View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 15, 1994

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTORY
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Assessing Progress toward Price
Stability: Looking Forward and
Looking Backward
by John B. Carlson
We will be at price stability when
households and businesses need not
factor expectations of changes in the
average level of prices into their decisions. How those expectations form is
not always easy to discern, and they
can for periods of time appear to be at
variance with underlying economic
forces. But history tells us that it is economic and financial forces and their
consequences for realized inflation that
ultimately shape inflation expectations.
Alan Greenspan1

The high cost of obtaining information
via surveys limits their scope and frequency. Ascertaining the appropriate information with the right questions is
difficult, and imperfect survey methods
invariably lead to sampling error.
Nevertheless, policymakers cannot always depend on the rear-view mirror as a
guide to where the price level might be
headed. Traditional economic thinking
holds that the impact of monetary policy
affects inflation only with a significant
lag. Thus, an overly stimulative policy
stance may not become evident until it is
too late to be turned around without
wrenching consequences.

inflation, as measured by the rate of
change of the Consumer Price Index
(CP1), has slowed substantially in recent
years. Since 1990, it has averaged less
than 3 percent, compared with an average
rate of about 5 percent in the previous
three years (see figure 1). Similarly, other
measures, designed to exclude transitory
special factors and focus on the so-called
core or underlying rate of inflation, have
also slowed to around 3 percent. From
the perspective of this rear-view mirror,
it seems evident that the deceleration in
prices has stopped, as both measures
have tended to stabilize around the recent lower mean levels.
Survey data on inflation expectations of
households and professional forecasters,
on the other hand, suggest that not all of
the decline is permanent and that the
price level will tend to rise slightly over
the coming year. Although survey data
provide some forward-looking element,
the problems associated with measuring
inflation expectations are well known.

ISSN 0428-1276

Such a situation is sometimes likened
to a freighter with a full head of steam.
The captain must take actions well in
advance if he is to alter the course of
the ship and avoid treacherous shoals.
The experience of the 1970s, when
double-digit inflation rates reigned, is
typically offered as a case in point of
the failure of policy to act preemptively. Most analysts agree that appropriate countermeasures were not taken
soon enough.
The purpose of this Economic Commentary is to examine more closely the
problem of assessing the inflationary
effects of current policy. I first describe
how a selected measure of core inflation excludes potential transitory effects. I review the behavior of this
measure since 1982, then contrast the
pattern of core inflation with house-

Inflation moderated in the early 1990s,
as revealed by the Consumer Price Index and measures of core inflation. Significant changes in inflation have been
infrequent and rather abrupt over the
past decade and have coincided with
similar changes in inflation expectations. Although survey data from both
consumers and professional forecasters
suggest that expected inflation has been
an unbiased predictor of future inflation, recent experience indicates a persistent overprediction. Nevertheless, the
timing between changes in actual and
expected inflation implies that both are
driven by the same factors; that is, expectations are formed rationally.

hold expectations one year ahead. Although their mean inflation expectations have historically been unbiased,
households have overpredicted inflation in recent years. The survey data of
professional forecasters reveal a similar, albeit less pronounced, tendency.
• Core Inflation
Core inflation measures are generally designed to extract the long-run, or permanent, component of the measured price
index by filtering out transitory special
factors. For example, food and energy
components of the CP1 are subject to periodic supply shocks that produce relatively large but short-lived (although
sometimes persistent) shifts in the index

that are unrelated to more permanent
changes. Although food and energy are
among the more volatile components
of the CPI, other comparably volatile
components remain in the core inflation measure; thus, the CPI excluding
food and energy is somewhat arbitrary.
One alternative measure of core inflation proposed in a recent Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland study does
not preselect any particular sectors for
exclusion.2 Rather, it is calculated by
trimming the outlying portions of the
cross-sectional distribution of the components of aggregate price indices in each
month. Thus, it does not single out any
sector as the primary source of transitory
distortion for all periods. More specifically, the authors consider a trimmed
mean that represents the weighted average of the central 85 percent of the pricechange distribution. They chose the 15
percent trimmed mean because it had the
smallest monthly variance of all estimators of this type.
Figure 2 illustrates core inflation as
measured by the 15 percent trimmed
mean since 1982, along with trend
rates of change within selected subperiods. Statistical change-point methods
have identified these as periods in
which the mean inflation rate is essentially fixed and deviations from the
mean are random and independent
from period to period.1 One implication of these results is that the best
guess of inflation in any period is its
mean value in that period.
The success of this measure in excluding transitory special factors is best
highlighted when contrasted with the
behavior of the CPI around 1985-86
(see figure 1). At that time, the dip in
the CPI was largely held to be the result of a transitory decline in oil prices.
The 15 percent trimmed mean showed
no such downturn.
Although the trend in the core measure
has changed since 1982, the statistical
change-point procedures find that such
shifts have been infrequent and rather
abrupt. Core inflation first accelerated
moderately around May 1988, then fell

FIGURE 1

INFLATION AND CORE INFLATION OVER
PREVIOUS 12 MONTHS

Percent
16
CPI inflation

I
1969

1974

1979

1984

1989

1994

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor. Bureau of Labor Statistics: and the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

