View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September
producing unit; when the price of imported
energy rises, productivity
falls-exactly
as
in the case of the simple factory.
Extending
this example,
it can be
argued that increases in prices of imported
intermediate
goods
lead to contractions
in the entire set of production
choices
for economies
importing
the good. This
is equivalent
to saying that the price increase leads to a contraction
in output
capacity
and a decline
in productivity
for domestic
capital and labor. A formula
may be used to illustrate
the relation between
the long-run
fall in productivity
and the price change
of any imported
input.11
This decline in productivity
would
be observed
after full adjustment
of the
economy.
The formula
treats capital and
labor as one aggregate factor, but that is
equivalent
to investigating
the "residual"
change in productivity,
after taking into account changes in the capital-labor
ratio. In
effect, capital and labor are "altered"
when
the price of imported energy rises, and they
become less productive
in both an average
and a marginal sense.
The
contraction
in productivity
is
related to price changes by: 12
(t)

-1~'.

% change in productivity

m

ULM

'

(% change

=

in

PI,

where P is the relative price of the imported
input in question, ()m is the factor share of
the imported
input in domestic GNP, and
aLM is the elasticity of substitution
between
the imported
input
and domestic
value
added (capital, labor, and other resources).
Rough
estimates
of
the
relevant
variables can be substituted
into equation 1.
The percent
increase in the price of imported
oil for 1973-75
was about 400
percent.13
The share of imported
fuels
in U.S. GNP averaged
1.117 percent
between
1973 and 1976.14
The elasticity
11 .

See Plaut [131.

12.

See Plaut [131.

13.

This, of course, varied by types of crude.
But the number is conservative, since one
could argue that further
price increases
were anticipated.
By mid-1980, oil prices
rose more than tenfold in real terms.
The actual numbers were 0.367 percent,
1.168 percent, 1.302 percent, and 1.629
percent for the four years beginning 1973,
respectively.
This refers to gross imports;
the share of net imports was slightly less.

14.

of substitution
between
imported
oil and
domestic
value added is unknown.
However,
the elasticity
of substitution
between all energy inputs and domestic factors has been estimated.
Hudson
and
Jorgenson
[6)
estimated the elasticity of substitution
between
energy and labor for the United States to
be 2.16,
and that
between
energy and
capital
to be -1.39, for an "aggregate"
elasticity
of substitution
of about 1.27.15
(Griffin and Gregory
[5) and Berndt and
Wood [2) produce lower estimates.)
This
elasticity
refers to all energy consumption.
The elasticity for imported energy should be
larger. Even if we use 1.27 for aLM and
1.117 percent for ()m- then by equation
1,
the post-1973
oil price hike should have
caused a "long-run"
aggregate contraction
in productivity
of 4.74 percent.16
This
alone is three-quarters
of the 6.4 percent
decline
that
constitutes
the "productivity mystery"
of Denison for 1973-76, even
though
it ignores
substitution
between
domestic
and imported
energy.
If, after
taking
that
into account,
the elasticity
of substitution
between
imported
oil and
domestic
value added were 1.35, then the
entire
"mystery"
of Denison
would
be
accounted for fully.
In conclusion,
the analysis here indicates that the energy price increase caused
by OPEC after 1973 probably explains most
of the slowdown in U.S. productivity
growth.
As oil prices rose, productivity
and output
capacity
contracted
for the United States
and other OECD countries.
The increase in
energy prices directly caused capital accumulation to slow down, and indirectly caused
higher inflation,
resulting
in the effective
increase in taxation of capital income. Moreover, higher energy prices directly reduced
the productivity
of U.S. resources,
and
thus caused most or all of the "residual"
slowdown
not explained
by the fall in
capital accumulation.
15.

As calculated

by Griffin and Gregory

16.

The estimate of 1.27 for ULM is somewhat
arbitrary.
If ULM = 1.5, the estimated productivity decline because of the energy price
change would be 5.6 percent; if ULM = 0.8,
the decline
would
be 3.0 percent;
if
aLM = 0.6, the decline would be 2.2 percent.

References
1.

2.

3.

Berndt,
creases

Ernst R. "Energy
Price Inand the Productivity
Slow-

down
in United
States
Manufacturing." Manuscript, 1980.
and David O. Wood. "Technology, Prices and the Derived Demand
for Energy,"
Review of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 57 (August 1975),

11.

pp.259-68.
de Leeuw,
Rasche
and

Frank.
"Comments
Tatom,"
in U.s.

vol. 2 (1979),
12.

4.

5.

6.

13.

Denison,
Edward
F. Accounting for
Slower Economic Growth: The United
States in the 1970s. Washington, D.C.:

14.

7.

Hudson, Edward A., and Dale W. Jorgenson. "U.S. Energy Policy and Economic
Growth,
1975-2000,"
Bell
Journal of Economics, vol. 5 (Autumn
1974), pp, 461-514.

15.

9.

10.

script, 1980.
Kopcke,
Richard
W. "Capital
Accumulation
and Potential
Growth."
Manuscript, 1980.
Nordhaus,
William
D. "Policy
Responses
to the Productivity
Slowdown." Manuscript, 1980.

L. "Potential

Output:

Washington
University, Center for the
Study of American Business.Workinq
Paper 2~, December
1977, pp. 1-20.
Plaut, Steven E. "The Pure Theory
of International
Trade
in Intermediate Goods." Manuscript, 1979.
Rasche,
Robert
H., and John
A.
Tatom. "Energy Resources and Potential GNP," Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review, vol. 59 (June 1977),
. "The Effects of the New
Energy Regime on Economic
Capacity, Production,
and Prices," Federal

Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
vol. 59 (May 1977), pp. 2-12.
16.

. "Potential
Output
and Its
Growth
Rate-The
Dominance
of
Higher Energy Costs in the 1970s,"
in U.S. Productive Capacity: Esti-

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
In this issue:

The Productivity Slowdown:
Is Oil the Culprit?
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101
Address correction

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

requested

mating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis:

. "Energy Prices and the U.S.
1972-76,"
Data Resources
U.S. Review,
September
1978,
pp, 1.24-1.37.
Kendrick,
John W. "Survey
of the
Factors Contributing
to the Decline
in U. S. Productivity
Growth."
Manu-

pp. 387-431.

pp.l0-24.

Economy:

8.

George

mating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis:

on

The Brookings Institution,
1979.
Griffin, James M., and Paul R. Gregory. "An Intercountry
Translog Model
of Energy Substitution
Responses,"
American Economic Review, vol. 66
(December 1976), pp. 845-57.

Perry,

Activity,

Recent
Issues and Present Trends,"
in U.S. Productive Capacity: Esti-

Study of
Paper 23,

University,
Center for the
American Business, Working
December 1977, pp. 137-45.

