View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

January 25,1974

T o w g u r d k U m iF r a r m l^ r
Equivalent reserve requirements
should apply to all deposits that
effectively serve as a part of the
public's money balances. That is the
principle underlying the Federal
Reserve proposal for the extension
of the present system of reserve
requirements to nonmember institu­
tions, to the extent that such
institutions issue deposits that
perform any type of checkingaccount function.
Under the proposed legislation, the
reserve-requirement range would
be between 5 and 22 percent for
demand deposits, with the specific
figure determined, just as now, by
the Federal Reserve Board of
Governors. The range would be
between 3 and 20 percent for NOW
accounts, that is, interest-bearing
deposits for which the depositor can
make withdrawals by negotiable or
transferable instrument. (Other time
and savings deposits of nonmember
institutions would not be covered.)
The proposal would apply not only
to banks, but also to savings and
other depository institutions, along
with foreign-owned banking institu­
tions that provide demand (or
checking account) deposits. The
reserves would be held in the form
of vault cash or non-interest-earning
deposits at the Fed.
Easing the transition

Uniform requirements could impose
some burden on nonmember
institutions, because even more of
their assets than now could be re­
quired to be in non-interest-bearing
form, thereby cutting into earnings.



To offset this problem, the
legislation includes a provision
which effectively exempts the first
$2 million of net demand deposits
and NOW accounts from reserve
requirements. In view of this
provision, about 62 percent of
present nonmember banks would
be exempt from any reserve re­
quirements that exceed their present
vault-cash holdings. This apparent
exception to the basic principle of
equivalent reserve requirements can
be safely ignored, because the dollar
amounts involved are relatively
small and thus do not represent a
problem for Federal Reserve control
of the monetary aggregates.
To ease the transition, required
reserves would be phased in
gradually over a four-year period,
on those deposits (over $2 million)
held at the time the law goes into
effect. However, deposit increases
above those existing at time of
enactment would be immediately
subject to the full reserve require­
ment. The legislation also would
permit Federal Reserve credit to be
made available to any institutions
that maintain deposits with Reserve
Banks, thus easing the rigid
restrictions that now make non­
member borrowing difficult. This
increased access to the Fed's
discount window would provide a
useful resource at times of strong
pressures on institutions' liquidity
positions.
Liquidity— and policy

Bankers have always recognized the
need to hold some funds in liquid

(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

form to honor deposit withdrawals
promptly. Such reserves were
usually held in the form of vault
cash, deposits with central banks or
other commercial banks, or short­
term government securities. To
ensure maintenance of adequate
liquidity, many nations have enacted
banking legislation specifying
minimum reserves to be held against
deposits. In this country, prior to
the founding of the Federal Reserve
System, reserve requirements were
imposed by national and state
legislation as a means of protecting
bank liquidity.
The basic function of minimum
reserve requirements, however, is
not to ensure bank liquidity, but
rather to permit the Federal Reserve
to control the supply of money and
credit in the pursuit of its important
monetary-policy objectives. Reserve
requirements can influence the
growth of bank loans, investments
and deposits, and thus are an
important element in the monetarycontrol mechanism. The Federal
Reserve controls the total amount
of assets eligible to be used as legal
reserves (through open-market
operations) as well as the per­
centage of deposits that must be
held as reserves, and thus can
influence the key monetary aggre­
gates in accord with its basic policy
goals.
To permit proper central-bank
management of the supply of
money and credit, banking institu­
tions should meet their reserve
requirements by holding assets in



a form which is under the most
direct control of the Federal Re­
serve. These assets could be either
vault cash (Federal Reserve notes)
or deposits at the Reserve Banks.
This test cannot be met by present
state legislation. Under such
legislation, nonmember banks are
not required to hold reserves in the
form of deposits at Federal Reserve
Banks, but may rather hold their
reserves as correspondent balances
with other commercial banks. When
such reserves are held at a member
bank, that bank naturally must sup­
port these balances with its own
reserves consisting either of vault
cash or cash at the Federal Reserve,
but the size of its cash reserves
will be only a fraction of the initial
deposit at the nonmember bank.
With present differential reserve
requirements, therefore, shifts of
deposits between member and non­
member banks alter the quantity of
deposits at all commercial banks
that can be supported by a given
volume of bank reserves. This factor
tends to loosen the links between
bank reserves and the money
supply, and weaken the Fed's con­
trol over the monetary aggregates.
Combatting erosion

The problem has been magnified
by the substantial variability in the
relative growth rates of member and
nonmember banks. Over the past
decade, nonmember banks have
accounted for about 40 percent of
the total increase in the volume of
checking deposits, but the propor­
tions have varied widely from year

to year. This variability has made it
difficult to measure the impact of
Federal Reserve actions on the
monetary aggregates— and there­
fore on final policy objectives
related to income, employment and
prices. This may not have been a
problem in 1945, when nonmember
banks accounted for only 14 percent
of all commercial-bank deposits,
but it is a decided problem today,
when the nonmember-bank share
is 22 percent and rising.

