period.
Our analysis of one-month investments in seasoned three-month T-bills is limited to 1961 to 1999—
the period for which daily secondary market prices on
U.S. Treasury securities are available from the New
York Fed and the Wall Street Journal.18 Using the
composite “quote sheets,” we collected the annualized
yield-to-maturity on the final trading day of the month
for the T-bill with closest to 60 days until maturity
and then recorded its yield on the final trading day of
the next month. We then computed a synthetic annualized 30-day holding period yield as

¨ ¥ 60 ´ ·
©1  ¦§ R2 365 µ¶ ¸
¸  1,
R2,1  ©
© 1  ¥ R 60 ´ ¸
¦ 1
µ
ª© § 365 ¶ ¹¸
where R2 is the annualized yield-to-maturity on the
reference T-bill with approximately 60 days until
maturity, and R1 is the annualized yield on the same
T-bill a month later. Due to weekends, holidays, and
the monthly calendar, we do not always observe prices
30 days apart, so our computation assumes that R1
whenever observed also applies on the 30th and final
day of the holding period. This ignores changes in secondary market yields that might arise for a seasoned
T-bill over at most a two-day period, but does not generate any systematic bias. We convert to real terms
by subtracting Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation.
After again obtaining surprises to T-bill returns,
inflation, and growth of the T-sec supply from a series of 30-month rolling VARs with two lags and the
S&P 500 return as a control, we use the coefficient
estimates from equation 8 to compute the overall effects of supply risk over the course of a month (that
is, both pre-purchase and holding period risk) as the
square root of

product of a3* and the standard deviation of the
forecast errors for inflation. We obtained the series of
variance–covariance matrices from 12-month rolling
samples of the forecast errors. Figure 7 presents our
results for the 1961–79 period, which have been annualized by compounding over 12 months. We report
the corresponding estimates for equation 8 in table 6.
In figure 7, an inflation surprise of one standard
deviation lowers the holding period yield by 1.77 percent on average. Like the results in figures 2 and 5
for the buy-and-hold strategy, inflation risk rises to
nearly 4.5 percent in the mid-1970s after fluctuating
at about 1 percent to 2 percent throughout the 1960s.
Supply risk, though not significant in equation 8,
averages .10 percent, which is only slightly smaller
than that observed under the buy-and-hold strategy
for 1947–79.
Figure 8 and the two other columns of table 6
cover the 1980–99 period and offer a direct comparison with figures 5 and 6. Whether we use all T-secs
in the hands of the public (figure 8) or only T-bills
and T-notes (figure 9) in forming gˆ u *, the effects of
supply risk on one-month yields are similar to those
obtained under the three-month buy-and-hold strategy, averaging .16 percent and .21 percent in figures 8
and 9, respectively. The coefficients on the pre- and
post-purchase surprises to growth in the T-sec supply
variables also have the expected and opposite signs,
but are statistically significant only when T-bills and
T-notes are included in gˆ tu*1,t . This differs from the
results under the buy-and-hold strategy, where our
analysis of pre-purchase risk in isolation showed
significant effects of supply surprises for total T-secs
as well. Inflation risk is larger on average with the
FIGURE 7

Effect of surprises in T-sec supply
on one-month T-bill returns, 1961–79
percentage points
5
4
3

Inflation risk
2

2

Var 	 t 1 rˆt,*tu1 
  	 aˆ1* 
 Var 	 t 1 gˆ tu*1, t 

* 2
	 2


 aˆ

1

Var 	 t 1 gˆ tu,*t 1 


2aˆ aˆ Cov 	 t 1 gˆ
* *
1 2

u*
t 1, t t 1

,

0

gˆ

u*
t, t 1 


,

where the Var(·) terms are variances and Cov(·)
the covariance. The effects of inflation risk are the

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

T-sec supply risk

-1
1964

’66

’68

’70

’72

’74

’76

’78

’80

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the
supply of T-secs on annualized real one-month returns on T-bills.

27

TABLE 6

9)

Interest rate regressions for the
one-month holding strategy

u*
t 1 t, t 1

sˆ

z a1* 	 t 1 gˆ tu*1,t 
  a2* 	 t 1 gˆ tu, *t 1 

 a3* 	 t 1 Qˆ ut,*t 1 
 .

g = T-bills
and notes
1980–99

The results, which we report in table
7, indicate that surprises to gˆ do not generate substantive supply risk for investors
Constant
.0000
.0001
.0001
who are about to buy the S&P portfolio,
(0.17)
(1.12)
(1.03)
but that positive shocks after purchase raise
u*
ˆ
.0046
.0061
.0075
t  1 g t  1,t
one-month stock returns for the 1980–99
(1.02)
(1.28)
(1.77)
period. This runs counter to the standard
ˆu*
–.0041
–.0064
–.0076
t  1 g t ,t  1
view that stocks lose when the Fed tight(–0.83)
(–1.36)
(–1.76)
ens and gain when the Fed cuts rates.
ˆ ut ,*t  1
The lack of significance on the coef–.9644
–.9370
–.9501
t 1 Q
(–27.10)
(–20.54)
(–21.32)
ficient for the pre-purchase surprise could
simply suggest that the Fed cannot direct.796
.683
.704
R2/(DW)
ly and consistently affect the stock market.
(2.09)
(1.50)
(1.50)
The positive and significant coefficient on
N
196
205
205
the holding period supply shock, on the
Notes: The dependent variable is the unanticipated real return on a T-bill  rˆ  .
other hand, is consistent with a policy of
The table presents coefficient estimates for equation 8, with T-statistics in
passive responses by the Fed to changing
parentheses. The R and Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics and number of
observations (N) for each regression appear in the final two rows.
conditions in other asset markets. For example, when the stock market is surging, the
Fed may try to slow it down a bit by injecting bonds and raising interest rates. Since any relationone-month holding strategy than with the buy-andship between Fed policy and the stock market is probably
hold. The closeness of the coefficients on the inflation
loose, however, the bond sale often seems to have litsurprises to unity is also good news for our specificatle effect, and the market continues to push ahead.
tion, as inflation should affect the real return point
for point when the time periods for the inflation and
The effects of foreseen policy changes:
return observations coincide.
The secular decline of Treasury finance
Next, we again place the unanticipated compou*
The relative importance of T-bills and other marnent of the real S&P 500 return (s ) on the left-hand
ketable T-secs in the aggregate portfolio has declined
side of equation 8 to obtain
g = Marketable T-secs

1961–99

1980–99

u*
t 1 t ,t 1

2

FIGURE 8

FIGURE 9

Effect of surprises in T-sec supply
on one-month T-bill returns, 1980–99

Effect of surprises in supply of T-bills and
T-notes on one-month T-bill returns, 1980–99

percentage points

percentage points

2.4

2.4

1.8

1.8

Inflation risk

Inflation risk
1.2

1.2

0.6

0.6

0.0

0.0

T-sec supply risk

-0.6
1982

’85

’88

’91

’94

’97

’00

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the
supply of T-secs on annualized real one-month returns on T-bills.

28

T-bill and T-note supply risk

-0.6
1982

’85

’88

’91

’94

’97

’00

Note: Figure illustrates effects, in percentage points, of one
standard deviation surprises in inflation and growth in the supply
of T-bills and T-notes on annualized real one-month returns on T-bills.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

have become larger relative to the quantity
of outstanding T-secs. Figures 10 and 11
Stock return regressions for the
suggest that such a trend may be emerging.
one-month holding strategy
Figure 10 shows that the amount of T-secs
g = T-bills
in the hands of the public has fallen since
g = Marketable T-secs
and notes
the mid-1990s. Figure 11, on the other
1961–99
1980–99
1980–99
hand, indicates that the standard deviation
Constant
–.0070
.0042
.0040
of the growth rate surprises (the cause of
(–1.89)
(1.12)
(1.07)
supply risk) has increased a little.19 In this
u*
ˆ
section, we document long-run trends in
.1020
.3533
.3089
t  1 g t  1,t
(0.37)
(1.17)
(1.12)
Treasury financing over the Fed’s history
u*
and argue that their effects on supply risk
ˆ
.2447
.5797
.5693
t  1 g t ,t  1
up until now have probably been small.
(0.81)
(1.93)
(2.03)
The size of the bond market can be
ˆ ut ,*t  1
–4.153
.6752
.1401
t 1 Q
measured
by the share of these securities
(–1.913)
(0.24)
(0.05)
in the aggregate portfolio. This share will
.023
.019
.020
R2/(DW)
decline if, because of a policy change, the
(1.93)
(1.71)
(1.73)
quantity of Treasury securities made available to the public begins to shrink. The
N
196
205
205
share will also decline as more individuals
Notes: The dependent variable is the unanticipated real return on the
ˆ
gain access to instruments other than bank
s
.
S&P 500, 
The table presents coefficient estimates for equation 9,

with T-statistics in parentheses. The R and Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics and
deposits for lodging their surplus balances.
number of observations (N) for each regression appear in the final two rows.
Figures 12 and 13, which include the ratios
of federal debt, commercial and corporate
debt, and corporate equities to gross doover the postwar period. This should not matter for
mestic product and the aggregate portfolio, respecreal interest rates if it is only surprises to the growth
tively, indeed show substantial declines in the share
of bond supplies that matter. Indeed, most rational
of marketable federal debt from its postwar high in
expectations models with money and no nominal ri1945. The growing importance of financial assets in
gidities specify no real effects for expected changes
the U.S. economy and the rapidly rising share of eqin the money or bond supplies. One such change is
uity in total finance are also apparent. Figure 14 prothe gradual decline in outstanding T-secs, since this
vides additional detail on the rising share of equity in
is probably well understood by agents in the bond
total business finance, with both the corporate bond and
and money markets. But this change may not be neubank lending components of business debt falling to
tral, or at least may begin to matter soon if the trend
continues. This is because fluctuations in bond supFIGURE 11
plies stemming from rollover risk and other sources
TABLE 7

t 1

u*
t ,t 1

2

Standard deviation of surprises to monthly
growth of T-secs and monetary base

FIGURE 10

T-secs in hands of public and
monetary base, 1960–99

percent
5

trillions of 1999 dollars

T-bills and T-notes

4

4

3

Marketable
T-secs

3

2

T-bills and
T-notes

2

1

1

Marketable T-secs

0
1960

M-base
0
1960

’65

’70

’75

’80

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

’85

’90

M-base

’95

’00

’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

Note: Figure displays rolling standard deviations of surprises to
monthly growth rates of real per capita supplies of T-secs and
the monetary base, 1960–99.

29

their lowest levels in recent years. The market for
commercial paper has also grown rapidly over the past
three decades, but it remains a small part of total finance. (See boxes 2 and 3 for descriptions of how we
constructed the series for outstanding corporate equities and the components of outstanding debt that are
presented in these figures.)
Figure 15, which provides a breakdown of marketable Treasury securities by type, shows that longterm bonds dominated government finance between
1915 and 1960, but that medium-term T-notes and
short-term T-bills have risen to preeminence more recently. These shifts suggest that a broad measure
of government bond activity, such as the sum of all
marketable Treasury securities in the hands of the
public, may be best for evaluating the effects of supply shocks related to the Fed’s open market policies

over the long term, but that the quantities of T-bills
and T-notes might be more relevant in recent years.
These considerations more precisely explain our
choices of variables for quantifying supply risk earlier
in this article. Interestingly, and in keeping with most
rational expectations models, we found in most cases
that the choice of supply variable did not matter.
Figures 12 and 13, when combined with the effects
of changes in the supply of T-secs presented in figure 2,
suggest that the decline in the share of these securities in the aggregate portfolio has had little effect on
the distribution of rt—the real return on T-bills. This
stands in sharp contrast to the implications that such
a decline would have in the limited participation model
of Alvarez et al. (2001), in which the interest rate effects of monetary injections depend inversely on the
fraction of agents that take part in the bond market.

FIGURE 12

FIGURE 14

Federal and business securities
as share of GDP, 1915–99

Corporate financing
in the 20th century

ratio of securities to GDP

percent

3.0

100

Marketable
Treasury
securities

2.0

80

Corporate equities

60
40

1.0

Corporate
bonds

Corporate equities
Commercial paper

20

Business debt

Bank loans
0.0
1915

’25

’35

’45

’55

’65

’75

’85

’95

0
1900 ’10

’20

’30

’40

’50

’60

’70

’80

FIGURE 13

FIGURE 15

Outstanding federal and business securities,
1915–99

Marketable Treasury financing,
1915–99

percent

percent

100

100

80

80

’90

’00

Other
Corporate equities

T-bonds

60

60

T-notes

40

40

Business debt
20

20

T-bills

Marketable Treasury securities
0
1915

30

’25

’35

’45

’55

’65

’75

’85

’95

0
1915

’25

’35

’45

’55

’65

’75

’86

’95

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

BOX 2

Estimating the market value of outstanding corporate equity
To estimate the market value of outstanding corporate equity, we extend the Federal Reserve Board’s
Flow of Funds series (table L.4) backwards, using the
available data on capitalization for the New York Stock
Exchange (NYSE), the regional exchanges, and overthe-counter (OTC) markets. We work backwards not
from 1945 (which is when the Flow of Funds data series
begins) but, rather, from 1949 because the closest overlapping observations of OTC activity are for 1949.
The Flow of Funds reports $117 billion for outstanding corporate equities in 1949, which we divide
into the value of NYSE-listed firms, the value of firms
listed exclusively on The American Stock Exchange
(AMEX) and the regional exchanges, and the value
of firms traded exclusively in OTC markets. Friend
(1958) estimates the sum of NYSE and regional capital in 1949 at $95 billion. We know from the Center
for Research on Securities Prices (CRSP) database that
NYSE capitalization was $68 billion. This implies a
regional capitalization of $27 billion and OTC capital
of $22 billion in 1949. Assuming that the capitalizations of NYSE listed and regionally listed firms are
proportional to their transaction values, which are
available from various issues of the Annual Report
of the Securities and Exchange Commission for
1935–49, we multiply NYSE capital by the ratio of
regional to NYSE transactions to approximate movements in capitalization on the regional exchanges.
We then adjust the resulting regional series to match
the $27 billion that we estimate for 1949. To estimate
regional capital for 1920–34, we observe that the ratio
of regional to NYSE transaction value was steady at
0.18 for 1935–50 and again use NYSE capital to derive regional capital from 1920.
The OTC market presents a double-counting
problem. Friend estimates that, in 1949, 25 percent
of quoted OTC issues were also listed on a registered
exchange. Our measure of OTC capital must exclude
such firms. To derive estimates for 1920–49, we use
Friend’s counts of the number of OTC-quoted firms
over a three-month window surrounding three benchmark dates in 1949, 1939, and 1929. There were 5,300
such OTC firms in 1949, of which 75 percent were
not listed on registered exchanges. The median market
value of these unlisted firms was $2.4 million. Therefore, we approximate exclusive OTC capital at $9.54
million (.75 ´ 5,300 ´ÿ $2.4) in 1949. Assuming that
the real median size of unlisted OTC firms did not
change over 1920–49, we next use the gross domestic
product (GDP) deflator to convert the median size
into nominal terms at the other benchmark dates. Next,
we observe that the $9.47 million for 1949 is too small
by a factor of 2.3, given our comparable estimate from
the Flow of Funds, and adjust the OTC benchmark

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

estimates by this factor. Finally, we interpolate between the benchmarks to obtain an annual OTC series for 1929–49.
To obtain OTC capital for 1920–28, we continue
to assume that capital on the exchanges is proportional
to relative transaction values. Since we know NYSE
capitalization and now have estimates for the regional
and OTC markets in 1929, we can estimate the share
of the OTC in total market value in 1929. Using
Friend’s (1958, p. 109) estimates of this share for 1926
and 1920, we can estimate OTC capital for these
years given the values of NYSE capitalization from
CRSP and our earlier estimates of regional capital.
We interpolate between the benchmarks once again
to obtain OTC capital for 1920–29.
FIGURE 2A

Estimates of outstanding equity, 1900–99
share of GDP
1.8
1.5
1.2

Flow of funds
and backcast

0.9
0.6
0.3

CRSP

0.0
1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 ’70 ’80 ’90 ’00

By adding NYSE, regional and OTC capitalizations, we obtain a series for total market value for
1920–49 that is consistent with the Flow of Funds in
the sense that the two segments coincide in 1949. Our
final estimates of equity capital outstanding, displayed
in figure 2A, are obtained by splicing our series with
the Flow of Funds in 1945. The figure also includes
the series for equity capital that would result from
the use of CRSP (1925–99) and our NYSE listings
(1900–24) data alone. The importance of equities that
were not listed on the NYSE from the end of the First
World War to the start of Nasdaq in 1971, as depicted
by the vertical distance between the black and colored
lines in the figure, is considerable. Since we wish to use
market value from 1900 in figures 12 and 13, for the
purpose of computing the share of equity in total finance, we ratio splice the value of NYSE capital for
1900–20 (obtained from individual issues of the New
York Times Co.’s The Annalist, Dana & Company’s
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, the New York
Times, and Bradstreet’s) to our result for 1920–99.

31

BOX 3

Estimating the market value of business debt
We define U.S. business debt as the value of outstanding commercial and industrial bank loans, corporate bonds, and commercial paper. For 1945–99,
book values for loans and corporate bonds are from
the Flow of Funds (table L.4, lines 5 and 6, respectively). For 1900–44, the book value of outstanding
corporate bonds is from Hickman (1952) and that of
bank loans is from the Federal Reserve Board’s AllBank Statistics. Since bank loans are reported in the
latter source as June 30 figures, we average across
years for consistency with the calendar-year basis of
the Flow of Funds.
For commercial paper, the outstanding amount
for 1970–93 is available from the FRED database of
the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. We carry this
series to the present using the quantity of open market paper from the Flow of Funds (table L.4, line 2).
We extend the series backwards to 1959 using the
Federal Reserve Board’s Banking and Monetary Statistics (Board of Governors, 1976b, pp. 717–719).
These quantities include paper placed both directly
(that is, finance company) and by dealers. For 1919–
58, we have a continuous series for dealer-placed
paper only, again from Banking and Monetary Statistics (1976b, pp. 714–717; 1976a, pp. 465–467),
which we ratio-splice to the later series. The splice
leads to what is likely to be an overestimate of outstanding commercial paper by 1918 due to the rapid
growth of directly placed paper between the mid1920s and 1941. For example, Greef (1937, p. 118)
presents a figure of $874 million for outstanding
commercial paper in 1918, while the spliced series
would imply a total of $4.2 billion. Since we do not
have the data on finance paper that would be required to reconcile these series, we have chosen to
simply use Greef’s figures before 1931, the point at

Conclusion
Bond-supply risk normally contributes between
10 basis points and 40 basis points to movements
in the real rate of interest on T-bills. The effect has
shown no tendency to decline over the past half century. The Fed will find it harder and harder to push
this risk to zero because the gradual paying down of
the federal debt has meant that it has become harder
to expand T-bill issues to accommodate unexpectedly
large rollover demands from foreign sources. Further,
so long as the Fed uses the secondary market for
Treasury securities as its chief means of conducting
open market operations, shocks to the supply of these
securities to the public will persist. If the supply of
outstanding Treasury securities indeed does continue

32

which the outstanding totals from both series differ
the least in percentage terms. Prior to 1918, Greef
(1937, pp. 57–59) provides estimates of the volume
of commercial paper trading in 1907 and 1912–16.
Assuming four- to six-month maturities, we then estimate the amount of commercial paper outstanding
at 5/12 of the trading volume, and assume constant
growth between the benchmarks of 1907 and 1912.
We apply the same growth rate to 1900–06 to complete the series. From the above, it should be clear
that the commercial paper series is not very reliable
prior to 1931. Since we do not perform any econometric analysis with this series, however, and it
turns out to be a small portion of total debt finance
in any case during this period, we consider the inclusion of the totals in figures 12–14 to be useful.
To build a market value series, we include both
commercial paper and bank loans, due to their short
maturities, at their book values. We then convert
outstanding corporate bonds from par values to market values using the average annual yields on
Moody’s AAA-rated corporate bonds (from Moody’s
Investors Service for 1919–98 and Hickman’s “high
grade” bond yields, which line up precisely with
Moody’s, for 1900–18). To determine market value,
we let rt be the bond interest rate and compute the
weighted average

rt* 

¤

¤

t
1
(1  E )t  i rt  i .
t i
(1  E ) i 1885

t
i 1885

We choose d = 10 percent to approximate the
growth of new debt plus retirements of old debt and
multiply the book value of outstanding corporate
rt*

bonds by the ratio rt to obtain their market value.

its decline, an increase in the use of other debt instruments for open market operations will reduce the
supply-risk for the group as a whole.
We also find that despite the challenges to implementing monetary policy that are imposed by supply
risk, the Fed has been managing this risk well. This
is clear from observing that the variability of the
monthly growth rate of the T-bill supply has not
changed much in recent years.
The bond and stock markets also show a lack
of comovement that is hard to explain unless one
assumes that the markets are segmented. Characterizing the nature of such segmentation is an endeavor in
which we are actively engaged.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

NOTES
Tables 1 and 2 both deal with ex post real returns of investors
who purchase three-month U.S. Treasury bills in the secondary
market with two months remaining until maturity and sell them
a month later. We obtain monthly nonborrowed reserves from the
FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, and describe other data sources in the text and note 8.

an absence of bond-supply risk. Therefore, It–1 contains insufficient information to forecast Pt perfectly.

