View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF
1
April 3, 19

,tj~::J-

WEEKLY LETTER

A Model Central Bank?
Despite the recent slowdown associated with
appreciation of the yen exchange rate, japan's
overa.1I ma.croeconomic performance during the
last decade has been impressive (Chart 1). Real
GNP in japan has averaged a robust 4.3 percent
since 1975, while inflation (GNP deflator) has
averaged less than 4 percent. Comparable figures for the United States are 2.5 percent GNP
growth and 6.9 percent average inflation.
Moreover, japan alone among the major industrial countries was able to maintain strong output growth while avoiding the continual
inflationary pressures that followed the second
oil price shock in 1979. The U.S. eventually also
reduced inflation after the second oil price
shock, but only after undergoing a severe recession in 1981-1982. In fact, the volatility (standard deviation divided by average growth) of
u.s. real GNP growth since 1980 has been more
than six ti'mes greater than that of japan.
One frequently cited explanation for japan's successful macroeconomic performance focuses on
japanese monetary policy. Several prominent
economists have argued that the Bank of japan
(BOj) - japan's central bank - undertook a
major policy shift in the mid-1970s that created
the conditions necessary to attain an environment of low inflation and stable output growth.
At least two views regarding the nature of this
policy shift may be distinguished. Milton Friedman argues that "The Bank of japan has been
the least monetarist central bank in its rhetoric,
the most monetarist in its policy". Allan Meltzer
has characterized japan's shift in monetary
regimes in terms of the adoption of a more
"credible" monetary policy. By credible,
Meltzer means that Bank of japan policy has
become more predictable, that is, can be predicted with less forecast error. This Letter evaluates the evidence supporting these two views.

Monetarist principles?
A central theme of monetarism is that achieving
a low and stable rate of growth in a basic money
aggregate is a necessary condition for a central
bank to achieve a low rate of price inflation and
stable output growth. Some monetarists have
recommended that a constant money growth
objective be pursued. To achieve money growth
targets, monetarists usually argue that the central
bank should operate to control strictly growth in
either total bank reserves or the monetary base
(total bank reserves plus currency in circulation
outside banks). In particular, Milton Friedman
states that "monetary \authorities should avoid
trying to manipulate either interest rates or
exchange rates" because an interest rate or an
exchange rate operating procedure is inconsistent with the objective of monetary control.
Friedman's evidence for concluding that the
Bank of japan is following monetarist principles
is based primarily on two facts: japan's rate of
money growth (broad money defined as M2 plus
certificates of deposit) has followed a fairly
steady trend of decline since the mid-1970s, and
this trend has coincided with a decline in the
rate of japanese price inflation.
Although japanese money growth remains high
by international standards, Chart 2 shows a
declining trend from the peak reached in 1975
through 1983, at which time money growth
appears to have stabilized at roughly 8 percent
per annum. Similarly, japanese inflation reached
a peak in 1974-1975, trended downwards until
1983, and has since fluctuated within the 0-2.5
percent range. In addition, the growth in japanese broad money - the BOYs intermediate
indicator - has been less volatile than growth
in the U.S. narrow money aggregate (M1).
However, growth in the japanese narrow money
aggregate - usually preferred by monetarists as.

FRBSF
an intermediate target of policy - has been
considerably more volatile than its U.S. counterpart. Moreover, the Bank of Japan also has not
ach~eved the decline in money growth by followln~ monetary control procedures typically
prescribed by monetarists. The BOj's primary
short-term operating instrument is the interbank
interest rate (call loans and discounted commercial bills), and the Balik's moves to "smooth"
i~terbank interest rates are at least partly responsible for their stability in recent years. In fact,
Japanese interbank interest rates have shown
considerably less variability than the federal
(Chart 3).
funds rate in the

u.s.

deviation from traditional monetarist principles
and argues instead that Japan's relative success
is attributable to the greater consistency - or
greater predictability - of its monetary policy.
Greater predictability, according to Meltzer,
makes the BOJ more "credible" than the Fed
and greater credibility has resulted in Japan's'
experience of disinflation without recession.
Meltzer's argument derives from the principles
of the so-called "new classical" macroeconomics. This school of economic thought argues
that only monetary policy "surprises" (e.g.,
unpredictable and therefore unexpected policies) have an impact on real output. In this
view, if money growth were predictable, and
therefore could be anticipated, monetary policy
should have no influence on real output.

It therefore seems inconsistent for monetarists to
criticize the interest rate operating instrument of
the Fed while lauding the operating control procedures of the BOJ. The HOJ has apparently
found the use of an interest rate operating instrument compatible with a reasonably steady
deceleration in money growth and a low inflation environment.

The basic reasoning behind this theory is that
real output in the economy is fundamentally
determined by such "real" factors as labor productivity, labor/leisure choice, technology, and
r~source endo",:ments. Money is a nominal magnlt~de t~at has Inflation consequences, but
which, In an equilibrium setting with price flexibility, has no impact on fundamental real factors and therefore on output.

Also noteworthy in this context is that attempts
to control money growth as an explicit intermediate target of policy have never been
embraced in Japan with the same enthusiasm as
in the U.S. by the Federal Reserve between
1979-1982. Since 1978, the BOJ has announced
"projections" of the annual rate of broad money
growth for four quarters ending one quarter
ahead. The information imbedded in its money
projections therefore amounts to one-quarter
ahead forecasts of money growth that, on balance, have been fairly accurate.

