View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Chart 2 Food Price Differential
Cleveland vs. U.S. Average
Percent
6

4

2

o

-2
1975
NOTE:

1977

1976

Shaded areas represent

periods of indictment

1978

1979

METHODOLOGY:
The food price differential represents the percentage difference
CPI·measured
food price index and the food price index for the U.S. city average.
SOURCE:

1980

for price-fixing.
between

Cleveland's

Bureau of Labor Statistics.

civil liabilities that apply to the price conspirators. That is, what damage did the pricefixing scheme inflict on consumers in Cleveland? The plaintiffs in the civil actions
sought substantial reparations against the
food retailers, who repeatedly maintained
their innocence.
Cleveland's food prices rose above the
U.S. average in each count of the indictment against the three food retailers (see
chart 2). On the basis of these price differentials and after adjusting for differences in
relative labor costs, economic experts for
the plaintiffs contended that price collusion
cost Cleveland's consumers $37.9 million$28.5 million in count I of the indictment
(pre-price war collusion) and $9.4 million in
count II (post-price war collusion).
Conceptually, it is difficult for one to draw
conclusions from price differences measured with the Consumer Price Index (CPl)
because of product-mix inconsistencies between regional and national market bas-

kets.? Cleveland's retail-food prices often
have risen above the U.S. average as measured by the CPI. Specifically, they did so
between 1960-62, 1968-71, and 1972-73
(although never rising above the U.S. average as much as in the first count of the price
conspiracy). Moreover, the acceleration in
Cleveland's food prices began at least eight
months prior to any formal price discussions and continues today, almost four
years after the ill-fated price scheme supposedly ended. The relative price differential between Cleveland's retail foods and the
U.S. average is influenced by a number of
factors, not all necessarily linked with illegal
agreements. For example, the USDA study
of retail-food concentration and prices sug-

6. Attempting
to dis aggregate
the local market
basket to conform with a national measure is also
problematic, since the relatively small size of specific
local samples makes price movements statistically difficult to interpret.

gests that, even without explicit agreements,
retail-food prices in Cleveland probably
would have risen above the U.S. average as
a result of individual firm growth in the
market. Further, the study concludes that
the market concentration/retail-food
price
relationship is strengthened
in three-firm
concentration
markets, as in Cleveland,
where growth in the second leading firm's
market share is greatest. Between 1975-76,
the three-firm market concentration
of
Cleveland's retail-food industry jumped from
51.0 percent to 65.4 percent; Fisher's
showed the largest single firm growth, rising
from a second-place 20.4 percent share to a
first-place 26.3 percent share. Generalizing
from the evidence in the USDA study, the
1975-76 increase in Cleveland's market concentration would have resulted in a 2.5 percent increase in its retail-food prices above
the U.S. average. In sum, a covert pricefixing arrangement is not a definitive explanation for local food-price increases above
national averages.
Another approach for measuring the
price conspiracy's damage to Cleveland's
consumers used data relating to firm gross
margins, an important control mechanism
for the pricing policies of food retailers."
The gross margin evidence yields a substantially lower total consumer damage
estimate, between $20.0 million and $21.3

million. Economic experts for the defense
offered a net-profit approach to estimate
consumer
damage, arguing that actual
damages would most accurately be reflected in additional profits accruing to the
conspiring retailers. According to these
estimates, the conspiracy was not nearly
as lucrative as one would imagine; the
damage was estimated at $2.4 million for
the first count of the indictment, while no
damage was found for the second count.
The primary objection to this analysis is
the source of the profit data-the
defendant price-fixing firms themselves.
The problems associated with the estimation of consumer damages are complex,
as evidenced by the wide range of estimates
presented during litigation. Finally, the federal court negotiated a settlement between
plaintiff consumer advocates and the food
retailers to provide $20 million in food coupons to be distributed throughout the Cleveland area. The civil settlement, touted as
"fair and reasonable" by all of the participants directly involved, serves as another
expensive lesson on the imprudence of
interfering in the marketplace.
7. Gross margins are derived by subtracting the cost
of goods sold from total sales. As with the CPI, gross
margin comparisons are very sensitive to product-mix
differences, which tend to distort the signals from margin movements.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

Federal Reserve Bank of Clevela~d
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101

Economic Commentary
ISSN 0428·1276

Anatomy of a Price-Fix
by Michael F. Bryan
On February 19, 1982, the three largest
retail food chains in the Cleveland area
were fined $4.2 million by a federal court for
criminal price-fixing, after entering pleas of
no contest to the charges against them.
Four supermarket
executives were given
three-year suspended sentences and fined
$200,000 each for their participation in the
price conspiracy.! In related civil actions,
the federal court accepted a $20-million
coupon repayment plan from the local food
stores, payable to the approximately one
million households that the retailers serve.
This is the largest consumer settlement in
U.S. history.
Although there are harsh penalties against
attempts to fix prices, experience suggests
that such efforts are relatively commonplace. Under the antitrust laws, it is the
attempt to fix prices that is the crime, even if
the attempt should not result in any impact
on actual prices and pricing behavior. In
theory, inherent forces in a free market
should limit the effective life of most price
conspiracies. History is replete with soured
price-fixing schemes, as illustrated by testimony in a U.S. Senate investigation into

1. The court suspended $2.5 million of the corporate
fines and $125,000 each of the individual fines. See
"Supermarkets
Fined for Price- Fixing," The Cleveland
Press, May 12, 1982. For additional information see
Margaret Yap, "Three Grocery Chains in Cleveland
Face Trial on Charges of a Price- Fixing Plot," The Wall
Street Journal, August 13, 1981; and United States v.
First National Supermarkets,
et al., No. CR 80·175
(N.D. Ohio) (Bill of Particulars in Response to Request
of Defendant Charles Rini, filed April 16, 1981).

Address Correction Requested: Please send corrected
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,

mailing label to the Federal
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

July 12, 1982

Michael F. Bryan is an economic analyst with the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Mark S. Snider·
man collaborated on many sections of this artie/e, and
his comments are very much appreciated.
The views stated herein are those of the author and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

price agreements
turing industry.f

in the electrical manufac-

Senator
Hruska:
By and large, Mr. Ginn, you
have had considerable experience in the business
of meetings with competitors. How effective were
those meetings to get the job done that they purported to have as an objective?
Mr. Ginn: Senator, this is the way I will put it. If
people did not have the desire to make it work, it
never worked. And if people had the desire to
make it work, it wasn't necessary to have the meetings and violate the law.
Senator Hruska:
So that your preliminary discussions and meetings with competitorsMr. Ginn: Were worthless.
Senator
Hruska:
Were not necessarily controlling?
Mr. Ginn: Were worthless .... I think that the
boys could resist everything but temptation. No sir,
I'll tell you frankly, Senator, I think if one thing I
would pass on to posterity, that it wasn't worth it. It
didn't accomplish anything, and all you end up with'
is by getting in trouble.

