View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Vol. 3, No. 2
FEBRUARY 2008­­

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

F e d e ral R e s e r v e B a n k of Dallas

Accounting For the Bond-Yield Conundrum
by Tao Wu
Long-term interest rates tend to rise as monetary policymakers increase

This conundrum has

short-term interest rates. This relationship didn’t hold, however, during the recent

prompted a great deal of

U.S. monetary policy tightening cycle. Between June 2004 and June 2006, the Fed-

discussion regarding both

eral Open Market Committee increased the federal funds rate 17 times — going

its magnitude and the

from 1 percent to 5.25 percent. Yet, long-term interest rates declined or stayed flat

factors behind it. However,

until early 2006.

a compelling and broadly

This divergence between short- and long-term interest rates caught many

accepted explanation has

economists, investors and central bankers by surprise. In his Feb. 16, 2005, con-

yet to be reached.

gressional testimony, former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan characterized the behavior of long-term interest rates since June 2004: “For the moment,
the broadly unanticipated behavior of world bond markets remains a conundrum.
Bond price movements may be a short-term aberration, but it will be some time
before we are able to better judge the forces underlying recent experience.”

Based on past
performance, the
10-year bond
yield seemed
to be off track
in mid-2005,
possibly by 130
basis points or more.

Since then, this conundrum has
prompted a great deal of discussion
regarding both its magnitude and the
factors behind it. However, a compelling and broadly accepted explanation
has yet to be reached.
The correct understanding and
quantification of the conundrum have
direct implications for monetary policy,
which largely impacts economies as
long-term interest rates respond to
changes in central banks’ target rates.
Persistent changes in the relationship
between short- and long-term interest
rates will affect the timing and impact
of monetary policy actions.
The Conundrum Period
During the previous three monetary policy tightening cycles—1988–89,
1994–95 and 1999–2000—the 10-year
Treasury yield responded to increases
in the federal funds rate target by rising an average 26 basis points for
every 100-basis-point increase in the
target (Chart 1).
In the tightening episode that
started June 30, 2004, however, the
10-year Treasury yield showed a dis-

Chart 1

Federal Funds Rate Target and 10-Year Treasury Yield
Percent
12

10
10-year Treasury rate

8

6

4
Federal funds rate target

2

0

’86 ’87 ’88 ’89 ’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07

SOURCE: Haver Analytics.

EconomicLetter 2

F ederal Re serve Bank of Dallas

tinctly different pattern. During the 12
months following the initial federal
funds rate increase, this long-term
bond yield declined by about 80 basis
points as short-term rates rose rapidly. Based on past performance, the
10-year bond yield seemed to be off
track in mid-2005, possibly by 130
basis points or more.
Such a decline appeared even
more puzzling in light of other pressures in the economy, such as a robust
expansion, rising energy prices and a
falling federal fiscal deficit. All had put
upward pressure on long-term interest
rates in the past.
Some analysts have suggested the
conundrum occurred because the bond
market expected very rapid federal
funds rate increases at the beginning of
the tightening. When the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) instead
moved in 17 consecutive 25-basis-point
steps, it surprised the market from the
downside and bond yields were adjusted downward to be consistent.
This explanation, however,
contradicts the general impression
that U.S. monetary policy’s transparency has improved considerably the
past two decades. During the most
recent monetary policy tightening, the
FOMC’s actions were well anticipated.
After the first increase, for example,
the federal funds futures market and
the Eurodollar futures market correctly
anticipated almost every quarter-point
increase in the federal funds rate for
the next 12 to 18 months (Chart 2).
Thus, it doesn’t seem plausible that the
long-term interest rate declines that followed the early-stage tightening arose
from a misperception of monetary
policy intention.
The Usual Suspects
In principle, bond yields can be
divided into two components. One is
the long-term real interest rate, which
consists of an expected future real
interest rate, plus a risk premium to
cover the uncertainties of its future
changes. The other is an inflation
component, which depends on the

Chart 2

Monetary Policy
Tightening Was
Well Anticipated
Percent
4.5
4
3.5

Eurodollar futures
path: June 30, 2004

3
2.5
2

Actual federal funds
rate target changes

1.5
1

Fed funds futures
path: June 30, 2004

.5
0
June Sept. Dec. Mar. June Sept. Dec.
2004
2005
Maturity

SOURCE: Haver Analytics.