According to this view, only when unanticipated
money causes unanticipated inflation will monetary policy have even temporary effects on output. These effects would result from firms that
i~crease their output in response to what they
view as a favorable relative price shift rather
t~an. what in fact amounts to an economy-wide
rise In the general price level. Once they realize
that costs as well as all other prices in the economy have increased proportionately with their
own product price, they will cut production
back to the original "natural" output level.

The projections do not, however serve as a
guide to the intermediate or longer term policy
st.a~ce of the BOJ and, in fact, have varied signrflcantly (between 6.5 and 12.5 percent) since
the anno~ncements began in 1978. Moreover,
by ~eportlng new growth projections each quarter Independent of deviations from previous projects, the BOJ in essence allows complete "base
drift" - a practice monetarists criticize the Fed
for pursuing.

Applying the newclassical theory to Japan,
Meltzer suggests that 1) a highly predictable BOJ
policy (i.e., one with few "surprises") has led to
t~e apparent independence of output from inflation, and 2) that the overall decline in money
growth is responsible for low Japanese inflation.

"Credibility" and predictability
Allan Meltzer also attributes the seemingly more
!avorable output/i nflation tradeoff experienced
In J~pan to substantive differences in monetary
policy. However, he recognizes the BOYs clear

The .evide~c~ .marshalled by Meltzer in support
of hiS credibility thesis is that the forecast error
variance (generated from sophisticated forecasting equations) of nominal GNP real GNP and
prices in Japan decreased mark~dly after the
country's switch to fluctuating exchange rates in
1971. Moreover, the forecast errors for these
variables were higher in the U.S. under fluctuating than under fixed exchange rates. Fewer surprises in Japan and more surprises in the

u.s.

Chart ยท1
Japan's Strong Output Growth
Percent

10.0

lead Meltzer to conclude that the BOj must be
following a more credible monetary policy.
The difficulty with this conclusion, as Meltzer
also points out, is that the variance of money
(M1) forecast errors for japan and the
did
not decline after 1971 when forecast errors for
GNP and price did decline. Moreover, the variability of forecast errors for
money growth
is less than that for japan during both periods.

7.5

u.s.

5.0

u.s.

2.5
0.0
-2.5
-5.0

Chart 2
Declining Trend in Japanese Money Growth
Percent

17.5
15.0

,
12.5
10.0

,

/", Japanese
\ Broad Money
\ Growth
#~,

"-'

,

~

\

Nonetheless, Meltzer argues that greater output
and price stability in japan since 1971 has been
associated with increased Bank of japan "credibility" as opposed to a wide variety of other
potential explanations (e.g., differences in financial and labor market institutions, differences in
fiscal policy, and so on). As part of this thesis, he
also suggests that japan's introduction of publicly announced quarterly money growth projections - which were not even initiated until the
third quarter of 1978 - contributed substantially to a more stable environment following
japan's move to fluctuating exchange rates. He
does not, however, offer any direct empirical
evidence to support this view.

\
7.5

Conclusion

5.0
2.5

Support for either the "monetarist" view or the
"credibility" view of the reasons behind the
seemingly more favorable output/inflation tradeoff in japan compared to the
seems rather
weak. Reaching a similar conclusion after analyzing the monetarist view, one observer has
noted that" ... japan achieves results that are
monetarist in nature without using the procedures frequently advocated by monetarists." A
similar statement could be made about the credibility hypothesis: The Bank of japan achieves
results that are credible in nature without having
used more predictable policies.

u.s.

Chart 3
Less Variability in Japanese
Interbank Interest Rate
Percent

20.0
17.5
15.0

,

12.5

I
I

10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5

I

~ ....-

. . ,_JI Japanese
Interbank
Interest Rate

.....- - - -

Given the limited empirical support for either
the monetarist or credibility hypothesis regarding the Bank of japan's behavior, other explanations for the japanese success in maintaining
stable output growth during the recent period of
disinflation should be explored.

Michael Hutchison

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author .... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco
94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6U!4S0m

040PI

4o~n

!!omoH O!UJO:!!I0)

uo6~lJO

OUOZiJl:J

0POI\3U
oljsoll:J

O)SI)UOJ:J UOS

JO

~uo8

aAJaSa~ IOJapa:J

~uaw~Jodaa lpJOaSa~
BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments 1 2
Loans and Leases 1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
U.S. Treasury and Agency Securities2
Other Securities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts -Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Two Week Averages
of Daily Figures
Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ )/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves ( + )/Net borrowed( - )

Amount
Outstanding

Change
from

3/11/87
203,682
182,766
53,593
67,908
37,153
5,460
13,821
7,095
208,398
52,821
36,272
19,561
136,015

3/4/87
124
1
143
261
56
6
98
26
- 1,442
1,481
303
- 278
316

46,718

261

32,517
23,440

-

103
387

Change from 3/12/86
Dollar

-

-

-

-

203
1,580
115
1,749
3,094
192
2,787
1,005
6,373
4,913
3,522
4,172
2,713
890

1.9

6,007
3,622

- 15.5
- 13.3

Period ended

Period ended

3/9/87

2/23/87

91
18
72

45
7

38

1 Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans

Excludes trading account securities
Excludes U.S. government and depository institution deposits and cash items
4 ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers
S Includes borrowing via FRB, TT&L notes, Fed Funds, RJ>s and other sources
6 Includes items not shown separately
7 Annualized percent change
2

3

0.0
0.8
0.2
2.6
7.6
- 3.3
25.2
- 12.4
3.1
10.2
10.7
27.1
1.9

-