View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

takeovers and leveraged buyouts
much easier to accomplish and, thereby, may have induced an acceleration in business debt above its
longer-term trend rate.
The apparent increase in debt of
state and local governments since
1982 is essentially a consequence of
double counting. In recent years,
state and local governments have
increasingly assumed the role of
financial intermediaries,
i.e., borrowing funds directly at tax-exempt
interest rates and making the proceeds available to other borrowers
(some for private purposes). Late last
year, the House tax bill threatened to
significantly limit the incentives
leading to this kind of intermediation. Consequently, many state and
local governments came to market
early to avoid missing opportunities
that they thought would be taken
away January 1, 1986.
Flush with additional funds, these
issuers invested the surplus amounts
in credit market instruments.
While
much attention was given to the
increased demand for SLUGS (a special class of treasury issues sold only
to state and local governments), state
and local governments invested heavily in a wide spectrum of U.S.
government and agency issues. Over
90 percent of the assets acquired
were U.S. government securities.
Private assets acquired through
mortgage bonds and student loan
bonds were sold off.
Because state and local governments are essentially acting as
financial intermediaries-buying
federal debt-much
of their debt
should not be counted in DNFD, that
is, as nonfinancial debt. Because it is,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Material may be reprinted provided that the
source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted
materials to the editor.

however, federal debt is counted both
directly as a federal liability and
indirectly as "financial" debt of state
and local governments. In fact, since
1982, the buildup in state and local
debt has been associated with an
even greater buildup in credit market
assets held by state and local governments. The nonfinancial component
actually declined.
It seems evident in DNFD behavior
since 1982 that the recent spate in
financial innovation has not been
selective in its disruption of seemingly reliable relationships between
financial measures and ultimate
targets of policy. As has occurred
with measures of money, DNFD has
deviated significantly from its historical relationship with economic activity. The disruption of the debt relationship was probably also affected
by the recent surge in federal government budget deficits.
The seemingly stable nature of the
ratio, DNFD/GNP, before 1982 is
perhaps even more curious now than
ever before. It would appear that the
winding down of federal debt from
its World War II buildup coincidentally equaled the rise in private debt
over the same period. Many of the
factors that accounted (albeit more
intensively) for the recent surgesuch as convenient use of credit, tax
arbitraging, etc.-also
accounted for
the upward trend in private debt
before federal debt began to balloon.

Policy Implications

When first announcing annual
growth ranges for DNFD, the Federal Reserve made the distinction
between monitoring ranges and
target ranges. The growth range for

DNFD was a monitoring range,
while the growth ranges for money
measures had typically been target
ranges. This indicated that deviations in debt from its expected path
would be weighed less heavily in the
policymaking process than money
measures, particularly Ml. In fact,
with the breakdown in the relationship between money and income, the
Fed has placed less reliance on Ml as
a short-term guide to policy. For
much of the period since 1982, no one
financial measure has proved to be
reliable enough to be a sole shortterm policy guide.
In retrospect, the reluctance to rely
much on a credit measure as a guide
for short-run policy actions appears
appropriate. The extremely rapid
growth in DNFD has not been followed by excessively rapid growth in
nominal GNP, as would be suggested
by the simple historical relationship.
Without a well-developed framework
linking DNFD to economic activity,
and strong empirical support for the
framework, it seems unlikely that
DNFD will provide information
about the economy that is sufficiently reliable for predicting nearterm growth of the economy.
Over a longer horizon, however,
the continued trend of DNFD/GNP
cannot be sustained without having
serious economic consequences. If
debt were to continue to grow around
6 percent faster than GNP, as it has
since 1982, then sometime early next
century, the public would be forced
to borrow the equivalent of the entire
gross national product simply to pay
the interest on the debt. In view of
the longer-term concern, it seems
appropriate to continue to monitor
DNFD growth, despite its limitations
as a short-term policy guide.
BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385

Address Correction Requested: Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

July 1, 1986
ISSN 0428-1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
The Federal Reserve is required by
the Full Employment and Balanced
Growth Act of 1978 to report to Congress its annual growth objectives
for money and credit. Over the years,
most attention has been paid to
objectives for measures of moneyparticularly Ml, which traditionally
served as the primary guide for
monetary policy. Recently, however,
measures of credit have received
more attention by researchers.
In 1983, the Federal Reserve began
reporting to Congress expected
annual growth ranges for domestic
nonfinancial debt (DNFD), the aggregate net indebtedness of all nonfinancial borrowers in the United
States. In addition to borrowings by
U.S. households and businesses,
DNFD includes debt owed by all levels of government, federal, state and
local. It excludes dollar-denominated
debt owed by foreigners, however,
and is nonfinancial in that it excludes liabilities of financial intermediaries, such as commercial
banks, thrift institutions and finance
companies.
Prior to 1983, the Federal Reserve
had established ranges for bank
credit, but this category of credit did
not seem to convey reliable information about economic activity such as
output, employment and inflation.
Research suggested, however, that
the changes in the broader DNFD
measure provided better indications
of changes in future nominal gross
national product (GNP). Some
researchers even argued that DNFD
was as closely related to economic
activity as some measures of money,
including the monetary base. Nevertheless, the Federal Reserve distin-