That the retail-food industry often operates in a viciously competitive environment
provides an incentive for tampering with the
marketplace. Indeed, food retailers might
rationalize price conspiracies as a means of
survival rather than a strategy for reaping
unwarranted
profits. However, the large
number of goods sold by food retailers, in
addition to the competitive dynamics of the
markets they serve, makes this industry an
unlikely candidate for a successful price-fix.
The retail-food price conspiracy in Cleveland is a case in point.

Economic Environment
of the Retail-Food Industry
Food stores are limited in the ways they
can successfully compete by the standard
nature of the products
that they sell.
2. Mr. Ginn was vice president and general manager
of the turbine division for General Electric. Price- Fixing
and Bid·Rigging in the Electrical Manufacturing Industry, hearings before the U.S. Senate Committee on the
Judiciary, Parts 27 and 28, 87th Congo 1 Sess. April,
May, and June 1961, pp. 17069-17070.

Standardized (or homogeneous) products
make it difficult for a store to develop a
unique image and maintain customer loyalty, making prices the most powerful
competitive tool of retail-food sellers. Food
sellers have long recognized the cost advantages of centralizing operations and
increasing store sizes to accommodate
larger sales volumes. Cost or efficiency
gains enable retailers to lower unit-selling
costs, thereby lowering prices. The retailfood industry typically operates
within
razor-thin profit margins, usually between
0.6 percent and 0.9 percent of total sales.f
For the return on equity to be high enough
to attract investors, retailers must turn
over their merchandise stocks quickly.
Investing in retail-food facilities was attractive in the 1960s and early 1970s, as
swelling populations
indicated
market
growth for years to come. The U.S. retailfood industry, however, has undergone
some difficult transitions. Since 1960, the
percentage of personal income spent on
food prepared at home has been declining.
In 1960, 17.5 percent of disposable income
was allocated to retail-food purchases; by
1970, the retail-food share of income had
fallen to 15 percent, and in June 1982 it was
slightly under 13.5 percent. Clearly, the
increasing number of single persons and the
growing prominence of women in the labor
force are primary contributors to this trend,
as more and more persons eat meals away
from home.
As consumer buying habits have shifted,
the retail-food industry has been restructured. Convenience-food
stores have proliferated, offering late hours and location
advantages
over supermarkets.
These
stores skim customers from supermarket
traffic, particularly for the purchase of highturnover items such as milk, bread, and
beer. Consequently,
supermarkets
have
had to make up for the reduction in stock
turnover by bolstering profit margins and
increasing store traffic through other means.
For example, many supermarkets
have
opened extensive check-cashing systems,
which in some cases have led to in-store
banking facilities. Goods from in-store bakeries, delicatessens, and health and beauty
3.

Progressive

Grocer, 49th Annual Report, vol. 61,

no. 4 (April 1982), p. 47 and pp. 100-101.

sections are higher profit items that some
supermarkets carry to increase traffic and
improve earnings.
In addition to consumer behavior and
structural changes, rapid and unforeseen
fluctuations in food prices have had serious
repercussions
on the financial health of
supermarkets
because of their relatively
high proportion of fixed expenses (e.g.,
union wages, capital rents, and energy
usage). These food price fluctuations have
been particularly alarming during the last
decade. In 1973 Cleveland's food prices
increased at a 21. 7 percent rate, but in less
than three years that pace slowed to 1.7
percent. Labor, rent, and energy expenses
have accounted for roughly 60 percent of
the industry's total marketing costs over the
last decade, and these continued to register
strong price advances, thus squeezing profit
margins and forcing marginal firms from the
market. As a firm's market share in an area
shifts, pressure builds in the marketplace
for lowering prices even further.

Chart 1

firms recognize their joint dominance of a
market, they tend to develop collusive pricing strategies. Simply said, they set prices
with the unspoken understanding that lowering prices would reduce profitability for all
of the participating firms, while collectively
raising prices would benefit all the firms.

Food Retailer Market Shares

Cleveland SMSA
Percent
30

25

The Price-Fix

,-""

20

","

--------_//

15
Pick·N·Pay

10

_

Fisher's
Stop-NShop __

5

1971

1973

1977

1975

1979

1981

SOURCE: Grocers' Spotlight, August issues, 1971-81.

Scene of the Crime
The retail-food industry is a textbook
example of a competitive market, having a
large number of sellers of standardized
products, none with sufficient market share
or power to control prices. Yet, urban
markets are often dominated by a few retailfood sellers. In the 1970s two food retailersFisher Foods (Fisher's) and First National
Supermarkets (Pick-N-Pay)-accounted
for
40 percent or more of Cleveland's total
retail-food markct.f Pick-N-Pay was the
dominant food seller in Cleveland prior to
1975, commanding 21 percent to 24 percent
of total retail-food sales, while Fisher's maintained a competitive second place with 18
percent to 20 percent (see chart 1). However, a number of factors were at work in
the early 1970s that would affect the profitability of the Cleveland market. For example, the 1970s witnessed a shrinking of
Cleveland's retail-food market, caused not
4. Pick·N-Pay is the Cleveland operating name for
the national food chain of First National Supermarkets,
Inc. Fisher Foods Inc. sells in the Cleveland area under
the names of Fisher's and Fazio's. A third firm has
more recently risen to a position of market strength in
the Cleveland area as part of the national food chain
Association of Stop-N·Shop Supermarkets.