We compute surprises to T-secs and nonborrowed reserves as
one-step ahead forecast errors from a series of rolling bivariate
vector autoregressions (VARs) with four lags and a 30-month
estimation window.

11
The Consumer Price Index, which we also use to deflate the Tsec quantities, is that for all urban consumers from the U.S. Bureau
of Labor Statistics.

1

2

Noncompetitive bidders who specify a bank account for direct
debit under the Treasury Direct investment plan also do not pay
for their bills until the issue date.
3

We compute this figure as the average share of accepted noncompetitive bids in the total face value of T-bills sold at each
weekly auction of 13-week and 26-week T-bills from July 30,
1998, through April 5, 2000. Press releases of auction results
are available at the Bureau of the Public Debt’s website,
www.publicdebt.treas.gov.
4

Before November 1998, marketable Treasury securities were
auctioned in a discriminatory fashion, with the highest bidders receiving their requested quantities in full at the tendered price subject to a maximum of 35 percent of the total quantity auctioned
(this “35 percent rule” is still in effect). Noncompetitive bidders
received their requests in full at prices based on a weighted average of accepted competitive bids. Both auction systems, discriminatory and single-price, generate some degree of supply risk.
5

Foreign bids are now restricted to $200 million or less per account, and are filled from smallest to largest until the $1 billion
total limit is reached. The size of foreign bids will be restricted to
$100 million or less as of January 1, 2002.
6

We compute the standard deviations using a 12-month rolling
window and then apply the Hodrick–Prescott filter to each series
before plotting.
7

The quantities of outstanding marketable Treasury securities are
end-of-month observations from individual issues of the Annual
Report of the Secretary of the Treasury for 1920–31, the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s Banking and Monetary Statistics (1976a, pp. 868–873; 1976b, pp. 509–511) for
1932–70, and individual issues of the U.S. Department of the
Treasury’s Monthly Statement of the Public Debt of the United
States thereafter. To compute the quantity in the hands of the public, we subtract the Fed’s holdings from Banking and Monetary
Statistics (1976a, p. 343; 1976b, pp. 485–487) for 1932–70 and
from individual issues of the Federal Reserve Bulletin for
1920–31 and 1971–99.
8

The monetary base is from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for 1936–99, with M1 from the Friedman
and Schwartz (1970, table 1, pp. 4–58) ratio, spliced to the M0
aggregate for 1920–35.
The information set It–1 consists of the realized inflation rate
from t–1 to t (that is, pt–1,t), the real T-bill return from t–1 to t
(that is, rt–1,t), the real return on the S&P 500 portfolio from t–1
to t, and the growth in the bond supply from t–2 to t–1 (that is,
gt–2,t–1). In other words, thinking of date t as February and date t–1
as January, and so on, when we commit funds to the bond market
before any February auction, we know the return on the S&P 500
and the inflation rate for January, and the growth of the bond supply
in December. We do not include the growth of bond supply in
January, however, because that would imply knowledge of Pt and
9

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Nominal secondary market interest rates on three-month T-bills
are from the FRED database for 1934–99 and Board of Governors (1976a) for earlier years.

10

Nominal calendar-month returns on the S&P 500 assume the reinvestment of dividends and are from worksheets underlying
Wilson and Jones (2001).

12

As we show in a later section, the government’s maturity preferences have shifted considerably over time, but these shifts in
themselves did not introduce risk in the total supply of securities
available to the public. Thus, focusing on supply shocks to a
single instrument such as T-bills over the long term would overemphasize variations in the maturity structure of government finance that were not “shocks” but rather just substitutions of one
maturity for another. For this reason, we work primarily with the
total of marketable Treasury securities in the hands of the public
rather than a narrower quantity measure such as T-bills alone.

13

Figure 2 does not span the full 1920–99 period because observations are lost in accommodating the lag length of the VAR, in
constructing the initial estimation window, and in computing the
initial and final rolling standard deviations of the forecast errors.
We also lose observations early in the sample when making similar computations for figures 3–9.

14

In this section, however, we measure inflation over only the
first month of the T-bill term and then assess its effect on the
three-month real yield. Even here we obtain coefficients on the
inflation surprises that are close to unity for the 1920–99 period
and the 1920–46 subperiod, though the coefficients are considerably below unity for 1947–79 and 1980–99.

15

Since an adequate breakdown of Treasury securities into its Tbill and T-note components is not available on a monthly basis
prior to 1932, the correlations that include T-bills and T-notes in
the two upper panels of table 5 begin in 1932 rather than in 1920.

16

The correlations of nonborrowed reserves for 1959–79 are .110
with the S&P 500, .216 with T-bill returns, .071 with T-bill and
T-note quantities, and .091 with T-sec quantities. For 1980–99,
the respective correlations are .104, .134, .068, and .087. Correlations of the real monetary base for 1959–79 are .096 with the S&P
500, .461 with T-bill returns, .010 with T-bill and T-note quantities,
and .094 with T-sec quantities. The correlations of nonborrowed
reserves with real T-bill returns differ from those reported in table 1
because contemporaneous rather than leading relationships are
considered here. In addition, the return measure in table 1 reflects
a one-month yield on a seasoned T-bill rather than the return to
the “buy-and-hold” strategy considered here.

17

We obtained the secondary market quotes for 1961–86 from the
master microfilm reels that are on deposit at the New York Fed’s
Department of Public Information. Quote sheets for 1987–96 are
available at their website (www.ny.frb.org.) We collected quotes
for 1997–99 from individual issues of the Wall Street Journal.

18

We compute surprises to T-secs and the monetary base as onestep-ahead forecast errors from a series of rolling bivariate VARs
with four lags and a 30-month estimation window. In this figure
and all others in this section, we apply the Hodrick-Prescott filter
to our data series before plotting them.

19

33

REFERENCES

Alvarez, Fernando, Robert Lucas, and Warren
Webber, 2001, “Interest rates and inflation,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol.
91, No. 2, pp. 219–225.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2000, Flow of Funds Accounts, Fourth Quarter,
Washington, DC.
, 1976a, Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1914–1941, Washington, DC.
, 1976b, Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1941–1970, Washington, DC.
, 1959, All-Bank Statistics, United
States, Washington, DC.
, 1920–99, Federal Reserve Bulletin,
Washington, DC, various issues.
Bradstreet Co., 1920–25, Bradstreet’s, New York,
various issues.
Cammack, Elizabeth B., 1991, “Evidence on bidding strategies and the information in Treasury bill
auctions,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99,
No. 1, pp. 100–130.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Martin Eichenbaum, 1995, “Liquidity effects, monetary policy, and
the business cycle,” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 1113–1136.
Dana, William B., & Company, 1900–25, The
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, New York,
various issues.
Dow Jones and Company, 1997–99, The Wall Street
Journal, New York, various issues.
Evans, Charles L., and David A. Marshall, 1998,
“Monetary policy and the term structure of nominal
interest rates: Evidence and theory,” Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, Vol. 49, pp. 53–111.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2001, FRED,
database, St. Louis, MO.

34

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz, 1982,
Monetary Trends in the United States and the United
Kingdom, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
, 1970, Monetary Statistics of the United
States, New York: Columbia University Press.
, 1963, A Monetary History of the United States, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Friend, Irwin, 1958, The Over-the-Counter Securities Markets. New York: McGraw Hill.
Greef, Albert O., 1937, The Commercial Paper
House in the United States, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Grossman, Sanford, and Laurence Weiss, 1983,
“A transactions-based model of the monetary transmission mechanism,” American Economic Review,
Vol. 73, No. 5, pp. 871–880.
Hickman, W. Braddock, 1952, “Trends and cycles
in corporate bond financing,” National Bureau of
Economic Research, occasional paper, No. 37.
Johnston, J., 1984, Econometric Methods, third edition, New York: McGraw Hill.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., 1990, “Liquidity and interest
rates,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 50, No. 2,
pp. 237–264.
New York Times Co., The, 1913–25, The Annalist:
A Magazine of Finance, Commerce, and Economics,
New York, various issues.
, 1897–1928, The New York Times, New
York, various issues.
Phillips, A. W., 1958, “The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates
in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957,” Economica,
Vol. 25, No. 100, pp. 283–299.
Standard and Poor’s Corporation, 2000, Compustat, database, New York.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the
Census, 1975, Historical Statistics of the United
States, Colonial Times to 1970, Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.

U.S. Department of the Treasury, Bureau of the
Public Debt, 1975–2000, Monthly Statements of the
Public Debt of the United States, Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office, various issues.

U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission,
1935–49, Annual Report of the Securities and Exchange Commission. Washington, DC: Government
Printing Office, various issues.

University of Chicago, Center for Research on
Securities Prices, 1999, CRSP, database, Chicago.

U.S. Department of the Treasury, 1917–31, Annual
Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the State
of Finances, Washington, DC: Government Printing
Office, various issues.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Wilson, Jack W., and Charles P. Jones, 2001, “An
analysis of the S&P 500 index and Cowles’ extensions: Price indexes and stock returns,” Journal of
Business, forthcoming.

35

CALL FOR PAPERS
May 8-10, 2002
38th ANNUAL CONFERENCE ON BANK STRUCTURE AND COMPETITION
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

Financial Market Behavior and
Appropriate Regulation over
the Business Cycle
The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago invites the submission of research and policyoriented papers for the 38th annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition to
be held May 8-10, 2002, at the Fairmont Hotel in Chicago. Since its inception, the
conference has aimed to encourage an ongoing dialogue on current public policy
issues affecting the financial services industry. Although we are interested in papers
related to the conference theme, we are most interested in high-quality research
addressing public policy and the financial services industry.
he theme of the 2002 conference will be an evaluation
recovery from the recession was unusually slow. Deposit
of the changing condition and behavior of financial
flows were also disrupted, and as the economy recovered
institutions, and the appropriate regulatory response,
some institutions found it more difficult than others to raise
over the business cycle. Over the past decade, we have seen core deposit funds using traditional means. As we proceed
unprecedented economic expansion, yet events of the past through the current slowdown, there are reasons to believe
year suggest that the business cycle with its associated
that lending and deposit-taking institutions may react differ­
booms and recessions has not been eliminated. As we move
ently than in the past. Banks are more geographically diversified,
through the business cycle, it is important to understand how
offer a wider range of financial products, and are better able
financial firms respond to changing credit conditions and market
to hedge risk, all of which may make them more resilient to
demands. It is also important to understand the forces driving
adverse economic shocks. More generally, the current financial
financial firm behavior and to evaluate the alternative policy
sector is characterized by extensive securitization, increased
options available to regulators across the business cycle.
risk-management options, and a broad network of nonbank

n

In addition to their importance over the cycle, the events of

financial alternatives, such as mutual funds, commercial

September 11 underscore the importance of appropriate policy

paper, and deeper markets for debt securities. Many of the
functions provided by these alternatives previously resided

responses during a crisis. There is need for an immediate
response to allow financial markets to continue to function
efficiently, followed by a longer-term response to address the
adverse impact the shock could have on the financial industry.
In the early 1990s, financial institutions responded to the

almost exclusively in commercial banks. Although this new
network of intermediation is growing rapidly, it has never
been tested by recession and is not subject to the same

level of regulation as commercial banks. It remains an
unanswered question as to whether these changes have

economic slowdown by adjusting their credit standards and,

made the new financial system more or less susceptible to

as a result, credit availability. A "credit crunch" ensued, and

the business cycle and economic shocks.

Given the impact of the business cycle on the economic condi­
tion of financial firms, and the resulting impact on the economy,
what is the appropriate regulatory and supervisory response

over the business cycle? Some argue that policy should be
countercyclical: more stringent during upturns and more
accommodating during downturns. Examination standards, it
is argued, need to be relaxed during downturns to avoid
exacerbating an already bad situation. It has even been
argued that bank capital requirements should vary inversely
with the cycle. In essence, bank regulation and supervision
should be used as a macroeconomic tool to help smooth the
business cycle.
Others have argued that sound regulatory and supervisory policy
regarding credit quality and bank condition must be based on

established standards that are invariant to the business cycle.
The prompt-corrective-action provisions and least-cost-resolu­
tion requirements introduced under the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) are consistent
with this view. These provisions were designed to at least
partially limit supervisory discretion and forbearance when
banks encounter financial difficulties. However, the effective­

conflict between FDICI A provisions that eliminate supervisory
discretion and a desire to smooth the cycle via supervisory
tools? What are the advantages or disadvantages of having
responsibility for macroeconomic policy and bank regulation
combined within a single agency?

The 2002 conference will focus on these and related questions.
However, we are also interested in other financial topics
including, but not limited to:
■ Bank capital standards (particularly the proposed
Basel Accord)
■ Measuring and managing risk (particularly for
transnational/globaI financial services companies)
■ Alternative approaches to dealing with financial crises
■ Financial industry consolidation
■ The efficacy of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act
■ Fair lending issues and predatory pricing issues
■ The implications of technology on bank delivery systems
(for example, Internet banking) and payment innovations.
Continuing the format of recent years, the final session of the
conference will feature a panel of industry experts who will

ness of these provisions has recently come into question, and
many argue that the restrictions are not—and perhaps should
not be—binding on supervisors.

discuss the purpose, structure, problems, and proposed
changes associated with an important and topical banking
regulation. Past topics discussed at this session include bank
antitrust analysis, capital regulation, the role of government

These financial and regulatory issues raise a number of public
policy questions. Are financial firms more resilient to economic
shocks today than in the past? Have deregulation and
advances in portfolio management made them better prepared
for downturns? How are credit crunches initiated—are they a
supply or a demand phenomenon? How do changing credit
standards affect targeted or fair lending? Do firms attempt to
manage reported earnings over the business cycle? What
problems and opportunities does this create? Are smaller
financial firms at a competitive disadvantage at raising funds
during economic slowdowns? As conditions deteriorate, how
good are supervisors at identifying problem banks? How
successful have "early warning models" been for this objective?

sponsored enterprises (GSEs), optimal regulatory structures,
and the appropriate role of the lender-of-last-resort.
Proposals for this session are also welcome.

If you would like to present a paper at the conference, please
submit four copies of the completed paper or a detailed
abstract (the more complete the paper the better) with your
name, address, affiliation, telephone number, and e-mail
address, and those of any coauthors, by December 21, 2001.
Correspondence should be addressed to:
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition
Research Department

Do current capital requirements, and perhaps regulation in

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

general, exacerbate business cycles? Do proposals aimed at
increasing the role of market discipline diminish or further

230 South LaSalle Street

Chicago, Illinois 60604-1413

aggravate this procyclicality? What are the advantages or

disadvantages of having the new Basel Capital Accord incor­
porate a countercyclical component? Should regulation and
supervision be used as an additional tool to smooth the business
cycle? What problems does this create? Is there an inherent

For additional information contact:
Douglas Evanoff at 312-322-5814 (devanoff@frbchi.org), or

Portia Jackson at 312-322-5775 (portia.jackson@chi.frb.org)

Countering contagion: Does China’s experience
offer a blueprint?
Alan G. Ahearne, John G. Fernald,
and Prakash Loungani

Introduction and summary
China did not succumb to the Asian crisis of 1997–99.
In this article, we discuss why China was not swept
into the crisis despite two potential sources of vulnerability, a weak financial sector and increased export
competition from the Asian crisis countries. Next, we
discuss the role strong external accounts and capital
controls played in countering contagion. We conclude
by outlining the continuing risks to China’s outlook,
in an attempt to assess whether China is likely to avoid
future crises.
Table 1 shows China’s relatively strong growth
performance throughout the crisis. As shown in column 1, China’s real gross domestic product (GDP)
grew nearly 8 percent in 1998, a year in which the
median real GDP contraction among economies in the
region was 6 percent.1 China’s slowdown in growth
during 1999, shown in the second column, was modest. Another indicator of China’s stability amidst the
Asian crisis was its success at maintaining the peg between the Chinese renminbi and the U.S. dollar.2
China’s ability to counter contagion was very
much in doubt almost from the onset of the crisis, with
the question “Is China next?” being actively debated.3
Many observers pointed to financial sector vulnerabilities as the most likely reason for the crisis to spread
to China. It was generally accepted that problems with
China’s financial system were far worse than in other
regional economies (see, for example, Lardy, 1998a,
1998b). In addition, as indicated by the third column
of table 1, China’s banking system was similar in size
to that in the rest of Asia. In particular, the median
ratio of bank loans relative to GDP was 93 percent
in Malaysia, almost identical to the ratio in China.
Nevertheless, despite the large banking system
and prevalence of bad loans and other institutional
weaknesses, China avoided a crisis during 1997–99.
Why was this the case? We argue that the reason is

38

the absence of a “credit culture” in China. In a marketoriented system, pressures generally force rapid adjustment when institutions are, or are perceived to be,
insolvent; these mechanisms do not operate fully in
China. For example, banks can continue to operate
regardless of balance-sheet weaknesses, because of
the government’s support.
A second source of vulnerability for China that
was commonly mentioned was through increased export competition as a result of the sharp real depreciations of the currencies of the Asian crisis countries.
However, this channel of contagion also did not prove
to be very strong. The reason, in our view, is that the
trade relationship between China and other Asian
economies is far less adversarial than is generally assumed. Chinese exports were affected by the reduced
income of Asian economies, but much less so by the
relative price effects from the depreciations of other
currencies. We present evidence, based on an estimation of aggregate trade equations for Asian economies,
that a modest impact on China from the depreciations
elsewhere in Asia is what one should have expected.
By contrast, the robustness of industrial country growth
over the crisis period (excluding Japan, of course)
continued to anchor Chinese export growth. We also

Alan G. Ahearne is an economist at the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System; John G. Fernald is a senior
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; and
Prakash Loungani is assistant to the director (External
Relations) at the International Monetary Fund (IMF). The
authors are grateful to numerous colleagues at the Federal
Reserve Board, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and the
IMF for helpful comments and conversations about aspects
of this article. They particularly thank Christoph Duenwald,
Hali Edison, Dale Henderson, Jeremy Mark, David
Marshall, and John Rogers. They thank Oliver Babson
and Jon Huntley for helpful research assistance. The
views expressed are those of the authors and should not
be attributed to the IMF.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

TABLE 1

China and other Asian economies: Selected indicators (percent)
Real GDP
growth, 1998
China
Hong Kong
Indonesia
Korea

7.8
–5.4

Real GDP
growth, 1999

Bank loans/
GDP, 1996

Current account/
GDP, 1996

Total debt/
reserves, 1966

Short-term BIS
bank claims/
reserves, 1996

7.1
3.6

92.7
162.4

0.9
–1.7

130.5
—

25.1
—

–13.1

0.8

55.4

–3.4

607.0

187.6

–6.5

10.9

61.5

–4.4

420.4

198.3

Malaysia

–7.3

5.7

93.4

–4.4

137.4

41.4

Philippines

–0.6

3.4

49.0

–5.4

414.7

77.1

Singapore

0.5

5.7

96.0

15.2

—

—

Taiwan

4.6

5.4

143.7

3.9

31.1

21.4

–10.9

4.3

100.5

–7.9

322.9

121.1

Thailand

Notes: The first two columns show year-over-year growth rates for 1998 and 1999. The remaining columns show indicators for 1996,
and hence are not affected by the crisis itself. Debt figures for offshore banking centers (Hong Kong and Singapore) are not shown, as
they are not comparable with data from other economies due to the large size of external claims and liabilities.
Sources: All GDP figures are taken from IMF International Financial Statistics. Bank loans data and data for foreign exchange reserves
are also from IMF International Financial Statistics. Current account data are from FRB INTL databases. Total debt figures and shortterm BIS bank claims data are from the joint BIS-IMF-OECD-World Bank Statistics on External Debt.