expected future inflation rate, plus a
premium compensating investors for
the uncertainties of future inflation.
Changes in long-term bond yields
should reflect variations in long-term
real interest rates, long-run inflation
expectations or risk premiums.1
With this in mind, it’s worthwhile
to review some changes in the economy and financial markets that might
be relevant to the conundrum. In particular, market participants have cited
the following factors as lowering risk
premiums, putting downward pressure
on long-term interest rates.
Foreign official purchases.
Many market participants have suggested that substantial increases in
foreign official purchases of U.S.
Treasury securities in recent years
have substantially depressed long-term
Treasury yields.2 In particular, Asian
central banks built up their holdings
of foreign reserves and kept their currency values low relative to the dollar
to boost exports to the U.S.
Faced with a rapid accumulation of dollar assets from record-high

trade surpluses, Asian central banks
invested many of these reserves in U.S.
Treasury bonds, exerting downward
pressure on Treasury yields (Chart 3).
Some economists estimate such pressures on the 10-year Treasury yield at
40 to 120 basis points.
More generally, a global savings
glut has arisen from surges in revenues
for oil and commodity exporters, the
rapid income growth of high-saving
East Asian households and the reduction in fiscal deficits by several Latin
American countries. These developments have added to the net supply
of loanable funds to increasingly open
world financial markets, helping hold
down long-term interest rates in the
U.S. and other advanced nations.
Increased demand by pension funds. Some analysts argue that
declining bond yields may partly owe
to higher demand for longer-duration
Treasury securities as a result of proposed corporate pension reforms.
In particular, U.S. pension funds
might be required to match the maturities of their assets and liabilities. This
concern may have encouraged them
to increase their holdings of longer-

A global savings glut has
arisen from surges in
revenues for oil and
commodity exporters,
the rapid income growth
of high-saving East Asian
households and the
reduction in fiscal
deficits by several Latin
American countries.

Chart 3

Foreign Official Purchases and 10-Year Treasury Yield
Ratio							

Percent
10

3

9

2.5

8

2
10-year Treasury yield

1.5

7

1

6

.5

5

0

4

Foreign official
purchases/U.S. GDP

–.5

3

–1

2
’90

’91

’92

’93

’94

’95

’96

’97

’98

’99

’00

’01

SOURCES: Haver Analytics; Federal Reserve Board.

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dallas	

3 EconomicLetter

’02

’03

’04

’05

Foreign official purchases
of U.S. Treasury
securities, increased
demand for Treasury
securities by pension
funds, decreased
macroeconomic
uncertainty and
declines in asset
price volatility are
among the reasons
long-term Treasury
yields have fallen.

duration Treasuries ahead of any regulatory changes, suppressing long-term
Treasury yields. Some analysts also
cite U.K. pension reforms, which have
been associated with unusually low
yields on British bonds.
Decreased macroeconomic
uncertainty. Because long-term bond
yields are closely related to short-term
interest rates and other macroeconomic fundamentals (both present and
expected), declines in macroeconomic
uncertainty since the early 1980s may
have put downward pressure on longterm interest rates.
The Great Moderation of the
American business cycle, as described
by Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, has
been linked to decreased uncertainty
about inflation, real growth and real
interest rates.
Declines in asset price volatility. The deepening global integration
of financial markets, coupled with the
introduction of new financial instruments the past two decades, may have
played a role in reducing the magnitude of economic fluctuations and mitigating their effect on long-term investors. Consequently, less-volatile asset
prices—in this case, Treasury bond
prices—have ostensibly worked to
lower risk premiums and bond yields.
A Macro–Finance Analysis
Determining the impact of these
factors on the conundrum requires a
rigorous framework. Given the various forces at work, a joint macroeconomic and finance analysis is the most
desirable.
A macroeconomic perspective
calls for an examination of the relationship between current and future
economic fundamentals and the Fed’s
monetary policy. It recognizes that
long-term interest rate movements
reflect markets’ expectations of the
future federal funds rate, which the
Fed adjusts to achieve its inflation and
economic stabilization goals.
A finance perspective entails
quantifying changing investor perceptions of risks for bond pricing, both