only by a change in life-styles but by a persistently declining local population. In 1970
the retail-food industry in the Cleveland
SMSA served a population of slightly over
2 million, and that population has since declined approximately
16,000 persons
per year.
The competitive atmosphere for Cleveland's retail-food dollars was heightened by
additional structural changes in the local
industry. The first was the rise in popularity
of convenience-food
stores. Lawsons, a
major convenience-food
seller, operated
100 stores in Cleveland in 1971, growing to
163 stores in 1975. At the same time, Convenient Food Mart was emerging as a competitor: a virtual unknown prior to 1970, this
seller operated 68 stores by 1976.
Whether because of this additional competition or because of internal reasons, two
national food chains-A&P
and Kroger'sopted to withdraw from the Cleveland
market in the 1970s. Together, these two
food sellers represented
15.5 percent of
Cleveland's food market in 1971 and 8.0
percent in 1976; by 1979 they were virtually
nonexistent. The "void" created by the pullout of supermarket competition explains a

large part of the increase in market shares
enjoyed by the surviving major food sellers
in Cleveland between 1974 and 1976, as the
remaining participants aggressively repositioned themselves.
As Pick-N-Pay and
Fisher's were exchanging leads for marketshare superiority over the two-year period,
the third-place firm, Stop-N-Shop, added
nearly 6 percent to its market share. In
1976, this trio of food sellers accounted for
over 65 percent of Cleveland's total retailfood sales.
Market concentration can be an important determinant of industry prices and,
consequently,
industry profits. A recent
analysis by the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) of the price-concentration linkage in the food-retailing industry reports
that increased concentration in some cases
yields higher retail-food prices.f This linkage is particularly strong in urban markets
dominated by three firms or less, as in the
Cleveland market. In pricing theory, as

5. R. McFall Lamm, "Prices and Concentration in the
Food Retailing Industry," Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 30 (September 1981), pp. 67-78.

According to the U.S. Department
of
Justice, the retail-food industry in Cleveland ceased operating as a competitive
market halfway through 1976. The government alleged that executives of Pick-N-Pay
and Fisher's met to discuss the below-cost
advertising and selling of certain food items
and agreed to eliminate price competition
and raise prices-a
criminal violation of
antitrust law. Shortly after the initial meeting, a Stop-N-Shop
executive was contacted and a meeting arranged, supposedly
to secure an agreement from that food
retailer to join the price conspiracy.
Two major roadblocks underlie the success of any price-fixing scheme. The first
involves the difficulty in securing a price
commitment supported equally by the members of the conspiracy. Parties to the agreement may have different marketing approaches that result in inconsistent preferences for the pre-established prices of particular food items. Once prices have been
established, there also exist incentives for
conspiracy participants to cheat. Firms with
relatively small market shares stand to
improve their individual positions by drifting
below agreed-to price levels. This strategy,
however, depends on the ability of the price
cheat to improve market share without
being detected by its conspirators.
Once
exposed, the cheater is likely to be the
target of retaliation, as other conspirators
also lower prices and the price-fix dissolves.
Simply, the competition
that fosters
thoughts of price-fixing also serves to undermine the success of such agreements.
Indeed, the court evidence suggests
that the cheating incentives in Cleveland's
retail-food price conspiracy surfaced very
early in the price-fix, particularly with
respect to the cartel's smallest conspirator. Stop-N-Shop allegedly was either offering lower prices on certain food items or
not raising prices quickly enough to

agreed-to levels. One conspirator
supposedly complained that another of the
conspirators
had resorted
to non price
competition,
another
popular cheating
technique, in this case by offering trade
stamps. Almost without exception, cheating complaints were met with an exchange
of price information and a reaffirmation of
the conspirators' support for raising prices.
According to the Justice Department,
meetings between retail-food executives
continued throughout 1977, and price lists
were being exchanged on a regular basis.
Despite the efforts of the conspiracy to
resolve its differences, and possibly because of cheating, a retail-food price war
broke out in Cleveland in the summer of
1977. The event is a testimony to the frailty
of price-fix schemes.
As the pricing conspiracy fell apart, food
retailers sustained severe losses, providing
an incentive to reactivate illegal price manipulations. The government argued that
the three food retailers reaffirmed their
support for price uniformity and conspired
to raise prices again in the fall of 1977. By
year-end 1977, price lists allegedly were
being exchanged often, occasionally being
used to prepare identical advertising campaigns. Weekly price "bulletins" apparently
were distributed for a period in excess of
nine months, with the basic purpose of
coordinating the timing of price movements.
Once again, a common conspiracy topic
during the second price-fixing period was
the charge that one of the conspiring retailers was cheating against agreed-to prices.
Meetings were arranged to sort out the
accusations, each time ending in a reaffirmation of conspiracy solidarity. Cleveland's
food cartel came abruptly to an end late in
1978. While it is not known why the pricefixing scheme ended, economic theory indicates that most price-fixing arrangements
are highly unstable, often breaking down
because of the unwillingness of the participants to abide by price agreements.

The Damages
Inasmuch as the food retailers pleaded
no contest, the criminal evidence against
them was never formally contested.
Beyond the criminal violations of the law,
however, remain questions concerning any

Standardized (or homogeneous) products
make it difficult for a store to develop a
unique image and maintain customer loyalty, making prices the most powerful
competitive tool of retail-food sellers. Food
sellers have long recognized the cost advantages of centralizing operations and
increasing store sizes to accommodate
larger sales volumes. Cost or efficiency
gains enable retailers to lower unit-selling
costs, thereby lowering prices. The retailfood industry typically operates
within
razor-thin profit margins, usually between
0.6 percent and 0.9 percent of total sales.f
For the return on equity to be high enough
to attract investors, retailers must turn
over their merchandise stocks quickly.
Investing in retail-food facilities was attractive in the 1960s and early 1970s, as
swelling populations
indicated
market
growth for years to come. The U.S. retailfood industry, however, has undergone
some difficult transitions. Since 1960, the
percentage of personal income spent on
food prepared at home has been declining.
In 1960, 17.5 percent of disposable income
was allocated to retail-food purchases; by
1970, the retail-food share of income had
fallen to 15 percent, and in June 1982 it was
slightly under 13.5 percent. Clearly, the
increasing number of single persons and the
growing prominence of women in the labor
force are primary contributors to this trend,
as more and more persons eat meals away
from home.
As consumer buying habits have shifted,
the retail-food industry has been restructured. Convenience-food
stores have proliferated, offering late hours and location
advantages
over supermarkets.
These
stores skim customers from supermarket
traffic, particularly for the purchase of highturnover items such as milk, bread, and
beer. Consequently,
supermarkets
have
had to make up for the reduction in stock
turnover by bolstering profit margins and
increasing store traffic through other means.
For example, many supermarkets
have
opened extensive check-cashing systems,
which in some cases have led to in-store
banking facilities. Goods from in-store bakeries, delicatessens, and health and beauty
3.

