View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

li

ill)

(G)

rr rr(6\

(CIi

(G)

April 2, 1982

Underlying Inflation
Recently the inflation outlook has been
improving. Consumer prices rose at just a
3.0-percent annual rate during the JanuaryFebruary period, compared with a 5.5percent rate in the prior two months and 8.4
percent over the past 12 months as a whole.
Some analysts fear that the good news will
not last, since inflation had fallen sharply last
spring, only to rise in the fall by more than it
had declined. This time, however, the prospects are good that the current break in
inflation will last for some time. Indeed, the
seesawing pattern in prices appears to be
around a declining trend, with the peak
having been reached in the first half of 1980.
Underlying and actual inflation
We may distinguish-here between the actual
and underlying rate of inflation. The former
may be measured by any number of indexes,
for example, the consumer-price index estimates the average price of items consumers
purchase-while the G N P implicit deflator
provides a more inclusive measure, since it
includes items produced not only for households but for other sectors as well. Actual
rates of inflation are often quite volatile
because of sharp, short-term changes
occurring in specific items, such as agricultural and energy prices.

The underlying rate is basically a measure of
trend movements in the actual index, and
therefore does not exhibit the sharp, transichanges of the actual measure. It provides a clearer picture of basic movements in
prices, which are often obscured by transitory
price shocks.
What are the forces generating price trends?
Some analysts emphasize average movements in factor costs-for example,
Harvard's Otto Eckstein measures the "core"
rate as the trend of unit labor and capital
costs. Another view emphasizes trend movements in the money supply as the basic force
determining underlying inflation. Here we

have estimated the underlying inflation rate
on the basis of changes in the M-1 money
supply (currency and checking-type
deposits).
This raises the question-what is the appropriate
of the money supply?
Recently, a number of institutional and financial innovations have occurred-such as a
phenomenal increase in the use of moneymarket mutual funds and the nation-wide
introduction of N OW accounts-and these
have led the public to change the traditional
proportions of their money holdings relative
to their income and to market interest rates.
Some evidence suggeststhat the two types of
changes have roughly offset each other, and
that M-1 growth (fully adjusted for such
innovations) grew at approximately the measured rate of 5 percent in 1981. Hence, we
make this assumption in our inflation
esti mates.
Divergence in late 19705
The inflationary problem can be illustrated by
comparing our estimated underlying rate
with the actual rate (as measured by the GN P
implicit deflator). In 1975, for example, both
actual and underlying inflation declined after
the earl ier shocks created by food and energy
pressures plus wage-and-price decontrol.
However, with the recovery from these
shocks, the actual inflation rate diverged
sharply from the u nderlyi ng rate, fall i ng twice
as rapidly between the first half of 1975 and
the first half of 1976. From late 1976 through
1977, in contrast, food and energy prices
were exceptionally stable, so that actual and
underlying inflation moved in parallel during
that time.

But trouble was on the way. In the next
several years, inflation worsened substantially by any measure. The sawtoothed path
of the actual rate reflected sharp increases in
food prices in 1978, plus major energy price
jolts in 1979 and 1980. Measured inflation
moved from 6.0 percent in 1977 to 9.7

C)plnions
01 rhe

or of P-If>
Re:ief'Ve

-__--------_
..

C-'><FHf:S';ed
in
nevvslettc'f do liot
rei lect the vievv':, 01 the rnanagernent
Resen/t:: Bank of San Franci<;co,
BOdt'd ()j COvPi Tlorsof the Federal

-._-_
...-.__
....------_

•..

_

_-_._---_._--'

•.

ments of the Teamsters, Ford and General
Motors workers-with their emphasis on
wage concessions-are especially important
since these contracts largely set the trend for
smaller unions.

percent in 1980. Over the same period, the
underlying rate also soared, but not quite so
high -from about 5.5 percent to 8.5 percent.
Influence of money growth
This buildup in the underlying inflation rate
can be traced to a steady increase in monetary growth after allowing for a two-year lag
between monetary and inflation changes.
The M-1 money supply increased from 5.0
percent in 1975 to 8.2 percent in 1 978roughly equal to the rise in underlying inflation in the 1 977-80 period.

Deficits and inflation
The outlook has been darkened, however, by
the issue of deficits and inflation. According
to the Administration's February estimates,
Federal budget deficits will reach $98.6
billion and $91 .5 billion in 1 982 and 1 983,
respectively. But with the worsening economy, according to Treasury Secretary Regan,
those deficits will be somewhat greater than
first estimated.

In 1981 , we again experienced sharp gyrations in measured inflation with a dip to an
8.0-percent rate in the first half followed by a
jump to a 9.7-percent rate in the last half of
the year. Most of the sharp decline and
bounceback was due to the special factors of
oil and food price movements. Currently we
are seeing another big drop in inflation,
reflecting lower energy prices. And again, we
may see some rebound in the inflation
indexes-but a smaller rebound this time
because underlying forces are exerting strong
downward pressures.

