View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

February 7, 1986

Base Drift
The narrow measure of the money supply, M1,
consisting of coin and currency in the public's
hands and deposits with unlimited checking
privileges, grew rapidly in 1985. By june, M1
had greatly exceeded the 4-7 percent 1985 target range set in February, havi ng grown at an 11
percent annual rate to that point. In july, the
Federal Reserve's Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC, announced a new target range of
3-8 percent growth for the second half of 1985
and a new base - the actual level of M1 in the
second quartet - from which to calculate
growth. Since second quarter M1 was well
above the original target range, the decision to
use actual M1 as the new base in essence
impounded the overshoot into the level of M1.
As shown in Chart 1, the practice of using the
actual level of M1 as the base from which new
target ranges are calcuated shifts the level of the
target path. For example, if M1 had grown at 5112
percent (the midpoint of the 3-8 percent range)
after july, it would have remained permanently
above the path implied by a 5112 percent growth
rate starting from the base at the fourth quarter
of 1984.
In this Letter, the factors that determine the
appropriate adjustment in the base from which
to calculate target ranges are discussed. It is
argued that eliminating all base adjustments is
likely to lead to inappropriate monetary policy,
and that, even if M1 always grew at the midpoint
of its target range, adjustments in the target base
would often be necessary.

Definition and criticism
The difference between the base used to calculate a new monetary target range and the value
of the monetary aggregate M1 implied by the
midpoint of the old target is commonly called
"base drift." If the midpoint were always used as
the new base no matter what actual M1 turned
out to be, no base drift would occur. In the past,
however, the FOMC has used the actual level of
M1 as its base - a procedure that results in
complete base drift. From 1975 through 1978,
the FOMC rebased its target ranges every quarter

using actual M1. Since 1979, rebasing has
occurred only at the start of each year with two
exceptions: in both 1983 and 1985 the target
ranges for M1 were rebased in july.
Monetarists have long criticized the FOMC for
allowing base drift to occur. Milton Friedman
has likened the Fed's practice to that of a marksman who always hits the bulls-eye by painting
the target after taking his shot (Wall Street Journal, August 20,1985). Base drift has been called
a major impediment to achieving price stability
since it essentially ratifies, and makes permanent, deviations of money growth from target.
Federal Reserve officials have taken the view
that frequent shifts in the demand for money
often have required adjustments in the base of
target ranges. In this view, deviations from the
target growth path due to money demand shifts
in anyone year should be accommodated in
order to prevent monetary policy from automatically becoming "too tight" or "too easy."
If deviations from the midpoint of the Fed's M1
target growth path were small and as likely to be
positive as negative, average drift would be
close to zero even under a policy that allowed
complete base drift. However, as shown in Chart
2, base drift was positive in every year between
1976 and 1985 except two. Furthermore, it
ranged from negative $8.8 billion in 1981 to a
high of $20.9 billion in 1982.
The respective roles of base drift and the target
growth ranges can be seen in Chart 3. The solid
lines plot successive actual fourth quarter to
fourth quarter target ranges as established by the
FOMe. These target cones originate from the
actual level of M1 (M1-A prior to 1980) at the
start of each target period under the FOMC's
policy of allowing complete base drift. The
dashed set of target cones are drawn under a
hypothetical pol icy of zero base drift - each
cone originates from the midpoint of the previous cone. As Chart 3 shows, the cumulative
effect of base drift accounts for a substantial part
of the total rise in M1 over the period plotted. In

FRBSF
fact, base drift accounts for almost 25 percent of
the total increase in M1 since 1975.
Base drift and price stability

The effect of base drift on price stability can be
understood by using the simple quantity equation of exchange. In this equation, GNP, a measure oftotaUinaLspendingby households,
businesses and government, is equal to the volume of money available for spending (M) times
the average number of times in the period each
dollar is spent (its velocity, or V). At the same
time, GNP reflects the total volume of goods and
services purchased (Q) times its average price
(P). Thus, MV = PQ.
Since this "equation of exchange" holds by definition at each point in time, a change in M must
result in changes in V, P, or Q. Most economists
agree that the effect of an autonomous change in
the money supply (M) eventually falls almost
entirely on the price level (P). Hence, the practiceof complete base drift would appear eventually to lead to a parallel drift in the price level
if Vand Q are unaffected. If price stability is a
goal of monetary policy, it would seem that all
base drift should be eliminated.
This conclusion is valid, however, only if
velocity and real GNP are not subject to persistent shifts. For example, suppose innovation
in the finan.cial market leads to a permanent
increase in velocity as individuals and businesses find they can manage the same volume of
transactions while holding, on average, smaller
M1 balances. This appears to have happened in
the mid-1970s as corporations developed more
efficient methods for managing their money balances. If, in these circumstances, the velocity of
money rises above trend and the growth path of
M1is kept fixed, either P or Q must also rise
above trend. A policy that aims for price and
outputstability should, in this case, reduce the
level of the growth path of M enough to counteract the upward shift in velocity.
Similarly; a technological innovation that permanently affected the long-run, or full employment, path of real GNP \Yould lead to price level
adjustments if the growth path of M remained
unchanged. Price stability will therefore require
that the base of the target range for M be
adjusted in response to' some output and

velocity movements. However, such adjustments would not be appropriate in response to
all velocity and output disturbances. An important distinction must be made between permanent and temporary movements in output and
velocity.
Permanent and temporary disturbances