Progressive

Grocer, 49th Annual Report, vol. 61,

no. 4 (April 1982), p. 47 and pp. 100-101.

sections are higher profit items that some
supermarkets carry to increase traffic and
improve earnings.
In addition to consumer behavior and
structural changes, rapid and unforeseen
fluctuations in food prices have had serious
repercussions
on the financial health of
supermarkets
because of their relatively
high proportion of fixed expenses (e.g.,
union wages, capital rents, and energy
usage). These food price fluctuations have
been particularly alarming during the last
decade. In 1973 Cleveland's food prices
increased at a 21. 7 percent rate, but in less
than three years that pace slowed to 1.7
percent. Labor, rent, and energy expenses
have accounted for roughly 60 percent of
the industry's total marketing costs over the
last decade, and these continued to register
strong price advances, thus squeezing profit
margins and forcing marginal firms from the
market. As a firm's market share in an area
shifts, pressure builds in the marketplace
for lowering prices even further.

Chart 1

firms recognize their joint dominance of a
market, they tend to develop collusive pricing strategies. Simply said, they set prices
with the unspoken understanding that lowering prices would reduce profitability for all
of the participating firms, while collectively
raising prices would benefit all the firms.

Food Retailer Market Shares

Cleveland SMSA
Percent
30

25

The Price-Fix

,-""

20

","

--------_//

15
Pick·N·Pay

10

_

Fisher's
Stop-NShop __

5

1971

1973

1977

1975

1979

1981

SOURCE: Grocers' Spotlight, August issues, 1971-81.

Scene of the Crime
The retail-food industry is a textbook
example of a competitive market, having a
large number of sellers of standardized
products, none with sufficient market share
or power to control prices. Yet, urban
markets are often dominated by a few retailfood sellers. In the 1970s two food retailersFisher Foods (Fisher's) and First National
Supermarkets (Pick-N-Pay)-accounted
for
40 percent or more of Cleveland's total
retail-food markct.f Pick-N-Pay was the
dominant food seller in Cleveland prior to
1975, commanding 21 percent to 24 percent
of total retail-food sales, while Fisher's maintained a competitive second place with 18
percent to 20 percent (see chart 1). However, a number of factors were at work in
the early 1970s that would affect the profitability of the Cleveland market. For example, the 1970s witnessed a shrinking of
Cleveland's retail-food market, caused not
4. Pick·N-Pay is the Cleveland operating name for
the national food chain of First National Supermarkets,
Inc. Fisher Foods Inc. sells in the Cleveland area under
the names of Fisher's and Fazio's. A third firm has
more recently risen to a position of market strength in
the Cleveland area as part of the national food chain
Association of Stop-N·Shop Supermarkets.

only by a change in life-styles but by a persistently declining local population. In 1970
the retail-food industry in the Cleveland
SMSA served a population of slightly over
2 million, and that population has since declined approximately
16,000 persons
per year.
The competitive atmosphere for Cleveland's retail-food dollars was heightened by
additional structural changes in the local
industry. The first was the rise in popularity
of convenience-food
stores. Lawsons, a
major convenience-food
seller, operated
100 stores in Cleveland in 1971, growing to
163 stores in 1975. At the same time, Convenient Food Mart was emerging as a competitor: a virtual unknown prior to 1970, this
seller operated 68 stores by 1976.
Whether because of this additional competition or because of internal reasons, two
national food chains-A&P
and Kroger'sopted to withdraw from the Cleveland
market in the 1970s. Together, these two
food sellers represented
15.5 percent of
Cleveland's food market in 1971 and 8.0
percent in 1976; by 1979 they were virtually
nonexistent. The "void" created by the pullout of supermarket competition explains a

large part of the increase in market shares
enjoyed by the surviving major food sellers
in Cleveland between 1974 and 1976, as the
remaining participants aggressively repositioned themselves.
As Pick-N-Pay and
Fisher's were exchanging leads for marketshare superiority over the two-year period,
the third-place firm, Stop-N-Shop, added
nearly 6 percent to its market share. In
1976, this trio of food sellers accounted for
over 65 percent of Cleveland's total retailfood sales.
Market concentration can be an important determinant of industry prices and,
consequently,
industry profits. A recent
analysis by the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) of the price-concentration linkage in the food-retailing industry reports
that increased concentration in some cases
yields higher retail-food prices.f This linkage is particularly strong in urban markets
dominated by three firms or less, as in the
Cleveland market. In pricing theory, as

5. R. McFall Lamm, "Prices and Concentration in the
Food Retailing Industry," Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 30 (September 1981), pp. 67-78.

According to the U.S. Department
of
Justice, the retail-food industry in Cleveland ceased operating as a competitive
market halfway through 1976. The government alleged that executives of Pick-N-Pay
and Fisher's met to discuss the below-cost
advertising and selling of certain food items
and agreed to eliminate price competition
and raise prices-a
criminal violation of
antitrust law. Shortly after the initial meeting, a Stop-N-Shop
executive was contacted and a meeting arranged, supposedly
to secure an agreement from that food
retailer to join the price conspiracy.
Two major roadblocks underlie the success of any price-fixing scheme. The first
involves the difficulty in securing a price
commitment supported equally by the members of the conspiracy. Parties to the agreement may have different marketing approaches that result in inconsistent preferences for the pre-established prices of particular food items. Once prices have been
established, there also exist incentives for
conspiracy participants to cheat. Firms with
relatively small market shares stand to
improve their individual positions by drifting
below agreed-to price levels. This strategy,
however, depends on the ability of the price
cheat to improve market share without
being detected by its conspirators.
Once
exposed, the cheater is likely to be the
target of retaliation, as other conspirators
also lower prices and the price-fix dissolves.
Simply, the competition
that fosters
thoughts of price-fixing also serves to undermine the success of such agreements.
Indeed, the court evidence suggests
that the cheating incentives in Cleveland's
retail-food price conspiracy surfaced very
early in the price-fix, particularly with
respect to the cartel's smallest conspirator. Stop-N-Shop allegedly was either offering lower prices on certain food items or
not raising prices quickly enough to

agreed-to levels. One conspirator
supposedly complained that another of the
conspirators
had resorted
to non price
competition,
another
popular cheating
technique, in this case by offering trade
stamps. Almost without exception, cheating complaints were met with an exchange
of price information and a reaffirmation of
the conspirators' support for raising prices.
According to the Justice Department,
meetings between retail-food executives
continued throughout 1977, and price lists
were being exchanged on a regular basis.
Despite the efforts of the conspiracy to
resolve its differences, and possibly because of cheating, a retail-food price war
broke out in Cleveland in the summer of
1977. The event is a testimony to the frailty
of price-fix schemes.
As the pricing conspiracy fell apart, food
retailers sustained severe losses, providing
an incentive to reactivate illegal price manipulations. The government argued that
the three food retailers reaffirmed their
support for price uniformity and conspired
to raise prices again in the fall of 1977. By
year-end 1977, price lists allegedly were
being exchanged often, occasionally being
used to prepare identical advertising campaigns. Weekly price "bulletins" apparently
were distributed for a period in excess of
nine months, with the basic purpose of
coordinating the timing of price movements.
Once again, a common conspiracy topic
during the second price-fixing period was
the charge that one of the conspiring retailers was cheating against agreed-to prices.
Meetings were arranged to sort out the
accusations, each time ending in a reaffirmation of conspiracy solidarity. Cleveland's
food cartel came abruptly to an end late in
1978. While it is not known why the pricefixing scheme ended, economic theory indicates that most price-fixing arrangements
are highly unstable, often breaking down
because of the unwillingness of the participants to abide by price agreements.