John B. Carlson is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The views stated herein
are those of the author and not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

guished monitoring ranges for DNFD
from target ranges for monetary
aggregates to indicate a somewhat
lesser status for debt in the determination of monetary policy (see box).
In recent years, there have been
some strong crosscurrents
affecting
the behavior of financial measures
watched by the Federal Reserve. It is
widely understood in financial
markets that financial innovation
and deregulation, in conjunction
with declining interest rates and

Financial Variables as
Intermediate Targets

One purpose of an intermediate
target is to provide guidance for
policy action. The effects of monetary policy on ultimate targets (e.g.
output employment and prices) is
both slow and uncertain. While not
itself the ultimate concern of policymakers,
a financial
variable
target can usually be measured
more quickly and frequently than
measures of ultimate policy targets
and, therefore, provide more timely
information about both the state of
the economy and the consistency of
policy actions with the ultimate
objectives. Thus intermediate
targets must be closely linked to ultimate targets so that policy actions
that seek to achieve intermediate
targets will also achieve ultimate
targets.
Equally important,
the
intermediate
target must be amenable to control by policy actions.
inflation, have had a drastic impact
on the relationship between Ml-the
most widely recognized measure of
money-and
nominal GNP. This is
especially evident in the behavior of
velocity, the ratio of nominal GNP to
Ml. In the 30 years prior to 1982, Ml
velocity increased at a trend growth
rate of 3 percent. Since 1982, however, it has not increased along any
trend.

Domestic
Nonfinancial Debt:
After Three Years
of Monitoring
by John Carlson

With the breakdown in the relationship of money to the economy, it
would seem that credit might
assume a greater role in the determination of monetary policy. However,
the behavior of DNFD has also been
unusual relative to its historical
pattern. In the 30 years prior to 1982,
DNFD tended to grow in proportion
to nominal GNP. Since 1982, debt
has tended to grow much more
rapidly than nominal GNP.
In this Economic Commentary, we
examine the recent behavior of
DNFD in relation to its historical
pattern. Likely factors accounting for
the recent surge in debt are discussed. The implications of this large
increase for the role of DNFD in the
determination of monetary policy are
also examined.'

Debt and Nonfinancial
Economic Activity: 1946-1982

Chart 1 displays the virtually trendless pattern of total debt, relative to
GNP, that seemed evident through
1982. An intriguing characteristic
of
these data is that total debt remained
stable despite the disparate trends
evident in its major components.
While the federal government ran
budget deficits for most years in this
period, federal debt declined relative
to the size of the economy. However,
as federal debt fell, private debt
increased relative to GNP by roughly
the same amount.
The stability of total DNFD relative to GNP through 1980 suggested
to some researchers that DNFD
could provide reliable information
about current and future levels of
nominal GNP. This implied that

1. Some of the concerns about debt are not about
its implications for short-run economic activity,
but about implications for the soundness and
safety of the banking system.

DNFD was a reasonable variable to
consider as an intermediate target
for monetary policy. It also suggested
that relatively steady growth in
DNFD might be associated with
steady growth in nominal GNP. This
latter view is analogous to that of
Friedman and Schwartz (1963), who
built an extensive argument for
monetarist policies on the basis of
the stability of the velocity of
money."
Benjamin Friedman (1981) applied
a variety of empirical methodologies
along the lines of Friedman and
Schwartz to argue an equally "persuasive" case for the importance of
debt in explaining changes in nonfinancial economic activity.' The central thrust of this case was to document and explain the relative stability of the ratio of DNFD to nominal
GNP from 1953 to 1980. Overall,
Friedman found that changes in
DNFD explained changes in nominal
GNP at least as well as alternative
measures of money, including the
monetary base.
While DNFD fared well in empirical comparisons with money, the
relationship of DNFD to GNP lacked
the extensive theoretical basis underlying models of money demand. Models for the demand for transactions
balances had been derived from principles of individual behavior. In lieu
of such rigorous underpinnings
for
debt, B. Friedman offered three
alternative explanations for the stable pattern. Each of these explanations relates the observed stability of
the DNFD-to-GNP ratio to the savings and consumption patterns of
indi vid uals.
Total consumption and savings in
the economy tend to remain fairly
constant in proportion to income
over time because individuals like to
smooth their spending over their lifetimes. They tend to spend more than
their income (dissave) in their
younger years, save in their middle
years and run down their savings in
later years. In the overall economy,
demographics must be such that this
behavior is possible; that is, a large
enough segment of the population
must save so that others without
savings can borrow to smooth spending over their lives. Since the ability
of some (including businesses and
the government) to borrow on net
depends on the willingness of others
2. See Friedman, Milton and Anna Schwartz. A
Monetary History of the United States; 18671960, Princeton University Press, Princeton,
(1963).

