View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

§©,ll\l IF1©\[ffi<C
f
II
February 26, 1982

- - - - - - - - - - - - -

Say" Kondratieff"
In this winter of our discontent, media pundits have examined the entrails of a hecatomb
of economists, but still remain undecided
about the economic outlook. Some claim that
the recession is already over, while others
claim thatthe worst is still ahead of us. In
view of this disagreement, it may be useful to
examine a number of indicators to determine
what lies ahead in 1 982.
Long waves
The world of economic theory has led to one
useful indicator which Alfred Malabre mentioned recently in a Wall StreetJournal
column, but which has been evident to
veteran analysts throughout the past generation. In a word, the recession reaches bottom
just at the time when market-letter writers all
begin to say "Kondratieff". The reference is to
a theory originally developed in the 1920s by
the Russian economist Nikolai Dimitriyevich
Kondratieff. According to this view, economic history moves in half-century-Iong
waves, and each wave is generated by the rise
and fall of some major industry. This suggests
that during the downswing of a Kondratieff
long wave, the normal ups and downs of a
business cycle are exaggerated -with business recoveries being short and mild, and
recessions being long and severe.
Economists generally put little stock in the
Kondratieff thesis. For a recent cover story,
Forbesmagazine obtained quotes from two
leading MI T economists, with Nobel
Laureate Paul Samuelson describing the
thesis as "nonsense", and Charles Kindleberger describing it as "astrology". Nonetheless, the theory has a following among
economists with engineering degrees, who
see most things in terms of sine waves-and
especially among market-letter writers of the
gloom-and-doom school, who revive the
theory during every recession as an explanation of why the outlook looks so dismal. But
whatever the value of the thesis, it has provided more sanguine economists with a

useful rule of thumb: the economy begins to
turn up whenever most financial writers
describe the outlook in terms of a Kondratieff
decline. Incidentally, Joseph Stalin did exactly what most policymakers would like to
do with their economists-he shipped
Kondratieff off to Siberia.

Inventory watch
A better fix on the outlook may be obtained
by watching
measures which take into
account the automatic nature of businesscycle forces. In particular, sales and employment should begin to improve as business
firms run-off their present excess inventories,
and are forced to reorder new materials and
equipment. Inventory data suggest, however,
thatthis process is just beginning, and that we
may be facing a situation similar to the sharp
inventory cutback which climaxed the
1 974-75 recession (see chart).
During 1 981 , businesses added $18 billion of
inventories-$9 billion of that total in the
volatile durable-goods sector-yet the volume of durable-goods sales declined 7 percent between the fourth quarter of 1980 and
fourth quarter of 1 981 . Even with no further
decline in sales, substantial inventory liquidation would be needed to restore stocks to
proper levels. And if sales weaken further, the
swing from accumulation in 1981 to liquidation during 1 982 will be a substantial nearterm drag on total output of the economy.
Still, most economists expect the liquidation
process to end by about mid-year, leading to
a new accumulation of inventories-and
therefore higher orders, sales and employment-in the second half.

Automatic stabilizers
In another almost automatic process, the
downward spiral should be neutralized by
the fiscal reforms of the past generation -the
automatic reductions in income-tax receipts,
and increases in unemployment compensation and social-security benefits, that go
along with any downturn in production and
employment. A generation ago, in his role as
business-cycle analyst, Arthur Burns emphasized the automatic stabil izing effects of

lEDfr,iIk\(Ol
cil\
17
§CQurtPIf @-lJm
I
Opinions

expn..

Ql

in lhi'.:- nc\-v::;lettc't' do not

necessarilv retleci' the views of the management
of the h:deral
Bank of San francisco,

or 0-1 thF: Board of CovL'mors
ResE'l've SYstem.

of the Federal
1976

- - - - - - - - - - - - Actually, given the present level of M-1 currency plus transaction (checkable)
deposits-and given last year's relatively
slow money growth, the Fed could live with
money growth in the upper half of its 2V,-toSV, percent growth range for 1982. This
would be consistent with an economic
recovery later this year, but not with the type
of sharp rebound experienced in past cycles.

