View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 2020, EB20-11

Economic Brief

How Do Small Business Finance
and Monetary Policy Interact?
By Hailey Phelps and Russell Wong

Economists at the Richmond Fed, the University of Virginia, UC Irvine, and
Purdue analyze how monetary policy affects the creation of lending relationships for small businesses and vice versa. Bank loans are an important funding source for small businesses, but many small businesses have no access to
them. The researchers develop a search model that analyzes the supply and
demand for lending relationships. Understanding the key role these relationships play in the economy can help central banks develop optimal monetary policy responses to crises like the Great Recession and COVID-19.
Small businesses (those with fewer than 500
workers) employ almost half of the American
labor force.1 But unlike large businesses, they are
often unable to borrow in the corporate bond
market or raise capital in the stock market. Most
small businesses must finance their investments
either internally, from retained earnings or the
owners’ personal funds, or externally, with loans
from a bank. For external financing, many small
businesses access credit through longstanding
relationships with banks. These relationships
often provide firms with adequate liquidity: according to the 2003 Survey of Small Business
Finances (SSBF), firms with access to bank credit
typically hold 20 percent less cash than firms that
are not in a lending relationship.2 Still, the SSBF
reports that 32 percent of small businesses do
not have access to a credit line or a revolvingcredit arrangement with banks. This difference

EB20-11 – Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

between banked and unbanked small businesses
creates the potential for asymmetric transmission of monetary policy, depending on firms’
access to credit and their cost of internal finance.
The traditional model for explaining monetary
policy focuses on the aggregate demand channel. This approach asserts that when the central
bank reduces interest rates, it decreases the cost
of borrowing and increases the demand for credit. Lowering interest rates, therefore, encourages
investment and consumption spending. However, an alternative model considers how monetary policy affects the supply of credit through
the bank-relationship channel. This approach
asserts that when the central bank raises interest
rates, it encourages banks to create relationships
with firms to increase the revenue of the banks
via higher interest payments and fees. Addition-

Page 1

ally, firms may find it more profitable to be in banking relationships when the interest rate is higher.
In the long run, these new relationships lead to an
increased number of loans to firms, which provides
more funds with which firms can invest. However,
relationships between banks and small businesses
take time to develop. As a result, this match-making
friction affects the transmission of monetary policy
in this alternative model.
In a recent working paper, Russell Wong of the Richmond Fed, Zachary Bethune of the University of
Virginia, Guillaume Rocheteau of the University of
California, Irvine, and Cathy Zhang of Purdue University analyze the channel through which monetary
policy affects the creation of new lending relationships, the financing of firms’ investments, and the
trade-offs of the central bank.3 Their model predicts
the economy’s response to an unanticipated banking
crisis that destroys lending relationships. From there,
they analyze the optimal monetary policy responses
under different levels of central bank commitment.
Lastly, they adapt their model to characterize the optimal response to a partial lockdown of the economy
caused by a crisis like the COVID-19 pandemic.
The Model
The researchers develop a search model in which
banks and firms search for and develop relationships
with one another to maximize lifetime utility. In their
model, each period of time is composed of three
stages. During the first stage, investment opportunities arise that are financed by cash or bank loans.
During the second stage, unbanked firms search for
lending relationships with banks. During the third
stage, firms settle bank loans, trade assets, and raise
more cash internally if needed. While the researchers consider a general case in their working paper,
for the sake of brevity, this Economic Brief considers
a simpler case in which a nominal bond (one whose
return is not adjusted for inflation) is the only asset,
and the central bank can directly control its interest
rate by trading nominal bonds and cash in the open
market. Since cash and nominal bonds are imperfect
substitutes, the interest rate is essentially the opportunity cost of holding cash, regardless of whether