EconomicLetter 4

F ederal Re serve Bank of Dallas

in the amount of interest rate risks
and changes in the pricing of those
risks. It recognizes that reductions in
risk premiums are likely a part of the
conundrum.
In a 2006 article, Glenn Rudebusch, Eric Swanson and Tao Wu
provide a good example of such
a macro–finance approach.3 The
analysis is based on two different
models. The first is a vector autoregression-based model developed by
Bernanke, Vincent Reinhart and Brian
Sack (BRS) in 2004.4 The second is
a New Keynesian-based model that
Rudebusch and Wu (RW) developed
about the same time.5
Both models incorporate important linkages between interest rates
and macroeconomic fundamentals.
They also impose the standard noarbitrage restriction from financial
analysis to model the variations of
term premiums across all bond maturities and over time. However, these
models have technical specifications
that differ in important ways, such as
the short-run effect on interest rates
and the economy. Analysis drawing
from both may very well yield more
robust explanations for the conundrum and other aspects of interest rate
behavior.
Both models account for the generally downward trend in the 10-year
bond yield over the past two decades
(Charts 4A, B). The risk-neutral component—the sum of long-run inflation
expectations and the expected real
interest rate—falls considerably over
the same period. So does the associated risk premium in BRS. This is
consistent with the Great Moderation
interpretation that the U.S. economy
has become much less volatile and
inflation has gradually stabilized at
low levels.
Nevertheless, the estimations also
yield notable prediction errors in the
most recent monetary tightening cycle
(Charts 5A, B). Both models overpredicted the 10-year Treasury yield by 50
to 75 basis points in the second half of
2004 and almost all of 2005.

Chart 4

Models Account For 10-Year Bond-Yield Trend
A. Bernanke–Reinhart–Sack
Percent
14

Model-implied 10-year Treasury yield
10-year Treasury yield
Model-implied risk-neutral 10-year yield
Model-implied 10-year term premium

12
10

Both macro–finance

8

models find

6

evidence of a

4

substantial and

2

persistent conundrum

0
’84 ’85 ’86 ’87 ’88 ’89 ’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06

in long-term bond yields

B. Rudebusch–Wu

in 2004 and 2005

Percent

that can’t be accounted

10
Model-implied 10-year Treasury yield
10-year Treasury yield
Model-implied risk-neutral 10-year yield
Model-implied 10-year term premium

9
8

for by changes in
macroeconomic

7
6

fundamentals.

5
4
3
2
1
0

’88

’89

’90

’91

’92

’93

’94

’95

’96

’97

’98

’99

’00

’01

’02

’03

’04

’05

’06

SOURCE: Author’s estimates.

The models failed to closely track
the 10-year bond yield on a few other
occasions as well — in 1997–99, for
instance. But the prediction errors in
2004–05 are substantially larger and
much more persistent than in previous
episodes.
In other words, both macro–
finance models find evidence of a

substantial and persistent conundrum
in long-term bond yields in 2004 and
2005 that can’t be accounted for by
changes in macroeconomic fundamentals and estimated declines in risk premiums implied by such changes. Yet,
the magnitude of the conundrum is
much smaller than what a simple correlation analysis would suggest.

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dallas	

5 EconomicLetter

Chart 5

Models Overpredict 10-Year Treasury Yield
in Conundrum Period
A. Bernanke–Reinhart–Sack
Basis points

150

100

50

0

–50

–100

–150

’84 ’85 ’86 ’87 ’88 ’89 ’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06

B. Rudebusch–Wu
Basis points

60

40

20

0

–20

–40

–60

’88

’89

’90

’91

’92

’93

’94

’95

’96

’97

’98

’99

’00

’01

’02

’03

’04

’05

’06

NOTE: Charts depict variations in bond yields not explained by the models.
SOURCE: Author’s estimates.