present evidence from disaggregated export data that
the crisis did little to disrupt ongoing changes in
China’s market share in different product markets
and regions.
In contrast to these two sources of vulnerability,
China’s external accounts looked favorable compared
with the rest of Asia, as shown by columns 4 to 6 of
table 1. China runs current account surpluses (about
1 percent of GDP in 1996, but closer to 3 percent in
1997 and 1998), and its total debt relative to reserves
was lower than in most Asian economies. Measures of
short-term debt relative to reserves looked particularly favorable for China, as shown by column 6.4 Hence,
the mainstream view was that the strength of China’s
external fundamentals could preclude a financial “panic” or “country run” as investors sought to pull funds
out of an economy, akin to a self-fulfilling bank run.5
Furthermore, some argued that China’s capital
controls would prevent a destabilizing speculative attack on the Chinese renminbi. We share the view that
external sector strength helped to counter contagion.
However, we make a somewhat different argument for
the potential role of China’s capital controls in contributing to stability: Regardless of their other (often
adverse) effects, capital controls prevented Chinese
financial institutions from borrowing excessively
abroad and, hence, helped keep the external fundamentals strong. In the following two sections, we spell
out in greater detail our arguments for why financial
sector weaknesses and increased trade competition

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

were not as damaging to China as expected. Next, we
discuss the role of external sector strength and capital
controls in China’s ability to avoid a crisis. Then, we
provide evidence on an increased “country risk” premium for China since the crisis and discuss risks facing China over the next few years.
China’s financial sector
Understanding China’s resilience requires some
understanding of why the crisis was so virulent elsewhere. Although the underlying cause or causes remain controversial,6 explanations tend to fall into one
of two broad categories: 1) weak fundamentals in the
affected economies, or 2) a self-fulfilling financial
panic (also known as multiple equilibria). In this section—and the two that follow—we argue that neither
explanation would point to an imminent crisis in
China. In a market-oriented system, pressures generally force rapid adjustment when institutions are, or
are perceived to be, insolvent; these mechanisms do
not operate fully in China. Hence, despite serious
fundamental weaknesses in Chinese enterprises and
financial institutions, a crisis need not develop.
Perhaps the most common view is that the Asian
crisis reflected fundamental macroeconomic and
microeconomic weaknesses in the most affected economies. Externally, large short-term external borrowing—especially when used to finance current account
deficits—left the economies vulnerable to capital flow
reversals. Domestically, inadequately supervised and

39

capitalized banks made excessively risky loans to
poorly governed firms.7 The story is typically some
variant of the following (the emphasis differs across
analysts, and not all aspects of the story are relevant
for every economy in Asia). Widespread moral hazard existed because financial institutions were poorly
regulated and companies had little accountability to
shareholders. As a result, corporations borrowed
heavily to invest in risky projects, financed by loans
from banks that, in turn, borrowed excessively (and
unhedged) from abroad. At the same time, foreign
creditors were willing to lend large amounts to banks
and corporations in these economies: The region had
a strong track record for economic performance, and
the borrowers were often state-owned banks and corporations which, the lenders thought, had implicit or
explicit sovereign guarantees. Hence, risky investments were financed through excessive leverage, and
especially through excessive short-term, unhedged
external borrowing.
These fundamental weaknesses left economies
vulnerable to crisis from several directions. First, consider external pressures. The large short-term external
borrowing—especially when used to finance current
account deficits—left the economies dependent on
sustained short-term capital flows. If these flows
slowed or reversed for any reason (for example, because of changes in monetary policy in industrial countries, changes in perceptions of the riskiness of these
loans, or a “run” on the country), then the economy
and the currency were vulnerable. Reversal of inflows
contributed to slower growth of the real economy as
a result of the need to reduce current account deficits;
the reversal also contributed to downward pressure
on the exchange rate peg, which might prove to be
unsustainable. A substantial depreciation, in turn,
weakened banking systems because of the unhedged
currency exposure.
Second, consider domestic forces. Poor supervision of banks, particularly those with inadequate capital, led to excessively risky bank lending. If the risks
turn out badly, then banks might find themselves without enough capital to make new loans, or even insolvent. In addition, excessive leverage by corporations
meant that if risky or speculative projects (office buildings and other real estate investments, say, or a hightech semiconductor factory) did not pay off, then firms
might not have sufficient cash flow to pay workers and
suppliers, let alone to repay their creditors. If they
could not repay loans, then bad loans in the banking
sector again would contribute to a banking crisis.
Are these considerations relevant for China?
The external considerations are probably not of great

40

concern to China, since its external debt is relatively
small in proportion to GDP. As noted earlier, China’s
short-term external bank debt relative to reserves is
among the lowest in Asia. We return to these external
considerations in the next section when we consider
speculative attacks and the role of capital controls
in China.
Domestically, however, it is often argued that
China looks very similar to some of the frontline
crisis economies, with poorly regulated banks making
policy loans to inefficient, over-leveraged state enterprises.8 China’s central bank, the People’s Bank of
China, has undertaken a widely publicized campaign
to improve financial supervision and the operations
of the banking system. In the meantime, however,
Chinese banks continue to operate with an enormous
overhang of bad loans. In May 2001, for example,
the Bank of China (one of China’s largest state banks)
announced that nearly 30 percent of its loan book was
nonperforming, even after a large chunk of nonperforming loans had been transferred to an asset management
company. Western observers generally estimate that
the proportion of nonperforming loans in the banking
system as a whole may be even higher.
In most Asian economies, policymakers’ postcrisis concern with banking-sector health reflects not
only long-run concerns about the allocation of capital,
but also short-run concerns. In particular, poor bank
health can lead to a “credit crunch,” as banks reduce
lending even to viable nonfinancial firms. This credit
crunch exacerbates the real effects of the crisis. For
example, banks may lose the funding base (deposits)
with which to make loans; and even if they have the
funding, they may not have adequate capital to make
loans. In addition, creditors (depositors and foreign
lenders) may lose confidence in financial institutions,
leading to fund withdrawals or even bank runs.
These short-term concerns are probably not relevant for China: Banks can and will continue to lend
even if loans go bad. That is, it is unlikely that in order
to restore their “profitability,” Chinese banks will be
forced to cut back on other loans. First, it is fairly clear
that the Chinese government continues to guarantee
bank deposits—which are, after all, primarily held in
state banks. Hence, depositors continue to have faith
in the banking system, and the deposit base remains
sound. Second, if a severe credit crunch begins to impinge on the real economy, Chinese authorities can in
essence order the banks to lend. In the first quarter of
1998, for example, bank loans grew particularly slowly amid reports that banks were concerned about loan
quality and amid reports of a credit crunch; in the second half of the year, loans grew very quickly amid

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

reports of new loans to state enterprises in order to
maintain growth. In other words, despite substantial
moves in recent years to make the banking system
more competitive and commercially oriented, neither
the Chinese authorities nor anyone else believes the
banking system is fully commercially oriented or operates independently from the government. Hence,
Chinese banks can continue to operate even with
substantially negative net worth.

percent change

Trade linkages between China
and the Asian crisis economies

10

From the onset of the crisis, fears kept surfacing
in the financial press that devaluations of the Asian
crisis currencies would have a substantial adverse
impact on Chinese exports and, therefore, ultimately
trigger a Chinese devaluation. Often, the impression
given was that China was locked in mortal combat
for market share with other Asian economies. However, the evidence to support such an adversarial view
of trade linkages between China and the other Asian
economies is hard to come by.
In this section, we present evidence that, over the
last 20 years, changes in real exchange rates have not
been the primary determinant of export growth for the
major Asian exporters. Instead, the most important
determinant has been demand from major trading
partners (mostly the industrialized countries, particularly the United States). Industrial country demand
and the effects of structural changes are likely to have
outweighed exchange rate fluctuations as determinants
of China’s export growth.9
Figure 1 shows strikingly that exports by China
and by other Asian economies tend to move together.
The figure shows export growth (measured in dollar
values) to the world from China (including Hong
Kong) and from the rest of developing Asia. Both
panels use trading partner statistics. Fernald (1999)
argues that it makes economic sense to combine data
for China and Hong Kong even in the period preceding formal unification, since many goods use Chinese
labor and Hong Kong management and distribution
skills. It makes statistical sense to use trading-partner
statistics to avoid double-counting Chinese and Hong
Kong exports.10
The similarity in export growth between China
and other Asian economies suggests that common
factors—such as growth in developed economies,
movements in the world price of key exports such as
semiconductors, and movements in the yen–dollar
rate—were probably more important determinants
of Asian exports than competition with China. Discussions of China’s export performance tend to

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

FIGURE 1

Exports from greater China
and developing Asia
40

World imports from China/HK
(net of internal China/HK trade)

30
20

World imports from
developing Asia
(excl. China and Hong Kong)

0
-10
1979

’83

’87

’91

’95

’99

Note: Exports are measured by trading partner imports.
Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics.

emphasize factors peculiar to China, such as economic
reform initiatives, rapid investment, or tax incentives.
However, these discussions appear to miss the prevalence of common shocks.
A closer look at the changes in Asian export
growth also does little to support the adversarial view
of trade linkages. Consider the U.S. market for these
countries’ exports. In 1989, China accounted for about
one-tenth of total exports to the United States from
the major Asian exporters (excluding Japan). By 1993,
China’s share had risen to one-quarter of all exports
from these countries. However, contrary to popular
perceptions, this gain in “market share” did not come
about at the expense of the labor-intensive so-called
ASEAN-4 economies (comprising four major economies of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations,
Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand).
Instead, China displaced the newly industrialized
economies (NIEs—Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan)
in industries—such as apparel, footwear and household products—that these more advanced economies
were relinquishing. This is a healthy, rather than disturbing, development. It mimics an earlier period, when
the NIEs moved into the industries relinquished by a
more advanced Japan.
Even over the more recent period, 1994 to 2000,
we have seen virtual stability in export shares of
the three Asian groups (China, the NIEs, and the
ASEAN-4), both at the aggregate level and in key
industries. This stability of export shares holds in the
United States, Japan, and many major European markets. To the extent that there have been small gains in
China’s export shares, these have continued to come
largely by displacing the NIEs. The significant real

41

depreciations of the currencies of the Asian crisis
economies have not had the dramatic impact on market
shares that we would have expected if exchange rate
movements were a strong factor behind export growth.
Next, we substantiate these arguments, beginning
with a look at the disaggregated export data and then
presenting estimates of aggregate trade equations.

United States have been scaled up so that they add up
to 100. As shown in column 1 of table 2, in 1989 China
and Hong Kong together accounted for about onequarter of total exports to the United States from the
three groups. By 1993, China’s share had increased
to one-third. Mainland China alone nearly doubled
its share of the U.S. market, helped perhaps by the
real depreciation of the renminbi over this period.
The ASEAN-4 group also increased its market share,
but by a smaller magnitude than that for mainland
China. Correspondingly, the NIEs’ share of the U.S.
market fell from 59 percent to 44 percent. There is,
therefore, some evidence of “competition”—shifts in
market share—among the three groups over the period
1989 to 1993. By contrast, the period between 1993
and 1997 is far more tranquil. The shares of China
and the ASEAN-4 inch up over this period at the expense of the NIEs.
The Asian crisis, and the associated sharp real
depreciations in the currencies of many Asian economies, did not lead to any dramatic changes in market
shares: The relative stability that characterized the
period 1993 to 1997 continued through 2000.
It may be argued that the evidence presented in
table 2, which was for an aggregate of all industries,
masks changes in market shares in particular industries. Our analysis of data for the 48 industries that
make up the aggregate shows that is not the case. In
table 3, we show examples of our analysis for two

Export competition in particular markets
and industries
For this analysis,11 we classified the Asian economies we consider into one of three groups: 1) China
(China and Hong Kong), 2) the NIEs (Korea, Singapore,
and Taiwan), and 3) the ASEAN-4 (Indonesia,
Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand).
We begin by examining the export performance
of these three groups in different geographical regions
and industries for evidence of “export competition,”
defined as “shifts in market share” across the three
groups.12 In particular, we want to see if China’s
market share has increased markedly in a particular
region or industry.13
Competition in the U.S. market
Our analysis is based on three-digit industry level
data published by the U.S. Department of Commerce’s
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). The numbers
in table 2 provide the “market shares” of the three
groups in the U.S. market in 1989, 1993, and 1996–
2000. The total exports of these economies to the

TABLE 2

Export shares of selected Asian economies in the U.S. market
Economy

1989

1993

1996

1997

China

24

33

34

37

China

13

25

29

HK

11

8

5

NIEs

59

44

Korea

22

Singapore
Taiwan

1998

1999

2000

39

40

40

32

34

35

36

5

5

5

4

41

38

36

36

36

14

13

12

11

13

14

10

10

11

10

9

8

7

27

20

17

16

16

15

15

ASEAN-4

17

23

25

25

25

24

24

Indonesia

4

4

5

5

4

4

4

Malaysia

5

8

10

9

9

9

9

Philippines

3

4

4

5

6

5

5

Thailand

5

7

6

6

6

6

6

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

90

126

180

199

211

234

276

Total (China +
NIEs + ASEAN–4)
Total (US$ billions)

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

42

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

key industries, industry 213 (computers, peripherals,
and semiconductors) and industry 400 (apparel, footwear, and household products).
For industry 213 (table 3, panel A), mainland
China’s market share rose from essentially zero in
1989 to 7 percent in 1997; however, over half of this
increase appears to have come at the expense of Hong
Kong. When the two are combined, their market share
increases only slightly over the period. The share of
the ASEAN-4 increases somewhat more substantially, with a corresponding fall in the share of the NIEs.
In the period since the onset of the Asian financial
crisis, both China and the ASEAN-4 have continued
to gain market share at the expense of the NIEs.
The story in the case of industry 400 is a bit different (table 3, panel B). Here, China does experience
a big increase in market share between 1989 and 1997,
from 36 percent to 62 percent, with the bulk of this
increase occurring between 1989 and 1993. The share
of the ASEAN-4 also increased over the period, with
the change being more substantial in the earlier part
of the period than the latter. Since the onset of the crisis, there has been virtual constancy in market shares.
In summary, our analysis of competition in the
U.S. market leads to three conclusions:14
■

Over the period 1989 to 1993, China did gain market share in many markets. In contrast, the period
1993 to 1997 is characterized by relative stability
in market shares across the three groups.

■

China’s gains have come largely at the expense of
the NIEs rather than the ASEAN-4.

■

The Asian crisis has not led to any dramatic changes
in market shares across the three groups.

Aggregate export equations
We also estimated standard aggregate export equations for the nine Asian economies, that is, equations
expressing real export growth as a function of real income growth of the major trading partners and real
exchange rate changes. The estimates show the dominance of income effects over relative price effects.
This suggests that Chinese export growth should not
have been expected to slow dramatically as long as
overall growth among its trading partners remained
robust, despite the price effects from the depreciations
of the Asian crisis currencies.
The data used in the estimation are annual, and
extend from 1973 to 1996. To obtain sufficient degrees
of freedom, we pool the data for all economies and run
a panel vector autoregression (VAR) with three variables: real export growth, real income growth among
major trading partners, and real exchange rate growth.
We include country fixed effects in all regressions.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

We also conducted a test of whether China could be
pooled with the other economies and could not reject
the hypothesis that it could.
Since our sample period has been characterized
by many structural changes (for example, the “opening up” of China’s economy) and changes in exchange
rate regimes, there may be concern that the parameters
of the export equations may not be stable over time.
We reestimated the equation over two subsample periods, 1973 to 1985 and 1986 to 1996, and found the
conclusions to be fairly similar to those for the full
sample period.
Figure 2 shows the estimated response of export
growth to standard-sized (one standard deviation) increases in each of the three sources of shocks in the
panel VAR, going out four years after the shock.15 As
expected, an increase in income growth among trading partners leads to an increase in a “representative”
Asian economy’s export growth. There is a strong contemporaneous, and statistically significant, impact,
which dissipates over the next few years. A depreciation in the currencies of major trading partners has
the predicted adverse impact on export growth in the
representative economy; however, the impact is weak.
Table 4 presents the variance decomposition of real
export growth. As shown, income effects account for
a much larger percentage of the variance than relative
price effects. For instance, at the one-year horizon,
income growth accounts for 20 percent of the variance,
compared with 2 percent for real exchange rate
changes. (Not surprisingly, shocks to exports themselves show the largest dynamic response in figure 2
and account for the largest share of the variance.)
In sum, since in the case of China, overall demand
remained high (with strength in the United States and
Europe countering weakness among Asian partners),
export growth remained quite robust despite the drag
from the depreciation of many Asian currencies.
External sector strength
and capital controls
One view of the Asian crisis, most clearly associated with Sachs and Radalet (1998), is that the Asian
crisis reflects financial panic, akin to self-fulfilling
bank runs on the affected economies. However,
China’s external fundamentals were more favorable
than in most Asian economies, making it plausible
that China would not have been subject to such a run.
At the end of 1998, China had about $150 billion in
total reserves less gold. This compared with gross
nominal external debt of $146 billion at the end of
1998, of which less than $32 billion was short-term
debt to foreign banks. Given China’s reserves, its
sizable external debt remained manageable.

43

TABLE 3

Export shares for Asian economies in the U.S. market, selected industries
A. Industry 213 (computers, peripherals, and semiconductors)
Economy

1989

1993

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

China

7

7

8

10

12

14

15

China

0

3

5

7

9

12

13

HK

7

4

3

3

2

2

2

NIEs

72

68

65

60

55

53

52

Korea

21

16

18

16

13

17

18

Singapore

31

29

28

24

22

18

16

Taiwan

20

23

19

20

20

18

18

ASEAN-4

21

25

27

29

33

33

33

Indonesia

0

0

1

1

1

1

1

Malaysia

12

15

15

15

16

17

17

Philippines

5

6

5

8

10

10

10

Thailand

4

4

6

5

6

5

5

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

1997

1998

1999

2000

Total

B. Industry 400 (apparel, footwear, and household products)
Economy

1989

1993

1996

China

36

55

60

62

62

63

64

China

18

41

47

50

49

51

52

HK

18

14

13

12

13

12

12

NIEs

52

26

17

15

15

15

15

Korea

27

13

7

6

7

7

7

3

2

1

1

1

1

1

Taiwan

22

11

9

8

7

7

7

ASEAN-4

12

19

23

23

23

22

21

Indonesia

3

6

8

8

8

8

8

Malaysia

2

3

4

4

4

3

2

Philippines

3

5

5

5

5

5

5

Singapore

Thailand
Total

4

5

6

6

6

6

6

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

China is often cited as an example of a country
using capital controls successfully and avoiding a destabilizing currency attack.16 China’s controls take
various forms, including restrictions on foreign borrowing by Chinese entities, restrictions on portfolio
outflows by Chinese citizens and inflows by foreigners, and a ban on futures trading in the renminbi. (Note
that a major reversal in capital flows—an apparent
panic—need not reflect a situation of multiple equilibria. It may reflect an informational revelation: The
fundamentals of these economies are in bad shape.)