hypothesis presumes individuals
have a strong bequest motive. If
individuals save, in part, to leave
Chart 1 Debt Relative to GNP
1946-1986
wealth to their heirs, then they
might save more (less) when govPercent of annual GNP
ernment debt rises (falls) in order to
175·.----------------.
offset any expected future tax
increase (decrease) associated with
the debt. This would affect the private savings rate in a manner that
would offset federal government dissaving. While this latter view seems
to be more soundly based on principles of individual behavior, it is
nevertheless inconsistent with the
relatively constant private savings
Total nonfinancial
rate in the postwar period.
Friedman's second explanation
argues that the growth of total debt
is limited by the availability of tangible assets that provide collateral for
the debt. He assumes in this argument that individuals regard
b' bX, £0' £ox,0." 0.x, rt;,' rt;,"<;) government
debt (which they hold in
their portfolios) as part of their net
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
wealth; that is, they do not associate
a liablity with government debt. If
to save, Friedman suggested that
the government would reduce its
explanations for the stability of
debt, individuals would reshuffe
DNFD-to-income ratio could be
their portfolios, acquiring more tangrelated to the stable savings ratio in
ible assets to maintain their constant
different ways.
savings rate. Friedman argues that
His first explanation alleges that
the increase in tangible assets would,
individuals "see through the shell"
in turn, provide additional collateral
of both corporations and governagainst which consumers and firms
ment. If corporations save more
could borrow. Thus, private debt
(less), individuals adjust by saving
could increase by the amount governless (more) from their wage income
ment debt decreased.
to keep the private saving ratio and
Friedman's third explanation
hence the amount of net debt relative
assumes that the public holds both
to income constant. This seems reasdebt assets and nondebt assets in its
onable because individuals ultiportfolios, each in proportion to
mately own the corporations and
income. If the government reduces
receive the profits that arise from
its debt outstanding, the relative
corporate saving, that is, the returns
return on government securities
from corporate investment. Consewould fall and individuals would
quently, individuals could view corshift their portfolios toward private
porate savings as their own.
debt securities. It is implicitly preThe "see-through-the-shell"
argusumed that prices of private securiment is more controversial as it appties would increase sufficiently to
lies to government debt. Essentially,
induce an additional supply of priit is assumed that the public in some
vate debt to match the amount of the
way seeks to maintain a constant
decline in government debt. This
level of liabilities-owed relative to
also presumes that individuals do not
national income. The result is that it
wish to hold more tangible assets or
is the amount of private borrowing
equity as relative yields change.
that adjusts to changes in governEach of Friedman's three explanament borrowing, not private saving.
tions for the stability between DNFD
This hypothesis is in conflict with
and GNP had some plausibilty until
another popular hypothesis that
1982, Yet each is rather ad hoc, lacktreats government saving as equivaling the theoretical underpinnings
ent to private saving. The latter
that money-demand hypotheses
enjoy, and none has independent
empirical support like money3. See Friedman, Benjamin M., "The Relative
demand equations. Indeed, based on
Stability of Money and Credit 'Velocities' in the
other research, Friedman was careful
United States: Evidence and Some Speculanot to suggest relying too much on
tions," Working Paper Series, No.645, National
DNFD
or, for that matter, on anyone
Bureau of Economic Research, March 1981.

*'
-es,~~~~~~~-es

financial variable for policy purposes.
This caution was well advised; after
1982, the link between DNFD and
GNP no longer seemed very stable.