In effect, the System must use this
monetary weapon quite sparingly,
since an increase in required
reserves would worsen the competi­
tive disadvantage of member banks
and thereby threaten a further
erosion of membership. Admittedly,
reserve requirements were in­
creased during the 1973 boom, but
their utilization as a major anti­
inflationary weapon may have been
inhibited on other occasions by the
considerations noted here.

The growing importance of non­
member banks mainly reflects the
competitive disadvantage imposed
on member banks by requiring
them to hold reserves in the form
of vault cash or as deposits at the
Federal Reserve. Nonmember banks,
in contrast, can utilize required
reserves as earning assets even
when they are held as demand
balances with other commercial
banks, since these balances also
serve as a form of payment for
services rendered by city corres­
pondents. As a consequence, banks
generally have an incentive to
avoid membership in the Federal
Reserve System. Since 1960, about
750 banks have left the System
through withdrawal or mergers, and
nearly 1,700 newly chartered state
banks have remained outside,
compared with just over 140 that
elected System membership.

Confronting NOW

The erosion of membership in the
System not only reduces the
precision of monetary control, but it
also reduces the potential for using
changes in reserve requirements as
an effective instrument of policy.



Finally, the concept of equivalent
reserve requirements gains new
urgency because of the recent
efforts of nonbank deposit institu­
tions to evolve new modes of
money transfer. Mutual savings
banks in Massachusetts and New
Hampshire have begun to offer
depositors a NOW account that
closely resembles an interest­
bearing checking account. In
California, savings-and-loan associa­
tions have sought direct access to
an electronic money-transfer system
operated by California banks, so
that they could charge and credit
the savings accounts of their
customers in much the same way
that checking accounts are handled
at commercial banks.
These initiatives offer obvious
marketing advantages. However,
they could affect monetary control
adversely unless reserve require­
ments established by the Federal
Reserve were applied to all deposit
accounts involving money-transfer
services.
William Burke

uoi8umseyv\ • qein • uoftejo • EpeAa|\| • oqepi

7 J |E 3

SSZ

.

B ! U J O p |B 3

•

BUOZUy

0 3 S ID U E J J I U B S

ON ilW tH d

aivd

3DV1SO J s n
HVW SSV1D 1SBIJ

BANKING DATA— TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans adjusted and investments*
Loans adjusted— total*
Securities loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other securities
Deposits (less cash items)— total*
Demand deposits adjusted
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits— total*
Savings
Other time I.P.C.
State and political subdivisions
(Large negotiable CD's)
W eekly Averages
of Daily Figures
Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess reserves
Borrowings
Net free (+ ) / Net borrowed (— )
Federal Funds— Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal funds transactions
Net purchases (+ ) / Net sales (— )
Transactions: U.S. securities dealers
Net loans (+ ) / Net borrowings (— )

Amount
Outstanding
1/9/74

Change
from
1/2/74

79,461
60,615
1,475
20,951
18,310
9,146
6,039
12,807
75,077
22,831
735
50,330
17,737
22,733
7,261
10,619

770
716
35
—
168
+
10
+
7
—
98
+
44
1,063
—
158
—
564
+ 222
—
22
+ 298
+
68
+
94

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+ 9,996
+ 10,022
+
156
+ 3,116
+ 3,134
+ 1,265
—
1,398
+ 1,372
+ 6,938
+ 1,103
+
12
+ 5,807
—
660
+ 5,511
+
598
+ 3,846

-

+

Week ended
1/9/74

-

30
79
49

Week ended
1/2/74

-

32
217
185

+
+
+
+
+
+
—

+
+
+
+
+
—

+
+
+

14.39
19.81
11.83
17.47
20.65
16.05
18.80
12.00
10.18
5.08
1.66
13.04
3.59
32.00
8.97
58.36

Comparable
year-ago period

-

8
68
60

+ 1,755

+ 1,852

+ 420

+

+

+ 364

264

348

in c lu d e s items not shown separately.
Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the
Administrative Services Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
Digitized for FR&SERrancisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 397-1137.
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

•

E > |S E|V

m

NBMEH