44

As already noted, China does not have a marketoriented financial system; the government uses controls of various sorts, including capital controls, to
limit the ability of market forces to operate.17 Because
of their role in China’s repressed financial system,
capital controls probably did play a role in limiting
China’s vulnerability. Without capital controls, for
example, it seems likely that many investors would
have tried to invest abroad for precautionary reasons,
removing resources from the state banks.18 In addition,
without a freely accessible onshore futures market,19

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 2

Impulse responses of exports
to various shocks
0.08
0.06
0.04

Export
shock

0.02
0

Income

Exchange
rate

-0.02
-0.04
1

2

3

4

Note: Lines show responses over time of Chinese exports to
shocks to income of their trading partner, their trade-weighted
real exchange rate, and exports themselves.

financial stability, by helping to keep China’s fundamentals strong. Chinese financial institutions suffer
moral hazard problems that are at least as severe as
those in other countries: Financial institutions are inadequately regulated and supervised, and they bear
little responsibility for losses. Had they been allowed
full access to international capital markets, they would
have sought to borrow far more from abroad than was
optimal from a social perspective. (Until the October
1998 default of the Guangdong International Trust and
Investment Corp., foreign lenders generally considered
Chinese borrowers to have implicit or explicit guarantees from the state and were therefore willing to lend
large amounts at favorable rates.) Thus, regardless of
their other effects, capital controls could have helped
keep China’s external fundamentals sound, thereby
helping to ward off the worst aspects of the crisis.
Risks to China

it is difficult to speculate against the future value of
the renminbi, and controls on outflows make it harder for Chinese investors to convert their renminbi if
they expect the currency to weaken.
But China’s financial system is not a system that
other countries would want to emulate in order to avoid
crisis. Just as a tourniquet on a bleeding arm is no
substitute for proper medical care, controls—even if
they have contributed to China’s stability—have serious costs. First, controls are often leaky. They may
work well enough to prevent financial crisis for a time,
but people always have an incentive to find ways
around the rules. Moreover, this evasion potentially
contributes to further problems in the form of corruption and fraud, such as capital flight through underreporting exports or overreporting imports. Second, the
controls may work too well, placing unacceptable limits
on a country’s opportunities for growth and prosperity. For example, Eichengreen (1999, p. 6) points out
that “North Korea’s financial system is immune from
crises because it is subject to such draconian controls.”
However, these harsh controls also help explain the
country’s extreme poverty.
Fortunately for China, as noted earlier, capital
and other controls are not the whole story behind its
resilience. China’s financial system may be weak, but
many of the economy’s fundamentals look far stronger than in the front-line crisis economies. In particular, China has relatively low external debt relative to
GDP, large foreign-exchange reserves, a current-account surplus, and continuing sizable inflows of foreign
direct investment (FDI). And much of the non-state
sector remains vibrant.
Nevertheless, there is an indirect channel by
which capital controls could well have contributed to

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

That China successfully dodged the bullet is not
to say that foreign financial market participants were
unconcerned about China’s vulnerability during the
crisis. In the first part of this section, we assess indicators of foreign perceptions of China. The evidence
suggests that the risk premium attached to China by
foreign investors did indeed increase during the crisis.
Since then, China’s risk premium appears to have returned to near pre-crisis levels, partly reflecting the
Chinese government’s efforts to step up the pace of
structural reforms. In the second part of this section,
we present some conjectures on the outlook for China.
Several measures showed an increased China risk
premium during 1997 and 1998.
Stock prices
The top panel of figure 3 shows stock indices in
Shanghai and Hong Kong.20 After stock exchanges
opened in Shanghai and Shenzhen in the early 1990s,
China maintained separate classes of shares for domestic residents (so-called A shares) and foreigners (B or
H shares). Foreigners could not buy the domestic-only
shares; domestic residents could neither purchase
the foreign-only shares, nor, given China’s capital
TABLE 4

Variance decomposition of Asian export growth
Income

Exchange

Exports
rate

1

20

2

78

2

20

5

75

3

25

5

70

Step

45

account restrictions, generally invest legally in assets
abroad.21 The Shanghai foreign shares have sometimes
tracked the domestic shares, sometimes Hong Kong’s
Hang Seng index, and sometimes neither. From late
1996 until October 1997, the foreign and domestic
Shanghai shares (the black and gray lines) generally
tended to move together. (Although not shown, domestic and foreign share prices in Shenzhen generally move
similarly to their counterparts in Shanghai.)
Following sharp declines in the Hong Kong
stock market in October 1997, Shanghai foreign
share prices followed the Hang Seng down. Indeed,
in the second half of 1998, Shanghai foreign shares
underperformed relative to the Hang Seng. Domestic
share prices, by contrast, remained largely unaffected
by the crisis and, as of early 1999, were close to their
October 1997 levels. Since the dividend stream is the
same for the foreign and domestic classes of shares,
the most plausible interpretation for the divergence is
an increase in the return required by foreign investors.
This increase in returns could reflect an increase in
the risk-free real rate, an increase in the risk premium, or both.
An even more striking way to see this divergence
is to look at the average relative price paid by foreigners in the three markets, shown in the bottom panel
of figure 3. Although at times there have been wide
differences across markets—for example, Hong Kong
shares in 1994 and 1995 traded near parity—by mid1998, foreigners in all three markets typically paid
less than one-fifth the price paid by Chinese residents
for the corresponding share. Thus, China is unlike
most markets with investment restrictions, where
foreigners typically pay a premium.
The most plausible reason for the pricing difference is that Chinese investors have lower required rates
of return, reflecting their lack of access to alternative
investments. Their main alternative is bank deposits,
since financial markets remain poorly developed, and
Chinese capital controls make it difficult to invest
overseas. Bank deposits tend to pay interest rates below world levels. In addition, Chinese investors may
have a low equity premium because stocks offer one
of the few opportunities available to diversify their
investments.
As noted earlier, the Asian financial crisis appeared
to raise the risk premium demanded by foreign investors. Fernald and Rogers (2001) estimate how much
required returns must have widened, given data on
earnings–price ratios (the inverse of typically quoted
price–earnings ratios) and dividend–payout ratios
in China. In particular, they calibrate the standard
Gordon (1962) pricing formula, which says that

46

P = D/(r – g), where P is the price, D is the current
dividend, r is the investor’s expected return, and g
is the growth rate of dividends. Everything except r
is the same for foreign and domestic investors.
Fernald and Rogers rearrange this formula to
show that the difference in expected returns is:

´
¥ D´ ¥¥ E ´
¥ E´
¦ µ
.
µ
¦
µ
¦
E ¶ § § P ¶ Foreign § P ¶ Domestic µ¶

rForeign  rDomestic  ¦
§

The dividend-payout rate D/E for listed stocks
averaged about 0.5 from 1993 to 1997. The 1997
peak in relative prices was around one-half (larger
in Hong Kong, smaller in Shanghai). With earnings–
price ratios of about 0.05 for foreign shares and
0.025 for domestic shares, this equation implies that
FIGURE 3

Foreign and domestic equity prices in China
A. Stock indices in Shanghai and Hong Kong
July 1997=100
400

Shanghai B

300

200

Shanghai A
100

Hang Seng
0
1993

’94

’95

’96

’97

’98

’99

’00

’01

’02

B. Relative price paid by foreigners
2.0

Hong Kong
1.6
1.2

Shenzhen

0.8
0.4

Shanghai
0.0
1993

’94

’95

’96

’97

’98

’99

Notes: Average prices for foreign-only shares relative to prices
for corresponding domestic-only shares, using capitalization
(domestic plus foreign shares) weights. In Shanghai and
Shenzhen, foreign and domestic shares trade on the same
exchange. For Hong Kong H shares, the corresponding
domestic share trades in Shanghai. Foreign prices are
converted into Chinese renminbi.
Source: Fernald and Rogers (2001).

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

the difference in expected returns was only about 1.25
percent. By mid-1998, the earnings–price ratios had
risen to about 0.1 for foreign shares and 0.025 for domestic shares, implying a difference in expected returns of 3.75 percent. Hence, the Asian crisis widened
the difference in expected returns by about 2.5 percentage points.
This equation does not tell us whether domestic
required returns fell or foreign required returns rose.
However, domestic share prices changed little, while
foreign share prices fell sharply. Hence, much of the
movement presumably reflected an increase in the
return required by foreign investors.
Other financial market evidence
The top panel of figure 4 shows the forward
price of renminbi from the offshore nondeliverable
forward market. This market offers one direct (though
somewhat illiquid and, hence, imperfect) way to hedge
renminbi exposure, and prices may reflect either expected currency depreciation or a currency risk premium. Until Hong Kong’s stock market crashed in
late October 1997, the forward market priced in little
change in the value of the renminbi at all horizons.
After late 1997, however, the forward price rose sharply, pricing in a considerable likelihood of devaluation;
the forward price remained high, on balance, until early 2000, as sluggish exports and reduced capital inflows
led many foreign investors to conjecture that China
might devalue the renminbi. Since then, strong export
growth, a pickup in inflows of foreign portfolio equity capital, and an increase in the value of FDI contracts have contributed to a narrowing of the premium.22
Finally, the bottom panel of figure 4 shows the
widening of the yield spread between Chinese sovereign debt and U.S. Treasuries during the crisis, using
a dollar-denominated Chinese government bond due
in 2006. The spread widened from under 100 basis
points to a high of around 400 basis points in September 1998. In early 1999, spreads stood at around 250
basis points, but declined to roughly 150 basis points
in the latter half of 1999 and remained at these levels
through much of 2000. Spreads narrowed even further in 2001, as government measures to restructure
the economy seemingly boosted foreign investors’
confidence in China.
Given the higher value of FDI contracts signed
in 2000, increased capital inflows seem likely. Of
course, China does not rely on foreign capital in a
macroeconomic sense. That is, China has a currentaccount surplus and, hence, is a net exporter of capital
(taking the form, especially, of central bank purchases of U.S. Treasuries and other foreign exchange assets). Therefore, even if foreign investment were to

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

decline, China could in principle offset the direct effect on domestic investment by reducing its investments
abroad (for example, by converting its investments in
U.S. Treasury bonds into investments in, say, factories
in China).
Nevertheless, FDI has played an important role
in improving China’s economy. One direct benefit of
FDI is that foreign firms provide new products, improved technology, and examples of a “reengineered”
employer–employee relationship (see Rosen, 1999).
A second, indirect benefit of FDI is the support it provides to the dynamic non-state sector (see Fernald
and Babson, 1999). Gross inflows of foreign capital
allow the non-state sector to bypass domestic intermediated channels, and hence allow profitable investments that otherwise would not be made. As a result,
increased FDI would tend to make enterprise restructuring less difficult. Downsizing state-owned enterprises requires destroying existing jobs and laying
off workers, which is socially and politically much
easier if new jobs are being created.
Outlook for China
We argued above that the acceleration of economic reform in China since the crisis has contributed to improved foreign-investor sentiment toward
China. In part, the reform program has been stepped
up in order to prepare the economy to meet the challenges of international competition following China’s
entry to the World Trade Organization (WTO). Now,
we briefly discuss these reforms, including government efforts to restructure China’s financial and stateowned enterprise sectors, and outline risks to the
outlook for China. Many of these risks stem from
factors that threaten to slow the pace of economic
reforms, which in turn would likely depress inflows
of foreign capital.
Since the crisis, the Chinese government has intensified efforts to reform the major state-owned commercial banks that dominate the banking system. These
efforts include cleaning up Chinese banks’ mountains
of bad loans—in large part a legacy of directed lending under central planning—by transferring about
$170 billion of bad loans to asset management companies. These entities, in turn, are expected to write
off about one-third of the transferred bad loans through
debt–equity exchanges. The assets underlying the remainder of the bad loans will eventually be sold via
auction.23
China has also made some progress in reforming
the state enterprise sector. Many small firms have been
privatized or shut down, while larger firms have shed
some surplus labor. However, reform has been hindered by concerns about possible social unrest. The

47

FIGURE 4

Financial market evidence of China’s risk
A. Forwards
non-deliverable forwardsa renminbi/$
10.0

9.5

1-year
9.0

3-month

8.5

Spot
8.0

Q3
Q4
1997

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2
Q3
1999

Q4

Q1

Q2
Q3
2000

Q4

Q1

Q2
2001

Q2
Q3
1998

Q4

Q1

Q2
Q3
1999

Q4

Q1

Q2
Q3
2000

Q4

Q1

Q2
2001

1998

Q3

B. Yield spreads
yield spreadb (percentage points)
5

4

3

2

1

0

Q3
Q4
1997

Q1

Q3

a

Rates from offshore forward market, where all transactions are settled in U.S. dollars based on the value of the renminbi.
Government bonds relative to U.S. Treasuries.
Source: Reuters.
b

development of a functioning social welfare system
to provide laid-off workers with unemployment benefits, pensions, and health insurance is still in its early stages.
The problem of surplus labor is even more acute
in rural areas. Increased pressures on the agriculture
sector following WTO entry may exacerbate the already large differential between urban and rural incomes. The threat of resulting massive rural-to-urban
migration may cause China’s leadership to slow the
reform process, not least because mass urbanization
will require massive fiscal spending. The fiscal costs

48

of resolving the banks’ bad loans, reforming the state
enterprises, and financing a new social welfare system
also raise concerns about whether the reform process
is fiscally sustainable.
In addition, if restructuring proves too painful, less
reform-minded policymakers may come to power and
reverse the reform agenda, perhaps as early as 2002,
when the current set of leaders step down. Another
risk is that reform may be slowed by China’s inadequate infrastructure for commercial transactions, especially its accounting and legal systems, including the
lack of a suitable framework for corporate bankruptcy.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Another concern raised by observers is that imports to China might surge following WTO entry as
China reduces trade barriers, possibly leading to pressure on the currency and balance of payments. Our
view is that the tariff reductions promised in China’s
protocol of accession to the WTO are unlikely to lead
to a substantial rise in the overall level of imports, because China’s average tariff rates are already relatively low, after having been cut sharply during the 1990s.
Likewise, the overall incidence of non-tariff barriers
fell significantly during the 1990s. In certain highly
protected sectors, however, notably agriculture and
automobiles, barriers are set to fall steeply, and competitive pressures in these sectors are likely to increase substantially as a result of WTO accession.
Observers have also questioned whether massive
capital flight could put pressure on the currency and
balance of payments, given evidence that China’s
capital controls can be easily evaded. Errors and omissions are, indeed, large, averaging a $16 billion outflow from 1995 to 2000. However, this is roughly an
order of magnitude smaller than international reserves.
With continuing current account surpluses and inflows
of FDI, outflows would have to rise very sharply before foreign exchange reserves would begin to fall
substantially and there would be irresistible pressure
on the currency.
Given the weakness of China’s banking system,
observers have expressed concern about Chinese
banks’ ability to compete with foreign banks following China’s WTO entry.24 If depositors were to shift
large amounts of funds from domestic banks to foreign banks, many domestic banks might face a liquidity crisis. If the government is then called upon to rescue
these banks with central bank funds, it may face the
undesirable choice of seeing an increase in inflation
or a substantial slowdown in growth (as banks are
unable to extend new loans and are forced to call in
outstanding ones).
Conclusion
China avoided the emerging market crisis of
1997–99 but, given the risks to the outlook, how likely
is it that China will avoid future crises? Chinese authorities appear aware of the risks, but the problems
are inherently difficult. China is attempting to balance
conflicting concerns—a desire for short-run stability
and growth (which tends to slow reforms) versus a need
for long-run improvements in the allocation of resources (which requires that reforms keep moving forward).

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Would Chinese banks operate more soundly if
they had adequate capital? The U.S. savings and loan
problem highlighted the moral hazard problems of
financial institutions with low net worth and access
to deposit insurance. In 1998, Chinese authorities announced a 270 billion renminbi ($33 billion) program
to recapitalize the banks.
However, before Chinese banks can operate on
a fully commercial basis. China needs to reduce the
need to make policy loans (through enterprise reform),
provide banks with experience and skill in assessing
loans on commercial grounds, and ensure that banks
are transparent and accountable. These are necessary—but obviously difficult—steps before Chinese
policymakers can successfully recapitalize the banks
or otherwise try to solve the underlying problems of
inherited bad loans of the banking system. Chinese
authorities certainly appear to recognize the need for
these steps and have made substantial progress in recent years in training bankers and examiners and in
increasing the accountability of banks.
But progress is slow. Suppose, for example, that
Chinese banks were successfully recapitalized, so that
they would meet capital adequacy standards under
the best of accounting systems. Major state-owned
employers would still need loans to pay wages and
pensions. In principle, the government could move
these quasi-fiscal operations onto the official budget.
However, financial instruments (including taxes but
also bond markets) remain underdeveloped, so such
a move is likely to happen later rather than sooner.
In addition, inherent incentive problems could remain.
In the United States, there were clear incentives for
the owners of poorly capitalized savings and loans to
engage in risky behavior; more capital would have
mitigated these incentives. For Chinese banks, however, the issue is the incentives faced by bank managers (rather than owners). Individual managers may
continue to have incentives to make loans to, say,
friends or powerful politicians.25
In sum, China now faces the very difficult task of
sequencing, that is, of trying to move from a non-commercial banking system where market mechanisms do
not fully work to a viable commercial banking system
where incentives are appropriate. The transitional
stage—where controls have been lifted but incentives
remain inappropriate—holds significant dangers, as
was evident in the Asian crisis economies.

49

NOTES
The strong output performance was surprising and appears in
part to have reflected substantial increases in investment in infrastructure and by state enterprises (including strong inventory investment), the latter apparently financed by substantially faster
lending by the four major banks. Hence, the increase in growth
may have been at the expense of previously announced enterprise
and bank reform. Numerous observers have also questioned the
reliability of the output data, particularly given the clear political
commitment at that time to an 8 percent growth target. Given
long-noted problems with Chinese statistics (see Borensztein and
Ostry, 1996, for instance), most analysts tend to interpret Chinese
statistics as indicating trends, even if levels, or even exact growth
rates, are uncertain. The concern is that the “biases” in the statistics are not constant, so that the economy might have weakened
in 1998 despite the reported growth.

1

The terms renminbi and yuan are often used interchangeably to
refer to China’s currency. (Technically, the renminbi is the currency; the yuan is the unit of account.) We use the term renminbi
throughout this article.

2

See, for instance, Dornbusch (1998), Manning (1999), and Butler and Palmer (1997).

3

To obtain consistent data across economies, we measure shortterm debt from creditor data, using short-term bank claims by
BIS reporting banks.

4

5

See the discussion in Sachs and Radelet (1998), p. 5.

6

See Kochhar, Loungani, and Stone (1998) and Berg (1999).

See, for example, IMF (1998), Goldstein (1998), and Krugman
(1998).

7

See, for example, Lardy (1998a, 1998b), McGraw-Hill Companies, Business Week (1998), Rennie (1998), and Harding (1998).

8

Chinese export growth has also been helped by structural reforms of the exchange and trade system, as detailed in Cerra and
Dayal-Gulati (1999). Examples include allowing local governments and exporting enterprises to retain a proportion of foreign
exchange receipts, eliminating mandatory export and import
planning, and opening up the economy to foreign direct investment. Despite occasional reversals, the overall trend has been to
reduce the role of central planning in China’s foreign trade.

9

See Arora and Kochhar (1995) for a comprehensive discussion
of size and source discrepancies in bilateral trade statistics between China and its main industrial-country trading partners.
10

11
Some of the analysis here is an updated version of section 3 in
Fernald, Edison, and Loungani (1999).

See Leamer and Stern (1970, Chapter 7) for a good discussion
of export share analysis. The effects of export competition can be
reflected not just in changes in export shares but also in export
prices or profit margins. We intend to explore these other effects
in future work.
12

Note that by focusing on shares in particular markets, we are
stacking the deck in favor of the export-competition view. A
country may have its share in a particular market decline without
necessarily experiencing a decline in the level of its exports to
that market. It may also be losing market share in one market but
gaining it in another. Furthermore, some changes in shares may
be deliberate. Several Asian economies have shifted production
toward components that are then assembled in China for export.
13

50

These shifts tend to increase China’s export shares and decrease
the shares of other economies, without having an adverse effect
on these other economies. These shifts were most pronounced in
Hong Kong (whose statistics we have combined with China’s)
and Taiwan, but to some extent affected the statistics of other
Asian economies as well.
14
A less detailed examination of the data for the European and
Japanese markets suggests broadly similar conclusions.

The results were not sensitive to the ordering of the VAR.

15

See, for example, Lardy (1998a) and Stiglitz (1998).

16

17
See Gordon and Li (2001) for a discussion of financial repression in China.
18
Of course, that capital account liberalization improves opportunities for risk diversification is one of its important benefits.
Eichengreen et al. (1998) provide a comprehensive review of the
benefits and potential costs of capital account liberalization, arguing that “... with appropriate safeguards, orderly and properly sequenced capital account liberalization and the broader financial
liberalization of which it is part are not only inevitable but clearly
beneficial.”
19
As discussed below, there is an offshore nondeliverable forwards (NDF) market in Hong Kong, where all transactions take
place in U.S. dollars, based on the underlying value of the
renminbi. Given the nonconvertibility of the underlying currency,
the existence of the NDF market does not bring much pressure
onto the renminbi.
20
This material draws heavily on Fernald and Rogers (2001). See
Fernald and Rogers for an expanded discussion of the market and
additional references.
21
In February 2001, China announced and began to implement
plans to allow domestic Chinese residents to legally purchase the
(much cheaper) “foreign” shares. The discussion here concerns
the period before that date, although it should be noted that many
Chinese investors were illegally purchasing B shares. The spike
in B-share prices in 2001 reflects the opening of the market to
domestic investors.
22
According to press reports, China raised about $21 billion on foreign equity markets in 2000 by selling off parts of the country’s
largest state enterprises. This figure is roughly double the amount
raised in each of the preceding three years. Contracted FDI inflows
soared roughly 50 percent in 2000 compared with a year earlier, although actual FDI inflows rose only 1 percent.
23
For discussions of how to deal with the bad loans of the banking
system, see Lardy (1998b) and Bonin and Huang (2001).
24
At present, foreign banks are not allowed to conduct local-currency business with domestic Chinese entities. Under the anticipated terms of China’s WTO accession agreement, however,
these restrictions will be lifted. In particular, following WTO accession, foreign banks will be allowed to conduct local-currency
business with Chinese firms after two years and with retail customers after five years.
25
China has undertaken a high-publicity anti-corruption campaign. One feature of this campaign is its focus on the financial
sector, evidenced by the arrest of several high-profile business
and bank executives. See, for example, Dow Jones (1999a,
1999b) and Faison (1999).