Federal-deficit financing on the economy.
Little did he realize, in his later role as central
banker, the amount of deficit financing that
would be likely in 1 982 and later years (see
chart).
Most economists believe that massive tax
cuts and increases in defense spending-the
key elements in the current fiscal outlookshould turn the economy around after
.I
rnid-year. The tax cuts alone are expected to
pump about $37 billion into the economy
(annual rate), most of it in the second half of
the year, after the first of two 1O-percent cuts
in income-tax rates takes hold on July 1.
Increases in defense spending may add $25
billion in annual spending. And beginning
July 1, the economy will also get a boost of
perhaps $14 billion in additional socialsecurity payments as a result of cost-of-living
adjustments. Partly offsetting these injections
of cash will be further cuts in government
spending at Federal, state and local levels, as
well as the January increase in social-security
taxes. Yet on balance, the overall Federal
stimulus should be substantial.

Market fears of a clash between a relatively
restrictive monetary policy and an excessively easy fiscal policy have helped account for
an unprecedented rise in real (inflationadjusted) interest rates, which has badly
undermined economic activity in recent
months. With the Federal Reserve's increasingly successful campaign against inflation,
rnost market observers last year expected
interest rates to decline substantially. This
proved not to be the case, however, and by
last summer, a number of businesses found
that they could neither absorb high realinterest costs nor pass thern along to their
customers. The results were cancellations of
merchandise orders, massive inventory
build-ups, business failures, and rising
unemployment. The recent increase in the
business prime-loan rate to 16112r 17
o
percent-which
meant a real-interest cost of
about 8 percent annually-testified to the
continuation of a problem which could
further undermine the economy. High realinterest costs, therefore, could swamp the
boost to demand expected from this year's tax
cuts.

The budget figures indicate also that the
. inventory decline may be less than generally
expected. The late-1981 increase in
inventories, especially in primary metals and
nonelectrical machinery, may reflect buying
by business firms in anticipation of a coming
boost in defense spending. This stock
accumulation, being planned rather than
unplanned, suggeststhat further inventory
cutbacks (and their depressing effect on the
economy) rnay be relatively modest.

Structural problems
Long-term structural problems also could
undermine the recovery process in many
industries, beginning with the crucial automotive industry. New-car sales, at 9 million
units in 1 981 , fell far below the 1 1 -millionplus pace in the boom years of the late 1970s.
For domestic producers, 1980-81 sales were
the worst in the past two decades, reflecting a
sharp upsurge in product costs. The average
price of a new Detroit rnodel ($9,000) was 28
percent higher than two years ago. And
financing and fuel costs were up considerably more.

Monetary role
In past business recoveries, the fiscal stimulus
was supported by an accommodative monetary policy. In the present cycle, however, the
size of the deficit to be financed could
unbalance a monetary policy dedicated to a
slow non-inflationary recovery. Federal
Reserve Chairman Volcker rnadethis point in
recent Congressional testimony, when he
said that consolidating the progress already
attained on the inflation front will require
continued restraint on monetary growth.
2

$Billions

100
150

Federal Deficit Estimates

1974

1976

1980

1978

1982

1984

1 982, Record large crops, sluggish demand
for farm products, high interest rates, and a
stagnant volume of agricultural exports
limited the recovery of farm incomes and
created cash-flow problems for the industry
during 1 981 , Net farm income last year
approached $23 billion-4 percent higher in
real terms than the 1 980 total, but largely
because of a build-up in crop inventories,
Moreover, reaVincome in both years was not
much more than half the 1 979 peak figure,

In early 1 982, Detroit has plans to slash the
number of units on showroom floors, which
have again reached record levels with more
than 1 00 days' supply on hand, Several major
producers have again announced sales rebates, and also have cut assembly schedules,
Production is less than as-million annual
rate, although sales averaged a 6-million
pace in January, All of these factors help
explain the severe pressure on the autoworkers' union to reduce labor costs, which
are roughly twice as high per car in Detroit
than on Japanese production lines,

Many highly-leveraged farm operators last
year experienced a severe cash-flow
squeeze, largely because of high interest rates
and lower commodity prices, Some of those
farmers, however, used the equity accumulated from rapid price appreciation of their
land to refinance their operations, But in early
1 982 at least, many operators face continued
downward pressure on prices and incomes
becauseof large grain stocks and weakening
demand for various farm products,