Chart 2 Domestic Nonfinancial
Debt and Monitoring Ranges
Billions of dollars
77001__ -----------

__

DNFD Since 1982

As stressed above, the reported
growth ranges for DNFD are for
monitoring credit growth and are not
target ranges. That is, the Federal
Reserve attempts to anticipate its
growth in relation to other goals, but
would not necessarily respond to
movements outside the stated
ranges. It is evident from the monitoring experience that the acceleration of debt growth was largely
unanticipated (chart 2). In each of
the years since 1983, when monitoring ranges were first announced,
actual DNFD growth exceeded the
upper bound of the range. This largely reflects an unanticipated disturbance to a seemingly stable relationship between debt and income. The
most striking aspect of this change is
that both private and government
debt components surged in relation
to income.
The large increases in federal debt
relative to the size of the economy
are largely a result of the Economic
Recovery Tax Act (ERTA) of 1981, a
tax initiative that sharply reduced
the growth rate of tax revenues.
Large tax cuts were instituted with
the expectation that there would be
subsequent spending reductions in
nonmilitary programs, as well as
additional revenues generated by
more rapid economic growth. Subsequent output growth was relatively
strong and generated proportionately
more revenues, but the impact of
ERTA fell short of supplysider
claims that it would produce sufficient revenue growth to eliminate
the deficit. Moreover, Congress did
not accept all the spending cuts
initially sought by the Administration. This imbalance is likely to persist if Gramm-Rudman objectives for
future deficit reductions are not
achieved.
The resurgence of growth in Federal debt in recent years was not
matched by a decline in private debt
that would have been required to
maintain the historical stability of
DNFD/GNP. In fact, nonfederal
domestic debt resumed the upward
trend that characterized its pattern
for most of the postwar period. This
new movement-uniform
across all
nonfederal borrowing sectors-seems
to contradict the three explanations

....

'.'

1986
Monitoring
Year
1983
1984
1985
1986

Ranges
Percent
8.5 to 11.5
8.5 to 11.5
9.0 to 12.0
8.0 to 11.0

Actual
10.8
13.4
13.1

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

that account for the stability of the
ratio.
The greatest impetus in private
borrowing came from the household
sector, with increases in mortgage
debt and a surge in consumer installment credit. The rise in household
mortgage debt was not particularly
strong when viewed against comparable stages of the business cycle.
The pace of consumer installment
credit since 1982 has, on the other
hand, exceeded that of any period
since World War II. This appears to
be attributable to several factors.
First, households have increasingly
expanded their use of credit cards for
their convenience in transactions,
as
opposed to spending in excess of
their incomes. Many credit card
users payoff their new balances in
full each month, thereby avoiding
interest charges. The additional
"free" debt created as this form of
usage increases is more like a transactions balance than debt, and adds
nothing to debt burden. The convenience use of credit cards helps to
explain why this form of debt has
grown so rapidly in spite of the high
interest charges on balances not paid
off immediately.
Another factor contributing to the
acceleration in consumer debt may
be a consequence of the lengthening

in the maturity of debt. For, example, an increasing number of new car
buyers have been choosing the fiveyear loans over the historically more
common three-year loan, thus
extending the average maturity of
this debt, for example, to 50.2
months in December 1984, from 41.3
months in 1983. Again, debt burden,
the monthly interest and principle
payments, has not increased as
rapidly as debt because monthly
payments are reduced (assuming
cars last longer).
Third, demographic factors probably could also have contributed to the
upward movement in consumer
installment credit.' The movement of
baby boom generation members into
the stage of their life where they
tend to borrow more raises the
aggregate level of borrowing in the
economy. This factor, in turn,
undermines the stable relationship
between wealth and income that was
assumed in the explanations offered
for the stability of DNFD/GNP.
Although part of the recent
increase in business borrowing may
reflect cyclical factors, a significant
amount can be attributed to taxrelated incentives that may account
for its longer-term upward trend.
Firms may deduct interest payments
from business income for tax purposes, but not dividends. This, in
effect, makes the cost of funds
acquired from issuing debt relatively
cheaper than from issuing equity.
While these tax incentives have
existed for many years, the recent
spate of mergers and leveraged
buyouts seems to have induced corporate financial managers to more
fully exploit the tax advantages of
debt. The increase in mergers and
leveraged buyouts reflects, in part,
other bases for perceived arbitrage
opportunities. Many of the takeover
targets were viewed as undervalued,
particularly before the recent surge
in stock prices. Furthermore, recent
developments in financial markets,
such as the trend toward junk bond
financing, have made corporate

4. Warshawsky (1985) presents theoretical evidence casting doubt on the underlying assumption about the stability of the wealth-to-income
ratio. These results undermine the fundamental
basis advanced by Friedman to rationalize the
observed stability between debt and income. See
Warshawsky, Mark, "The Fundamental Determinants of Aggregate Debt and Wealth," Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
August 1985.