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

REFERENCES

Arora, Vivek, and Kalpana Kochhar, 1995, “Discrepancies in bilateral trade statistics: The case of
China,” International Monetary Fund, paper on policy analysis and assessment, No. PPAA/95/10, June.
Berg, Andrew, 1999, “The Asia crisis: Causes, policy responses, and outcomes,” International Monetary
Fund, working paper, No. 99/138, October.
Bonin, John P., and Yiping Huang, 2001, “Dealing
with the bad loans of the Chinese banks,” Journal of
Asian Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 197–214.
Borensztein, Eduardo, and Jonathan Ostry, 1996,
“Accounting for China’s growth performance,”
American Economic Review, May, pp. 224–228.
Butler, Steven, and Brian Palmer, 1997, “Slow
boat in China: Its economy slows, its banks are wobbly, is China next?,” U.S. News and World Report,
December 15.
Cerra, Valerie, and Anuradha Dayal-Gulati, 1999,
China’s trade flows: Changing price sensitivities and
the reform process,” International Monetary Fund,
working paper, No. 99/01, January.
Diamond, Douglas, and Phillip Dybvig, 1983,
“Bank runs, liquidity, and deposit insurance,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, pp. 401–419.
Dornbusch, Rudi, 1998, “Is China next?,” Financial
Times, August 4.
Dow Jones, Inc., 1999a, “China newspaper says
1998 corruption could pass $10 billion,” wire service
report, January 8.
, 1999b, “Chinese bank executive given
10-year prison term for corruption,” wire service report, January 13.
Eichengreen, Barry, 1999, Safeguarding Prosperity
in a Global Financial System: The Future International Financial Architecture, Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Michael Mussa, with
Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, Enrica Detragiache, Gian
Maria Milesi-Ferretti, and Andrew Tweedie, 1998,
“Capital account liberalization: Theoretical and practical aspects.” International Monetary Fund, occasional paper, No. 172.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Faison, Seth, 1999, “China points finger at culprit
of the week,” New York Times, January 13, p. A8.
Fernald, John G., 1999, “China and Hong Kong:
Reconciling bilateral trade statistics,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, manuscript.
Fernald, John G., and Oliver Babson, 1999, “Why
has China survived the Asian Crisis so well? What
risks remain?,” in Financial Market Reform in
China: Progress, Problems, and Prospects, Baizhu
Chen, J. Kimball Dietrich, and Yi Feng (eds.), Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 55–85.
Fernald, John G., Hali Edison, and Prakash
Loungani, 1999, “Was China the first domino? Assessing links between China and the rest of emerging
Asia,” Journal of International Money and Finance,
Vol. 18, No. 4, August, pp. 515–535.
Fernald, John G., and John Rogers, 2001, “Puzzles in the Chinese stock market,” Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.
Goldstein, Morris, 1998, The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic Implications, Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Gordon, M., 1962, The Investment, Financing, and
Valuation of the Corporation, Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Gordon, Roger H., and Wei Li, 2001, “Government
as a discriminating monopolist in the financial market: The case of China,” Journal of Public Economics, forthcoming.
Harding, James, 1998, “China: Survey—Tighter
controls increase the pain,” Financial Times, November 16.
International Monetary Fund, 1998, “The Asian
Crisis: Causes and cures,” Finance and Development, Vol. 35, June, p. 2.
Johnston, R. Barry, 1998, “Sequencing capital account liberalization,” Finance and Development,
Vol. 35, December, p. 4.
Kochhar, Kalpana, Prakash Loungani, and Mark
Stone, 1998, “The East Asian crisis: Macroeconomic
developments and policy lessons,” International Monetary Fund, working paper, No. 98/128, September.

51

Krugman, Paul, 1998, “What happened to Asia?”
conference paper, available on the web at http://
web.mit.edu/krugman/www/DISINTER.html.
Lardy, Nicholas, 1998a, “China and the Asian crisis,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 77, No. 4, pp. 78–88.
, 1998b, China’s Unfinished Economic
Revolution, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Leamer, Edward, and Robert Stern, 1970, Quantitative International Economics, Boston: Allyn and
Bacon, chapter 7.
Manning, Robert A., 1999, “The coming China
crash?,” IntellectualCapital.com, February 19.
McGraw-Hill Companies, The, 1998, “Can China
avert a crisis?,” Business Week, March 16.
O’Neill, Mark, 1998, “China: No hurry to make
yuan fully convertible,” South China Morning Post,
December 1.
Reuters, 1999a, “China warns foreign banks—‘No
lending without state approval’,” wire service report,
January 14.
, 1999b, “China vows to improve accuracy of statistics,” wire service report, January 14.

52

, 1999c, “Full text—China central bank
governor’s speech,” wire service report, January 27.
Rennie, David, 1998, “Street protests as Chinese are
bled of their savings,” Telegraph Group, London,
November 19.
Rosen, Daniel H., 1999, Behind the Open Door: Foreign Enterprises in the Chinese Marketplace, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
Sachs, Jeffrey, and Steven Radalet, 1998, “The onset of the East Asian financial crisis,” National Bureau
of Economic Research, working paper, No. 6680.
Stiglitz, Joseph, 1998, “Second-generation strategies
for reform for China,” address given at Beijing University, July 20, available on the Internet at
www.worldbank.org/html/extdr/extme/
jssp072098.htm.
Ta Kung News Group, 1998a, “China’s policy on
Asian financial crisis—Interviewing Dai Xianglong,
governor of the People’s Bank of China,” Ta Kung
Pao, November 4, p. 8, reported as FBIS document,
No. FTS19981109000541.
, 1998b, “Central bank to boost euro asset holdings,” Ta Kung Pao, December 13, p. A2, reported as FBIS document, No. FTS19990101000613.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Growth in worker quality
Daniel Aaronson and Daniel Sullivan

Introduction and summary
Improvements in worker quality due to changes in the
distribution of education and work experience are
among the key determinants of the economy’s potential rate of growth. The rate of such improvements is
thus of substantial interest to monetary and fiscal
policymakers concerned with maintaining balance
between aggregate supply and demand. It also is of
importance to officials charged with planning for the
future of programs such as Social Security, whose
projected financial condition is highly sensitive to
assumptions about long-term economic growth.
In this article we provide new estimates and forecasts of the rate of improvement in worker quality.
Consistent with previous research, we find that changes
in the distribution of workers’ education and work
experience levels account for a significant portion of
the growth in labor productivity. In particular, of the
2.7 percent average growth rate in labor productivity
since 1965, we find that about 0.22 of a percentage
point is attributable to the growth of labor quality.
We also find that this contribution has fluctuated significantly over the last 35 years. For instance, as recently as the late 1980s and early 1990s, improvements
in worker skill levels were adding about 0.40 percentage points per year to the growth of output. However,
by the end of the 1990s, this figure had fallen to about
0.18 percentage points. Our forecasts call for a further decline to about 0.05 percentage points by 2010.
The recent figures represent the combined effects
of two long-running demographic trends and a partially
offsetting business-cycle effect. The two demographic trends are the continuing increase in the education
levels of the labor force and the movement of workers toward experience levels associated with higher
wages and productivity. A major factor in the latter
trend has been the aging of the Baby Boom generation,
many of whom are now in their peak earnings years.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The positive effects of demographic change are partially offset by what has recently been the relatively
faster employment growth of low-education and lowexperience workers, the typical pattern in a businesscycle expansion.
Our forecast of a declining growth contribution
from worker quality derives from two sources. First,
we expect a slight decline in the rate of educational
gains. Second, and more important, as the decade
progresses, a significant portion of the Baby Boom
generation will move beyond the highest earnings
years that most workers experience in their early 50s.
Indeed, by the end of the decade, the leading edge of
the Baby Boom will be at an age associated with lower than average wage rates. At the same time, the age
ranges associated with maximum wages and productivity will become populated with the smaller cohorts
born in the late 1960s and early 1970s. As a result,
the change in experience levels will turn from a positive to a negative factor for worker quality growth.
We also examine the gap in labor quality between
the employed and the pool of available workers, those
who, while not working, currently report that they
want a job. We find that available workers typically
have predicted wages and productivity that are 15
percent to 20 percent lower than the employed. Over
the course of a business cycle expansion, most potential workers with higher skill levels become employed,
which tends to expand this gap. The long business
cycle expansion that began in the early 1990s is particularly notable in pushing the gap in quality between
the employed and the pool of available workers to
nearly 23 percent, its highest level in our data.

Daniel Aaronson is a senior economist and Daniel
Sullivan is a vice president and senior economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

53

The compositional changes in the labor force we
study can obscure the effects of changes in labor supply and labor demand on the price of an hour of constant quality labor. This may make it more difficult to
evaluate macroeconomic theories that have implications for the behavior of real wages. Thus, we provide
new estimates of real wage growth adjusted to a constant quality of labor hour. The resulting series is modestly more procyclical than unadjusted real wage
growth measures. We also construct an unemployment
rate for human capital that accounts for the fact that
the loss in labor input associated with unemployment
is greater when the affected worker is at a higher skill
level. The resulting measure is between 0.5 and 1.0
percentage point lower than the standard civilian unemployment rate that counts all members of the labor
force equally.
The importance of labor quality has been made
clear by the development of human capital models,
which relate productivity and wage rates to characteristics such as education and work experience. The last
35 years have seen several major shifts in the distribution of such characteristics in the labor force, most
notably the increase in the share of college-educated
workers and the influx of relatively inexperienced
women and Baby Boomers in the 1970s. In addition,
the nature of the skills learned through formal education and on-the-job training has changed, with, in
particular, a tremendous increase in workers with computer skills in the 1980s and 1990s. Human capital
models quantify the extent to which these transformations have caused the growth of total labor input to
differ from that of raw hours worked. This difference
is known as worker quality growth. It is positive when
total labor input is growing faster than the raw total
of hours worked.
As we show in this article, fluctuations in labor
quality growth have had a significant impact on trends
in output growth. Thus, by quantifying the expected
future gains in labor quality, we can improve forecasts of potential output growth. In addition, quantifying past gains in labor quality is vital to producing
productivity growth estimates that constitute a meaningful measure of our economy’s progress. Indeed,
the simple observation that accurate measurement of
productivity is critically dependent on using correctly measured outputs and inputs has been the root of a
long literature on growth accounting that dates back
to influential work by Solow (1957), Denison (1962),
and Jorgenson and Griliches (1967) and has been updated and revised by Jorgenson and his coauthors
(1987, 1999, 2000) and the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) (1993), among
others.1 One recent prominent example is Young

54

(1995), who argues that input growth explains all
the extraordinary output growth in East Asia in the
1970s and 1980s. This is very much in the spirit of
Jorgenson and Griliches (1967) and Jorgenson,
Gallup, and Fraumani (1987), who argue that proper
measurement of inputs should result in estimates of
total factor productivity growth that are close to zero.2
By more clearly articulating the trends in worker
quality, this article also contributes to improved productivity measurement.
Our measure of labor quality relies on the basic
empirical implications of human capital models. Workers invest in productivity-increasing skills through
formal education and on-the-job training. Moreover,
in long-run competitive equilibrium, firms hire additional labor until workers’ marginal productivity coincides with their wage rate. This allows us to infer
the effects of worker characteristics on productivity,
which are not directly observable, from their effects
on predicted wages, which can be estimated from
cross-sectional data. We use such wage function estimates to value additional years of education, experience, and other forms of human capital. Applying
these value estimates to the changing distributions
of human capital indicators yields estimates of the
growth in average worker quality.
The critical assumption underlying our approach
is that workers’ wage rates are equal to their marginal
productivity, a basic implication of the competitive
model of labor markets. There are, of course, models
of the labor market in which wages are not equal to
marginal products. For example, if firms discriminate
against women or minority groups or if unions or
firms exercise market power, wage rates may differ
from productivity.3 In addition, Spence (1973) argues
that firms use education and other observable human
capital variables as a signal of unobservable worker
ability. This can lead workers to invest in education
even when it provides no actual increase in productivity. Finally, implicit contract models of the type
studied by Lazear (1979) suggest that in order to induce higher effort and investment in skills, firms defer a portion of workers’ compensation until later in
their careers. This leads to wages being below productivity early in workers’ careers and above productivity in later years.
While not denying the relevance of these alternative models of the labor market in some contexts, we
are nevertheless comfortable relying on the competitive
model to provide at least a good first approximation to
the growth in worker quality. An enormous number
of empirical studies of the labor market have found
competition to be a useful framework. In contrast, there
is less evidence for the widespread relevance of the

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

alternative models. Moreover, some direct support for
the link between human capital and aggregate growth
emerges from recent studies using international macroeconomic data. Though some early research found
little correlation between changes in human capital
and output growth, studies by Heckman and Klenow
(1997), Topel (2000), and Krueger and Lindahl
(1999) show that macro and micro estimates of the
return to education are similar once adequate account
is taken of measurement error.
A bigger concern is that the available data on
worker characteristics only begin to scratch the surface in explaining the determinants of wages and productivity. For instance, the productivity increase
associated with a college degree must depend on the
program of study, the quality of the institution, and a
myriad of other factors. But typical data sources merely record whether a worker has any college degree.
Similarly, the productivity increase associated with a
year of work experience will vary with the nature of
the work, how much time is devoted to training, and
other factors. But data sources do not typically include such information. Indeed, almost all research
on worker quality growth is based on proxies for years
of work experience derived from the difference between a worker’s age and their years of formal education. Unobserved differences in time out of the labor
force due, for example, to raising children will lead
such proxies to differ from actual experience.
The existence of unmeasured differences in worker characteristics will not greatly bias estimates of
worker quality growth if the distributions of such
characteristics around their means remain relatively
fixed over time. In that case, changes over time in
mean years of schooling and age are reasonable proxies for the overall improvement in productivity due to
education and work experience. But systematic changes
in unmeasured characteristics can lead to biases. For
example, women tend to spend more time out of the
labor force than men. So the ongoing increase in female labor force participation could lead to progressively greater overestimation of the average level of
labor market experience by the usual proxy measure.
In addition, some researchers suggest that the quality
of education has changed systematically over time,
which could cause growth in true education to differ
from that suggested by increases in years of schooling. In particular, Bishop (1989) attributes a significant portion of the post-1973 slowdown in measured
productivity growth to deterioration in the quality of
education as evidenced by declining test scores. More
recently, we suspect the greatly increased use of computers in the work place has raised the quantity of onthe-job training associated with a year of work

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

experience, which could also bias estimates of worker
quality growth.
Other recent work on labor quality includes Ho
and Jorgenson (1999) and BLS (1993). Our methodology and data differ somewhat from these papers, as
we discuss in a later section. This leads to some differences in estimates of labor quality growth. However, the broad contours of our results agree reasonably
well with earlier work for periods in which our results
overlap. Together, our research and the earlier work
show that growth in labor quality has fluctuated in
important ways over time.
The quarter century after World War II was a period of especially rapid gains in worker skill levels.
Indeed, Ho and Jorgenson describe the period from
1948 to 1968 as the golden age of labor quality growth.
During this period, they estimate that rapid expansion
of secondary and post-secondary education caused
labor quality growth to average nearly 1 percent per
year. As noted above, this means that changes in the
composition of the labor force caused total labor input to grow nearly 1 percentage point more rapidly
than total hours. However, with the flood of inexperienced Baby Boomers and female workers into the labor force in the 1970s, labor quality stagnated. Then,
after 1980 as the Baby Boomers aged and educational attainment soared to new heights, labor quality accelerated again, to a growth rate of about 0.5 percent
per year, about half of that seen in the 1950s and 1960s.
Our estimates indicate that labor quality continued to
advance in the last few years, but at a yet slower rate
of only about 0.27 percentage points per year. Our
forecasts call for annual growth to decline further to
about 0.07 percentage points by 2010.
Given the standard assumptions of constant returns-to-scale production and cost minimization, the
contribution of labor input to output growth is the
product of the growth rate of labor input and labor’s
share in production costs. The latter figure is approximately two-thirds. Thus, our estimates for labor quality growth imply effects on real output growth of 0.18
percentage points late in the 1990s and 2000, declining to about 0.05 percentage points by 2010.4
In the next section of this article, we review
some of the broad trends in human capital accumulation that underlie our estimates of labor quality growth.
In the following two sections, we discuss our methodology and our detailed results.
Trends in human capital accumulation
Here, we document some of the broad trends in
human capital accumulation that underlie estimates
of worker quality growth. These are the increases
in educational attainment, fluctuations in the age

55

population of 17 year olds, the number of new high
school diplomas granted in the late 1990s was 7 percentage points lower than it was in the early 1970s.
Only when general equivalency diplomas (GEDs) are
added to the totals do recent rates match earlier levels.
However, Heckman and Cameron (1993) have shown
that GED holders typically possess considerably less
Education
human capital than high school graduates. Thus, the
U.S. levels of formal education have expanded
recent data in figure 1 should be regarded as showing
greatly over the last century. We can see this in figure
an overall deterioration in the fraction of new labor
1, which shows the increase in high school and colmarket entrants with the skills typically associated
lege graduation rates since 1870.5 During this period,
with secondary school completion.6
high school graduation went from a rarity to the norm.
College graduation rates, however, have continAs the figure shows, a good part of that transformaued to increase, though not without some significant
tion occurred during the early part of the twentieth
fluctuations. Indeed, after an especially rapid advance
century, a period Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz
during the Vietnam War era, growth in new college
(Goldin 1998, Goldin and Katz, 1999a) argue was
degrees granted actually lagged the growth in 22 year
formative for American education. College attendance
olds until the mid-1980s, when it turned up again.
and graduation rates also rose rapidly during the
More recently, growth accelerated in the early 1990s,
twentieth century. Increases in college graduation
and by the end of the last decade graduation rates
rates were especially rapid after WWII with the introwere back to the trend line established in the postduction of the GI Bill and increased growth in federal
WWII period.
funding of higher education. But even before WWII,
Increasing graduation rates have led to a corregrowth in college graduation rates was impressive.
sponding increase in the percentage of workers with
Enrollment rates quadrupled between 1940 and 1970
high school and college education. In 1964, the bebut also tripled between 1910 and 1940. This pre-WWII
ginning year for the data we use for this study, less
expansion in education levels was unique to the U.S.;
than 58 percent of workers had completed high school
education did not expand at such rates in other counor had a GED. By 2000, this figure was over 90 pertries until several decades later. These trends likely
cent. In 1964, less than 12 percent of workers had
increased potential output growth in the U.S. during
college degrees. By 2000, more than 28 percent did.
the early twentieth century relative to other develThere were also healthy increases over the same perioped nations that were slower to invest in education.
od in the share of workers with at least some college
More recently, the growth in the rate of high
education and with post-graduate education.
school completion has stalled. Indeed, relative to the
Though still significant, the growth in
average
levels of education has slowed since
FIGURE 1
its high point in the early 1960s and late
Educational attainment, 1870–2000
1970s. This can be seen in figure 2, which
plots the five-year moving average of the
percent
100
annual change in the percentage of workers
GED
with high school and college degrees.7 The
figure indicates that the increase in high
80
school graduation rates has fallen relatively
steadily from around 1.7 percentage points
60
per year at its peak in the early 1970s to only
about 0.1 percentage points the last several
40
years. Increases in college graduation rates
College
have also declined over time, but the drop
High school
20
has been smaller. Between 1970 and 1975
and again between 1978 and 1983, the in0
crease in the share of college workers peaked
1870 ’80 ’90 1900 ’10 ’20 ’30 ’40 ’50 ’60 ’70 ’80 ’90 ’00
at a rate of about 0.8 percentage points per
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce,
year. Since the mid-1980s, the advance has
Bureau of the Census (1975) and U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, Current Population Survey, 1964–2000.
been relatively stable at about 0.4 percentage points per year.
distribution, and the rising fraction of female workers.
We also note some other changes in the nature and
composition of the work force that may affect the
growth of human capital but are not usually included
in analysis of labor quality.

56

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 2

Five-year moving average of change
in percentage with high school
and college education
average annual change in percentage
2.0

High school
graduates

1.6
1.2
0.8

College
graduates

0.4
0.0
1968

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2000.