The Damages
Inasmuch as the food retailers pleaded
no contest, the criminal evidence against
them was never formally contested.
Beyond the criminal violations of the law,
however, remain questions concerning any

Standardized (or homogeneous) products
make it difficult for a store to develop a
unique image and maintain customer loyalty, making prices the most powerful
competitive tool of retail-food sellers. Food
sellers have long recognized the cost advantages of centralizing operations and
increasing store sizes to accommodate
larger sales volumes. Cost or efficiency
gains enable retailers to lower unit-selling
costs, thereby lowering prices. The retailfood industry typically operates
within
razor-thin profit margins, usually between
0.6 percent and 0.9 percent of total sales.f
For the return on equity to be high enough
to attract investors, retailers must turn
over their merchandise stocks quickly.
Investing in retail-food facilities was attractive in the 1960s and early 1970s, as
swelling populations
indicated
market
growth for years to come. The U.S. retailfood industry, however, has undergone
some difficult transitions. Since 1960, the
percentage of personal income spent on
food prepared at home has been declining.
In 1960, 17.5 percent of disposable income
was allocated to retail-food purchases; by
1970, the retail-food share of income had
fallen to 15 percent, and in June 1982 it was
slightly under 13.5 percent. Clearly, the
increasing number of single persons and the
growing prominence of women in the labor
force are primary contributors to this trend,
as more and more persons eat meals away
from home.
As consumer buying habits have shifted,
the retail-food industry has been restructured. Convenience-food
stores have proliferated, offering late hours and location
advantages
over supermarkets.
These
stores skim customers from supermarket
traffic, particularly for the purchase of highturnover items such as milk, bread, and
beer. Consequently,
supermarkets
have
had to make up for the reduction in stock
turnover by bolstering profit margins and
increasing store traffic through other means.
For example, many supermarkets
have
opened extensive check-cashing systems,
which in some cases have led to in-store
banking facilities. Goods from in-store bakeries, delicatessens, and health and beauty
3.

Progressive

Grocer, 49th Annual Report, vol. 61,

no. 4 (April 1982), p. 47 and pp. 100-101.

sections are higher profit items that some
supermarkets carry to increase traffic and
improve earnings.
In addition to consumer behavior and
structural changes, rapid and unforeseen
fluctuations in food prices have had serious
repercussions
on the financial health of
supermarkets
because of their relatively
high proportion of fixed expenses (e.g.,
union wages, capital rents, and energy
usage). These food price fluctuations have
been particularly alarming during the last
decade. In 1973 Cleveland's food prices
increased at a 21. 7 percent rate, but in less
than three years that pace slowed to 1.7
percent. Labor, rent, and energy expenses
have accounted for roughly 60 percent of
the industry's total marketing costs over the
last decade, and these continued to register
strong price advances, thus squeezing profit
margins and forcing marginal firms from the
market. As a firm's market share in an area
shifts, pressure builds in the marketplace
for lowering prices even further.

Chart 1

firms recognize their joint dominance of a
market, they tend to develop collusive pricing strategies. Simply said, they set prices
with the unspoken understanding that lowering prices would reduce profitability for all
of the participating firms, while collectively
raising prices would benefit all the firms.

Food Retailer Market Shares

Cleveland SMSA
Percent
30

25

The Price-Fix

,-""

20

","

--------_//

15
Pick·N·Pay

10

_

Fisher's
Stop-NShop __

5

1971

1973

1977

1975

1979

1981

SOURCE: Grocers' Spotlight, August issues, 1971-81.

Scene of the Crime
The retail-food industry is a textbook
example of a competitive market, having a
large number of sellers of standardized
products, none with sufficient market share
or power to control prices. Yet, urban
markets are often dominated by a few retailfood sellers. In the 1970s two food retailersFisher Foods (Fisher's) and First National
Supermarkets (Pick-N-Pay)-accounted
for
40 percent or more of Cleveland's total
retail-food markct.f Pick-N-Pay was the
dominant food seller in Cleveland prior to
1975, commanding 21 percent to 24 percent
of total retail-food sales, while Fisher's maintained a competitive second place with 18
percent to 20 percent (see chart 1). However, a number of factors were at work in
the early 1970s that would affect the profitability of the Cleveland market. For example, the 1970s witnessed a shrinking of
Cleveland's retail-food market, caused not
4. Pick·N-Pay is the Cleveland operating name for
the national food chain of First National Supermarkets,
Inc. Fisher Foods Inc. sells in the Cleveland area under
the names of Fisher's and Fazio's. A third firm has
more recently risen to a position of market strength in
the Cleveland area as part of the national food chain
Association of Stop-N·Shop Supermarkets.

only by a change in life-styles but by a persistently declining local population. In 1970
the retail-food industry in the Cleveland
SMSA served a population of slightly over
2 million, and that population has since declined approximately
16,000 persons
per year.
The competitive atmosphere for Cleveland's retail-food dollars was heightened by
additional structural changes in the local
industry. The first was the rise in popularity
of convenience-food
stores. Lawsons, a
major convenience-food
seller, operated
100 stores in Cleveland in 1971, growing to
163 stores in 1975. At the same time, Convenient Food Mart was emerging as a competitor: a virtual unknown prior to 1970, this
seller operated 68 stores by 1976.
Whether because of this additional competition or because of internal reasons, two
national food chains-A&P
and Kroger'sopted to withdraw from the Cleveland
market in the 1970s. Together, these two
food sellers represented
15.5 percent of
Cleveland's food market in 1971 and 8.0
percent in 1976; by 1979 they were virtually
nonexistent. The "void" created by the pullout of supermarket competition explains a

large part of the increase in market shares
enjoyed by the surviving major food sellers
in Cleveland between 1974 and 1976, as the
remaining participants aggressively repositioned themselves.
As Pick-N-Pay and
Fisher's were exchanging leads for marketshare superiority over the two-year period,
the third-place firm, Stop-N-Shop, added
nearly 6 percent to its market share. In
1976, this trio of food sellers accounted for
over 65 percent of Cleveland's total retailfood sales.
Market concentration can be an important determinant of industry prices and,
consequently,
industry profits. A recent
analysis by the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) of the price-concentration linkage in the food-retailing industry reports
that increased concentration in some cases
yields higher retail-food prices.f This linkage is particularly strong in urban markets
dominated by three firms or less, as in the
Cleveland market. In pricing theory, as

5. R. McFall Lamm, "Prices and Concentration in the
Food Retailing Industry," Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 30 (September 1981), pp. 67-78.