Large deficits during recession periods largely
reflect cyclically-related reductions in tax
revenues and increased expenditures for
programs such as unemployment compensation. As such, the increased deficit results
from weakened demand and is generally
associated with reduced inflationary pressures.
Once the recovery is underway, the bulge in
the deficit largely disappears. Unfortunately,
the current budget problem is one of continued deficits even as private demands
recover.

The underlying rate indeed appears to have
peaked during the first half of 1 980. In 1 982
and 1983, the downward movement could
become more pronounced because of an
appreciable slowdown in money growth.
The growth rate of the M-1 money supply
decelerated from an 8.0-percent rate in the
1978-79 period to a 6.0-percent rate in the
1980-81 period -and the top of its target
range this year is 5112percent. With no major
commodity-price shocks, the actual and
underlying rates could again be as close
together as they were in the 1 976-1 977
episode.

do deficit increases necessarily lead to
increases in inflation? According to one view,
deficits tend to be inflationary because the
Federal Reserve often acts to smooth interestrate movements rather than money-supply
movements. In other words, when deficits
place upward pressure on interest rates, the
Federal Reserve tends to increase the money
supply, thereby' creating future inflationary
pressures. Some economists have found evidence of such trends in the historical record
of the 1960s and 1970s. Nonetheless, the
association which was relevant in the past
several decades may not be valid for the
1980s. The Fed, in other words, need not ease
its policy in the face of substantial deficits.
Indeed, since October 1979, the Fed has held
firmly to its announced intentions to improve
its control of monetary growth and to seek

From the labor-cost standpoint, the near-term
outlook also appears promising. The deceleration of consumer prices is now tempering
inflation expectations, which in turn are
acting to dampen wage demands. The agree-

2

reduced rates of monetary expansion. Subsequently, monetary growth has declined
from 7.2 percent in 1980 to 5.0 percent in
1981. With the continuation of the Fed's

present policy, then, the historical inflationary impact of deficit financing should not be
as evident in the 1980s as it was in earlier
decades.

RoseMcElhattan

.;

Change(%)

10

8

6
4

.

. /

Underlying
GN P Implicit Price Deflator

2

o

1975

1977

1979

1981

Underlying inflation for 1982-83 period estimated on basis
of M-1 money growth of between 4 and 5.5 percent.

3

1 983

!!EMEH •

I

• 4Eln •
E!UJOj!lE:::> •

((j):J)<§
Y:J)
@AJJ@<§@@
JJ\ill (0)

BANKING DATA-TWELfTH FEDERALRESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Loans(gross,adjusted)and investments*
Loans(gross,adjusted)- total #
Commercial and industrial
Realestate
Loansto individuals
Securitiesloans
U.s. Treasurysecurities*
Other securities*
Demand deposits - total#
Demand deposits - adjusted
Savingsdeposits - total
Time deposits - total#
Individuals, part. & corp.
(Largenegotiable CD's)
Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures
Member Bank ReservePosition
ExcessReserves(+ )/Deficiency (- )
Borrowings
Net free reserves(+ )/Net borrowed(- )

JJdI
((j)

'Jllt?JIO:.lSpUt?J:I
ut?S
lSL 'ON IlW1Bd
Ol\ld
19\1ISOd 's'n
11\1WSS\l1J ISHI:I

SelectedAssetsand Liabilities
LargeCommercial Banks

• EpEJ\aN • o4 EPI
EUOZPV • E>jsEIV

Amount
Outstanding
3/17/82
157,649
136,518
41,824
56,493
23,446
2,076
6,221
14,910
39,000
27,165
30,635
91,310
81,813
34,863
Weekended
3/17/82
35
107
73

Changefrom
year ago
Dollar
Percent

Change
from
3/10/82
-1,384
-1,440
58
70
56
- 220
50
6
58
- 299
39
- 634
280
756

10,644
11,993
5,325
5,093
3
666
555
773
2,093
1,621
583
13,990
13,539
4,959

Weekended
3/10/82
63
102
40

11-

-

7.2
9.6
14.6
9.9
0.0
47.2
8.2
4.9
5.1
5.6
1.9
18.1
19.8
16.6

Comparable
year-agoperiod
18
13
5

* Excludestrading account securities.
# Includes items not shown separately.
Editorial comments may be addressedto the editor (William Burke) or to the author .... Freecopiesof this
andother FederalReservepublications can beobtained by calling or writing the Public Information Section,
FederalReserveBankof SanFrancisco,P.O. Box 7702, SanFrancisco94120. Phone(415) 544-2184.

(O)Cill

(O)CQ[