Such fluctuations in the growth of average educational levels can occur for two reasons. First, younger
workers entering the labor force are constantly replacing older workers reaching retirement age. The former
have historically had more education. Second, some of
those in the age ranges typically associated with working choose to acquire more education, often while
continuing to work part or full time.
Figures 3 and 4 shed some light on the importance
of new entrants replacing retiring workers for the increase in education levels. Figure 3 plots the difference
in high school and college graduation rates between
those near the end of their careers (55 to 59 year olds)
and those near the beginning of their careers (25 to
29 year olds). As the graph shows, in the 1960s, there
was a more than 30-percentage-point difference between the high school graduation rates of older and
younger workers. Likewise, the expansion of college
graduation rates in the 1970s led to a more than 15percentage-point difference between the college graduation rates of older and younger workers. These large
gaps between workers entering and leaving the work
force were a major factor behind the rapid growth of
average educational attainment during those periods.
But those differences, and their resulting implications
for labor quality growth, had all but disappeared by
2000. This is one of the factors underlying the slower
growth in average education levels in the 1990s seen
in figure 2.
The size of cohorts entering and exiting the labor
force also drives fluctuations in the growth of educational attainment. When the flow into the labor market of younger, more highly educated workers is

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

faster than the flow out of the labor market of older,
less highly educated workers or vice versa, the average
educational level increases more rapidly for a given
gap in the two groups’ educational attainment. These
flows are, of course, largely determined by changes
over time in the size of birth cohorts. Figure 4 provides
an indication of how cohort sizes have varied since
the mid-1960s. Specifically, the colored line shows
the percentage of the working age (18–69) population
made up of 25 to 29 year olds and the black line
shows the percentage of 55 to 59 year olds.
The figure shows that the fraction of the workingage population accounted for by early-career workers
rose from around 10 percent in the early 1960s to
nearly 14 percent in the mid-1980s. A big part of that
rise, which acted to increase the growth of average
educational attainment, was the Baby Boom generation reaching working age. The first members of that
generation reached age 25 around 1970 and its last
members reached age 25 a few years after the peak in
the share of early-career workers. Since the mid-1980s,
the share of early-career workers has dropped to
around 10.5 percent, which has contributed to the
slower pace of growth in average educational attainment. Census Bureau projections call for the 25–29
share to stabilize this decade at around 10 percent.
The share of late-career workers fluctuated somewhat less, dropping from around 8 percent in the early
1960s to a minimum of about 6.5 percent in the mid1990s, before starting to rise again. Projections are for
it to continue to rise to nearly 10 percent by 2010. The
increase in the size of retiring cohorts is a positive for
the growth in average educational attainment, but given the currently small gap in educational attainment
shown in figure 3, it is only a small positive.
Of course, many workers continue to acquire
formal education until quite late in their lives. Moreover, workers with greater formal education tend to
live longer and to remain more firmly attached to the
labor force. Thus, even without additional school attendance, the average educational attainment of a cohort of workers can rise as the less educated workers
tend to drop out of the labor force more quickly. The
combined effects of additional education and the
greater tendency for the less educated to drop out of
the labor force induces a significant increase over
time in the average educational attainment of workers from a given birth cohort. For example, figure 5
follows the cohort born between 1941 and 1945. It
shows that the fraction with college degrees increased
between 1970, when they were aged 25 to 29, and
2000, when they were 55 to 59. The colored line
shows the proportion of the whole cohort with

57

FIGURE 3

FIGURE 4

Difference in worker graduation rates:
Age 25–29 minus 55–59

Population of working age
in 25–29 and 55–59 age range

percent

percent

40

14

High school
graduates

30

25–29

12

20
10

10

College
graduates

8

0
-10
1964

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2000.

college degrees, while the black line is limited to those
working in the given year.
As the graph shows, the increase in the share reporting a college education has been quite significant.
When this cohort was between the ages of 25 and 29
in 1970, only 16.5 percent reported having a college
education. Thirty years later, the share was 25.5 percent. When we limit the samples to those who were
working, the increase in the percentage was even greater, going from about 19.3 percent to about 29.3 percent. As the gap in educational attainment between
younger and older workers narrows, the increasing educational attainment of middle-aged workers is becoming a bigger factor in the growth of educational levels.
Work experience
Workers’ labor market experience is a second
important determinant of skill levels. Until they reach
their early fifties, workers’ wage rates and, thus by
inference, their productivity, tend to increase with age.
These increases presumably reflect skills learned over
time in the labor market. As a rough indication of the
trends in labor market experience, figure 6 shows the
average age of workers between 1890 and 2000. Consistent with greater life expectancies and lower birth
rates, the average age of workers grew from 35 at the
turn of the twentieth century to over 40 at its apex in
the mid-1960s. However, starting in the late 1960s,
the first of the large Baby Boom cohorts entered the
labor force, causing the average age to drop for the
next 20 years, reaching a bottom at around 37.5 as
the last of the Baby Boomers entered the labor force
in the early 1980s. As we show later, this drop in experience levels partially offsets the labor quality

58

55–59

6
1960

’70

’80

’90

’00

’10

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2000.

improvements arising from the tremendous gains
in formal education during the 1970s. Since the
early 1980s, the aging of the Baby Boom cohort has
helped to push the average age of the working population back to about 39.5, roughly where it was in
the early 1970s.
Sex composition
The final, major and easily quantifiable change in
the composition of the labor force is the rise of female
workers, particularly during the second half of the
twentieth century. Though the gap has been narrowing
in recent decades, women tend to earn lower wages
than men of the same age and educational level. The
competitive labor market framework that we employ
in this article implies that this male–female wage gap
reflects differences in productivity, rather than discrimination or some other factors.8 One interpretation
is that the error in approximating labor market experience by age minus years of education minus six is
greater for women than men, who generally spend
less time not in the work force or attending school.
Thus among groups with the same level of measured
experience, women will tend to have less actual experience. Indeed, the wage gap between men and
women is significantly smaller at low levels of experience. Under this interpretation, it is not that women
are intrinsically less productive than men, but rather
that they have less actual labor market experience than
men of the same age and education level. Still, given
their lower wage, an increasing share of women in
the labor force lowers the growth of labor quality below that expected on the basis of age and education.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 6

FIGURE 5

College graduate rate: Population
and workers born 1941–45

Average age of the labor force, 1890–2000
years
42

percent
32

40

Workers

28

38
24

Population
36

20

16
1970

34
1885 ’95 ’05 ’15 ’25 ’35 ’45 ’55 ’65 ’75 ’85 ’95 ’05
’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2000.

Beginning after WWII, the share of female workers rose from less than 25 percent to about 38 percent
in 1970 to close to 47 percent by 1990, before flattening out during the last decade. Given their lower wage
rates, rapid increases in the share of female workers,
such as occurred in the 1950s to 1980s, tended to hold
down the growth in labor quality. This negative effect
on worker quality has diminished as the share of
women has grown more slowly over the last decade.
Other factors
While most analyses of labor quality, including
the basic estimates we present below, are based exclusively on the trends in education, age, and sex composition that we have just discussed, there are good
reasons to think that other factors may also play a role.
We have already noted that crude measures of years
of schooling or labor market experience may fail to
fully capture the accumulation of human capital when
educational or work experiences differ across workers and time. One change that we wish to highlight is
the increasing computerization of the workplace,
which may be leading to more on-the-job investment
in skills per year of labor market experience.
The 1980s and 1990s saw an explosion in the
use of computer skills. Among workers age 18 to 64,
roughly 25 percent used a computer in 1984. That
fraction grew to 37.4 percent in 1989, 46.6 percent in
1993, and 60.5 percent in 1997.9 At first glance, this
seems like an obvious improvement in the skill level
of the work force. Kreuger (1993) even attempts to
quantify the rate of return to using a computer at work
by estimating the gap in wages between otherwise
similar workers who report that they do or do not use
a computer. However, DiNardo and Pischke (1997)

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census (1975) and U.S.
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current
Population Survey, 1964–2000.

argue that similar apparent rates of return are associated with using a pencil or sitting in a chair at work.
In other words, computer usage may be associated
with higher wages because it is correlated with unmeasured ability. On average, workers with more
ability tend to have jobs that require sitting or using
a computer (or pencil) at work. Therefore, the extent
to which computer usage has added to labor quality
is subject to a great deal of uncertainty. Thus, it would
be difficult to implement a labor quality measure incorporating computer usage, even if such data were
available in a general enough form. Nevertheless, the
fact that there has been such a sharp increase in an
important form of on-the-job training highlights the
fact that simple years of labor market experience is a
rather crude measure of the human capital acquired
while working.
Finally, there have been a number of other trends
in labor force composition that may have implications
for labor quality. One is the steady increase in the
minority and immigrant portions of the working population over the last 30 years. The latter is discussed
extensively in work by Borjas (1999). Because minorities and immigrants tend to have lower wages than
natives and whites, these trends may have had an impact on worker quality growth. A second trend is the
fall in the share of married workers from around 75
percent in the mid-1960s to around 60 percent in 2000.
Research on the productivity implications of marriage, and how those vary by gender, is discussed in
Gray (1997). Finally, the share of those working part
time has fluctuated over the years. This may have
implications for productivity, since part-time workers
tend to earn lower wages.10

59

Methodology
In this section, we discuss our methodology for
summarizing the effects of the changes outlined above
in an overall measure of labor quality growth.
Data
Our labor quality estimates are derived from the
Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Current Population Survey
(CPS). The CPS, the source for such well-known statistics as the unemployment rate, is a monthly, nationally representative survey of approximately 50,000
households conducted by the Census Bureau. Importantly for our purposes, it collects basic demographic
data, such as age, race, sex, and educational attainment,
as well as data on labor market status.
Participating households are surveyed for four
months, ignored for the following eight months, and
then surveyed again for four more months. Those
households in the fourth and eighth months of their
participation are known as the outgoing rotation groups
(ORGs) and are asked some additional questions that
allow construction of an hourly wage measure. Moreover, the micro data from the ORGs are collected in
easily accessible form. The major advantage of the
ORG files is the large sample sizes (150,000 households per year) that are available. However, the data
only go back to 1979, a relatively short period for
examining labor quality.
Therefore, we base most of our results on the
CPS data for March of each year, which are available
from 1962. The advantage of the March data is that
they are supplemented with additional questions about
income, weeks worked, and usual hours worked per
week in the previous calendar year. Using data since
1975, we can compute an hourly wage as annual earnings in the last year divided by the product of usual
weekly hours and number of weeks worked in the last
year. Prior to the 1976 survey, data on usual weekly
hours are not available; but there are data on hours
worked in the week prior to the survey that we can
use to construct a wage measure. Although the March
CPS files are available starting in 1962, education is
missing in the 1963 survey. So we begin our analysis
with the 1964 data. A disadvantage of the March data
relative to the ORG files is the smaller sample sizes
(50,000 households per year). However, we find that
after 1980 when we can compute measures based on
both data sources, the March data yield a series that,
while somewhat more variable, is quite close to that
based on the ORGs.
Statistical methodology
In order to compute an index of labor quality
based on the trends surveyed in the last section, we

60

need to evaluate the impact of such variables on productivity, or on what is assumed to be the same thing,
wages. We do this by estimating linear regression
models that relate the natural logarithm (log) of workers’ wage rates to their education, age, sex, and other
characteristics. The estimated coefficients are the predicted effects of worker characteristics on wages and
productivity. Combining the estimated regression coefficients with the micro data on education, experience, and sex yields a predicted average wage. Using
the same regression coefficients to compute the predicted average wage in adjacent years isolates the
portion of aggregate wage growth that is due to changes in worker characteristics, the definition of labor
quality growth.
One could in principle use a single, fixed regression model to evaluate worker characteristics in
all years. However, because there have been major
changes over time in the valuations associated with
worker characteristics, we choose to allow the regression coefficients to vary over time. Moreover, to compute our index, we adopt a chain-weighting procedure
that bases the growth in the index from one year to
the next on the geometric average of the growth rates
in worker quality obtained using regression coefficients
in the two years.
In more detail, the first step in the construction
of our index is to estimate for each year regression
models for the log wage of the form
log Wit  Sit B t 

¤E C ¤F E H
4

4

j 1

j
it

jt

j 1

it

j
it

jt



Fi Gt  X it E t  F it ,

where log Wit is the log hourly wage of worker i in
year t, Sit is a vector of education variables, Eitj is
estimated labor market experience raised to the jth
power, Fit is an indicator variable that takes the value
one if the worker is female, and Xit is a vector of other
background variables that might affect wages, including, race, marital status, and whether the worker is
employed part time.11 We also include an interaction
between the quartic polynomial in experience and the
female indicator to allow for different rates of return
to experience between genders. We do this because,
as we discussed in the last section, the only available
measure of work experience is potential (maximum)
experience, computed as age minus years in school
minus six. Since women have more career interruptions
than men, they also have larger deviations between
actual and potential experience. The interaction terms
account for this difference by allowing a different
rate of return to potential experience across genders.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

In each year in our sample, we classify individuals
into five education categories: less than high school,
high school graduate, some college, college graduate,
and post-graduate. However, a complication arises
because a 1992 redesign of the CPS changed the educational attainment question from one on the number
of years of education to one on type of degree completed. This change caused a significant break in the
fractions of our sample in the five education categories. We employed two methods for dealing with this
problem. First, we followed the method described in
Jaeger (1997) for optimally matching CPS education
questions pre- and post-1992. Second, for the construction of 1991 to 1992 labor quality growth rates, we
collapsed the responses into three more easily comparable categories: less than high school, high school
graduates (including some college), and college graduates (including post-graduates). We then use these
three categories to compute labor quality growth for
1991 to 1992 and the five categories for all other years.
The next step of the calculation is to compute
weighted averages of predicted wages for workers in
the CPS based on coefficients for education (at), experience (bjt), female–male differential in value of
experience (gjt), and female (ft) estimated from alternative years of data

¥

Wˆits  exp ¦ Sit B s 

§

¤
4

j 1

Eitj C js 

¤FE H
4

j 1

i

j
it

js

´
 Fi G s µ ,
¶

where the s superscript on Wˆits denotes that the predicted wage is computed using coefficients estimated
from year s data. The weights given to different individuals vary for two reasons. First, the CPS is a probability sample in which different individuals have
different probabilities of being sampled. In order to
form consistent estimates of population quantities, the
Census Bureau provides weights that undo the probability sampling in expectation. Using these weights
would allow us to consistently estimate the average
predicted wage for all workers in a given year. However, our interest is not in the average worker, but rather
in the average hour worked. Those who work more
hours are, therefore, more important for this average
than those who work fewer hours. Thus, we base our
weights on the product of the usual CPS weight and
hours worked by the individual. That is, the averages
of the Wˆits are based on w it  wit hit / wit hit for
i
person i in year t, where wit is the usual
CPS weight
and hit is the number of hours worked.
Finally, for each year t, we identify growth in
average labor quality with the growth in average
predicted wages relative to year t–1 using a common

¤

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

set of rates of return to value human capital characteristics in the two years. We compute such growth
using rates of return estimated using year t–1 data,
dQt0 

¤ w Wˆ / ¤ w
 it

t 1
it

ˆ t 1
 it 1W
it 1

i

,

i

and using year t data,

dQt1 

¤ w Wˆ / ¤ w
 it

i

ˆ
 it 1W
it 1

t
it

t

.

i

Both of these ratios are estimates of the growth
in average wages that is attributable to improved
worker quality; they differ from one only because of
changes from t–1 to t in the distribution of education,
experience, and sex. Since it is arbitrary whether we
use rates of return based on estimates from year t or
t–1, we emulate the strategy of a Fisher ideal index
by taking the geometric average of the results based
on year t and t–1 regression coefficients. Thus, the
final estimate of worker quality growth in year t can
be expressed as
1/ 2

dQt  	 dQt0 s dQt1 


.

An overall index can be formed by “chaining”
together the above growth rates from an arbitrary base
level in some year. Relative to an index based on a single, fixed vector of rates of return, the advantage of
the above is that it allows for varying rates of return.
Alternative measures of labor quality
Our method of measuring labor quality differs
to some extent from that used by earlier researchers.
BLS (1993) provides a detailed account of its methodology, along with those of Jorgenson et al. (1987) and
Denison (1985). Below, we briefly describe the BLS
(1993) methods and those of Ho and Jorgenson (1999),
an updated version of Jorgenson et al.
Ho and Jorgenson split the working population
into 168 possible cells, partitioned by sex, age ranges,
education, and self-employment status. They then compute changes in hours worked and compensation per
hour for each cell. In addition to using data from the
decennial Census of Population and the CPS, their
measures of compensation include imputations of the
value of nonwage compensation that they derive from
the National Income and Product Accounts. In this
framework, the growth in total labor input is a
Tornqvist index or weighted average of the change
in log hours in the various cells, where the weights
are given by the average share of total compensation
attributable to the cell in the two years. The growth
in their labor quality index is defined as the difference

61

between this total labor input growth and the growth
in raw labor hours worked.
Ho and Jorgenson’s disaggregation of workers into
many cells allows for substantial flexibility in measuring the distribution of labor services across “types” of
workers. However, their method assumes that all workers in a given cell have equal levels of human capital,
which our regression analysis shows not to be the case.
At the same time, mean wages must be estimated based
on some relatively small samples. Thus, we prefer our
approach, which in a sense allows for a separate cell
for each individual worker in the CPS, but derives wage
estimates from a standard wage regression. This provides the maximum possible flexibility, while keeping
the number of estimated parameters relatively low.
Since fringe benefits and the value of social insurance
make up a significant fraction of total labor compensation, we are sympathetic to Ho and Jorgenson’s attempts to account for them in their wage measures.
However, splitting measures of total nonwage compensation obtained at high levels of aggregation between
different classes of workers based on factors such as
age and education is inherently arbitrary. The fundamental problem is that none of the sources of data on
wages by demographic characteristics contain information on the value of nonwage compensation. Thus,
we find it most sensible to stick to wage and salary
compensation for which there is solid data.
The methodology developed by the BLS (1993)
uses a combination of a regression approach to estimating the effect of worker characteristics on wages
that is similar to ours and a Tornqvist index computed
on a number of discrete worker cells based on characteristics that resembles Ho and Jorgenson’s methodology. Relative to Ho and Jorgenson, the major difference
is that rather than estimating average wage rates for a
large number of cells, the BLS estimates cell means
using a regression model. This eliminates the problem
of cell means based on small numbers of observations,
but the use of a constant growth rate for all workers
in a cell still represents what we think is an unnecessary constraint relative to our less restrictive analysis.
A potential strength of the BLS methodology is
its use of a special data set containing records from
the 1973 CPS matched to Social Security Administration work history files. This allows the BLS to compute actual work experience for this group of workers.
Moreover, based on a regression model estimated using this sample of 25,000 workers, the BLS imputes
actual experience for workers in all time periods.
The BLS’s imputation of actual work experience
data addresses one of the most serious shortcomings
of CPS data for measuring labor quality. However,

62

patterns of labor force participation change over time,
so it is not clear that those imputations are particularly helpful for data separated significantly in time from
1973. Moreover, such imputations may do little other
than to provide an interpretation of why certain variables affect wages. For instance, if marital status affects the level of actual experience relative to potential
experience, then marital status may be useful for predicting wages even if wages in reality only depend on
education and actual work experience. Consistent with
this possibility, the BLS approach forces the dependence of wages on such factors to be through their
effect on experience. However, it is also possible that
factors such as marital status have a direct effect on
wages in addition to any effect on work experience.
In such cases, the alternative results discussed below,
in which we include such variables in the calculation
of the quality index, may better capture their effects
on worker quality growth.
Differences in methodology may not be particularly critical to estimates of labor quality. Where samples overlap, our results are broadly similar to those
of Ho and Jorgenson (1999) and the BLS (1993). However, as we discuss below, our estimated series appear
to be somewhat less variable and to align in a more
reasonable way with the business cycle.
Forecasting labor quality growth
In this article, we also provide forecasts of labor
quality growth for the rest of this decade. These are
necessarily somewhat speculative, relying on the extrapolation of certain trends in population, educational attainment and labor force participation. We do not
attempt to forecast changes in the regression coefficients used to value education and experience. We
simply rely on the coefficients estimated in the last
year of our actual data. These are applied to simulated populations of workers defined by age, education,
race, and sex.
In constructing these simulated populations for
the rest of this decade, we start with the “middle” population projections made by the U.S. Census Bureau.
These show the likely number of U.S. residents by
one-year age group, sex, race, and Hispanic ethnicity.
We combine this information with a statistical model
predicting educational attainment on the basis of such
characteristics to obtain a simulated population broken
down by educational levels as well. That is, each cell
of the Census’s projected population is divided into
separate cells corresponding to different levels of education. The breakdown of the population into these
sub cells is determined by the statistical model to be
described below. The final step in the construction of
our simulated population is to project what fraction of