DNFD was a reasonable variable to
consider as an intermediate target
for monetary policy. It also suggested
that relatively steady growth in
DNFD might be associated with
steady growth in nominal GNP. This
latter view is analogous to that of
Friedman and Schwartz (1963), who
built an extensive argument for
monetarist policies on the basis of
the stability of the velocity of
money."
Benjamin Friedman (1981) applied
a variety of empirical methodologies
along the lines of Friedman and
Schwartz to argue an equally "persuasive" case for the importance of
debt in explaining changes in nonfinancial economic activity.' The central thrust of this case was to document and explain the relative stability of the ratio of DNFD to nominal
GNP from 1953 to 1980. Overall,
Friedman found that changes in
DNFD explained changes in nominal
GNP at least as well as alternative
measures of money, including the
monetary base.
While DNFD fared well in empirical comparisons with money, the
relationship of DNFD to GNP lacked
the extensive theoretical basis underlying models of money demand. Models for the demand for transactions
balances had been derived from principles of individual behavior. In lieu
of such rigorous underpinnings
for
debt, B. Friedman offered three
alternative explanations for the stable pattern. Each of these explanations relates the observed stability of
the DNFD-to-GNP ratio to the savings and consumption patterns of
indi vid uals.
Total consumption and savings in
the economy tend to remain fairly
constant in proportion to income
over time because individuals like to
smooth their spending over their lifetimes. They tend to spend more than
their income (dissave) in their
younger years, save in their middle
years and run down their savings in
later years. In the overall economy,
demographics must be such that this
behavior is possible; that is, a large
enough segment of the population
must save so that others without
savings can borrow to smooth spending over their lives. Since the ability
of some (including businesses and
the government) to borrow on net
depends on the willingness of others
2. See Friedman, Milton and Anna Schwartz. A
Monetary History of the United States; 18671960, Princeton University Press, Princeton,
(1963).

hypothesis presumes individuals
have a strong bequest motive. If
individuals save, in part, to leave
Chart 1 Debt Relative to GNP
1946-1986
wealth to their heirs, then they
might save more (less) when govPercent of annual GNP
ernment debt rises (falls) in order to
175·.----------------.
offset any expected future tax
increase (decrease) associated with
the debt. This would affect the private savings rate in a manner that
would offset federal government dissaving. While this latter view seems
to be more soundly based on principles of individual behavior, it is
nevertheless inconsistent with the
relatively constant private savings
Total nonfinancial
rate in the postwar period.
Friedman's second explanation
argues that the growth of total debt
is limited by the availability of tangible assets that provide collateral for
the debt. He assumes in this argument that individuals regard
b' bX, £0' £ox,0." 0.x, rt;,' rt;,"<;) government
debt (which they hold in
their portfolios) as part of their net
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
wealth; that is, they do not associate
a liablity with government debt. If
to save, Friedman suggested that
the government would reduce its
explanations for the stability of
debt, individuals would reshuffe
DNFD-to-income ratio could be
their portfolios, acquiring more tangrelated to the stable savings ratio in
ible assets to maintain their constant
different ways.
savings rate. Friedman argues that
His first explanation alleges that
the increase in tangible assets would,
individuals "see through the shell"
in turn, provide additional collateral
of both corporations and governagainst which consumers and firms
ment. If corporations save more
could borrow. Thus, private debt
(less), individuals adjust by saving
could increase by the amount governless (more) from their wage income
ment debt decreased.
to keep the private saving ratio and
Friedman's third explanation
hence the amount of net debt relative
assumes that the public holds both
to income constant. This seems reasdebt assets and nondebt assets in its
onable because individuals ultiportfolios, each in proportion to
mately own the corporations and
income. If the government reduces
receive the profits that arise from
its debt outstanding, the relative
corporate saving, that is, the returns
return on government securities
from corporate investment. Consewould fall and individuals would
quently, individuals could view corshift their portfolios toward private
porate savings as their own.
debt securities. It is implicitly preThe "see-through-the-shell"
argusumed that prices of private securiment is more controversial as it appties would increase sufficiently to
lies to government debt. Essentially,
induce an additional supply of priit is assumed that the public in some
vate debt to match the amount of the
way seeks to maintain a constant
decline in government debt. This
level of liabilities-owed relative to
also presumes that individuals do not
national income. The result is that it
wish to hold more tangible assets or
is the amount of private borrowing
equity as relative yields change.
that adjusts to changes in governEach of Friedman's three explanament borrowing, not private saving.
tions for the stability between DNFD
This hypothesis is in conflict with
and GNP had some plausibilty until
another popular hypothesis that
1982, Yet each is rather ad hoc, lacktreats government saving as equivaling the theoretical underpinnings
ent to private saving. The latter
that money-demand hypotheses
enjoy, and none has independent
empirical support like money3. See Friedman, Benjamin M., "The Relative
demand equations. Indeed, based on
Stability of Money and Credit 'Velocities' in the
other research, Friedman was careful
United States: Evidence and Some Speculanot to suggest relying too much on
tions," Working Paper Series, No.645, National
DNFD
or, for that matter, on anyone
Bureau of Economic Research, March 1981.

