View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 5, NO. 12
DECEMBER 2010­­

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALL AS

Gauging the Odds of a Double-Dip
Recession Amid Signals and Slowdowns
by Harvey Rosenblum and Tyler Atkinson

Most forecasters project
growth at 2 to 3 percent
over the next year, but
not gaining sufficient
momentum to advance
safely above stall speed.

P

ublic sentiment says the recession isn’t over. Never mind that
the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), the arbiter
of recessions, declared that the Great Recession of 2008 and 2009 officially
ended in June 2009. An unrelenting pessimism constrains the recovery as
consumers spend reluctantly while paying down debt, gripped by persistent fears of unemployment. The economy grew at a 2.5 percent annualized
pace in the third quarter, according to the second estimate of real gross
domestic product (GDP), a moderate improvement after two quarters of
decelerating growth during the recovery. This tepid expansion has raised
concern that things could get worse again before getting better and that the
likelihood of another recession may have risen.
Slowdown or Imminent Recession?
Does the slow growth necessarily foretell a double dip? Just as a bicycle
requires momentum to stay upright, history tells us that once the economy
slows to a sluggish growth rate, it will likely fall into a recession. This “stall
speed” appears to be 2 percent annual real GDP growth. Every recession
since 1970 has been preceded by expansion of less than 2 percent, though
there was a false alarm in 1995. The second estimate of third-quarter GDP
shows real output rising 3.2 percent over the past year (Chart 1).
Even with researchers’ considerable effort, forecasting recessions may
be no more reliable than consulting a few indicators. The yield curve,
which is a measure of the differences in government debt yields at various
maturities, the unemployment rate and oil price shocks all have a good
history of signaling downturns just before or during the first quarter of a
recession. Still, the unique current economic environment raises questions
about applying such indicators.

The Yield Curve
The difference between the
10-year Treasury yield and the one-year
note turned negative—that is, shortterm interest rates were higher than

long-term rates—before every recession
in the postwar era, with one false signal
in 1966 (Chart 2). A common explanation for the predictive power of the
yield curve draws on the assumption

Chart 1

Economy “Stalls” at 2 Percent Four-Quarter Growth
Four-quarter real GDP growth*
16
14
12
10
8
2010:Q3
2nd release
3.2%

6
4
2
0
–2
–4
–6
–8
’50

’55

’60

’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

’05

’10

* Third-release vintage data. This refers to annual real GDP growth as it appeared when it was released for the third time.
NOTE: Bars denote NBER recessions.
SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Real-Time Data Research Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Chart 2

Inverted Yield Curve Has Signaled Every Recession
10-year – 1-year Treasury yield
4
3
2

False
signal

1

that long-term interest rates—to a great
extent, though not perfectly—represent
expectations of future short-term rates.
In that case, an inverted yield curve
indicates a market expectation that
short-term interest rates will be lower in
the future than they are today. Because
interest rates tend to be procyclical—
they rise with a growing economy and
decline with a contracting economy—
an expectation of falling interest rates
suggests that market investors believe a
recession lies ahead. This is reinforced
by monetary policy. Since short-term
interest rates hew close to the overnight
interest rate target set by the Fed, an
inverted yield curve is, equivalently,
signaling an expectation that the Fed
will soon be reducing its target interest
rate—something that typically happens
when recession is imminent or has
already begun.
Before the 2008 recession, the
inversion of the yield curve occurred
well before the recession is dated to
have begun. At the time, in early 2006,
some analysts pointed to factors that
might rationalize the inverted yield
curve as something other than a signal
of an impending downturn.1 Those
factors included increased demand for
long-maturity assets given the reduced
probability of recessions and lower,
less-volatile inflation during the period
of the Great Moderation; increased
global savings concentrated in the
hands of a few countries that tended
to invest their savings in U.S. capital
markets; and increased demand for
dollar-denominated assets by foreign
central banks. Whether those factors
played a role in the yield curve inversion in early 2006 is open to debate.

0
–1
–2
–3
–4
’55

’60

’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

’05

NOTE: Bars denote NBER recessions.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board.

EconomicLetter 2

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALL AS

’10

Unemployment Rate
An even more reliable signal
of recession, albeit with a lag, is a
0.33 percentage point increase in the
three-month moving average of the
unemployment rate from its recent
low. This signal assumes that workers
losing their jobs cut spending almost
immediately. Demand for goods and
services slides. Using revised data,

this unemployment jump is a flawless
indicator in the postwar era, signaling
every recession either before it began
or within three months of its start
(Chart 3).
Oil Price Shocks
The yield curve and unemployment rate signal disarray affecting
demand and subsequently output.
On the supply side, oil shocks have
figured in most U.S. recessions since
price volatility increased in the 1970s
(Chart 4). In fact, every recession in
the postwar era, except in 1960 and
1970, followed an oil price shock the
previous year. For this analysis, an oil
price shock is defined as the real price
of oil exceeding the high over the previous three years.2 This is more of a
required condition, but not solely sufficient, for a recession. Volatility in the
1990s and the gradual run-up in prices
in the 2000s were considered oil price
shocks under this criterion but did not
immediately lead to recession.
One might deduce that the oil
price spike in 2007 had a large role
in the latest recession. Economist
James Hamilton suggests that if oil
prices hadn’t increased from mid-2007
to mid-2008, the period would have
endured slow growth rather than
contraction.3
Similar Slowdowns
To analyze the current slowdown,
the third release of second-quarter
2010 GDP is used rather than the
second third-quarter report, which is
subject to an additional revision. There
have been 20 slowdowns similar to the
current one since 1955, with nine leading to a recession.4 Economic growth
picked up in the other 11 instances,
averting a recession (Table 1).
All of the slowdowns that led to
a recession had two or three signals
of recession, mostly accompanied by
yearly GDP growth of 2 percent or
less. The current slowdown has zero
signals. This indicates that a recession
in the near future is unlikely. So why
does concern of a double dip persist?