Both macro–finance models focus
only on macroeconomic fundamentals
and their associated risk premiums;
they don’t examine special factors that
might have affected the premiums. A
natural next step involves determining

which of those factors could have contributed to the conundrum in 2004–05.
To this end, Rudebusch, Swanson
and Wu sought to quantify those factors by examining:
• Three measures of financial

EconomicLetter 6

F ederal Re serve Bank of Dallas

market volatility: the implied volatility in the longer-term U.S. Treasury
market from the Merrill Lynch MOVE
index; the implied volatility from
Eurodollar options for uncertainty
about the near-term path of monetary
policy; and the VIX measure of implied
volatility from S&P 500 index options
for uncertainty in the stock market.
• Two measures of macroeconomic volatility: an eight-quarter trailing standard deviation of the real gross
domestic product (GDP) growth rate
to proxy output uncertainty and a
24-month trailing standard deviation
of core personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator inflation to proxy
inflation uncertainty.
• A measure of foreign government and central bank purchases of
U.S. Treasury securities: the 12-month
change in custodial holdings by the
New York Fed for all foreign official
institutions, normalized by the total
stock of U.S. Treasury debt held by the
public.
All these series are natural candidates for omitted variables that could
affect long-term bond yields. For
instance, less volatility in the longerterm Treasury market tends to make
Treasury securities more attractive relative to other assets and drive long-term
bond yields down. Similarly, reduced
uncertainty about future monetary
policy tends to lower the risks of holding long-term bonds and lead to lower
risk premiums.
Another possibility is that an
increase in stock market volatility
enhances the safety appeal of Treasury
bonds, driving their prices up and their
yields down. Lower macroeconomic
volatility and increased foreign purchases of U.S. Treasuries also depress
the term premium and lower long-term
bond yields.
Statistical analysis reveals how
these factors differ in their effect on
long-term bond yields (Table 1). The
most significant factor is the large
drop in the implied volatility of longer-term Treasury securities, with a
1 point decline in the index reducing

the 10-year Treasury yield by 0.5 to
1.2 basis points.
Increases in stock market volatility also tend to reduce long-term
Treasury yields, although such effects
aren’t always statistically significant.
Less uncertainty about real growth and
inflation—in particular, uncertainty
about inflation—significantly decreases
long-term Treasury yields.
Interestingly, foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasuries — the most
important factor many market participants and the financial press cited for
keeping long-term bond yields low
during the conundrum period —don’t
have a significant effect on long-term
Treasury yields.
Even the coefficient estimate’s sign
is “wrong.” The press had conjectured
a negative correlation between foreign official purchases and long-term
Treasury yields, but the data indicate a
positive relationship.

To add to the confusion, the relationship between foreign official purchases and Treasury yields hasn’t been
consistent over the past two decades.
Controlling for macroeconomic determinants of long-term bond yields
reveals that the correlation is significantly positive between 1987 and 2000
and negative only since 2002.6
Dissecting the Conundrum
How much of the conundrum
can these factors explain? One way
to answer this question is to break
down the regression results from the
declines in 10-year Treasury yields.
Focusing on the 12 months following
the initial monetary tightening in June
2004 isolates the period when the
conundrum was most apparent.
The actual decline in 10-year
Treasury yields over those 12 months
is approximately 90 basis points
(Table 2).7 Both models suggest that a

Table 1

Regressions of Model Residuals
				

Bernanke–Reinhart–Sack

Independent variable			

Coefficient

(t stat)

Implied volatility on longer-term Treasury
securities (Merrill Lynch MOVE index)

1.20

(5.47)

.49

(4.11)

Implied volatility on six-month-ahead
Eurodollar futures (from options, in
basis points)

–.23

(–1.35)

–.17

(–1.83)

Implied volatility on S&P 500
(VIX index)

–.33

(–.63)

–.50

(–1.73)

15.40

(3.10)

3.90

(1.45)

Realized volatility of monthly core PCE
price inflation (trailing 24-month
standard deviation, in percent)

360.00

(2.18)

214.00

(2.39)

Foreign official purchases of U.S. Treasury
securities (trailing 12-month total,
as percent of U.S. debt in hands of public)

147.00

(.76)

38.00

(.04)

Realized volatility of quarterly GDP growth
(trailing 8-quarter standard deviation,
in percent)

R

2

.30		

Rudebusch–Wu
Coefficient (t stat)

.14

SOURCES: Haver Analytics; Federal Reserve Board.