*'
-es,~~~~~~~-es

financial variable for policy purposes.
This caution was well advised; after
1982, the link between DNFD and
GNP no longer seemed very stable.

Chart 2 Domestic Nonfinancial
Debt and Monitoring Ranges
Billions of dollars
77001__ -----------

__

DNFD Since 1982

As stressed above, the reported
growth ranges for DNFD are for
monitoring credit growth and are not
target ranges. That is, the Federal
Reserve attempts to anticipate its
growth in relation to other goals, but
would not necessarily respond to
movements outside the stated
ranges. It is evident from the monitoring experience that the acceleration of debt growth was largely
unanticipated (chart 2). In each of
the years since 1983, when monitoring ranges were first announced,
actual DNFD growth exceeded the
upper bound of the range. This largely reflects an unanticipated disturbance to a seemingly stable relationship between debt and income. The
most striking aspect of this change is
that both private and government
debt components surged in relation
to income.
The large increases in federal debt
relative to the size of the economy
are largely a result of the Economic
Recovery Tax Act (ERTA) of 1981, a
tax initiative that sharply reduced
the growth rate of tax revenues.
Large tax cuts were instituted with
the expectation that there would be
subsequent spending reductions in
nonmilitary programs, as well as
additional revenues generated by
more rapid economic growth. Subsequent output growth was relatively
strong and generated proportionately
more revenues, but the impact of
ERTA fell short of supplysider
claims that it would produce sufficient revenue growth to eliminate
the deficit. Moreover, Congress did
not accept all the spending cuts
initially sought by the Administration. This imbalance is likely to persist if Gramm-Rudman objectives for
future deficit reductions are not
achieved.
The resurgence of growth in Federal debt in recent years was not
matched by a decline in private debt
that would have been required to
maintain the historical stability of
DNFD/GNP. In fact, nonfederal
domestic debt resumed the upward
trend that characterized its pattern
for most of the postwar period. This
new movement-uniform
across all
nonfederal borrowing sectors-seems
to contradict the three explanations

....

'.'

1986
Monitoring
Year
1983
1984
1985
1986

Ranges
Percent
8.5 to 11.5
8.5 to 11.5
9.0 to 12.0
8.0 to 11.0

Actual
10.8
13.4
13.1

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

that account for the stability of the
ratio.
The greatest impetus in private
borrowing came from the household
sector, with increases in mortgage
debt and a surge in consumer installment credit. The rise in household
mortgage debt was not particularly
strong when viewed against comparable stages of the business cycle.
The pace of consumer installment
credit since 1982 has, on the other
hand, exceeded that of any period
since World War II. This appears to
be attributable to several factors.
First, households have increasingly
expanded their use of credit cards for
their convenience in transactions,
as
opposed to spending in excess of
their incomes. Many credit card
users payoff their new balances in
full each month, thereby avoiding
interest charges. The additional
"free" debt created as this form of
usage increases is more like a transactions balance than debt, and adds
nothing to debt burden. The convenience use of credit cards helps to
explain why this form of debt has
grown so rapidly in spite of the high
interest charges on balances not paid
off immediately.
Another factor contributing to the
acceleration in consumer debt may
be a consequence of the lengthening

in the maturity of debt. For, example, an increasing number of new car
buyers have been choosing the fiveyear loans over the historically more
common three-year loan, thus
extending the average maturity of
this debt, for example, to 50.2
months in December 1984, from 41.3
months in 1983. Again, debt burden,
the monthly interest and principle
payments, has not increased as
rapidly as debt because monthly
payments are reduced (assuming
cars last longer).
Third, demographic factors probably could also have contributed to the
upward movement in consumer
installment credit.' The movement of
baby boom generation members into
the stage of their life where they
tend to borrow more raises the
aggregate level of borrowing in the
economy. This factor, in turn,
undermines the stable relationship
between wealth and income that was
assumed in the explanations offered
for the stability of DNFD/GNP.
Although part of the recent
increase in business borrowing may
reflect cyclical factors, a significant
amount can be attributed to taxrelated incentives that may account
for its longer-term upward trend.
Firms may deduct interest payments
from business income for tax purposes, but not dividends. This, in
effect, makes the cost of funds
acquired from issuing debt relatively
cheaper than from issuing equity.
While these tax incentives have
existed for many years, the recent
spate of mergers and leveraged
buyouts seems to have induced corporate financial managers to more
fully exploit the tax advantages of
debt. The increase in mergers and
leveraged buyouts reflects, in part,
other bases for perceived arbitrage
opportunities. Many of the takeover
targets were viewed as undervalued,
particularly before the recent surge
in stock prices. Furthermore, recent
developments in financial markets,
such as the trend toward junk bond
financing, have made corporate