Norsworthy,
J.R., Michael J. Harper,
and Kent Kunze. "The Slowdown
in
Productivity
Growth:
Analysis
of
Some Contributing
Factors,"
Brook-

ings Papers on Economic

t

Productive Capacity: Estimating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis: Washington

[51.

The opinions stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal ReserveSystem,

8, 1980

17.

Washington
University, Center for the
Study of American Business, Working
Paper 23, December 1977, pp. 67-106.
Tatom, John A. "Energy Prices and
Capital Formation:
1972-1977,"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
vol. 61 (May 1979), pp. 2-11.

18.

. "The Productivity

Problem,"

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, vol. 61 (September
1979),
pp.3-16.

Address

Change

o Correct
o Remove

as shown
from mailing list

Please send mailing label to the Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland,

OH 44101.

The Productivity

Slowdown: Is Oil the Culprit?
by Steven E. Plaut

One of the most controversial topics
debated in the United States today is the
dramatic fall in productivity growth in
recent years. This slowdown has been held
accountable for falling personal incomes,
higher inflation and unemployment rates,
and a falling dollar. Slower productivity
growth seems to be the disease for which
advocates of the "reindustrialization"
panacea have been searching. Hardly a single
major news publication has failed to give
cover space to the issue. Increasing attention is being devoted to the importance of
correcting the productivity problem, yet
no consensus has been reached as to the
reason for the slowdown in productivity.
It will be the contention here that
most of the productivity slowdown in the
mid-1970s was due to the quintupling of
oil prices in 1973-75. As such, this Commentary is in basic agreement with the
work done by researchers at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.1 This is in contrast to the views of most other authors.
The Productivity Mystery
On the surface, energy seems to be
the most obvious explanation for the productivity slowdown. The stylized facts about
productivity
trends all provide circumstantial evidence in support of the hypothesis that energy is the true culprit. The
facts are that productivity, as calculated by
Denison [4] and measured by real National
Income Per Person Employed (NIPPE),
grew at an average but declining rate of
2.4 percent per year from 1948 to 1973.
While slowing after 1965, productivity
suddenly fell in 1973, and decreased by
an average 0.5 percent per year from 1973-76.
After 1976, productivity rose somewhat, but
the growth rate of N IPPE for the entire period of 1973-78 was zero. That was equivalent
to a 12.6 percent decrease in productivit~
when compared with the pre-1973 trend.
1.
2.

See Rasche and Tatom (14),[15),and
and Tatom (17) and [181.
See Denison (4).

(16),

Steven E. Plaut is a research associate, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and assistant professor of economics, Oberlin College.

The decline in productivity growth
was not confined to the United States.
Productivity growth declined at the same
time in all major countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and
Development (OECD). In all these countries, the productivity decline was accompanied by a slowdown in the accumulation
of new capital. 3 For the United States,
"Growth of the high employment
net
capital stock per worker has practically
halted when compared with the trend
rate of growth of 2.9 percent per year
from 1950 to mid-1972. From mid-1972
to mid-1979, capital per worker grew at
a 0.6 percent rate, leaving the level of
capital per worker by mid-1979 about
17 percent lower than that implied along
the 1950-72 trend. ,,4 This implies a $200
bill ion (1972 prices) decrease in the capital
stock, compared with the earlier trend.
The fall in productivity growth varied
considerably across industries for the United
States. The slowdown for a number of
sectors is shown in table 1. Of these, the
largest decline occurred in mining. Part
of the decline in mining was due to new
environmental regulations. But a considerable portion was probably due to the increased cost of energy-intensive processing
of ore, especially smelting. The factor
shares of energy are shown in the table by
sector, and a weak correlation seems evident. The share of energy for the sectors
where productivity fell the most (mining,
agriculture, electricity and gas, and wholesale, and retail trade) is considerably larger
than for the sectors where productivity
did not fall greatly. Communications,
where productivity rose, is the least energyintensive sector shown. A deeper analysis
of the cross-sectoral productivity patterns
is beyond the scope of this study, but on
the surface energy intensity would appear
to explain a great deal of the pattern.
By 1977, productivity growth began
a modest recovery. Yet, beginning with the
first quarter of 1979, U.S. productivity fell
for six straight quarters. Once again, the
3.
4.

See Tatom
See Tatom

(18), p. 15.
(18), pp, 6-7.

Table 1 Decline in Growth Rates of National Product per Hour Worked
and Shares of Energy, by Sector
Growth rate
for 1948-73
minus rate
for 1973-76,
percent

Total input coefficient
from crude petroleum
and natural gas

Total input coefficient
from electricty, gas,
and sanitary services

Communications

-3.2

0.0016

0.0010

Construction

0.7

0.0179

0.0152

Services

1.2

0.0092

0.0021

Manufacturing
Durable ~oods
Nondura Ie goods

1.3
1.5

na
na

na
na

Wholesale and
retail trade

2.7

0.0075

0.0209

Electricity, gas, and
sanitary services

3.0

0.1120

0.1017

Agriculture, forestry,
and fisheries

3.4

0.0703

0.0273

10.2

0.0303

0.0345

2.9

0.0141

0.0494

Mining
All sectors in economy

F. Denison, Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The United States in
Institution,
1979), table 9-1, p. 146; and U.S. Department of Commerce
Bureau of Economic Analysis, The Detailed Input-Output Structure of the U.S. Economy:1972
(Washington, D,C., 1979).

SOURCE:

Based on Edward

the 19705 (The Brookings

fall in productivity followed sharp increases
in oil prices. While oil prices had remained
fairly constant in real terms from 1976 to
1978, they shot up rapidly following disruptions of Iranian exports
in the fall
and winter of 1978-79. In the second
quarter of 1980, nonfarm business productivity fell at an adjusted annual rate of 4.1
percent, the largest fall in six years.
There have been a number of recent
analyses of the productivity slowdown.F
Of these, perhaps the most familiar is that
by Denison [4]. His study attempted to
explain the causes of the shift in productivity, and he concluded that his search
was largely unsuccessful. Denison summarized his findings by saying, "What
happened, is, to be blunt, a mystery"(p.4).
Since then, a number of other studies have
attempted
to resolve the "productivity
mystery," many of which have debated the
importance of the OPEC-induced energyprice change.
,
One could divide the factors contributing to the productivity growth slowdown into two sets. First, there seems to
5.