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dallas	

substantial part of it stems from modelimplied term premiums. The RW
model also identifies a decline in the
risk-neutral component of the 10-year
rate, primarily reflecting a decline in
long-run inflation expectations.
However, a large portion of the
bond-yield declines remains unexplained by macroeconomic fundamentals and associated risk premiums.
Changes in the model residuals are
nearly 87 basis points in the BRS
model and 32 basis points in the RW
model.
These residuals can be decomposed using six measures of volatility and foreign purchases. The fall
in implied volatility of longer-term
Treasuries accounts for the greatest
fraction of the conundrum, or more
than a third of the unexplained residuals from both models. Declines in the
uncertainty of real GDP growth also
contribute to the conundrum, accounting for about 10 percent of the model
residuals.
Inflation volatility doesn’t change
substantially in those 12 months and
has essentially no effect. The three
remaining factors aren’t statistically
significant and account for relatively
small changes in bond yields during
the period.
Half or more of the model
residuals—49 basis points in the BRS
model and 23 basis points in the RW
model—remain unexplained after the
six variables are taken into account.
These may be related to such factors
as pension fund reforms or abnormal
changes in risk appetites that aren’t
considered in the analysis.
Despite its incomplete results, the
macro–finance approach provides a
useful perspective for disentangling the
conundrum.
Two models identify a bond-yield
conundrum during the most recent
monetary tightening cycle, albeit a
smaller one than was presented by
the financial press. The conundrum is
heavily related to a substantial decline
in the volatility of long-term bond prices. Contrary to many accounts, foreign

7 EconomicLetter

EconomicLetter

Table 2

Decomposition of Long-Term Bond-Yield Conundrum
					
Independent variable			

Bernanke–Reinhart– Rudebusch–
Sack model
Wu model

Observed change in 10-year yield (basis points),
June ’04–June ’05, of which:		

–93.3

–87.0

• Model-implied change in risk-neutral 10-year yield		

13.1

–29.6

• Model-implied change in term premium		

–19.9

–25.2

• Change in model residuals, of which:		

–86.5

–32.2

–29.9
1.1
–11.6
7.0
1.2
–6.0
–48.6

–12.2
.7
–2.9
5.1
1.7
–1.6
–23.0

Change in implied volatility on longer-term Treasuries
Change in realized volatility of core PCE inflation		
Change in realized volatility of GDP growth		
Change in implied volatility of Eurodollar rate		
Change in implied volatility of S&P 500		
Change in foreign official purchases		
Unexplained by above		

is published monthly
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the authors and should not be
attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge
by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX
75265-5906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone
at 214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed website, www.dallasfed.org.

SOURCE: Author’s construction.

official purchases of Treasury securities
apparently play little or no role.
The bond-yield conundrum—falling long-term interest rates in the midst
of monetary tightening—posed challenges to the Fed’s monetary policy
actions in 2004 and 2005. Will the
opposite of the bond-yield conundrum
occur now, with the Fed cutting the
federal funds rate at a time of uncertainty about rising energy and food
prices and long-run inflation stability?
This question increases the importance
of closely monitoring the relationship
between long- and short-term rates.
Wu is a senior economist in the
Research Department of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Notes
1

“Globalization’s Effect on Interest Rates and the

Yield Curve,” by Tao Wu, Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas Economic Letter, vol. 1, September 2006.
2

3

“The Bond Yield ‘Conundrum’ from a Macro–

Finance Perspective,” by Glenn Rudebusch, Eric
Swanson and Tao Wu, Monetary and Economic
Studies, vol. 24, no. S-1, November 2006, pp.
83–109.
4

“Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero

Bound: An Empirical Assessment,” by Ben
Bernanke, Vincent Reinhart and Brian Sack,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Issue 2,
2004, pp. 1–78.
5

“A Macro–Finance Model of the Term Structure,

Monetary Policy, and the Economy,” by Glenn
Rudebusch and Tao Wu, Economic Journal,
forthcoming.
6

“The Long-Term Interest Rate Conundrum: Not

Unraveled Yet?” by Tao Wu, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco FRBSF Economic Letter,
April 29, 2005.
7

Actual changes in the 10-year bond yield differ

by a few basis points across the two models. The

Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer
Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research
W. Michael Cox
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
Robert D. Hankins
Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision
Executive Editor
W. Michael Cox
Editor
Richard Alm
Associate Editor
Kathy Thacker
Graphic Designer
Ellah Piña

Bernanke–Reinhart–Sack model uses monthaverage yield data, while the Rudebusch–Wu
model uses end-of-month yields.

“International Capital Flows and U.S. Interest

Rates,” by Francis Warnock and Veronica
Warnock, International Finance Discussion
Papers no. 840, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, September 2005.

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St.
Dallas, TX 75201