FIGURE 2

CORE INFLATION, 1983-94

Percent change, annual rate

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

NOTE: Numbers above solid rules indicate central tendency. Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations
of central tendency.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

sharply between January and February
1991—at the same time the Persian
Gulf War was resolved, eliminating a
great deal of uncertainty about the future of oil prices.4
Interestingly, the variability of core inflation around means within periods
tended to rise and fall with the mean
level of change. The standard deviation
of core inflation since 1991 has been
less than 1 percentage point, suggesting that inflation has fallen in some per-

manent sense to rates not seen since the
mid-1960s.
• Household Inflation Expectations
The Survey of Consumers conducted by
the University of Michigan asks households what they expect the inflation rate
to be over the following 12 months.
Although the responses have at times
been at odds with realized inflation,
household forecasts have generally
been unbiased.5 Figure 3 reveals that
from early 1983 to 1991, household inflation expectations were, on average,

FIGURE 3

ONE-YEAR-AHEAD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS:
MICHIGAN SURVEY MEAN, 1983-94
Percent change, annual rate

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

prices may have been a turning point
for the inflation outlook.

1995

NOTE: Solid rules indicate central tendency.
SOURCE: University of Michigan, Survey of Consumers.

FIGURE 4

ONE-YEAR-AHEAD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS:
PHILADELPHIA SURVEY, 1983-94

• Expectations of
Professional Forecasters
The Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia conducts a quarterly survey of professional forecasters on their expectations for inflation over the next four
quarters. Historically, surveys of professional economists have tended to exhibit some bias.7 The series compiled
by the Philadelphia Fed beginning in
1983, as shown in figure 4, indicates
that these respondents have been more
upbeat than households about the inflation outlook.

Percent change, annual rate
5.5

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

NOTE: Solid rules indicate central tendency.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

consistent with trend rates within subperiods delineated by change points in
the core inflation measure. Although
expectations fell sharply in early 1991,
the average expected inflation rate has
exceeded actual trend rates since then.
Relatively permanent changes in household inflation expectations coincided
closely with substantial and abrupt
changes in the mean of core inflation,
such as between May and June 1988
and between January and February
1991. The latter break occurred pre-

The coincidental nature of changes in
both expected inflation and actual core
inflation suggests that households did
not anticipate the timing of these
changes. Had they done so, expected
inflation would have changed less
abruptly and would have begun falling
prior to the decline in the actual core
rate. Moreover, the coincidence in timing is consistent with the idea that
household expectations have been rational, responding to the same factors
that determine actual prices. What is
curious is that households have not
been persuaded that lower levels of inflation since early 1991 are permanent.

cisely at the climax of the Persian Gulf
War. It appears that such events can
trigger a watershed change in expectations.6 In the four or five years prior
to the Gulf War victory, price pressures
had been building. Although a series of
policy actions had been taken to contain and even reduce inflation, households remained unconvinced and were
generally correct: Inflation advanced at
higher rates until the conflict ended.
The timely resolution of the war and
the prospect for permanently lower oil

As is true with household surveys
(though to a lesser extent), large changes
in the expectations of professional forecasters appear to coincide with breaks in
the core inflation series. Professional
forecasters tended to anticipate the change
point in 1991, however, as the series began to descend more than a year earlier
than did actual inflation. Nevertheless,
they too have overpredicted inflation during the past two years.
• Concluding Thoughts
Substantial and rather abrupt changes
in core inflation since 1982 have generally been accompanied by significant
changes in the inflation expectations of
both households and professional forecasters. The coincidence in timing suggests that these expectations are driven
by the same factors that determine actual changes in the price level; that is,

expectations are formed rationally. The
implication, of course, is that wellarticulated policies can influence inflation expectations. To the extent that
such policies are credible, they can reduce the inflation premiums built into
interest rates and the adjustment costs
that result when inflation rates change.
Although this article has examined a
limited sample of available survey data,
the recent discrepancy between expected and actual inflation is a matter
of some concern. The fact that households have generally been unbiased in
their predictions suggests that actual inflation will adjust to expected levels,
rather than the other way around. Looking forward has, in this sense, been
more reliable than looking backward.

• Footnotes
1. Hearing of the Economic Growth and
Credit Formation Subcommittee of the
House Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs
Committee, February 22, 1994.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, Ohio 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

2. See Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G.
Cecchetti, "Measuring Core Inflation," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Working
Paper No. 9304. August 1993. Although the
authors describe a class of "limited information" measures, we consider a particular
member of this class to illustrate a point.
3. See Edward Bryden and John B. Carlson,
"On Disinflation since 1982: An Application
of Change-Point Tests," Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. Economic Review, vol.
30, no. 1 (1994 Quarter 1), pp. 31-42.

John B. Carlson is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author
thanks Jean Mclntire for research assistance.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

4. Although Bryden and Carlson (footnote
3) report a subsequent reduction in core inflation around March 1992, the test indicates no
break when the sample is extended to include
the most recent data and is adjusted with revised seasonal factors.
5. See Michael F. Bryan and William T.
Gavin, "Models of Inflation Expectations
Formation: A Comparison of Household and
Economist Forecasts," Journal of Mone\,
Credit, and Banking, vol. 18, no. 4 (November 1986). pp. 539-44.
6. For a more extensive discussion of this conjecture, see Bryden and Carlson (footnote 3).
7. See Bryan and Gavin (footnote 5).

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385