For a concise yet comprehensive
Nordhaus (10).

survey, see

have occurred a sharp decline in the U.S.
capital-labor ratio or the rate of accumulation of capital. There is disagreement,
however, as to the magnitude, significance,
and cause of the decline.
The Role of Capital
Tatom [18] estimates that 38 percent
of the decline in productivity in the mid1970s may be attributed to this fall in
capital accumulation, although some have
argued this may be too large, given the
lagged impact that changes in capital have
on productivity. Kopcke [9] believes that
one-half of the slowdown is due to this
factor, and for manufacturing perhaps the
entire slowdown is due to it. Norsworthy,
Harper, and Kunze [11] also claim that it
explains half, but explains only 30 percent
for manufacturing. Denison [4], however,
estimates that the change in capital accumulation can explain only 4.0 percent of
the observed decline in actual non-residential
NIPPE growth, and explains about the same
(4.8 percent) for potential growth. Berndt
[1] is even dubious that growth of the
capital-labor ratio slowed very much, at
least in manufacturing, where it grew at a

rate of 2.5 percent from 1973-77, compared with 2.9 percent for the preceding
eight years.6
There seem to be two candidates for the
factor causing this slowdown in capital accumulation. The first is inflation and its distorting effects on taxation of capital, especially because of obsolete mandated depreciation standards. Yet, it seems unlikely
that the inflation-caused
tax distortion
could entirely explain a worldwide pattern, since other countries have very different tax systems and inflation histories.
The second candidate is the change in energy
prices. Hudson and Jorgenson [7], among
others, have argued that energy and capital
tend to be complements, and therefore the
capital-labor ratio would fall when energy
prices rise.
The decrease in capital accumulation,
whatever its causes, explains only part of the
fall in productivity growth. In addition, another set of factors must be included. Again,
there is debate about what these factors are
or how important they are. It is striking
that almost all studies find that a significant
part of the slowdown is "unexplained."
Denison takes into account various demographic, sociological, and economic factors,
together with changes in capital, yet is
still left with an unexplained fall of 2.1
percent in productivity growth for the
1973-76 period. This is 72 percent of the
slowdown and constitutes his "mystery."
Norsworthy, Harper, and Kunze [11] find
that, after taking into account various capital and labor changes, 13 percent of the
productivity slowdown in private business
remains unexplained, compared with 78 percent in manufacturing. Other studies also
are forced to allow for large "residuals.,,7
Some have argued that these large
residuals are really manifestations of a slowdown in technological development. It is
true that the percentage of U.S. GNP devoted to research and development fell
somewhat in the 1970s. But this reflected
decreased government funding of space and
defense research; private funding of research
rose during most of the period. Moreover,
6.

7.

Berndt, however, does not conclude that
energy is the sol ution to the mystery.
Part of the confusion has to do with definitions of capital.
Compare
Norsworthy,
Harper, and Kunze [11 I.
See Nordhaus

(10), table 1.

any fall in research funding should affect
productivity growth only after a long lag.
It could well be the case that the 1948-73
"residual" in Denison's study (1.4 percent)
represents technological advance. But the
technological advance probably was not
much different during 1973-76, meaning
that a 2.1 percent decrease in productivity
growth after accounting for technology
remains "unexplained."
In any case, it is
very hard to believe that this slowdown
in research could explain a worldwide
pattern, or the slowdown-recovery-slowdown pattern that has been observed for
the United States.
The Role of Energy
Among the factors we are left with
is the direct impact of energy prices, that is,
the impact' after taking into account their
effect on capital investment. Denison is
skeptical about the ability of energy to explain the "mystery." He estimates that the
factor share of energy in GNP is only 4.6
percent.8 Perry [12] and de Leeuw [3] also
reject the energy explanation on grounds
that sharp productivity changes due to
energy prices could only result if a great
deal of energy conservation occurred, that
is, if energy demand elasticity were high.
Perry estimates that energy used per unit
of output declined 10.2 percent from 1973
to 1976, but that most of this reflected a
time trend.9 Tatom [18], however, estimates the elasticity of the energy/real GNP
ratio to energy prices as -1.207, indicating
considerable responsiveness to price.1 0
Consider a factory that used only
capital and electricity to produce some
product. When the price of electricity rose,
less output would be, produced in the
factory. The output or "capacity" of the
factory would really be a direct function
of the cost of obtaining electricity. At a
higher cost, the factory and its capital
stock would be less productive in both
an average and marginal' sense. By analogy, the entire United States and all of
its domestic resources (including labor)
may be thought of as constituting a large
8.
9.
10.

It is not clear from the book whether this
number refers to direct or total shares.
Tatom (18) disagrees that there was any
trend at all.
Tatom (18) notes that there may be problems with the data.

The Productivity

Slowdown: Is Oil the Culprit?
by Steven E. Plaut

One of the most controversial topics
debated in the United States today is the
dramatic fall in productivity growth in
recent years. This slowdown has been held
accountable for falling personal incomes,
higher inflation and unemployment rates,
and a falling dollar. Slower productivity
growth seems to be the disease for which
advocates of the "reindustrialization"
panacea have been searching. Hardly a single
major news publication has failed to give
cover space to the issue. Increasing attention is being devoted to the importance of
correcting the productivity problem, yet
no consensus has been reached as to the
reason for the slowdown in productivity.
It will be the contention here that
most of the productivity slowdown in the
mid-1970s was due to the quintupling of
oil prices in 1973-75. As such, this Commentary is in basic agreement with the
work done by researchers at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.1 This is in contrast to the views of most other authors.
The Productivity Mystery
On the surface, energy seems to be
the most obvious explanation for the productivity slowdown. The stylized facts about
productivity
trends all provide circumstantial evidence in support of the hypothesis that energy is the true culprit. The
facts are that productivity, as calculated by
Denison [4] and measured by real National
Income Per Person Employed (NIPPE),
grew at an average but declining rate of
2.4 percent per year from 1948 to 1973.
While slowing after 1965, productivity
suddenly fell in 1973, and decreased by
an average 0.5 percent per year from 1973-76.
After 1976, productivity rose somewhat, but
the growth rate of N IPPE for the entire period of 1973-78 was zero. That was equivalent
to a 12.6 percent decrease in productivit~
when compared with the pre-1973 trend.
1.
2.

See Rasche and Tatom (14),[15),and
and Tatom (17) and [181.
See Denison (4).

(16),

Steven E. Plaut is a research associate, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and assistant professor of economics, Oberlin College.