According to the U.S. Department
of
Justice, the retail-food industry in Cleveland ceased operating as a competitive
market halfway through 1976. The government alleged that executives of Pick-N-Pay
and Fisher's met to discuss the below-cost
advertising and selling of certain food items
and agreed to eliminate price competition
and raise prices-a
criminal violation of
antitrust law. Shortly after the initial meeting, a Stop-N-Shop
executive was contacted and a meeting arranged, supposedly
to secure an agreement from that food
retailer to join the price conspiracy.
Two major roadblocks underlie the success of any price-fixing scheme. The first
involves the difficulty in securing a price
commitment supported equally by the members of the conspiracy. Parties to the agreement may have different marketing approaches that result in inconsistent preferences for the pre-established prices of particular food items. Once prices have been
established, there also exist incentives for
conspiracy participants to cheat. Firms with
relatively small market shares stand to
improve their individual positions by drifting
below agreed-to price levels. This strategy,
however, depends on the ability of the price
cheat to improve market share without
being detected by its conspirators.
Once
exposed, the cheater is likely to be the
target of retaliation, as other conspirators
also lower prices and the price-fix dissolves.
Simply, the competition
that fosters
thoughts of price-fixing also serves to undermine the success of such agreements.
Indeed, the court evidence suggests
that the cheating incentives in Cleveland's
retail-food price conspiracy surfaced very
early in the price-fix, particularly with
respect to the cartel's smallest conspirator. Stop-N-Shop allegedly was either offering lower prices on certain food items or
not raising prices quickly enough to

agreed-to levels. One conspirator
supposedly complained that another of the
conspirators
had resorted
to non price
competition,
another
popular cheating
technique, in this case by offering trade
stamps. Almost without exception, cheating complaints were met with an exchange
of price information and a reaffirmation of
the conspirators' support for raising prices.
According to the Justice Department,
meetings between retail-food executives
continued throughout 1977, and price lists
were being exchanged on a regular basis.
Despite the efforts of the conspiracy to
resolve its differences, and possibly because of cheating, a retail-food price war
broke out in Cleveland in the summer of
1977. The event is a testimony to the frailty
of price-fix schemes.
As the pricing conspiracy fell apart, food
retailers sustained severe losses, providing
an incentive to reactivate illegal price manipulations. The government argued that
the three food retailers reaffirmed their
support for price uniformity and conspired
to raise prices again in the fall of 1977. By
year-end 1977, price lists allegedly were
being exchanged often, occasionally being
used to prepare identical advertising campaigns. Weekly price "bulletins" apparently
were distributed for a period in excess of
nine months, with the basic purpose of
coordinating the timing of price movements.
Once again, a common conspiracy topic
during the second price-fixing period was
the charge that one of the conspiring retailers was cheating against agreed-to prices.
Meetings were arranged to sort out the
accusations, each time ending in a reaffirmation of conspiracy solidarity. Cleveland's
food cartel came abruptly to an end late in
1978. While it is not known why the pricefixing scheme ended, economic theory indicates that most price-fixing arrangements
are highly unstable, often breaking down
because of the unwillingness of the participants to abide by price agreements.

The Damages
Inasmuch as the food retailers pleaded
no contest, the criminal evidence against
them was never formally contested.
Beyond the criminal violations of the law,
however, remain questions concerning any

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Chart 2 Food Price Differential
Cleveland vs. U.S. Average
Percent
6

4

2

o

-2
1975
NOTE:

1977

1976

Shaded areas represent

periods of indictment

1978

1979

METHODOLOGY:
The food price differential represents the percentage difference
CPI·measured
food price index and the food price index for the U.S. city average.
SOURCE:

1980

for price-fixing.
between

Cleveland's

Bureau of Labor Statistics.

civil liabilities that apply to the price conspirators. That is, what damage did the pricefixing scheme inflict on consumers in Cleveland? The plaintiffs in the civil actions
sought substantial reparations against the
food retailers, who repeatedly maintained
their innocence.
Cleveland's food prices rose above the
U.S. average in each count of the indictment against the three food retailers (see
chart 2). On the basis of these price differentials and after adjusting for differences in
relative labor costs, economic experts for
the plaintiffs contended that price collusion
cost Cleveland's consumers $37.9 million$28.5 million in count I of the indictment
(pre-price war collusion) and $9.4 million in
count II (post-price war collusion).
Conceptually, it is difficult for one to draw
conclusions from price differences measured with the Consumer Price Index (CPl)
because of product-mix inconsistencies between regional and national market bas-

kets.? Cleveland's retail-food prices often
have risen above the U.S. average as measured by the CPI. Specifically, they did so
between 1960-62, 1968-71, and 1972-73
(although never rising above the U.S. average as much as in the first count of the price
conspiracy). Moreover, the acceleration in
Cleveland's food prices began at least eight
months prior to any formal price discussions and continues today, almost four
years after the ill-fated price scheme supposedly ended. The relative price differential between Cleveland's retail foods and the
U.S. average is influenced by a number of
factors, not all necessarily linked with illegal
agreements. For example, the USDA study
of retail-food concentration and prices sug-

6. Attempting
to dis aggregate
the local market
basket to conform with a national measure is also
problematic, since the relatively small size of specific
local samples makes price movements statistically difficult to interpret.

