View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 95-43, December 29, 1995

Bank Stock Repurchases
In 1994, bank holding companies (BHCs}-ineluding such large ones as Wells Fargo, Bank
of America, and Citicorp-bought back roughly
$10.5 billion of common and preferred stock,
two and one-half times more than they did in
1993. In addition, 1994 marked the first time
in several years that BHCs' total repurchases
of stock exceeded their total issuances of new
stock-by about $4.3 million. Available data for
1995 indicate that BHCs have continued to buy
back their stock in large amounts.
In this Weekly Letter, I discuss the theories that
economists have given for why companies buy
back their stock. I then examine the characteristics of the BHCs that were primarily responsible
for the increase in repurchases to see which of
the theories may help explain the increase.

What is a repurchase?
Firms can buy back their own stock, thereby reducing the number of shares outstanding in the
market, in several ways. The most common way
is for the firm to buy the stock in the open market;
in this case, a company announces that it will
buy up to a certain number of shares at the market price, whatever that may be. Another way is
with a tender offer; in that case, a firm announces
that it will buy a certain number of shares at a
price of its choosing. A third way is for a firm to
negotiate a private purchase with specific sellers.
When thinking about repurchases and the reasons
firms do them, it is important to keep in mind that
although the repurchased shares were assets of
whoever sold them, they do not become assets
of the repurchasing firm. The firm simply retires
the shares or keeps them as "treasury stock," which
makes them available for reissuance.

Why do firms buy back
their stock? Some explanations.
One of the simplest economic explanations of why
a fi rm buys back its own stock is that it does so
to reduce the firm's ratio of capital to assets, or
at least to control its growth, while maintaining
asset growth. (Of course, the firm could reduce
the growth of capital by increasing stock dividends,
but that does not have the same tax advantages

as stock buybacks.) The capital-to-assets ratio
reflects a firm's mix of equity and debt financing,
and changing that can have an effect on the firm's
overall value. For example, a firm (or a BHC) may
want to increase its debt financing if it perceives
that market participants distrust management's
investment decisions. In particular, because investors may not be able to tell when a firm has
profitable investment opportunities, they may
suspect that firm growth beyond a certain size is
due solely to managers' desire to increase the resources under their control. Asa result, the market may suppress the stock prices of firms that
growtoo much. Realizing this, managers can restructure their financing to demonstrate that they
really do have profitable projects. Specifically,
they can fund investments with relatively more
debt than equity. The fixed payment pattern of
the debt allows management to argue credibly
that it has profitable projects whose proceeds
will be transferred back to the financial claimants
rather than being at management's disposal. For
a BHC, the existence of deposit insurance may
mute this type of signal but should not completely
eliminate it.
For banks in particular, the capital-to-assets ratio
is affected by regulatory capital requirements.
(A critical reason for such requirements is deposit
insurance, which gives SHCs an incentive to hold
less capital than they otherwise would-it reduces
the cost of debt relative to equity by partially insuring debtholders against loss, and partially
insured debtholders do not demand as high a
return on their investment as they would if they
were not insured.) In the early 1990s, regulations
designated new minimum acceptable and "wellcapitalized" levels for three types of capital-toassets ratios (with differing d~finitions of capital
and assets), and, on average, SHCs exceeded
these levels by the end of1993. For example,
BHCs' weighted average "leverage rq.tio," calculated with more weight given to larger SHCs, increased from 6.0 percent at the end of 1990 to
7.9 percent at the end of 1993, much above the
"welkapitalized" level of 5.0 percent. Having
exceeded the regulatory requirements, some
BHCs may have begun to consider ways to control further increases in their capital-to-assets ratio.

FABSF
Economists have posed explanations for stock
buybacks other than for the purposes of adjusting
capital-to-assets ratios. Some have suggested that
firms may repurchase stock when they lack profitable opportunities, such as acquiring other firms,
or investing in new or existing projects. In that
case, a firm may choose to return earnings to
shareholders, in the form of dividends or share
repurchases, thereby reducing the growth of capital and assets.
In the short run, the amount of debt likely would
not decrease too much, so the growth of the capital"to-assets ratio would slow. For the reasons
discussed above, this might be an acceptable,
or even welcome, consequence of such a slowdown in asset growth. Again, because of tax differentials, the firm might choose to repurchase
shares rather than pay dividends. With more
money in hand, shareholders can then increase
their profitable investments.
However, some firms repurchase because their
stock is a "good investment." As pointed out
above, a firm does not obtain assets when it buys
back its stock. However, under certain circumstances, repurchasing can increase the value of
the remaining outstanding shares, thereby increasing the market value of the capital-to-assets ratio.
In particular, suppose that the firm's managers
know that the market price of its stock is lower
than it should be. That is, the managers know that
the future earnings prospects of the firm really are
betterthan investors think. If the firm repurchases
shares under such circumstances, and the market
eventually corrects its valuation of the firm, the
price of the remaining shares will increase, as will
the market value of assets. So, when the market
undervalues the stock, a repurchase can be a
good investment, made by the firm's managers
on behalf of its shareholders.
Other reasons for repurchasing stock are more
idiosyncratic and therefore not likely to have
played a major role in the large increase in BHC
repurchases in 1994. These include repurchasing
to defend against takeover or acquire another
firm or to meet the needs of employee incentive
compensation programs or security conversions.