The decline in productivity growth
was not confined to the United States.
Productivity growth declined at the same
time in all major countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and
Development (OECD). In all these countries, the productivity decline was accompanied by a slowdown in the accumulation
of new capital. 3 For the United States,
"Growth of the high employment
net
capital stock per worker has practically
halted when compared with the trend
rate of growth of 2.9 percent per year
from 1950 to mid-1972. From mid-1972
to mid-1979, capital per worker grew at
a 0.6 percent rate, leaving the level of
capital per worker by mid-1979 about
17 percent lower than that implied along
the 1950-72 trend. ,,4 This implies a $200
bill ion (1972 prices) decrease in the capital
stock, compared with the earlier trend.
The fall in productivity growth varied
considerably across industries for the United
States. The slowdown for a number of
sectors is shown in table 1. Of these, the
largest decline occurred in mining. Part
of the decline in mining was due to new
environmental regulations. But a considerable portion was probably due to the increased cost of energy-intensive processing
of ore, especially smelting. The factor
shares of energy are shown in the table by
sector, and a weak correlation seems evident. The share of energy for the sectors
where productivity fell the most (mining,
agriculture, electricity and gas, and wholesale, and retail trade) is considerably larger
than for the sectors where productivity
did not fall greatly. Communications,
where productivity rose, is the least energyintensive sector shown. A deeper analysis
of the cross-sectoral productivity patterns
is beyond the scope of this study, but on
the surface energy intensity would appear
to explain a great deal of the pattern.
By 1977, productivity growth began
a modest recovery. Yet, beginning with the
first quarter of 1979, U.S. productivity fell
for six straight quarters. Once again, the
3.
4.

See Tatom
See Tatom

(18), p. 15.
(18), pp, 6-7.

Table 1 Decline in Growth Rates of National Product per Hour Worked
and Shares of Energy, by Sector
Growth rate
for 1948-73
minus rate
for 1973-76,
percent

Total input coefficient
from crude petroleum
and natural gas

Total input coefficient
from electricty, gas,
and sanitary services

Communications

-3.2

0.0016

0.0010

Construction

0.7

0.0179

0.0152

Services

1.2

0.0092

0.0021

Manufacturing
Durable ~oods
Nondura Ie goods

1.3
1.5

na
na

na
na

Wholesale and
retail trade

2.7

0.0075

0.0209

Electricity, gas, and
sanitary services

3.0

0.1120

0.1017

Agriculture, forestry,
and fisheries

3.4

0.0703

0.0273

10.2

0.0303

0.0345

2.9

0.0141

0.0494

Mining
All sectors in economy

F. Denison, Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The United States in
Institution,
1979), table 9-1, p. 146; and U.S. Department of Commerce
Bureau of Economic Analysis, The Detailed Input-Output Structure of the U.S. Economy:1972
(Washington, D,C., 1979).

SOURCE:

Based on Edward

the 19705 (The Brookings

fall in productivity followed sharp increases
in oil prices. While oil prices had remained
fairly constant in real terms from 1976 to
1978, they shot up rapidly following disruptions of Iranian exports
in the fall
and winter of 1978-79. In the second
quarter of 1980, nonfarm business productivity fell at an adjusted annual rate of 4.1
percent, the largest fall in six years.
There have been a number of recent
analyses of the productivity slowdown.F
Of these, perhaps the most familiar is that
by Denison [4]. His study attempted to
explain the causes of the shift in productivity, and he concluded that his search
was largely unsuccessful. Denison summarized his findings by saying, "What
happened, is, to be blunt, a mystery"(p.4).
Since then, a number of other studies have
attempted
to resolve the "productivity
mystery," many of which have debated the
importance of the OPEC-induced energyprice change.
,
One could divide the factors contributing to the productivity growth slowdown into two sets. First, there seems to
5.

For a concise yet comprehensive
Nordhaus (10).

survey, see

have occurred a sharp decline in the U.S.
capital-labor ratio or the rate of accumulation of capital. There is disagreement,
however, as to the magnitude, significance,
and cause of the decline.
The Role of Capital
Tatom [18] estimates that 38 percent
of the decline in productivity in the mid1970s may be attributed to this fall in
capital accumulation, although some have
argued this may be too large, given the
lagged impact that changes in capital have
on productivity. Kopcke [9] believes that
one-half of the slowdown is due to this
factor, and for manufacturing perhaps the
entire slowdown is due to it. Norsworthy,
Harper, and Kunze [11] also claim that it
explains half, but explains only 30 percent
for manufacturing. Denison [4], however,
estimates that the change in capital accumulation can explain only 4.0 percent of
the observed decline in actual non-residential
NIPPE growth, and explains about the same
(4.8 percent) for potential growth. Berndt
[1] is even dubious that growth of the
capital-labor ratio slowed very much, at
least in manufacturing, where it grew at a

rate of 2.5 percent from 1973-77, compared with 2.9 percent for the preceding
eight years.6
There seem to be two candidates for the
factor causing this slowdown in capital accumulation. The first is inflation and its distorting effects on taxation of capital, especially because of obsolete mandated depreciation standards. Yet, it seems unlikely
that the inflation-caused
tax distortion
could entirely explain a worldwide pattern, since other countries have very different tax systems and inflation histories.
The second candidate is the change in energy
prices. Hudson and Jorgenson [7], among
others, have argued that energy and capital
tend to be complements, and therefore the
capital-labor ratio would fall when energy
prices rise.
The decrease in capital accumulation,
whatever its causes, explains only part of the
fall in productivity growth. In addition, another set of factors must be included. Again,
there is debate about what these factors are
or how important they are. It is striking
that almost all studies find that a significant
part of the slowdown is "unexplained."
Denison takes into account various demographic, sociological, and economic factors,
together with changes in capital, yet is
still left with an unexplained fall of 2.1
percent in productivity growth for the
1973-76 period. This is 72 percent of the
slowdown and constitutes his "mystery."
Norsworthy, Harper, and Kunze [11] find
that, after taking into account various capital and labor changes, 13 percent of the
productivity slowdown in private business
remains unexplained, compared with 78 percent in manufacturing. Other studies also
are forced to allow for large "residuals.,,7
Some have argued that these large
residuals are really manifestations of a slowdown in technological development. It is
true that the percentage of U.S. GNP devoted to research and development fell
somewhat in the 1970s. But this reflected
decreased government funding of space and
defense research; private funding of research
rose during most of the period. Moreover,
6.

7.