gests that, even without explicit agreements,
retail-food prices in Cleveland probably
would have risen above the U.S. average as
a result of individual firm growth in the
market. Further, the study concludes that
the market concentration/retail-food
price
relationship is strengthened
in three-firm
concentration
markets, as in Cleveland,
where growth in the second leading firm's
market share is greatest. Between 1975-76,
the three-firm market concentration
of
Cleveland's retail-food industry jumped from
51.0 percent to 65.4 percent; Fisher's
showed the largest single firm growth, rising
from a second-place 20.4 percent share to a
first-place 26.3 percent share. Generalizing
from the evidence in the USDA study, the
1975-76 increase in Cleveland's market concentration would have resulted in a 2.5 percent increase in its retail-food prices above
the U.S. average. In sum, a covert pricefixing arrangement is not a definitive explanation for local food-price increases above
national averages.
Another approach for measuring the
price conspiracy's damage to Cleveland's
consumers used data relating to firm gross
margins, an important control mechanism
for the pricing policies of food retailers."
The gross margin evidence yields a substantially lower total consumer damage
estimate, between $20.0 million and $21.3

million. Economic experts for the defense
offered a net-profit approach to estimate
consumer
damage, arguing that actual
damages would most accurately be reflected in additional profits accruing to the
conspiring retailers. According to these
estimates, the conspiracy was not nearly
as lucrative as one would imagine; the
damage was estimated at $2.4 million for
the first count of the indictment, while no
damage was found for the second count.
The primary objection to this analysis is
the source of the profit data-the
defendant price-fixing firms themselves.
The problems associated with the estimation of consumer damages are complex,
as evidenced by the wide range of estimates
presented during litigation. Finally, the federal court negotiated a settlement between
plaintiff consumer advocates and the food
retailers to provide $20 million in food coupons to be distributed throughout the Cleveland area. The civil settlement, touted as
"fair and reasonable" by all of the participants directly involved, serves as another
expensive lesson on the imprudence of
interfering in the marketplace.
7. Gross margins are derived by subtracting the cost
of goods sold from total sales. As with the CPI, gross
margin comparisons are very sensitive to product-mix
differences, which tend to distort the signals from margin movements.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

Federal Reserve Bank of Clevela~d
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101

Economic Commentary
ISSN 0428·1276

Anatomy of a Price-Fix
by Michael F. Bryan
On February 19, 1982, the three largest
retail food chains in the Cleveland area
were fined $4.2 million by a federal court for
criminal price-fixing, after entering pleas of
no contest to the charges against them.
Four supermarket
executives were given
three-year suspended sentences and fined
$200,000 each for their participation in the
price conspiracy.! In related civil actions,
the federal court accepted a $20-million
coupon repayment plan from the local food
stores, payable to the approximately one
million households that the retailers serve.
This is the largest consumer settlement in
U.S. history.
Although there are harsh penalties against
attempts to fix prices, experience suggests
that such efforts are relatively commonplace. Under the antitrust laws, it is the
attempt to fix prices that is the crime, even if
the attempt should not result in any impact
on actual prices and pricing behavior. In
theory, inherent forces in a free market
should limit the effective life of most price
conspiracies. History is replete with soured
price-fixing schemes, as illustrated by testimony in a U.S. Senate investigation into

1. The court suspended $2.5 million of the corporate
fines and $125,000 each of the individual fines. See
"Supermarkets
Fined for Price- Fixing," The Cleveland
Press, May 12, 1982. For additional information see
Margaret Yap, "Three Grocery Chains in Cleveland
Face Trial on Charges of a Price- Fixing Plot," The Wall
Street Journal, August 13, 1981; and United States v.
First National Supermarkets,
et al., No. CR 80·175
(N.D. Ohio) (Bill of Particulars in Response to Request
of Defendant Charles Rini, filed April 16, 1981).

Address Correction Requested: Please send corrected
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,

mailing label to the Federal
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

July 12, 1982

Michael F. Bryan is an economic analyst with the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Mark S. Snider·
man collaborated on many sections of this artie/e, and
his comments are very much appreciated.
The views stated herein are those of the author and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

price agreements
turing industry.f

in the electrical manufac-

Senator
Hruska:
By and large, Mr. Ginn, you
have had considerable experience in the business
of meetings with competitors. How effective were
those meetings to get the job done that they purported to have as an objective?
Mr. Ginn: Senator, this is the way I will put it. If
people did not have the desire to make it work, it
never worked. And if people had the desire to
make it work, it wasn't necessary to have the meetings and violate the law.
Senator Hruska:
So that your preliminary discussions and meetings with competitorsMr. Ginn: Were worthless.
Senator
Hruska:
Were not necessarily controlling?
Mr. Ginn: Were worthless .... I think that the
boys could resist everything but temptation. No sir,
I'll tell you frankly, Senator, I think if one thing I
would pass on to posterity, that it wasn't worth it. It
didn't accomplish anything, and all you end up with'
is by getting in trouble.

That the retail-food industry often operates in a viciously competitive environment
provides an incentive for tampering with the
marketplace. Indeed, food retailers might
rationalize price conspiracies as a means of
survival rather than a strategy for reaping
unwarranted
profits. However, the large
number of goods sold by food retailers, in
addition to the competitive dynamics of the
markets they serve, makes this industry an
unlikely candidate for a successful price-fix.
The retail-food price conspiracy in Cleveland is a case in point.

Economic Environment
of the Retail-Food Industry
Food stores are limited in the ways they
can successfully compete by the standard
nature of the products
that they sell.
2. Mr. Ginn was vice president and general manager
of the turbine division for General Electric. Price- Fixing
and Bid·Rigging in the Electrical Manufacturing Industry, hearings before the U.S. Senate Committee on the
Judiciary, Parts 27 and 28, 87th Congo 1 Sess. April,
May, and June 1961, pp. 17069-17070.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Chart 2 Food Price Differential
Cleveland vs. U.S. Average
Percent
6

4

2

o

-2
1975
NOTE:

1977

1976

Shaded areas represent

periods of indictment

1978

1979

METHODOLOGY:
The food price differential represents the percentage difference
CPI·measured
food price index and the food price index for the U.S. city average.
SOURCE:

1980

for price-fixing.
between

Cleveland's

Bureau of Labor Statistics.

civil liabilities that apply to the price conspirators. That is, what damage did the pricefixing scheme inflict on consumers in Cleveland? The plaintiffs in the civil actions
sought substantial reparations against the
food retailers, who repeatedly maintained
their innocence.
Cleveland's food prices rose above the
U.S. average in each count of the indictment against the three food retailers (see
chart 2). On the basis of these price differentials and after adjusting for differences in
relative labor costs, economic experts for
the plaintiffs contended that price collusion
cost Cleveland's consumers $37.9 million$28.5 million in count I of the indictment
(pre-price war collusion) and $9.4 million in
count II (post-price war collusion).
Conceptually, it is difficult for one to draw
conclusions from price differences measured with the Consumer Price Index (CPl)
because of product-mix inconsistencies between regional and national market bas-

kets.? Cleveland's retail-food prices often
have risen above the U.S. average as measured by the CPI. Specifically, they did so
between 1960-62, 1968-71, and 1972-73
(although never rising above the U.S. average as much as in the first count of the price
conspiracy). Moreover, the acceleration in
Cleveland's food prices began at least eight
months prior to any formal price discussions and continues today, almost four
years after the ill-fated price scheme supposedly ended. The relative price differential between Cleveland's retail foods and the
U.S. average is influenced by a number of
factors, not all necessarily linked with illegal
agreements. For example, the USDA study
of retail-food concentration and prices sug-