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

the people in these simulated populations will be in the
labor force. We do this also on the basis of a statistical model. We then use the 1999 regression coefficients
relating wages to worker characteristics to compute
the growth in predicted wages due to the changing distribution of age, education, and sex among the labor
force participants in the simulated populations.
Given that the Census Bureau has good information on the population of individuals not yet of working age as well as birth rates, they are in a good
position to forecast the growth and changing composition of the working-age population over the next
decade.12 These translate fairly straightforwardly into
projections for the component of labor quality based
on labor market experience.
Given that the average age of workers is projected to rise over the decade by about a year and a half
to a little over 42 years, one might expect the contribution of work experience to boost labor quality
growth over the decade. However, the contribution of
labor market experience to worker quality growth depends on the whole distribution of experience levels,
and as the decade progresses, the large Baby Boom
cohorts move beyond their peak earnings years, which
actually contributes to slowing labor quality growth.
The forces underlying our projections of the effect of experience on worker quality are illustrated
for men in figure 7.13 The upper panels of the figure
show the change in the proportion of people of a particular age. The leading edge of the Baby Boom stands
out in the graphs. In 2001, the cohort born in 1947,
which was much larger than that born in 1946 is 54
years old. Thus the first panel of the figure, which
covers the change from 2000 to 2001, has a large spike
at age 55. Birth cohorts continued to grow until the early 1960s. Thus, in the first panel there are generally
positive changes in the proportion of the population
aged 40 to 52. Of course, the sum over all ages of the
changes in the proportion of the population accounted for by each age is zero, so there are always ages
that are declining in their share of population. For instance, in the case of the panel corresponding to the
2000 to 2001 transition, most of the ages between 25
and 40 have decreasing shares of the population.
The top panel graphs in figure 7 also show the
relative wage rate associated with each age. These
are obtained from a log wage regression like those
described above, except that the quartic in experience
was replaced with a quartic in age. The coefficients
of the quartic are used to compute wages for each age
level. The plots show the percentage difference between this predicted wage and the overall mean wage
based on the base year’s distribution of ages. Thus,

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

if the value shown for a given age is 0.1, that age is
associated with wages that are 10 percent above average. The graph shows that male workers generally
earn higher than average wages between their midthirties and late fifties. The peak age for wages is in
the early fifties.
The contribution to worker quality will be greatest when there is a positive correlation between the
change in the proportion at the age and the relative
wage deviation. That is, quality grows fastest when
there are large increases in the proportion of workers
at the age levels associated with high relative wages
and large decreases in the proportion of workers at
ages associated with low relative wages. The bottom
panels in figure 7 show the product of the change in
the proportion at the age and the relative wage associated with the age. The overall contribution of the
changing age distribution to worker quality is approximately the sum of those products.
For the 2000 to 2001 transition, the positive products in the bottom panel substantially outweigh the
negatives, leading to a positive contribution to worker quality growth from the changing age distribution.
A big part of that contribution comes from the effects
of the leading edge of the Baby Boom. The age group
(55 year olds) associated with the big increase in proportion of the labor force is one that also has a high
relative wage. This implies a sizable positive contribution to labor quality growth.
The panels on the right in figure 7 show what
happens by the end of the decade. In 2010, the oldest
Baby Boomers will actually be at an age (63) associated with below-average wages. This, combined with
the movement of the smaller birth–dearth generation
into the peak earnings years, swings the overall labor
quality growth contribution of the age distribution to
negative territory.
Forecasting the effects of changes in education
requires making additional forecasts of educational
attainment and labor force participation. We make
these forecasts based on statistical models estimated
using the ORG files for the years 1992 to 1999. The
detailed methodology is described in box 1.
The approximate effects of our educational projections on labor quality growth are shown in figure
8. This figure has the same layout as figure 7, except
that instead of showing the impact of changes in the
age distribution, it shows the impact of changes in
the educational distribution. The top panels show the
projected change in the fraction of the population with
each of the five educational levels and the relative wage
rate associated with those levels. The contribution to
labor quality growth is the product of the change in

63

FIGURE 7

Effects of experience on male worker quality
Change in male age distribution 2000–01
and male relative wages 2001
relative wage

change in percent
0.6

Relative
wage

0.3

0.0

Change in age
distribution

-0.3

-0.6
15

20

25

30

Change in male age distribution 2009–10
and male relative wages 2010

35

40 45
age

50

55

60

65

change in percent

0.40

0.6

0.20

0.3

0.00

0.0

-0.20

-0.3

-0.40

-0.6

70

relative wage
0.40

Relative
wage

0.20

0.00

Change in age
distribution

-0.20

-0.40
15

20

25

30

35

40 45
age

50

55

60

65

70

Contribution to male quality growth 2000 to 2001

Contribution to male quality growth 2009 to 2010

contribution to quality growth

contribution to quality growth

0.10

0.10

0.05

0.05

0.00

0.00

-0.05

-0.05

-0.10

-0.10
15 20 25

30 35 40

45
age

50

55

60 65

70

15 20 25

30 35 40

45
age

50

55

60

65

70

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey, 1964–2000.

proportion with the relative wage and is shown in the
bottom panels. The sum of these contributions approximates the contribution of increasing education
to worker quality.
Figure 8 shows that between 2000 and 2001, the
shares of workers with less than a high school education and exactly a high school education were both falling. In contrast, the shares with some college, a college
degree, and post-graduate education were all rising.
Figure 8 also shows the relative wage rates associated
with the different levels of education. These range from
negative 45 percent for high school dropouts to positive 85 percent for those with post-graduate education.
Clearly, there is a strong positive correlation between
relative wages and growth in population share. This
positive correlation is reflected in the mainly positive
contribution estimates shown in the bottom left panel.
The sum of these contributions is substantially positive.

64

Figure 8 also shows that the effects of education
on worker quality will change only slightly by 2010.
Our predictions indicate that the rate at which the share
of high school dropouts is shrinking will decline by
about half from 0.29 percentage points to 0.14 percentage points, and that there will be a similar sized decline
in the rate at which the some college group is growing.
Given the large negative relative wage of dropouts,
the former effect has a bigger impact on labor quality growth. Thus, as the decade progresses, we predict a slightly smaller increase in labor quality growth
from improving educational attainment.
Results
Worker quality
Figure 9 displays our estimate of 1964 to 2000
labor quality growth for the working population based
on trends in the educational, experience, and sex

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

BOX 1

Forecasting trends in educational attainment and labor force participation
This section describes the statistical models that we
use to forecast trends in educational attainment and
labor force participation in order to forecast the growth
of labor quality. We begin by forecasting educational attainment as a function of age, birth year, sex and
race. We then forecast labor force participation on the
basis of those variables and educational attainment.
Let pitj  Prob < yit  j > j  1, ..., 5 be the
probability that the ith worker in year t has educational level j, where j=1 is less than high school and
j = 5 is more than college and let
qitj  Prob ¨ª yit r j yit r j  1·¹ j  2, ..., 5 be the probability that the worker reaches at least level j given
that he reached level j = 1. We fit statistical models
to predict the qitj and then recover the pitj from

pitj 

”q
j

k 2

1  qitj 1 
 . Specifically, the q j are
it

k
it 	

predicted on the basis of logistic regression models
of the form

log

qitj

1  qitj

¤D B  ¤D C
a
it

b
it

ja

a

jb

 xit H j ,

b

where the Dita and Ditb are indicator variables for the
person being age a and born in year b, respectively,
and xit is a vector of additional control variables.
Models for qitj are estimated using all those in the
ORG files from 1992 to 1999 that had education of
at least level j – 1 and met an age requirement of 18
for the high school, 19 for the some college, 22 for
the college, and 26 for the post-graduate models.
The idea behind this model is that there is a typical lifetime pattern of the probability of completing
another level of schooling. For instance, the probability of completing high school or the equivalent rises
very rapidly up to age 20, then increases only slowly
with age. According to the model, cohorts born in different years follow the same basic time pattern, but at
a uniformly higher or lower level in terms of the log
odds. Models for high school, some college, and college are estimated separately for the eight sex by race
combinations without any additional controls (xit
variables). Samples of nonwhite workers with college degrees become somewhat small, however. So

distributions of workers. The black line uses the CPS
March supplements. The colored line uses the ORG
files. As we mentioned earlier, the ORG begins in 1979
(so growth rates begin in 1980). As the ORG-based
measure is based on three times more data, the yearto-year variability of ORG-based labor quality growth
is lower.14 However, the general trends are very similar;

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

models for post-graduate education are estimated separately for men and women with race indicators included as controls. For each population cell defined
by age, birth year, sex and race, the estimated model
is used to predict the fraction in each year with each
of the five levels of educational attainment.
Our estimation samples yield birth year coefficients (bjb) corresponding to birth years for which
there are individuals in the appropriate age range in
the ORG files. But as the projection period progresses,
we also need cohort coefficients for workers born too
soon to be in the ORG files. For instance, no one born
in 1990 is included in our ORG files. Thus we have
no data from which to estimate the tendency for that
cohort to complete different educational levels. However, by 2010, many such individuals will be in the
labor force. For each race and sex combination, we
forecast these additional cohort coefficients on the
basis of a linear regression on year of birth using the
last 15 coefficients up to, but not including, the last
one estimated. (The last one estimated is based on
only one year of data and thus, especially for minority races, small sample sizes.) This admittedly ad hoc
procedure extrapolates recent trends in educational
attainment. We chose 15 years because most of those
trends appeared fairly close to constant over that period. Results are not sensitive to extrapolating based
on the last 10 or last 20 birth year coefficients.
The above procedure yields forecasts of the distribution of age, sex, and educational attainment. These
can be used to obtain forecasts of labor quality for the
whole population. However, to obtain forecasts of labor quality for workers only, we also need to forecast
labor force participation. We do that using a model
with the same form as above, except that educational
attainment becomes an additional control variable.
As with educational attainment, cohort coefficients
for birth years too late to yield workers in our data
sets are forecast from a linear regression on birth year
using the last 15 coefficients up to, but not including,
the last one estimated. For each year out to 2010,
this procedure yields a forecast of the population of
cells defined by age, race, sex, educational attainment, and labor force participation. Thus, we can
construct a forecast for labor quality in those years.

from 1980 to 2000, labor quality grew 0.50 percent
per year according to the ORG and 0.43 percent per
year according to the March supplements. Furthermore, since 1990, the ORG and March growth rates
are also similar—0.48 percent and 0.42 percent per
year, respectively. Therefore, the use of one data set
over another has little effect on any of our inferences.

65

There are several notable features of figure 9. First,
labor quality is somewhat countercyclical; peaks in the
data occur near the trough of recessions in November
1970, March 1975, November 1982, and March 1991.
This is consistent with firms reacting to economic
downturns by first dismissing low-quality workers,
resulting in an increase in the aggregate quality of the
working population (but not the full population). As
hiring heats up during expansions, workers of lower
productivity find employment more readily and labor
quality drops. Typically, toward the end of expansions,
we might expect to see labor quality growth slow
even further, as the pool of available human capital
is drained. This seems to have happened somewhat
in the 1990s but not during the 1980s expansion.
The extraordinary increase in educational attainment during the 1970s and 1980s offset any cyclical
effect from the declining pool of high human capital.

This brings us to the second notable feature of the data:
the deceleration, acceleration, and deceleration of labor quality over the last three decades. During the late
1960s and 1970s, labor quality grew by approximately 0.2 percent per year. This coincides with the beginning of the post-1973 productivity slowdown, which
lasted for two decades.15 But the slowdown in labor
quality did not last long. Beginning in the early 1980s,
the U.S. experienced a sizable acceleration in labor
quality growth, rising to 0.4 percent per year from
1979 to 1987 and close to 0.6 percent per year from
1988 to 1995. Since 1995, labor quality has decelerated to 0.27 percent per year, although there was a mild
upturn (0.36 percent per year) from 1997 to 1999, including a 0.38 percent rate of growth in 1999. In 2000,
labor quality growth fell to 0.
Figure 9 also shows our projections of labor
quality growth. As described above, these are based

FIGURE 8

Effects of education on worker quality
Change in educational distribution 2000–01
and relative wages 2001
change in percent

Change in educational distribution 2009–10
and relative wages 2001

relative wage

1.0

0.5

change in percent

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

1.0

0.5

relative wage

relative wage

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

chg. in
educational distribution

chg. in
educational distribution

-0.5

-1.0
1

2

3
education level

relative wage

4

-0.5

-0.5

-1.0

-1.0

5

Contribution to quality growth 2000 to 2001

-0.5

-1.0
1

2

3
education level

5

Contribution to quality growth 2009 to 2010

contribution to quality growth

contribution to quality growth

0.18

0.18

0.12

0.12

0.06

0.06

0.00

0.00

-0.06

-0.06

-0.12

-0.12

-0.18

4

-0.18
1

2

3
4
education level

5

1

2

3
4
education level

5

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey, 1964–2000.

66

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 9

Labor quality growth CPS March vs. ORG
percent
1.2

0.8

March

ORG

0.4

0.0

-0.4
1960 ’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

’05

’10

Note: Dashed line indicates projections.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

on projections of the labor force. Thus, they are free
from any variation due to changes in the level of unemployment. As can be seen, they decline smoothly
as the decade progresses. By 2010, they are down to
only 0.07 percent, much below the average of the
previous 35 years.
Figure 10 decomposes the growth of overall labor quality into contributions due to education, experience, and gender. The overall trends in education
and experience that we saw in figures 2 to 5 are readily apparent. The improvement in education attainment
in the 1970s and 1980s was the sole positive contributor to labor quality growth, adding 0.54 percent per
year to labor quality growth between 1965 and 1985.
The slowdown in education, particularly the lack of
further progress in reducing the fraction of high school
dropouts, resulted in a decelerating education component of labor quality growth of 0.30 percent per year
after 1985 and 0.18 percent per year after 1995.16 The
modest increase from 1997 to 1999 is the main contributor to the pickup in overall labor quality observed
in that period.
Offsetting the big increases in education during
the 1970s and 1980s was the drop in work experience
resulting from the entry of the Baby Boomers. This
cut 0.34 percentage points per year off labor quality
growth from 1965 to 1980. However, as those workers moved into age ranges associated with higher relative earnings after 1980, the contribution of labor
market experience averaged a positive 0.09 percentage points per year.
The increase in female labor force participation
has little overall impact on our labor quality growth
estimates, cutting only about 0.03 percentage points
per year over the full period. This small effect is

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

partly due to a somewhat arbitrary accounting choice.
That is, we include the effects of the female–experience
interactions in the contribution attributable to experience. This means that the only wage gap between men
and women that goes into the calculation of the female
contribution is that corresponding to zero years of
experience. Since the male–female wage gap is relatively minor for new labor market entrants, the corresponding implications for worker quality are also
minor. Given our preferred interpretation of the wage
gap, our accounting convention seems appealing. However, some might argue to include the interactions of
the female and experience terms in the female category.
Doing so would make the contribution of the female
component of the index substantially more negative.
The contribution of the experience component would
be correspondingly more positive.
The forecasts of the individual components show
that the forecast decline in quality growth over this decade is largely due to the contribution of experience becoming negative by mid-decade. The forces underlying
this projection were discussed in detail in the last section. The positive contribution to growth from increasing education levels is also forecast to decline slightly.
Given our definition of the female contribution, it is
unimportant to the projections.
Figure 11 provides an indication of how our results
change with the inclusion of an expanded list of human
capital variables available in the CPS. These are race,
gender–race, marital status, gender–marital status,
and full-time work status. As we discussed, on the
one hand, there are reasons why such variables might
affect workers’ productivity or be correlated with unmeasured variables that affect productivity, and, thus,
FIGURE 10

Quality growth due to education,
experience, gender
percent
1.5

Education

1.2
0.9
0.6
0.3
0.0

Female

-0.3

Experience
-0.6
1960 ’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

’05

’10

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

67

ought to be included in a measure of worker quality.
On the other hand, it is possible that the correlation of
such variables with wages may be due to labor market
discrimination or other reasons unrelated to productivity, in which case they ought not to be included in a
measure of labor quality. While the patterns look quite
similar, growth in the expanded labor quality index is
lower, particularly in the late 1970s and early 1980s.
This suggests that more work might be warranted to
investigate the source of correlation between these
variables and wages.
The detailed reasons for the growth in the extended
index being below the one based only on education,
experience, and sex are shown in figure 12. Race has
evidently had little impact and, since 1976, the same
is true for full-time/part-time status. But steady drops
in marriage rates have consistently been a drag on the
extended measure of labor quality growth.
Table 1 presents growth rates in labor quality by
gender, industry, and region. For comparison, the top
row presents overall trends. The results are split into
business cycle periods with the first column presenting
the average growth rate over the full 35-year period.
Rows 2 and 3 stratify the sample by sex. Since
1965, female labor quality has grown faster than male
labor quality by 0.15 percent per year.17 There has been
a remarkably stable 0.13 percentage point per year
difference in growth rates between the two sexes for
most of the sample—except the 1980s, when the difference expanded to 0.26 percent per year.
Productivity analysts have been concerned with
explaining differences in productivity growth across
industries and regions. Our results show that some
of those differences reflect differences in the growth

rates of labor quality. Table 1 shows that labor quality
has grown fastest in agriculture, durable and nondurable manufacturing, and transportation, communication, and public utilities (TCPU) over the last 35 years.
Lagging industries include retail trade and construction. All industries follow the general overall trend of
lower growth in the late 1960s and 1970s, followed
by accelerating growth during the 1980s and early 1990s.
However, some—for example, nondurable manufacturing and construction—experience more variable labor quality growth, while others—for example, services
and government—grow more steadily. Over the last
five years, labor quality growth has been particularly
strong in durable manufacturing and weakest in mining, agriculture, construction, and services.
Finally, labor quality in the south (East South Central and South Atlantic) and east (Mid Atlantic and New
England) has grown quickly since 1965, while the west
(Mountain and Pacific) has lagged behind. Since 1995,
the midwestern region has experienced the fastest labor quality growth and the western region the slowest.