Berndt, however, does not conclude that
energy is the sol ution to the mystery.
Part of the confusion has to do with definitions of capital.
Compare
Norsworthy,
Harper, and Kunze [11 I.
See Nordhaus

(10), table 1.

any fall in research funding should affect
productivity growth only after a long lag.
It could well be the case that the 1948-73
"residual" in Denison's study (1.4 percent)
represents technological advance. But the
technological advance probably was not
much different during 1973-76, meaning
that a 2.1 percent decrease in productivity
growth after accounting for technology
remains "unexplained."
In any case, it is
very hard to believe that this slowdown
in research could explain a worldwide
pattern, or the slowdown-recovery-slowdown pattern that has been observed for
the United States.
The Role of Energy
Among the factors we are left with
is the direct impact of energy prices, that is,
the impact' after taking into account their
effect on capital investment. Denison is
skeptical about the ability of energy to explain the "mystery." He estimates that the
factor share of energy in GNP is only 4.6
percent.8 Perry [12] and de Leeuw [3] also
reject the energy explanation on grounds
that sharp productivity changes due to
energy prices could only result if a great
deal of energy conservation occurred, that
is, if energy demand elasticity were high.
Perry estimates that energy used per unit
of output declined 10.2 percent from 1973
to 1976, but that most of this reflected a
time trend.9 Tatom [18], however, estimates the elasticity of the energy/real GNP
ratio to energy prices as -1.207, indicating
considerable responsiveness to price.1 0
Consider a factory that used only
capital and electricity to produce some
product. When the price of electricity rose,
less output would be, produced in the
factory. The output or "capacity" of the
factory would really be a direct function
of the cost of obtaining electricity. At a
higher cost, the factory and its capital
stock would be less productive in both
an average and marginal' sense. By analogy, the entire United States and all of
its domestic resources (including labor)
may be thought of as constituting a large
8.
9.
10.

It is not clear from the book whether this
number refers to direct or total shares.
Tatom (18) disagrees that there was any
trend at all.
Tatom (18) notes that there may be problems with the data.

The Productivity

Slowdown: Is Oil the Culprit?
by Steven E. Plaut

One of the most controversial topics
debated in the United States today is the
dramatic fall in productivity growth in
recent years. This slowdown has been held
accountable for falling personal incomes,
higher inflation and unemployment rates,
and a falling dollar. Slower productivity
growth seems to be the disease for which
advocates of the "reindustrialization"
panacea have been searching. Hardly a single
major news publication has failed to give
cover space to the issue. Increasing attention is being devoted to the importance of
correcting the productivity problem, yet
no consensus has been reached as to the
reason for the slowdown in productivity.
It will be the contention here that
most of the productivity slowdown in the
mid-1970s was due to the quintupling of
oil prices in 1973-75. As such, this Commentary is in basic agreement with the
work done by researchers at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.1 This is in contrast to the views of most other authors.
The Productivity Mystery
On the surface, energy seems to be
the most obvious explanation for the productivity slowdown. The stylized facts about
productivity
trends all provide circumstantial evidence in support of the hypothesis that energy is the true culprit. The
facts are that productivity, as calculated by
Denison [4] and measured by real National
Income Per Person Employed (NIPPE),
grew at an average but declining rate of
2.4 percent per year from 1948 to 1973.
While slowing after 1965, productivity
suddenly fell in 1973, and decreased by
an average 0.5 percent per year from 1973-76.
After 1976, productivity rose somewhat, but
the growth rate of N IPPE for the entire period of 1973-78 was zero. That was equivalent
to a 12.6 percent decrease in productivit~
when compared with the pre-1973 trend.
1.
2.

See Rasche and Tatom (14),[15),and
and Tatom (17) and [181.
See Denison (4).

(16),

Steven E. Plaut is a research associate, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and assistant professor of economics, Oberlin College.

The decline in productivity growth
was not confined to the United States.
Productivity growth declined at the same
time in all major countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and
Development (OECD). In all these countries, the productivity decline was accompanied by a slowdown in the accumulation
of new capital. 3 For the United States,
"Growth of the high employment
net
capital stock per worker has practically
halted when compared with the trend
rate of growth of 2.9 percent per year
from 1950 to mid-1972. From mid-1972
to mid-1979, capital per worker grew at
a 0.6 percent rate, leaving the level of
capital per worker by mid-1979 about
17 percent lower than that implied along
the 1950-72 trend. ,,4 This implies a $200
bill ion (1972 prices) decrease in the capital
stock, compared with the earlier trend.
The fall in productivity growth varied
considerably across industries for the United
States. The slowdown for a number of
sectors is shown in table 1. Of these, the
largest decline occurred in mining. Part
of the decline in mining was due to new
environmental regulations. But a considerable portion was probably due to the increased cost of energy-intensive processing
of ore, especially smelting. The factor
shares of energy are shown in the table by
sector, and a weak correlation seems evident. The share of energy for the sectors
where productivity fell the most (mining,
agriculture, electricity and gas, and wholesale, and retail trade) is considerably larger
than for the sectors where productivity
did not fall greatly. Communications,
where productivity rose, is the least energyintensive sector shown. A deeper analysis
of the cross-sectoral productivity patterns
is beyond the scope of this study, but on
the surface energy intensity would appear
to explain a great deal of the pattern.
By 1977, productivity growth began
a modest recovery. Yet, beginning with the
first quarter of 1979, U.S. productivity fell
for six straight quarters. Once again, the
3.
4.

See Tatom
See Tatom

(18), p. 15.
(18), pp, 6-7.

Table 1 Decline in Growth Rates of National Product per Hour Worked
and Shares of Energy, by Sector
Growth rate
for 1948-73
minus rate
for 1973-76,
percent

Total input coefficient
from crude petroleum
and natural gas

Total input coefficient
from electricty, gas,
and sanitary services

Communications

-3.2

0.0016

0.0010

Construction

0.7

0.0179

0.0152

Services

1.2

0.0092

0.0021

Manufacturing
Durable ~oods
Nondura Ie goods

1.3
1.5

na
na

na
na

Wholesale and
retail trade

2.7

0.0075

0.0209

Electricity, gas, and
sanitary services

3.0

0.1120

0.1017

Agriculture, forestry,
and fisheries

3.4

0.0703

0.0273

10.2

0.0303

0.0345

2.9

0.0141

0.0494

Mining
All sectors in economy

F. Denison, Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The United States in
Institution,
1979), table 9-1, p. 146; and U.S. Department of Commerce
Bureau of Economic Analysis, The Detailed Input-Output Structure of the U.S. Economy:1972
(Washington, D,C., 1979).

SOURCE:

Based on Edward

the 19705 (The Brookings

fall in productivity followed sharp increases
in oil prices. While oil prices had remained
fairly constant in real terms from 1976 to
1978, they shot up rapidly following disruptions of Iranian exports
in the fall
and winter of 1978-79. In the second
quarter of 1980, nonfarm business productivity fell at an adjusted annual rate of 4.1
percent, the largest fall in six years.
There have been a number of recent
analyses of the productivity slowdown.F
Of these, perhaps the most familiar is that
by Denison [4]. His study attempted to
explain the causes of the shift in productivity, and he concluded that his search
was largely unsuccessful. Denison summarized his findings by saying, "What
happened, is, to be blunt, a mystery"(p.4).
Since then, a number of other studies have
attempted
to resolve the "productivity
mystery," many of which have debated the
importance of the OPEC-induced energyprice change.
,
One could divide the factors contributing to the productivity growth slowdown into two sets. First, there seems to
5.