6. Attempting
to dis aggregate
the local market
basket to conform with a national measure is also
problematic, since the relatively small size of specific
local samples makes price movements statistically difficult to interpret.

gests that, even without explicit agreements,
retail-food prices in Cleveland probably
would have risen above the U.S. average as
a result of individual firm growth in the
market. Further, the study concludes that
the market concentration/retail-food
price
relationship is strengthened
in three-firm
concentration
markets, as in Cleveland,
where growth in the second leading firm's
market share is greatest. Between 1975-76,
the three-firm market concentration
of
Cleveland's retail-food industry jumped from
51.0 percent to 65.4 percent; Fisher's
showed the largest single firm growth, rising
from a second-place 20.4 percent share to a
first-place 26.3 percent share. Generalizing
from the evidence in the USDA study, the
1975-76 increase in Cleveland's market concentration would have resulted in a 2.5 percent increase in its retail-food prices above
the U.S. average. In sum, a covert pricefixing arrangement is not a definitive explanation for local food-price increases above
national averages.
Another approach for measuring the
price conspiracy's damage to Cleveland's
consumers used data relating to firm gross
margins, an important control mechanism
for the pricing policies of food retailers."
The gross margin evidence yields a substantially lower total consumer damage
estimate, between $20.0 million and $21.3

million. Economic experts for the defense
offered a net-profit approach to estimate
consumer
damage, arguing that actual
damages would most accurately be reflected in additional profits accruing to the
conspiring retailers. According to these
estimates, the conspiracy was not nearly
as lucrative as one would imagine; the
damage was estimated at $2.4 million for
the first count of the indictment, while no
damage was found for the second count.
The primary objection to this analysis is
the source of the profit data-the
defendant price-fixing firms themselves.
The problems associated with the estimation of consumer damages are complex,
as evidenced by the wide range of estimates
presented during litigation. Finally, the federal court negotiated a settlement between
plaintiff consumer advocates and the food
retailers to provide $20 million in food coupons to be distributed throughout the Cleveland area. The civil settlement, touted as
"fair and reasonable" by all of the participants directly involved, serves as another
expensive lesson on the imprudence of
interfering in the marketplace.
7. Gross margins are derived by subtracting the cost
of goods sold from total sales. As with the CPI, gross
margin comparisons are very sensitive to product-mix
differences, which tend to distort the signals from margin movements.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

Federal Reserve Bank of Clevela~d
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101

Economic Commentary
ISSN 0428·1276

Anatomy of a Price-Fix
by Michael F. Bryan
On February 19, 1982, the three largest
retail food chains in the Cleveland area
were fined $4.2 million by a federal court for
criminal price-fixing, after entering pleas of
no contest to the charges against them.
Four supermarket
executives were given
three-year suspended sentences and fined
$200,000 each for their participation in the
price conspiracy.! In related civil actions,
the federal court accepted a $20-million
coupon repayment plan from the local food
stores, payable to the approximately one
million households that the retailers serve.
This is the largest consumer settlement in
U.S. history.
Although there are harsh penalties against
attempts to fix prices, experience suggests
that such efforts are relatively commonplace. Under the antitrust laws, it is the
attempt to fix prices that is the crime, even if
the attempt should not result in any impact
on actual prices and pricing behavior. In
theory, inherent forces in a free market
should limit the effective life of most price
conspiracies. History is replete with soured
price-fixing schemes, as illustrated by testimony in a U.S. Senate investigation into

1. The court suspended $2.5 million of the corporate
fines and $125,000 each of the individual fines. See
"Supermarkets
Fined for Price- Fixing," The Cleveland
Press, May 12, 1982. For additional information see
Margaret Yap, "Three Grocery Chains in Cleveland
Face Trial on Charges of a Price- Fixing Plot," The Wall
Street Journal, August 13, 1981; and United States v.
First National Supermarkets,
et al., No. CR 80·175
(N.D. Ohio) (Bill of Particulars in Response to Request
of Defendant Charles Rini, filed April 16, 1981).

Address Correction Requested: Please send corrected
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,

mailing label to the Federal
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

July 12, 1982

Michael F. Bryan is an economic analyst with the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Mark S. Snider·
man collaborated on many sections of this artie/e, and
his comments are very much appreciated.
The views stated herein are those of the author and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

price agreements
turing industry.f

in the electrical manufac-

Senator
Hruska:
By and large, Mr. Ginn, you
have had considerable experience in the business
of meetings with competitors. How effective were
those meetings to get the job done that they purported to have as an objective?
Mr. Ginn: Senator, this is the way I will put it. If
people did not have the desire to make it work, it
never worked. And if people had the desire to
make it work, it wasn't necessary to have the meetings and violate the law.
Senator Hruska:
So that your preliminary discussions and meetings with competitorsMr. Ginn: Were worthless.
Senator
Hruska:
Were not necessarily controlling?
Mr. Ginn: Were worthless .... I think that the
boys could resist everything but temptation. No sir,
I'll tell you frankly, Senator, I think if one thing I
would pass on to posterity, that it wasn't worth it. It
didn't accomplish anything, and all you end up with'
is by getting in trouble.

That the retail-food industry often operates in a viciously competitive environment
provides an incentive for tampering with the
marketplace. Indeed, food retailers might
rationalize price conspiracies as a means of
survival rather than a strategy for reaping
unwarranted
profits. However, the large
number of goods sold by food retailers, in
addition to the competitive dynamics of the
markets they serve, makes this industry an
unlikely candidate for a successful price-fix.
The retail-food price conspiracy in Cleveland is a case in point.

Economic Environment
of the Retail-Food Industry
Food stores are limited in the ways they
can successfully compete by the standard
nature of the products
that they sell.
2. Mr. Ginn was vice president and general manager
of the turbine division for General Electric. Price- Fixing
and Bid·Rigging in the Electrical Manufacturing Industry, hearings before the U.S. Senate Committee on the
Judiciary, Parts 27 and 28, 87th Congo 1 Sess. April,
May, and June 1961, pp. 17069-17070.