4. Warshawsky (1985) presents theoretical evidence casting doubt on the underlying assumption about the stability of the wealth-to-income
ratio. These results undermine the fundamental
basis advanced by Friedman to rationalize the
observed stability between debt and income. See
Warshawsky, Mark, "The Fundamental Determinants of Aggregate Debt and Wealth," Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
August 1985.

takeovers and leveraged buyouts
much easier to accomplish and, thereby, may have induced an acceleration in business debt above its
longer-term trend rate.
The apparent increase in debt of
state and local governments since
1982 is essentially a consequence of
double counting. In recent years,
state and local governments have
increasingly assumed the role of
financial intermediaries,
i.e., borrowing funds directly at tax-exempt
interest rates and making the proceeds available to other borrowers
(some for private purposes). Late last
year, the House tax bill threatened to
significantly limit the incentives
leading to this kind of intermediation. Consequently, many state and
local governments came to market
early to avoid missing opportunities
that they thought would be taken
away January 1, 1986.
Flush with additional funds, these
issuers invested the surplus amounts
in credit market instruments.
While
much attention was given to the
increased demand for SLUGS (a special class of treasury issues sold only
to state and local governments), state
and local governments invested heavily in a wide spectrum of U.S.
government and agency issues. Over
90 percent of the assets acquired
were U.S. government securities.
Private assets acquired through
mortgage bonds and student loan
bonds were sold off.
Because state and local governments are essentially acting as
financial intermediaries-buying
federal debt-much
of their debt
should not be counted in DNFD, that
is, as nonfinancial debt. Because it is,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Material may be reprinted provided that the
source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted
materials to the editor.

however, federal debt is counted both
directly as a federal liability and
indirectly as "financial" debt of state
and local governments. In fact, since
1982, the buildup in state and local
debt has been associated with an
even greater buildup in credit market
assets held by state and local governments. The nonfinancial component
actually declined.
It seems evident in DNFD behavior
since 1982 that the recent spate in
financial innovation has not been
selective in its disruption of seemingly reliable relationships between
financial measures and ultimate
targets of policy. As has occurred
with measures of money, DNFD has
deviated significantly from its historical relationship with economic activity. The disruption of the debt relationship was probably also affected
by the recent surge in federal government budget deficits.
The seemingly stable nature of the
ratio, DNFD/GNP, before 1982 is
perhaps even more curious now than
ever before. It would appear that the
winding down of federal debt from
its World War II buildup coincidentally equaled the rise in private debt
over the same period. Many of the
factors that accounted (albeit more
intensively) for the recent surgesuch as convenient use of credit, tax
arbitraging, etc.-also
accounted for
the upward trend in private debt
before federal debt began to balloon.

Policy Implications

When first announcing annual
growth ranges for DNFD, the Federal Reserve made the distinction
between monitoring ranges and
target ranges. The growth range for

DNFD was a monitoring range,
while the growth ranges for money
measures had typically been target
ranges. This indicated that deviations in debt from its expected path
would be weighed less heavily in the
policymaking process than money
measures, particularly Ml. In fact,
with the breakdown in the relationship between money and income, the
Fed has placed less reliance on Ml as
a short-term guide to policy. For
much of the period since 1982, no one
financial measure has proved to be
reliable enough to be a sole shortterm policy guide.
In retrospect, the reluctance to rely
much on a credit measure as a guide
for short-run policy actions appears
appropriate. The extremely rapid
growth in DNFD has not been followed by excessively rapid growth in
nominal GNP, as would be suggested
by the simple historical relationship.
Without a well-developed framework
linking DNFD to economic activity,
and strong empirical support for the
framework, it seems unlikely that
DNFD will provide information
about the economy that is sufficiently reliable for predicting nearterm growth of the economy.
Over a longer horizon, however,
the continued trend of DNFD/GNP
cannot be sustained without having
serious economic consequences. If
debt were to continue to grow around
6 percent faster than GNP, as it has
since 1982, then sometime early next
century, the public would be forced
to borrow the equivalent of the entire
gross national product simply to pay
the interest on the debt. In view of
the longer-term concern, it seems
appropriate to continue to monitor
DNFD growth, despite its limitations
as a short-term policy guide.
BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385