For a concise yet comprehensive
Nordhaus (10).

survey, see

have occurred a sharp decline in the U.S.
capital-labor ratio or the rate of accumulation of capital. There is disagreement,
however, as to the magnitude, significance,
and cause of the decline.
The Role of Capital
Tatom [18] estimates that 38 percent
of the decline in productivity in the mid1970s may be attributed to this fall in
capital accumulation, although some have
argued this may be too large, given the
lagged impact that changes in capital have
on productivity. Kopcke [9] believes that
one-half of the slowdown is due to this
factor, and for manufacturing perhaps the
entire slowdown is due to it. Norsworthy,
Harper, and Kunze [11] also claim that it
explains half, but explains only 30 percent
for manufacturing. Denison [4], however,
estimates that the change in capital accumulation can explain only 4.0 percent of
the observed decline in actual non-residential
NIPPE growth, and explains about the same
(4.8 percent) for potential growth. Berndt
[1] is even dubious that growth of the
capital-labor ratio slowed very much, at
least in manufacturing, where it grew at a

rate of 2.5 percent from 1973-77, compared with 2.9 percent for the preceding
eight years.6
There seem to be two candidates for the
factor causing this slowdown in capital accumulation. The first is inflation and its distorting effects on taxation of capital, especially because of obsolete mandated depreciation standards. Yet, it seems unlikely
that the inflation-caused
tax distortion
could entirely explain a worldwide pattern, since other countries have very different tax systems and inflation histories.
The second candidate is the change in energy
prices. Hudson and Jorgenson [7], among
others, have argued that energy and capital
tend to be complements, and therefore the
capital-labor ratio would fall when energy
prices rise.
The decrease in capital accumulation,
whatever its causes, explains only part of the
fall in productivity growth. In addition, another set of factors must be included. Again,
there is debate about what these factors are
or how important they are. It is striking
that almost all studies find that a significant
part of the slowdown is "unexplained."
Denison takes into account various demographic, sociological, and economic factors,
together with changes in capital, yet is
still left with an unexplained fall of 2.1
percent in productivity growth for the
1973-76 period. This is 72 percent of the
slowdown and constitutes his "mystery."
Norsworthy, Harper, and Kunze [11] find
that, after taking into account various capital and labor changes, 13 percent of the
productivity slowdown in private business
remains unexplained, compared with 78 percent in manufacturing. Other studies also
are forced to allow for large "residuals.,,7
Some have argued that these large
residuals are really manifestations of a slowdown in technological development. It is
true that the percentage of U.S. GNP devoted to research and development fell
somewhat in the 1970s. But this reflected
decreased government funding of space and
defense research; private funding of research
rose during most of the period. Moreover,
6.

7.

Berndt, however, does not conclude that
energy is the sol ution to the mystery.
Part of the confusion has to do with definitions of capital.
Compare
Norsworthy,
Harper, and Kunze [11 I.
See Nordhaus

(10), table 1.

any fall in research funding should affect
productivity growth only after a long lag.
It could well be the case that the 1948-73
"residual" in Denison's study (1.4 percent)
represents technological advance. But the
technological advance probably was not
much different during 1973-76, meaning
that a 2.1 percent decrease in productivity
growth after accounting for technology
remains "unexplained."
In any case, it is
very hard to believe that this slowdown
in research could explain a worldwide
pattern, or the slowdown-recovery-slowdown pattern that has been observed for
the United States.
The Role of Energy
Among the factors we are left with
is the direct impact of energy prices, that is,
the impact' after taking into account their
effect on capital investment. Denison is
skeptical about the ability of energy to explain the "mystery." He estimates that the
factor share of energy in GNP is only 4.6
percent.8 Perry [12] and de Leeuw [3] also
reject the energy explanation on grounds
that sharp productivity changes due to
energy prices could only result if a great
deal of energy conservation occurred, that
is, if energy demand elasticity were high.
Perry estimates that energy used per unit
of output declined 10.2 percent from 1973
to 1976, but that most of this reflected a
time trend.9 Tatom [18], however, estimates the elasticity of the energy/real GNP
ratio to energy prices as -1.207, indicating
considerable responsiveness to price.1 0
Consider a factory that used only
capital and electricity to produce some
product. When the price of electricity rose,
less output would be, produced in the
factory. The output or "capacity" of the
factory would really be a direct function
of the cost of obtaining electricity. At a
higher cost, the factory and its capital
stock would be less productive in both
an average and marginal' sense. By analogy, the entire United States and all of
its domestic resources (including labor)
may be thought of as constituting a large
8.
9.
10.

It is not clear from the book whether this
number refers to direct or total shares.
Tatom (18) disagrees that there was any
trend at all.
Tatom (18) notes that there may be problems with the data.

September
producing unit; when the price of imported
energy rises, productivity
falls-exactly
as
in the case of the simple factory.
Extending
this example,
it can be
argued that increases in prices of imported
intermediate
goods
lead to contractions
in the entire set of production
choices
for economies
importing
the good. This
is equivalent
to saying that the price increase leads to a contraction
in output
capacity
and a decline
in productivity
for domestic
capital and labor. A formula
may be used to illustrate
the relation between
the long-run
fall in productivity
and the price change
of any imported
input.11
This decline in productivity
would
be observed
after full adjustment
of the
economy.
The formula
treats capital and
labor as one aggregate factor, but that is
equivalent
to investigating
the "residual"
change in productivity,
after taking into account changes in the capital-labor
ratio. In
effect, capital and labor are "altered"
when
the price of imported energy rises, and they
become less productive
in both an average
and a marginal sense.
The
contraction
in productivity
is
related to price changes by: 12
(t)

-1~'.

% change in productivity

m

ULM

'

(% change

=

in

PI,

where P is the relative price of the imported
input in question, ()m is the factor share of
the imported
input in domestic GNP, and
aLM is the elasticity of substitution
between
the imported
input
and domestic
value
added (capital, labor, and other resources).
Rough
estimates
of
the
relevant
variables can be substituted
into equation 1.
The percent
increase in the price of imported
oil for 1973-75
was about 400
percent.13
The share of imported
fuels
in U.S. GNP averaged
1.117 percent
between
1973 and 1976.14
The elasticity
11 .

See Plaut [131.

12.

See Plaut [131.

13.

This, of course, varied by types of crude.
But the number is conservative, since one
could argue that further
price increases
were anticipated.
By mid-1980, oil prices
rose more than tenfold in real terms.
The actual numbers were 0.367 percent,
1.168 percent, 1.302 percent, and 1.629
percent for the four years beginning 1973,
respectively.
This refers to gross imports;
the share of net imports was slightly less.