FIGURE 11

FIGURE 12

Effects of including other human
capital variables

Quality effects due to race, married,
full-time status

Labor quality growth of nonworkers
The results above provide evidence on labor quality growth of the working population. However, in
light of the rise in employment-to-population ratios
over the last five years and the ensuing concern about
the size of the pool of available workers, we are also
interested in evaluating quality growth trends among
those who are available and interested in jobs, but not
currently at work. Therefore, in this section, we report
results for the quality of the potential work force.
Figure 13 presents one view of this. The colored
line represents the labor quality growth of workers

percent

percent

0.50

1.2

Basic human
capital variables

Full-time

0.8

0.25

0.4

0.00

0.0

-0.4
1964

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

68

Race

-0.25

Add race
married, full time

Married
’00

-0.50
1964 ’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

TABLE 1

Labor quality growth, by gender, industry, and region
1964–00

1964–71

1972–77

1978–86

1987–94

1995–00

All workers

0.33

0.15

0.23

0.40

0.58

0.22

Men
Women

0.40
0.55

0.23
0.37

0.36
0.49

0.49
0.75

0.59
0.72

0.25
0.30

Construction
Durables
Nondurables
TCPU
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Services
FIRE
Government
Agriculture
Mining

0.21
0.43
0.46
0.39
0.31
0.11
0.32
0.34
0.34
0.45
0.41

0.12
0.12
0.27
0.03
0.28
-0.10
0.20
0.27
0.03
0.25
0.46

0.07
0.24
0.16
0.40
0.21
–0.13
0.44
0.16
0.38
0.77
–0.45

0.27
0.61
0.60
0.63
0.07
0.18
0.44
0.30
0.48
0.27
0.94

0.46
0.52
0.83
0.61
0.58
0.41
0.42
0.76
0.39
1.01
0.90

0.06
0.63
0.30
0.19
0.43
0.15
0.06
0.13
0.44
–0.06
–0.37

New England
Mid Atlantic
East North Central
West North Central
South Atlantic
East South Central
West South Central
Mountain
Pacific

0.37
0.39
0.34
0.36
0.46
0.53
0.36
0.19
0.20

0.21
0.26
0.11
–0.11
0.39
0.60
0.18
0.37
–0.09

0.33
0.34
0.06
0.31
0.51
0.38
0.35
–0.34
0.07

0.36
0.39
0.32
0.37
0.49
0.43
0.56
0.46
0.29

0.74
0.64
0.54
0.53
0.65
0.79
0.45
0.34
0.52

0.07
0.21
0.52
0.48
0.17
0.47
0.05
0.00
–0.01

Notes: TCPU is transportation, communication, and public utility. FIRE is financial, insurance, and real estate.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey,
1964–2001.

and the black line represents labor quality growth of
the entire labor force. The latter includes workers plus
those who are unemployed (that is, searching for
work).18 Not surprisingly, the graphs line up quite well
since most of the labor force is employed. The most
important differences arise during recessions when
hoarding of higher-skilled workers leads to a more rapid increase in the labor quality of the working than
the unemployed.
A more comprehensive view of the quality of
available workers is presented in figure 14. Here, we
link two groups together—those unemployed (searching) and those not in the labor force (not searching)
but who want a job—and refer to them as the group
of available workers.19 Figure 14 reports the ratio of
the labor quality of workers to the labor quality of
available workers.20 For example, if the ratio is 1.18,
it implies that the labor quality of the employed is 18
percent higher, on average, than the quality of the
average available worker. If the ratio increases, the
quality of workers is growing faster than the quality
of available workers. If the ratio decreases, the quality of available workers is growing faster than the quality of workers.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

From 1965 to the early 1990s, the labor quality
ratio remained roughly flat, bouncing between 1.15
(during recessions) and 1.20 (at the end of expansions).21 However, in the last five years, the labor quality of workers has risen steadily faster than the quality
of available workers. By 2000, an average employed
worker had 21.5 percent higher human capital than
an average available worker; this is just off the highest that this ratio has been over the 35-year sample
period which was reached in 1999. The jump in the
last five years is due to relative changes in both education and work experience between the two groups.
Among the employed, high school and college graduation rates have increased by 0.5 percentage points
and 1.7 percentage points, respectively, since 1995,
but, among available workers, high school graduation
rates have dropped by 0.5 percentage points and college graduation rates have increased by only 0.7 percentage points. Furthermore, the average age of a
worker has increased by 0.9 years, but the average
age of an available worker has dropped by 0.8 years.
Moreover, it seems likely that the ratio of labor
qualities shown in figure 14 underestimates the true
ratio. As we have noted, the reported information on

69

FIGURE 13

FIGURE 14

Quality growth of workers
vs. labor force

Ratio of labor quality of employed workers
to available workers

percent

ratio

1.2

1.3

All workers

0.8

Labor
force

1.2

0.4
1.1

0.0

-0.4
1964

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

education and age barely begins to summarize the differences between workers’ skill levels. There are many
differences in the quality of education, actual labor
market experience, and the like that are unmeasured
in the CPS. It seems likely that those in the pool of
available workers would also have a worse distribution of such characteristics. This would lead to the
ratios in figure 14 being underestimated. Somewhat
more speculatively, the business-cycle-related swings
in the quality ratio may also be underestimated.
Related measures
In addition to being an input into forecasts of longrun output growth and improved measures of productivity, such as in Basu, Fernald, and Shapiro (2000),
our labor quality measures can also be used to adjust
measures of wage growth to better reveal fluctuations
in the price of a raw hour of labor and to provide a more
comprehensive measure of the extent of unemployed
labor resources.
Fluctuations in standard measures of aggregate
wage growth confound the effects of changes in the
price of a constant unit of labor with changes in worker quality. In particular, some portion of the increase
in measured wage rates reflects changes in the distribution of education and work experience rather than
actual changes in the price of a constant unit of labor
services. Using our measure of labor quality growth,
however, it is straightforward to adjust measures of
aggregate wage growth to reveal fluctuations in the true
price of labor services. Such a measure could help to
clarify the nature of business cycles. For instance, simple equilibrium business cycle models can only account
for the relatively substantial fluctuations in hours
worked if the real wage is significantly procyclical.

70

1.0
1964

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

One measure of the price of raw labor is shown
in figure 15. The black line is just the standard growth
rate in real hourly compensation in the business sector. 22 The colored line is our adjusted measure obtained
by subtracting our measure of labor quality growth.
As we have noted already, on average, labor quality
grew by roughly 0.33 percent per year over the last
35 years. However, the cyclical nature of labor quality growth implies the most important labor quality
adjusted differences in compensation growth occur in
or near recessions. For example, in March 1992, real
hourly compensation growth increased 2.0 percent,
but 0.9 percent of this gain was due to improvements
in the quality of the labor force. Therefore, the price
of raw labor increased only 1.1 percent over the previous March. Over the last four years, real hourly compensation has grown about 2.2 percent; the labor quality
adjusted growth rate is 1.9 percent. Thus, adjusting
for labor quality growth does make real wage growth
appear somewhat more procyclical.
The adjustments to the price of labor reported in
figure 15, while noticeable, do not greatly increase the
extent to which real wages appear to be procyclical.
Thus, they do not greatly change the evidence on the
plausibility of simple equilibrium business cycle models. However, as noted above, it is possible that our
results, which rely only on a few observable worker
characteristics, underestimate the effects of worker
quality in masking procyclical wage growth. For instance, Solon et al. (1994) find a larger compositional
effect using longitudinal data that control for changes
in unobserved worker differences.
Our labor quality growth measures can also help
to clarify the cost of unemployed labor resources.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

As we have seen, the characteristics of the labor
force have changed significantly over the last 35
years, with educational levels improving at varying
rates and typical labor market experience levels first
falling then rising. Using the cross-sectional relationship between these characteristics and wage rates

allows us to infer that the pace of improvement in
worker quality has varied over time from a low of
around 0.15 percent per year between 1964 and 1971
to a peak of around 0.58 percent per year between
1987 and 1994. In the period since 1995, we find that
worker quality improvement had slowed to about
0.27 percent per year. Largely because the Baby
Boom generation will be moving beyond their peak
earnings years, we forecast that worker quality improvement will slow further over the remainder of
this decade to a rate of about 0.07 percent per year.
In addition to such long-run variation in the pace
of worker quality improvement, we observe shorterrun fluctuations associated with the business cycle. In
particular, average worker quality improvement tends
to be especially rapid during downturns, as those with
lower predicted wages are more likely to become unemployed or leave the labor force. Conversely, as
more and more workers are drawn into the labor force
over the course of a long expansion, there is a tendency for worker quality growth to slow.
A related finding is that the gap in predicted quality between the employed and the pool of available
workers widens over the course of an expansion. That
pattern was particularly pronounced over the course of
the long expansion that began in the early 1990s, with
the gap between the average predicted wage rate for
workers and that for the pool of available workers
reaching an all-time high of 23 percent in 1999.
Correcting for variation over time in average
worker quality implies a modestly more procyclical
pattern to real wage growth. It also shows that

FIGURE 15

FIGURE 16

Growth of price of raw labor private hourly
compensation deflated by CPI

Unemployment rate adjusted
for labor quality

Because workers differ significantly in their levels of
human capital, the standard unemployment rate,
which counts every member of the labor force equally, does not fully capture variation in the level of unutilized labor resources. In particular, there is a
greater loss of output when high-productivity workers are unemployed than when low-productivity
workers are unemployed. Figure 16 shows an alternative measure of unemployed human capital based
on our labor quality estimates that does allow for differences in worker productivity. This is estimated by
computing the unemployment rate of the March CPS
labor force, weighted by our gauge of labor quality.
The colored line in figure 16 shows our qualityadjusted unemployment rate. In general, accounting
for human capital accumulation reduces the unemployment rate by 0.5 to 1.0 percentage points. Most
recently (March 2001), the CPS unemployment rate
drops from 4.4 percent to 3.6 percent, after labor
quality adjustments are included. These figures indicate that because higher skilled workers are less likely to be unemployed, the standard unemployment
measure overestimates the fraction of human capital
that is not being utilized.
Conclusion

percent

percent
12

4

Nonfarm
business

2

6

0

-2

CPS
unemployment rate

9

Nonfarm business
adjusted for LQ

-4
1964

’68

’72

’76

CPs unemployment
rate adjusted for LQ

3

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

Note: The real compensation measure is the nominal hourly
compensation measure reported in the Bureau of Labor
Statistics’ productivity report deflated by the CPI.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

’00

0
1964

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

Note: CPS unemployment rate and unemployment rate adjusted
for labor quality are computed for March of each year.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population
Survey, 1964–2001.

71

depending on the state of the business cycle, the rate
of unemployment of total human capital is between
0.5 and 1.0 percentage points lower than the standard
civilian unemployment rate that counts all members
of the labor force equally.
Finally, while our current findings provide substantial insight into the determinants of long-term productivity growth, it should be recognized that the
measures of worker characteristics on which our work
is based are quite crude. Levels of formal schooling
and years of potential labor market experience only

begin to scratch the surface in predicting productivity
and wage rates. While we find that including in our
analysis additional characteristics such as race, marital
status, and part-time status led to only modest changes
in our conclusions, even these characteristics likely
fail to capture the full range of human capital determinants that may be evolving in ways significant for
productivity growth. Extending the analysis to other
data sources that contain a richer characterization of
the determinants of workers’ wages may be a priority
for future research.

NOTES
1
A recent innovation has been the use of longitudinal firm-level data
to measure not only the factors that underlie productivity growth
but also the extraordinary amount of heterogeneity and persistence
in productivity growth across manufacturing firms. See Bartelsman
and Doms (2000) and Hulten (2000) for recent surveys.
2
Topel (2000) criticizes this line of research for, among other reasons, the difficult measurement issues involved, including the
complexity of distinguishing capital and labor returns in a simple
Cobb–Douglas framework and the limitations of human capital
measures.
3
See Altonji and Blank (2000) for a review of the labor market
discrimination literature and Lewis (1986) for a review of the
union literature.
4
That is, two-thirds of labor quality growth rates of 0.27 percentage points and 0.07 percentage points equals approximately 0.18
percentage points and 0.05 percentage points of output growth.

New high school and college graduates are compared to, respectively, the population of 17 year olds and 23 year olds. These figures were obtained from the National Center for Education Statistics
website at http://nces.ed.gov/ and the U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census (1975).
5

6
Unfortunately, the data we use to construct our measures of labor
quality do not distinguish between high school graduates and
GED holders. Given the more rapid growth in the latter, this may
imply some overestimation of the rate of quality improvement.
7
Because of the lack of strict comparability between the 1991 and
1992 figures, this change is left out of the moving averages. For the
five years effected, the average is based on only four years of data.
8

See Altonji and Blank (2000) for a review of the literature.

14
The standard deviation of the 1980 to 2000 annual growth rates
is 0.27 for the March data and 0.16 for the ORG data. Our March
estimates are actually slightly less variable than those of Ho and
Jorgenson. For comparable years in our samples (1965 to 1995),
the standard deviation of Ho and Jorgenson’s annual measure is
0.37 percent versus 0.31 percent for ours. We use the quality series reported in table B2 of Ho and Jorgenson.
15
Bishop (1989) argues that a drop in labor quality, as measured
by test scores, explains much of the productivity slowdown during
the 1970s.
16
As we noted earlier, growth in educational attainment of older
workers has been particularly strong in the last decade. The labor
quality of workers aged 50 to 59 increased by 0.72 percent per year
during 1996 to 2000. By comparison, over the same period, labor
quality of workers in their thirties grew 0.28 percent per year, and
labor quality of workers in their forties fell by 0.22 percent per year.
17
Note that labor quality growth for both men and women is higher
than for workers overall. This reflects the negative effects on overall quality growth of a growing fraction of female workers.
18
Because unemployed workers have no hours worked, our labor
quality measure is weighted by CPS population weights only. For
comparison purposes, the colored line also is weighted by CPS
population weights.
19
Prior to 1976, the CPS does not ask about wanting a job. Therefore, we include the unemployed from 1964–75 and the unemployed plus those not in the labor force who are available for
work from 1976 to the present.

¤ Wˆ / ¤ Wˆ where the
numerator is weighted by w h / ¤ w h and the denominator
is weighted by w h / ¤ w h .
The ratio is computed as

0
it

20

workers

0
it

available

it it

it it

workers

These are computed from the October supplements of the Current Population Survey.
9

10

See Aaronson and French (2001).

All of the results in this paper are very robust to some common
differences with other papers, including controlling for state of
residence, using age instead of potential experience, and eliminating government, self-employed, and private household workers
from the sample.

11

Of course, changes in immigration policy could make a significant difference to that composition.

12

The forces determining the contribution of work experience to
labor quality for women are very similar.

13

72

it it

it it

available

21
Educational attainment gains were fairly similar across groups
between 1964 and 1995. The rate of high school graduation of
employed workers grew from 58 percent to 90 percent, a gain of
32 percentage points, and from 41 percent to 75 percent among
available workers, a gain of 34 percentage points. Likewise, college graduation rates grew from 12 percent to 26 percent among
the employed and 3 percent to 11 percent among available workers. The average age of each group dropped by about two years.
22
The real compensation measure is the nominal hourly compensation measure reported in the BLS productivity report deflated
by the CPI. The adjusted growth rate subtracts the growth in
worker quality.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

REFERENCES

Aaronson, Daniel, and Eric French, 2001, “The
effect of part-time work on wages: Evidence from
the Social Security rules,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, working paper.
Altonji, Joseph, and Rebecca Blank, 2000, “Race
and gender in the labor market,” Handbook of Labor
Economics, Vol. 3C, Amsterdam: North Holland.
Barro, Robert, and Jong-Wha Lee, 1993, “International comparisons of educational attainment,” Journal
of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp. 363–394.
Barro, Robert, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 1995,
Economic Growth, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bartelsman, Eric, and Mark Doms, 2000, “Understanding productivity: Lessons from longitudinal microdata,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 38,
No. 3, pp. 569–594.
Basu, Susanto, John Fernald, and Matthew Shapiro, 2000, “Productivity growth in the 1990s: Technology, utilization, or adjustment?,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, mimeo.
Benhabib, Jesse, and Mark Spiegel, 1994, “The
role of human capital in economic development: Evidence from aggregate cross-country data,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 34, No. 2, pp. 143–174.
Bils, Mark, and Peter Klenow, 1998, “Does schooling cause growth or the other way around?,” National Bureau of Economic Research, mimeo, No. 6393.
Bishop, John, 1989, “Is the test score decline responsible for the productivity growth decline?,” American
Economic Review, Vol. 79, No. 1, pp. 178–197.
Borjas, George, 1999, Heaven’s door: Immigration
policy, and the American economy, Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Card, David, 1999, “The causal effect of schooling
on earnings,” Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol.
3A, Amsterdam: North Holland.
Card, David, and Alan Krueger, 1992, “Does
school quality matter? Returns to education and the
characteristics of public schools in the United
States,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100,
No. 1, pp. 1–40.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Denison, Edward, 1985, Trends in American Economic Growth, 1929–1982, Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
, 1962, Sources of Economic Growth in
the U.S. and the Alternative Before Us, New York:
Committee for Economic Development.
DiNardo, John, and Jorn-Steffen Pischke, 1997,
“The returns to computer use revisited: Have pencils
changed the wage structure too?,” Quarterly Journal
of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 1, pp. 291–303.
Goldin, Claudia, 1998, “America’s graduation from
high school: The evolution and spread of secondary
schooling in the Twentieth Century,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 345–374.
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence Katz, 1999a,
“Education and income in the early 20th Century:
Evidence from the Prairies,” National Bureau of
Economic Research, mimeo, No. 7217.
, 1999b, “The shaping of higher education: The formative years in the United States, 1890–
1940,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13,
No. 1, pp. 37–62.
Gray, Jeffrey, 1997, “The fall in men’s return to
marriage: Declining productivity effects or changing
selection?,” Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 32,
No. 3, p. 481–504.
Heckman, James, and Stephen Cameron, 1993,
“The nonequivalence of high school equivalents,”
Journal of Labor Economics, Part 1, Vol. 11, No. 1,
pp. 1–47.
Heckman, James, and Peter Klenow, 1997, “Human capital policy,” University of Chicago, mimeo.
Ho, Mun, and Dale Jorgenson, 1999, “The quality
of the U.S. work force, 1948–95,” Harvard University, Mimeo.
Hulten, Charles, 2000, “Total factor productivity:
A short biography,” National Bureau of Economic
Research, mimeo, No. 7471.
Jaeger, David, 1997, “Reconciling the old and new
Census Bureau education questions: Recommendations for researchers,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 300–309.

73

Jorgenson, Dale, and Kevin Stiroh, 2000, “Raising
the speed limit: U.S. economic growth in the Information Age,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.
Jorgenson, Dale, Frank Gallop, and Barbara
Fraumeni, 1987, Productivity and U.S. Economic
Growth, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Jorgenson, Dale, and Zvi Griliches, 1967, “The
explanation of productivity change,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34, No. 3, pp. 249–283.
Krueger, Alan, 1993, “How computers have changed
the wage structure: Evidence from microdata, 1984–
1989,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108,
No. 1, pp. 33–60.
Krueger, Alan, and Mikael Lindahl, 1999, “Education for growth: Why and for whom,” Princeton University, mimeo.
Lazear, Edward, 1979, “Why is there mandatory
retirement?,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87,
No. 6, pp. 1261–1284.
Lewis, H. Gregg, 1986, “Union relative wage effects,”
Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 2, Amsterdam:
North Holland.
Mincer, Jacob, 1974, Schooling, Earnings, and Experience, New York: Columbia University Press.

74

Solon, Gary, Robert Barsky, and Jonathan A.
Parker, 1994, “Measuring the cyclicality of real
wages: How important is composition bias?,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109, No. 1,
February, pp. 1–25.
Solow, Robert, 1957, “Technical change and the aggregate production function,” Review of Economics
and Statistics, Vol. 39, No. 2, pp. 65–94.
Spence, A. Michael, 1973, “Job market signaling,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 87, No. 3,
pp. 355–374.
Topel, Robert, 2000, Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3C, A. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.), Amsterdam: North Holland.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the
Census, 1975, Historical Statistics of the United
States, Colonial Times to 1970, Washington DC:
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1993, Labor Composition and U.S. Productivity Growth, 1948–90, bulletin, No. 2426.
Young, Alwyn, 1995, “The tyranny of numbers:
Confronting the statistical realities of the East Asian
experience,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 110, No. 3, pp. 641–680.

4Q/2001, Economic Perspectives

Index for 2001
Title & author

Issue

Pages

BANKING, CREDIT, AND FINANCE
Market discipline and subordinated debt:
A review of some salient issues
Robert R. Bliss

First Quarter

24—45

The financial performance of pure play Internet banks
Robert DeYoung

First Quarter

60-75

Competition among banks: Good or bad?
Nicola Cetorelli

Second Quarter

38—48

Stock margins and the conditional probability of price reversals
Paul Kofman and James T. Moser

Third Quarter

2-12

The value of using interest rate derivatives to manage risk
at U.S. banking organizations
Elijah Brewer, William E. Jackson, and James T. Moser

Third Quarter

49-66

ECONOMIC CONDITIONS
Growth in worker quality
Daniel Aaronson and Daniel Sullivan

Fourth Quarter

53-74

INTERNATIONAL ISSUES
Evidence of the North-South business cycle
Michael A. Kouparitsas

First Quarter

46-59

The credit risk-contingency system of an Asian development bank
Robert M. Townsend and Jacob Yaron

Third Quarter

31-48

Countering contagion: Does China’s experience offer a blueprint?
Alan G. Aheame, John G. Femald, and Prakash Loungani

Fourth Quarter

38-52

REGIONAL ISSUES
Are the large central cities of the Midwest reviving?
William A. Testa

Second Quarter

2-14

Polycentric urban structure: The case of Milwaukee
Daniel P. McMillen

Second Quarter

15-27

Private school location and neighborhood characteristics
Lisa Barrow

Third Quarter

13-30

MONEY AND MONETARY POLICY
The crisis of 1998 and the role of the central bank
David A. Marshall

First Quarter

2-23

Central banking and the economics of information
Edward J. Green

Second Quarter

28-37

Electronic bill presentment and payment—Is it just a click away?
Alexandria Andreeff, Lisa C. Binmoeller, Eve M. Boboch, Oscar Cerda,
Sujit Chakravorti, Thomas Ciesielski, and Edward Green

Fourth Quarter

2-16

Liquidity effects in the bond market
Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau

Fourth Quarter

17-35

To order copies of any of these issues, or to receive a list of other publications, please telephone (312)322-5111 or
write to: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Public Information Center, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, IL 60690-0834.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

75