When output temporarily rises above trend during the upswing of a business cycle, the appropriate monetary policy would be to avoid base
drift - that is, to prevent a rise in the growth
path of M. Such a policy would result in a rise in
interest rates which, in turn, would moderate
spending and help to stabilize real output. Temporary fluctuations in real GNP should not be
completely accommodated by adjusting the
level of the money supply's growth path since
this would eventually affect prices. Similarly, if
M1 rose during the year in response to a temporary velocity decl ine, or if technical factors
prevented the Fed from controlling M1 exactly
and caused a target to be missed, any base drift
would be inappropriate.
There is an increasing body of empirical evidence suggesting that disturbances to velocity
and real output on an annual basis are predominately permanent in nature. For example,
the work of Charles Nelson of the University of
Washington and Charles Plosser of the University of Rochester has shown that both real GNP
and velocity can be thought of as growing at an
average, or trend rate, while subject to unpredictable shifts up or down in their levels - shifts
that, in the absence of further shocks, are permanent. Thus, if M1 velocity rises 4 percent during
a year, rather than its average rate of 3 percent,
the extra 1 percent growth is likely to represent a
shift upward in its level that in itself is permanent. Similar results have been found to apply to
deviations from the trend growth of real GNP.
This suggests that, more often than not, the monetary target base should be adjusted to offset
velocity or output disturbance almost completely.
For example, in late 1982, velocity declined relative to its trend, and M1 was allowed to overshoot its target range. In setting the new base for
the 1983 target range, the FOMC explicitly
allowed base drift to occur by using the abovetarget actual value of M1 as the new base, since

$ Billions

Chart 1
M1

Chart 2
Base Drift 1976-1985

630
620
610

Chart 3
Actual Target Ranges and
Alternative Zero-Base-Drift Ranges

$ Billions

$ Billions

25

650

600

20

600

590

15

550

580

10

500

5

450

Of---J'LilLLLLLllLdLLL"v-7~'-LLL'-"'-r:,-rL..1­

400

570
560
550
540

·5

530

·10

520

350
300
250

l..L.LLLl..LLl--l...L.l..L.LLLl..LLl...J...J...w...LJ...LLJ

ONDJFMAMJJASONDJFMAMJJASOND
19831964

1976 1977 1976 1979 1960 1961 1982 1983 1984 1985:6

'-'-.l....-.l....-.l....-.l....-.l....-~~~~~~

1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1960 1981 1982 1963 1984 1985 1986

1985

the decline in velocity appeared to be permanent. The subsequent behavior of the economy,
which showed no acceleration of inflation, confirmed the appropriateness of base drift in this
case.
More recently, the rebasing of the M1 target
ranges in July 1985 followed the approximately
5 percent decline in M1 velocity during the first
six months of 1985. In its July meeting, the
FaMC reviewed whether the fall in velocity was
a one-time. shift or was likely to reverse itself. By
rebasing the target path, the FaMC chose a policy that was consistent with a belief that the
velocity decline was permanent. If M1 had not
been allowed to rise sufficiently in the face of a
permanent velocity decline, monetary policy
would have become overly tight, and the new
base for subsequent target ranges would need to
be above the actual value of M1 to offset the
lack of policy response.

rule of zero drift nor one of complete drift will
always provide a superior guideline for policy.
However, because both velocity and output disturbances tend to persist, price level stability will
generally require some year-to-year adjustment
in the base from which target ranges are calculated.
The policy records of the FaMC reveal that the
Committee has attempted to distinguish between
shifts in velocity that are viewed to be permanent and those viewed as transitory. However,
by automatically using actual M1 as the base for
new target ranges, it is likely that some temporary disturbances have led to permanent
changes in the price level. The most appropriate
adjustment of the target base in any particular
period can only be determined by analyzing the
sources of velocity and output movements in
that period.

Carl E. Walsh, Senior Economist
Conclusion
Because the nature of velocity and output movements can differ in different episodes, neither a

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author ..•. Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco
94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6U!4S0m

040PI

4o~n

uo6l?iJO

!!omoH O!UJOj!l0)

ouoz!J~

0POl\l?iU
0>tsol~

O)SI)UOJj UOS

JO
aAJaSa~

~U08

IOJapaj

~uaw~Jodaa lpJOaSa~
BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments 1 2
Loans and Leases 1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
U. S. Treasu ry and Agency Secu rities 2
Other Secu rities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances 4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Two Week Averages
of Daily Figures

Amount
Outstanding

Change
from

1/15/86
202,908
183,591
52,574
65,987
38,618
5,694
10,761
8,555
203,987
50,934
33,072
15,239
137,813

118/86
676
1,043
- 141
7
95
151
- 400
31
223
790
-1,177
- 249
- 319

46,013

-

33

38,134
26,086

-

143
1,403

Period ended

Change from 1/16/85
Dollar
Percent 7

14,913
13,555
325
4,081
6,260
428
266
1,623
8,615
4,837
4,178
2,173
1,604

-

3,062

7.1

1,900
5,486

- 4.7

Period ended

1113/86

12/30/85

107
3
104

97
84
14

Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ l/Deficiency (- l
Borrowings
Net free reserves (+ l/Net borrowed( -)

1 Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans
2

Excludes trading account securities

3 Excludes U.S. government and depository institution deposits and cash items
4 ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers

s Includes borrowing via FRB, TT&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
6 Includes items not shown separately
7 Annualized percent change

-

7.9
7.9
.6
6.5
19.3
8.1
2.4
23.4
4.4
10.4
14.4
16.6
1.1

26.6