should have decreased their capital-to-assets
ratios with little change in asset growth. If the
explanation involving lack of investment opportunitiesholds, then the increase in repurchases
would have been accompanied by decreases in
asset growth and, in the short run (which includes
1994)~ decreases'in the growth rates of capitalto-assets ratios. If the undervaluation explanation
holds, then the stocks' prices should have risen
relative to the market and so should have the
marketcapital-to-assets ratios.
What do the data tell us about the val id ity of these
explanations? First, between 1993 and 1994,319
BHCs increased their repurchases by a total of
about $6.9 billion, while 258 BHCs decreased
their repurchases by a total of about $0.5 billion.
Second, ranking BHCs by the amount of their increase in repurchases between 1993 and 1994,
the top 30 account for 90 percent of the gross increase in repurchases. Therefore, these 30 BHCs
constitute a convenient sample for studying the
possible reasons for the large increase in the dollar volume of BHC repurchases between 1993
and 1994.
Capital-to-assets ratios for these 30 BHCs suggest
that these firms were attempting to decrease their
capitalization levels because they were near
their desired levels. Between 1993 and 1994,
the average capital-to-assets ratio of these 30
BHCs declined from 7.9 percent to 7.6 percent,
while the average capital-to-assets ratio of all
other SHCs increased, from 8.5 percent to 8.7
percent. Moreover, 76.7 percent of the 30 BHCs
saw a decrease in their capital-to"assets ratio,
while only 46.7 percent of all other BHCs did.
These comparisons are consistent with estimates
of the target capital-to-assets ratios for the two
groups. Banks'capital-to-assets ratios between
1989 and 1994, and the rates at which they adjusted those ratios, suggestthat, on average, the
30 largest repurchase increasers had a desired
capital-to-assets ratio right around 8 percent,
while other BHCs were aiming much higher, for
11 percent or more. Thus, at the end of 1993, the
group of 30 BHCs found themselves, on average,
just about at their target capital-to-assets ratio
and might have wanted to avoid overshooting
that bound. In contrast,other BHCs still had far
to go.

Which theories fit?
Each explanation suggests a different outcome.
If the capital adjustment explanation holds, then
(assuming that optimal capital-to-assetsratios did
not rise) BHCsthat increased their repurchases

In addition, asset growth rates for the two groups
suggest that a relative lack -of investmentopportunities also may have played a role. Between 1993
and 1994, the average growth rate of assets of the

30 BHCs declined from 10.8 percent to 9.2 percent, while the average growth rate of assets of
all other BHCs just barely decreased, from 8.0
percent to 7.9 percent.
Finally, a look at bank stocks provides evidence
that can be consistent with the undervaluation
hypothesis, as well as the other hypotheses. I
located repurchase announcement dates for 11
of the top 30 repurchase increasers. Although 7
out of these 11 repurchase announcements generated negative stock price reactions, the other
4 were large enough that, on average, the group
of 11 announcements generated a positive and
statistically significant stock price reaction. The
positive average reaction is consistent with the
undervaluation hypothesis and also with the hypotheses that the bank may be moving toward a
more favorable capital-to-assets ratio or wisely
returning money to shareholders for investment
elsewhere.

Conclusion
In 1994, BHCs increased their purchases of their
own stock by about$6.4 billion. Thereiuethree
main explanations of why firms repurchase stock,
and all three seem to have played pt least some
role in the repurchase increase-indeed, it is important to note that the explanations pre not rnutually exclusive. Specifically, it appears that some
of the BHCs most responsible for the increase
were explicitly attempting to decrease their capital-to-assets ratios, some were reactingto alack
of investment opportunities, and some were taking advantage of the market's undervaluation of
their stock.

Elizabeth S. Laderman
Economist

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflectthe views of the managementof the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System..Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor
or to the author. Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, CA 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341. Weekly
Letter texts and other FRBSF publications and data are available on FedWest Online, a public bulletin board service reached
by setting your modem to dial (415) 896-0272.

Research.Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA94120

Printed on recycled paper Q),.
with soybean inks
~

~
~

Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter
DATE

NUMBER TITLE

AUTHOR

5/19
5/26
6/9
6/23

95-20
95-21
95-22
95-23
95-24
95-25
95-26
95-27
95-28
95-29

Kwan
Schaan/Cogley
Kasa
Rudebusch
Motley
Zimmerman
Mattey/Spiegel
Golub
Cogley/Schaan
Walsh
Kasa
Walsh
Huh
Gabriel
Huh
Jaffee/Levonian
Furlong/Zimmerman
Glick/Moreno
Parry
Laderrllan
Rudebusch
Spiegel
Moreno

7/7
7/28
8/4
8/18
9/1
9/8
9/15
9/22
9/29

10/6
10/13

10/20
10/27
11/3

lJ/lO
11/17
11/24
12/1
12/15

95~30

95-31
95-32
95-33
95-34
95-35
95-36
95-37
95-38
95-39
95-40
95-41
95-42

The Economics of Merging Commercial and Investment Banking
Financial Fragility and the Lender of Last Resort
Understanding Trends in Foreign Exchange Rates
Federal Reserve Policy and the Predictability of Interest Rates
New Measures of Output and Inflation
Rebound in U.s. Banks' Foreign Lending
Is State and Local Competition for Firms Harmful?
Productivity and Labor Costs in Newly !ndustrializing Countries
Using Consumption to Track Movements in Trend GDP
Unemployment
Gaiatsu
Output-Inflation Tradeoffs and Central Bank Independence
Inflation-Indexed Bonds
California Dreamin': A Rebound in Net Migration?
Interest Rate Smoothing and Inflation, Then and Now
Russian Banking
Consolidation: California Style
Is Pegging the Exchange Rate a Cure for Inflation? East Asia
Monetary policy ina Dynamic, .Global Environment
The Rhymeand.Reason of Bank Mergers
New Esti.mates of the Recent Growth in Potential Output
Reserve Requirements and Asian Capital Inflow Surges
Budget Deficit Cots and the Dollar

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in June, July, August, and December.