Chart 3

The Economy Rarely Escapes an Uptick in Unemployment
Unemployment rate (percent)*
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
’50

’55

’60

’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

’05

’10

* Three-month moving average (first-release vintage).
NOTES: Red lines indicate the three-month moving average is more than 0.33 percentage points from the recent low.
Bars denote NBER recessions.
SOURCES: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Real-Time Data Research Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Chart 4

Oil Price Shocks Precede Recessions
Real price of oil index, 1982 = 100
180

150

120

90

60

30

0
’50

’55

’60

’65

’70

’75

’80

’85

’90

’95

’00

’05

’10

NOTES: Red lines indicate a price higher than the previous three years’ maximum. Bars denote NBER recessions.
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Concerns and Caveats
The yield curve’s steep upward
slope suggests a low probability
of a recession in the coming year.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALL AS

Nonetheless, many economists are
reluctant to rely on this indicator
because the curve’s shape and slope
have been distorted by the Federal

3 EconomicLetter

Reserve’s unconventional monetary
policy: a near-zero federal funds rate
and a quantitative-easing program that
damped intermediate- and longer-term
Treasury rates. With near-zero shortterm rates, it is almost impossible for
a yield curve inversion, that is, shortterm rates exceeding longer-term ones.
There is some reason to believe
the unemployment rate could climb
again. Claims for jobless benefits remain
at a level usually associated with an
increasing unemployment. Even if the
rate does not increase, it remains elevated, straining the overall recovery.
While the current real price of oil
does not fit the criterion of a shock,

it sits at levels only seen in the early
1980s and 2006–08. An oil supply
shock would be especially damaging
to the already weak recovery.
Most forecasters project growth at
2 to 3 percent over the next year, but
not gaining sufficient momentum to
advance safely above stall speed.
Until this situation is resolved, policymakers will continue facing pressure
to pursue fiscal and monetary measures to guide the economy toward
full employment and more robust
growth.
Rosenblum is the director of research and an
executive vice president at the Federal Reserve

Bank of Dallas and Atkinson is a research assistant in the Research Department.
Notes
1

“Reflections on the Yield Curve and Monetary

Policy,” speech by Federal Reserve Chairman
Ben S. Bernanke before the Economic Club of
New York, New York City, March 20, 2006; and
“Globalization’s Effect on Interest Rates and the
Yield Curve,” by Tao Wu, Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas Economic Letter, vol. 1, no. 9, 2006.
2

“What Is an Oil Shock?” by James D. Hamilton,

Journal of Econometrics, vol. 113, no. 2, 2003,
pp. 363–98.
3

“Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock

of 2007–08,” by James D. Hamilton, Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2009, pp.
215–84.
4

Table 1

For this analysis, a similar slowdown is defined

as two consecutive quarters of slowing real gross

Similar Slowdowns: What Signals Were Saying

domestic product growth, with the last quarter
at or below 2 percent annualized quarter over

Yield curve
negative
in previous
year?

quarter, excluding those more than one quarter
Unemployment
jump?*

Oil shock
in previous
year?

Year-over-year
growth**

Recession
in following
year?

1956:Q1

N

N

N

3.6

N

1957:Q2

Y

Y

Y

1.7

Y

1960:Q3

Y

Y

N

2.6

Y

1963:Q1

N

N

N

4.1

N

1964:Q4

N

N

N

4.4

N

1966:Q2

Y

N

N

5.9

N

1967:Q1

Y

N

N

2.5

N

1969:Q2

Y

Y

N

3.0

Y

1970:Q1

Y

Y

N

0.2

Y

1974:Q1

Y

Y

Y

0.2

Y

1978:Q1

N

N

N

3.8

N

1979:Q2

Y

N

Y

1.9

Y

1980:Q1

Y

Y

Y

1.0

Y

1984:Q3

N

N

N

6.1

N

1995:Q2

N

N

N

3.3

N

1999:Q2

N

N

N

3.9

N

2000:Q4

Y

Y

Y

3.4

Y

2001:Q2

Y

Y

Y

1.2

Y

2003:Q1

N

Y

N

2.0

N

2006:Q3

Y

N

Y

3.0

N

2010:Q2

N

N

N

3.0

?

into a recession.

EconomicLetter

is published by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views expressed
are those of the authors and should not be attributed
to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal
Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge
by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX
75265-5906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone
at 214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed website, www.dallasfed.org.

* First-release vintage. ** Third-release vintage.
SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Real-Time Data Research Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Federal
Reserve Board; Bureau of Labor Statistics.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS
2200 N. PEARL ST.
DALLAS, TX 75201