The housing industry, if anything, exhibits
even more severe structural problems, During 1981 , most statistical series representing
housing activity reached record or nearrecord lows-far below the 1978 peak of 2
mi II ion starts -because of high interest rates
and severely curtailed availability of mortgage funds, Most estimates of housing
demand, derived from population growth,
exceed 2 million new houses per yearwhich suggestsa shortfall of roughly 600,000
units in each of the past three years, Nonetheless, there is no indication that that shortfall
will be overcome any time soon, Record
interest rates have not only depressed the
effective demand for new housing, but also
have devastated the nation's thrift institutions
and thus dried-up the major source of mortgage financing, In contrast, homebuilding
typically has helped lead the economy out of
each recession, with housing starts rising as
lower interest rates improve the availability
and cost of mortgages,

End of recession?
In a word, structural as well as cyclical problems now beset some major industries, thus
providing support to the gloomy Kondratieff
thesis, Most observers, however, expect a
cyclical upturn later in the year, on the basis
of the automatic processes involved in inventory liquidation and rebuilding, as well as
the automatic stabilizers working through the
Federal budget In Malabre's apt phrase,
recessions (like Wagnerian operas) eventually do corne to an end,
The autornatic stabilizers this year will be
supplemented by outright tax reductions, and
rnore importantly, by the boost to real incomes created by the increaSingly successful
fight against inflation, The fiscal picture,
needless to say, has severely destabilizing
implications given the expectation of sharply
rising deficits beyond 1 982, If progress can be
achieved in reducing those deficits, however,
the Fed's monetary-policy stance gives promise of a sustainable noninflationary
recovery-something we have not been able
to achieve in the last several decades,
William Burke,

A slight uptick recently in home sales, an
apparent bottoming-out of housing starts, the
, lowest level of home inventories since
1971 -and of course the massive shortfall in
building during the last several yearsindicate grounds for a strong recovery in
1 982, Yet real-estate analysts generally
believe that mortgage rates must decline
several percentage points-to below 14
percent-to generate a significant demand
for mortgage credit and housing,
The nation's basic industry-agriculturealso continues to face serious problems in
3

SS'ot1 3. LSl:Il:I
U013U!45l?M.4Eln • uoSaJO• epE'AaN oyepi
•

!!I?ME'H•

l?!UJOJ!W)

euo Z! N.

I

U2S

ZSL'ON llWHld

TI'@Jl@tpJ@,;il

OI Vd

IS0<'

's'n

11 ssvn
VW

:l)\ill \\!JIl:l)Jl
Widl

RANKINGDATA-TWELFTH
FEDERAL
RESERVE
DlSTRlcr
(Dollar amountsin millions)

Seleded
Assets nd Liabilities
a
Large
Commercial
Banks
loans(gros5,
adjusted) investments'"
and
loans(gross,
adjusted) total#
Commercialand industrial

Real
estate
loansto individuals
Securities
loans
U.$.Treasury
securities'"
Othersecurities'"
Demand
deposits total#
Demand
deposits adjusted
Savings
deposits total
Timedeposits total#
Individuals, & corp.
part.
(Laille negotiableCD'sl

Weekly
Averages
of DailyFigures
Member
BankReserve
Position
Excess
Reserves l/Defidency(-)
(+
Borrowings
Net
reserves l/Net borrowed(
(+
-)

Amount

Outstanding
1/20/82
156,448
135,279
41,458
55,912
23,712
2,038
6,031
15,138
40,398
28,042
30,754
90,052
81,034
35,953

Weekended
1/20/82
75
21
54

Change
from
1/13/82

Changefrom
year ago

Dollar

-

152
279
- 231
24
- 48
40
194
- 67
-1,613
-1,943
- 280
528
483
218

-

Weekended

Percent

9,500
10,834
4,498
5,221
81
564
771
542
1,556
2,129
1,477
14,432
15,070
6,334

6.5
8.7
12.2
10.3
0.3
38.3
I- 11.3
I- 35
3.7
f- 7.1
5.0
19.1
22.8
21.4

Comparable
period

1/13/82
68
131
63

-

47
312
265

* Excludes
trading
account
securities.
# Includes
items shown
not
separately.
Editorial
comments beaddressed theeditor(WilliamBurke) to theauthor•••. Free
may
to
or
copies this
of
andotherFederal
Reserve
publications beobtained calling writingthePublic
can
by
or
Information
Section,
federalReserve of SanFrancisco, Box7702, SanFrancisco41,20.Phone
Bank
P.O.
9
(415)

\\1l;})
JlWi

(ill