Address Correction Requested: Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

July 1, 1986
ISSN 0428-1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
The Federal Reserve is required by
the Full Employment and Balanced
Growth Act of 1978 to report to Congress its annual growth objectives
for money and credit. Over the years,
most attention has been paid to
objectives for measures of moneyparticularly Ml, which traditionally
served as the primary guide for
monetary policy. Recently, however,
measures of credit have received
more attention by researchers.
In 1983, the Federal Reserve began
reporting to Congress expected
annual growth ranges for domestic
nonfinancial debt (DNFD), the aggregate net indebtedness of all nonfinancial borrowers in the United
States. In addition to borrowings by
U.S. households and businesses,
DNFD includes debt owed by all levels of government, federal, state and
local. It excludes dollar-denominated
debt owed by foreigners, however,
and is nonfinancial in that it excludes liabilities of financial intermediaries, such as commercial
banks, thrift institutions and finance
companies.
Prior to 1983, the Federal Reserve
had established ranges for bank
credit, but this category of credit did
not seem to convey reliable information about economic activity such as
output, employment and inflation.
Research suggested, however, that
the changes in the broader DNFD
measure provided better indications
of changes in future nominal gross
national product (GNP). Some
researchers even argued that DNFD
was as closely related to economic
activity as some measures of money,
including the monetary base. Nevertheless, the Federal Reserve distin-

John B. Carlson is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The views stated herein
are those of the author and not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

guished monitoring ranges for DNFD
from target ranges for monetary
aggregates to indicate a somewhat
lesser status for debt in the determination of monetary policy (see box).
In recent years, there have been
some strong crosscurrents
affecting
the behavior of financial measures
watched by the Federal Reserve. It is
widely understood in financial
markets that financial innovation
and deregulation, in conjunction
with declining interest rates and

Financial Variables as
Intermediate Targets

One purpose of an intermediate
target is to provide guidance for
policy action. The effects of monetary policy on ultimate targets (e.g.
output employment and prices) is
both slow and uncertain. While not
itself the ultimate concern of policymakers,
a financial
variable
target can usually be measured
more quickly and frequently than
measures of ultimate policy targets
and, therefore, provide more timely
information about both the state of
the economy and the consistency of
policy actions with the ultimate
objectives. Thus intermediate
targets must be closely linked to ultimate targets so that policy actions
that seek to achieve intermediate
targets will also achieve ultimate
targets.
Equally important,
the
intermediate
target must be amenable to control by policy actions.
inflation, have had a drastic impact
on the relationship between Ml-the
most widely recognized measure of
money-and
nominal GNP. This is
especially evident in the behavior of
velocity, the ratio of nominal GNP to
Ml. In the 30 years prior to 1982, Ml
velocity increased at a trend growth
rate of 3 percent. Since 1982, however, it has not increased along any
trend.

Domestic
Nonfinancial Debt:
After Three Years
of Monitoring
by John Carlson

With the breakdown in the relationship of money to the economy, it
would seem that credit might
assume a greater role in the determination of monetary policy. However,
the behavior of DNFD has also been
unusual relative to its historical
pattern. In the 30 years prior to 1982,
DNFD tended to grow in proportion
to nominal GNP. Since 1982, debt
has tended to grow much more
rapidly than nominal GNP.
In this Economic Commentary, we
examine the recent behavior of
DNFD in relation to its historical
pattern. Likely factors accounting for
the recent surge in debt are discussed. The implications of this large
increase for the role of DNFD in the
determination of monetary policy are
also examined.'

Debt and Nonfinancial
Economic Activity: 1946-1982

Chart 1 displays the virtually trendless pattern of total debt, relative to
GNP, that seemed evident through
1982. An intriguing characteristic
of
these data is that total debt remained
stable despite the disparate trends
evident in its major components.
While the federal government ran
budget deficits for most years in this
period, federal debt declined relative
to the size of the economy. However,
as federal debt fell, private debt
increased relative to GNP by roughly
the same amount.
The stability of total DNFD relative to GNP through 1980 suggested
to some researchers that DNFD
could provide reliable information
about current and future levels of
nominal GNP. This implied that

1. Some of the concerns about debt are not about
its implications for short-run economic activity,
but about implications for the soundness and
safety of the banking system.