14.

of substitution
between
imported
oil and
domestic
value added is unknown.
However,
the elasticity
of substitution
between all energy inputs and domestic factors has been estimated.
Hudson
and
Jorgenson
[6)
estimated the elasticity of substitution
between
energy and labor for the United States to
be 2.16,
and that
between
energy and
capital
to be -1.39, for an "aggregate"
elasticity
of substitution
of about 1.27.15
(Griffin and Gregory
[5) and Berndt and
Wood [2) produce lower estimates.)
This
elasticity
refers to all energy consumption.
The elasticity for imported energy should be
larger. Even if we use 1.27 for aLM and
1.117 percent for ()m- then by equation
1,
the post-1973
oil price hike should have
caused a "long-run"
aggregate contraction
in productivity
of 4.74 percent.16
This
alone is three-quarters
of the 6.4 percent
decline
that
constitutes
the "productivity mystery"
of Denison for 1973-76, even
though
it ignores
substitution
between
domestic
and imported
energy.
If, after
taking
that
into account,
the elasticity
of substitution
between
imported
oil and
domestic
value added were 1.35, then the
entire
"mystery"
of Denison
would
be
accounted for fully.
In conclusion,
the analysis here indicates that the energy price increase caused
by OPEC after 1973 probably explains most
of the slowdown in U.S. productivity
growth.
As oil prices rose, productivity
and output
capacity
contracted
for the United States
and other OECD countries.
The increase in
energy prices directly caused capital accumulation to slow down, and indirectly caused
higher inflation,
resulting
in the effective
increase in taxation of capital income. Moreover, higher energy prices directly reduced
the productivity
of U.S. resources,
and
thus caused most or all of the "residual"
slowdown
not explained
by the fall in
capital accumulation.
15.

As calculated

by Griffin and Gregory

16.

The estimate of 1.27 for ULM is somewhat
arbitrary.
If ULM = 1.5, the estimated productivity decline because of the energy price
change would be 5.6 percent; if ULM = 0.8,
the decline
would
be 3.0 percent;
if
aLM = 0.6, the decline would be 2.2 percent.

References
1.

2.

3.

Berndt,
creases

Ernst R. "Energy
Price Inand the Productivity
Slow-

down
in United
States
Manufacturing." Manuscript, 1980.
and David O. Wood. "Technology, Prices and the Derived Demand
for Energy,"
Review of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 57 (August 1975),

11.

pp.259-68.
de Leeuw,
Rasche
and

Frank.
"Comments
Tatom,"
in U.s.

vol. 2 (1979),
12.

4.

5.

6.

13.

Denison,
Edward
F. Accounting for
Slower Economic Growth: The United
States in the 1970s. Washington, D.C.:

14.

7.

Hudson, Edward A., and Dale W. Jorgenson. "U.S. Energy Policy and Economic
Growth,
1975-2000,"
Bell
Journal of Economics, vol. 5 (Autumn
1974), pp, 461-514.

15.

9.

10.

script, 1980.
Kopcke,
Richard
W. "Capital
Accumulation
and Potential
Growth."
Manuscript, 1980.
Nordhaus,
William
D. "Policy
Responses
to the Productivity
Slowdown." Manuscript, 1980.

L. "Potential

Output:

Washington
University, Center for the
Study of American Business.Workinq
Paper 2~, December
1977, pp. 1-20.
Plaut, Steven E. "The Pure Theory
of International
Trade
in Intermediate Goods." Manuscript, 1979.
Rasche,
Robert
H., and John
A.
Tatom. "Energy Resources and Potential GNP," Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review, vol. 59 (June 1977),
. "The Effects of the New
Energy Regime on Economic
Capacity, Production,
and Prices," Federal

Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
vol. 59 (May 1977), pp. 2-12.
16.

. "Potential
Output
and Its
Growth
Rate-The
Dominance
of
Higher Energy Costs in the 1970s,"
in U.S. Productive Capacity: Esti-

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
In this issue:

The Productivity Slowdown:
Is Oil the Culprit?
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101
Address correction

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

requested

mating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis:

. "Energy Prices and the U.S.
1972-76,"
Data Resources
U.S. Review,
September
1978,
pp, 1.24-1.37.
Kendrick,
John W. "Survey
of the
Factors Contributing
to the Decline
in U. S. Productivity
Growth."
Manu-

pp. 387-431.

pp.l0-24.

Economy:

8.

George

mating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis:

on

The Brookings Institution,
1979.
Griffin, James M., and Paul R. Gregory. "An Intercountry
Translog Model
of Energy Substitution
Responses,"
American Economic Review, vol. 66
(December 1976), pp. 845-57.

Perry,

Activity,

Recent
Issues and Present Trends,"
in U.S. Productive Capacity: Esti-

Study of
Paper 23,

University,
Center for the
American Business, Working
December 1977, pp. 137-45.

Norsworthy,
J.R., Michael J. Harper,
and Kent Kunze. "The Slowdown
in
Productivity
Growth:
Analysis
of
Some Contributing
Factors,"
Brook-

ings Papers on Economic

t

Productive Capacity: Estimating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis: Washington

[51.

The opinions stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal ReserveSystem,

8, 1980

17.

Washington
University, Center for the
Study of American Business, Working
Paper 23, December 1977, pp. 67-106.
Tatom, John A. "Energy Prices and
Capital Formation:
1972-1977,"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
vol. 61 (May 1979), pp. 2-11.

18.

. "The Productivity

Problem,"

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, vol. 61 (September
1979),
pp.3-16.

Address

Change

o Correct
o Remove

as shown
from mailing list

Please send mailing label to the Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland,

OH 44101.

September
producing unit; when the price of imported
energy rises, productivity
falls-exactly
as
in the case of the simple factory.
Extending
this example,
it can be
argued that increases in prices of imported
intermediate
goods
lead to contractions
in the entire set of production
choices
for economies
importing
the good. This
is equivalent
to saying that the price increase leads to a contraction
in output
capacity
and a decline
in productivity
for domestic
capital and labor. A formula
may be used to illustrate
the relation between
the long-run
fall in productivity
and the price change
of any imported
input.11
This decline in productivity
would
be observed
after full adjustment
of the
economy.
The formula
treats capital and
labor as one aggregate factor, but that is
equivalent
to investigating
the "residual"
change in productivity,
after taking into account changes in the capital-labor
ratio. In
effect, capital and labor are "altered"
when
the price of imported energy rises, and they
become less productive
in both an average
and a marginal sense.
The
contraction
in productivity
is
related to price changes by: 12
(t)

-1~'.

% change in productivity

m

ULM

'

(% change

=

in

PI,

where P is the relative price of the imported
input in question, ()m is the factor share of
the imported
input in domestic GNP, and
aLM is the elasticity of substitution
between
the imported
input
and domestic
value
added (capital, labor, and other resources).
Rough
estimates
of
the
relevant
variables can be substituted
into equation 1.
The percent
increase in the price of imported
oil for 1973-75
was about 400
percent.13
The share of imported
fuels
in U.S. GNP averaged
1.117 percent
between
1973 and 1976.14
The elasticity
11 .

See Plaut [131.

12.

See Plaut [131.

13.

This, of course, varied by types of crude.
But the number is conservative, since one
could argue that further
price increases
were anticipated.
By mid-1980, oil prices
rose more than tenfold in real terms.
The actual numbers were 0.367 percent,
1.168 percent, 1.302 percent, and 1.629
percent for the four years beginning 1973,
respectively.
This refers to gross imports;
the share of net imports was slightly less.

14.

of substitution
between
imported
oil and
domestic
value added is unknown.
However,
the elasticity
of substitution
between all energy inputs and domestic factors has been estimated.
Hudson
and
Jorgenson
[6)
estimated the elasticity of substitution
between
energy and labor for the United States to
be 2.16,
and that
between
energy and
capital
to be -1.39, for an "aggregate"
elasticity
of substitution
of about 1.27.15
(Griffin and Gregory
[5) and Berndt and
Wood [2) produce lower estimates.)
This
elasticity
refers to all energy consumption.
The elasticity for imported energy should be
larger. Even if we use 1.27 for aLM and
1.117 percent for ()m- then by equation
1,
the post-1973
oil price hike should have
caused a "long-run"
aggregate contraction
in productivity
of 4.74 percent.16
This
alone is three-quarters
of the 6.4 percent
decline
that
constitutes
the "productivity mystery"
of Denison for 1973-76, even
though
it ignores
substitution
between
domestic
and imported
energy.
If, after
taking
that
into account,
the elasticity
of substitution
between
imported
oil and
domestic
value added were 1.35, then the
entire
"mystery"
of Denison
would
be
accounted for fully.
In conclusion,
the analysis here indicates that the energy price increase caused
by OPEC after 1973 probably explains most
of the slowdown in U.S. productivity
growth.
As oil prices rose, productivity
and output
capacity
contracted
for the United States
and other OECD countries.
The increase in
energy prices directly caused capital accumulation to slow down, and indirectly caused
higher inflation,
resulting
in the effective
increase in taxation of capital income. Moreover, higher energy prices directly reduced
the productivity
of U.S. resources,
and
thus caused most or all of the "residual"
slowdown
not explained
by the fall in
capital accumulation.
15.

As calculated

by Griffin and Gregory

16.

The estimate of 1.27 for ULM is somewhat
arbitrary.
If ULM = 1.5, the estimated productivity decline because of the energy price
change would be 5.6 percent; if ULM = 0.8,
the decline
would
be 3.0 percent;
if
aLM = 0.6, the decline would be 2.2 percent.

References
1.

2.

3.

Berndt,
creases

Ernst R. "Energy
Price Inand the Productivity
Slow-

down
in United
States
Manufacturing." Manuscript, 1980.
and David O. Wood. "Technology, Prices and the Derived Demand
for Energy,"
Review of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 57 (August 1975),

11.

pp.259-68.
de Leeuw,
Rasche
and

Frank.
"Comments
Tatom,"
in U.s.

vol. 2 (1979),
12.

4.

5.

6.

13.

Denison,
Edward
F. Accounting for
Slower Economic Growth: The United
States in the 1970s. Washington, D.C.:

14.

7.

Hudson, Edward A., and Dale W. Jorgenson. "U.S. Energy Policy and Economic
Growth,
1975-2000,"
Bell
Journal of Economics, vol. 5 (Autumn
1974), pp, 461-514.

15.

9.

10.

script, 1980.
Kopcke,
Richard
W. "Capital
Accumulation
and Potential
Growth."
Manuscript, 1980.
Nordhaus,
William
D. "Policy
Responses
to the Productivity
Slowdown." Manuscript, 1980.

L. "Potential

Output:

Washington
University, Center for the
Study of American Business.Workinq
Paper 2~, December
1977, pp. 1-20.
Plaut, Steven E. "The Pure Theory
of International
Trade
in Intermediate Goods." Manuscript, 1979.
Rasche,
Robert
H., and John
A.
Tatom. "Energy Resources and Potential GNP," Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review, vol. 59 (June 1977),
. "The Effects of the New
Energy Regime on Economic
Capacity, Production,
and Prices," Federal

Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
vol. 59 (May 1977), pp. 2-12.
16.

. "Potential
Output
and Its
Growth
Rate-The
Dominance
of
Higher Energy Costs in the 1970s,"
in U.S. Productive Capacity: Esti-

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
In this issue:

The Productivity Slowdown:
Is Oil the Culprit?
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101
Address correction

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

requested

mating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis:

. "Energy Prices and the U.S.
1972-76,"
Data Resources
U.S. Review,
September
1978,
pp, 1.24-1.37.
Kendrick,
John W. "Survey
of the
Factors Contributing
to the Decline
in U. S. Productivity
Growth."
Manu-

pp. 387-431.

pp.l0-24.

Economy:

8.

George

mating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis:

on

The Brookings Institution,
1979.
Griffin, James M., and Paul R. Gregory. "An Intercountry
Translog Model
of Energy Substitution
Responses,"
American Economic Review, vol. 66
(December 1976), pp. 845-57.

Perry,

Activity,

Recent
Issues and Present Trends,"
in U.S. Productive Capacity: Esti-

Study of
Paper 23,

University,
Center for the
American Business, Working
December 1977, pp. 137-45.

Norsworthy,
J.R., Michael J. Harper,
and Kent Kunze. "The Slowdown
in
Productivity
Growth:
Analysis
of
Some Contributing
Factors,"
Brook-

ings Papers on Economic

t

Productive Capacity: Estimating the Utilization Gap. St. Louis: Washington

[51.

The opinions stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal ReserveSystem,

8, 1980

17.

Washington
University, Center for the
Study of American Business, Working
Paper 23, December 1977, pp. 67-106.
Tatom, John A. "Energy Prices and
Capital Formation:
1972-1977,"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
vol. 61 (May 1979), pp. 2-11.

18.

. "The Productivity

Problem,"

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, vol. 61 (September
1979),
pp.3-16.

Address

Change

o Correct
o Remove

as shown
from mailing list

Please send mailing label to the Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland,

OH 44101.