a firm is banked or not. Having cash benefits unbanked firms more because they do not have access
to bank loans to finance their investments. Banked
firms can finance their investments by drawing on
bank lines of credit line in addition to their cash holdings. The loan rate and credit line are determined by
bargaining between firms and banks.
Consistent with the data, the model predicts the
following. First, banked firms hold less cash than
unbanked firms, but their level of investment is
higher. Second, banks are able to pass on the higher
interest rate to borrowers in the form of higher loan
rates. Third, while a higher interest rate reduces
cash holdings in general, unbanked firms retain
more cash than banked firms because unbanked
firms cannot rely on bank credit, and therefore,
need to retain some cash. Taken together, these
outcomes imply that the cash demand of unbanked
firms is less sensitive to interest rate movements
than that of banked firms.
To see the effect of monetary policy on this bankrelationship channel, consider what would happen if
the central bank increases the interest rate. A direct
effect is that holding nominal bonds would have a
higher return. Since banked firms can rely more on
bank loans than cash to finance investment, they can
afford to hold less cash in exchange for more nominal
bonds. For this reason, banked firms find their existing banking relationships more beneficial, and unbanked firms become more likely to seek out relationships with banks. Additionally, increasing the interest
rate allows banks to increase their income — via
higher loan rates — and encourages them to create
new relationships with firms to expand their credit
lines. Finally, because there are now more banked
firms and because banked firms have higher levels of
investment, total aggregate investment can increase.
The Central Bank’s Dilemma after a Crisis
Following a negative credit-supply shock, such as the
2008 financial crisis, a fraction of banks and businesses shut down, and some lending relationships
are destroyed. After the shock, the central bank must
choose either to support firms by providing greater

Page 2

access to cash or to encourage banks to form new
lending relationships. This choice represents two
basic monetary policies: interest rate targeting and
aggregate liquidity targeting. Interest rate targeting
holds the interest rate constant and supports firms
by allowing them access to cash at the same opportunity cost. Following the shock, investment by
individual firms under interest rate targeting remains
unaffected, but aggregate investment decreases
because of an increased number of unbanked firms,
which have lower levels of investment than the
banked firms. In contrast, aggregate liquidity targeting holds the cash supply constant. Firms’ demand
for cash is higher, and their demand for nominal
bonds lower, after they lose access to lending relationships, so this approach pushes up the interest
rate if the central bank does not increase the supply
of cash. Thus, if the central bank wants to encourage banks to form new lending relationships, it can
hold the cash supply constant and allow the interest
rate to rise. Aggregate investment, especially of the
unbanked firms, decreases under aggregate liquidity
targeting due to the higher interest rate and insuffi-

cient cash. In the longer run, however, the economy
performs better under liquidity targeting because
the higher interest rate encourages the creation of
new lending relationships.
Using data from the SSBF and Compustat, the
researchers calibrate their model to simulate how
the economy would respond to a negative credit
shock under the policies described above. They
simulate 10 percent, 35 percent, and 60 percent
contractions in banking relationships, corresponding to different interpretations of small business
lending contractions during the 2008 financial
crisis. In Figure 1, the solid lines represent the
interest rate targeting policy, and the dashed lines
represent the liquidity-targeting policy. If the central bank decides to hold the cash supply constant,
then the rise of the interest rate corresponds to the
size of the contraction: the greater the shock, the
greater the initial jump in interest rate. If the central bank decides to hold the interest rate constant,
then the rate remains fixed at two percent. (See
the left panel of Figure 1.) Additionally, the decline

Figure 1: Liquidity Targeting (Dashed Lines) vs. Interest Rate Targeting (Solid Lines) Following a Credit Crisis

Interest
Rate
Spread
Annual
Interest
Rate
(Percent)

20
20

16
16

0.09
0.090

12
12

0.085
0.085

88

0.08
0.080

44

0.075
0.075

25

50

75

100

125

150

s_sfixed_small
s_Mfixed_medium

Months
s_Mfixed_small

s_sfixed_medium

0.07
0.070

0

25

50

75

100

125

150

1
7
13
19
25
31
37
43
49
55
61
67
73
79
85
91
97
103
109
115
121
127
133
139
145

0

1
7
13
19
25
31
37
43
49
55
61
67
73
79
85
91
97
103
109
115
121
127
133
139
145

00

Aggregate
AggregateInvestment
Investment

0.095
0.095

inv_sfixed_small

Months

inv_Mfixed_small

10%s_sfixed_large
Contraction and Liquidity
Targeting
s_Mfixed_large

10%inv_Mfixed_medium
Contraction and Interest
Rate Targeting
inv_sfixed_large

35% Contraction and Liquidity Targeting

35% Contraction and Interest Rate Targeting

60% Contraction and Liquidity Targeting

60% Contraction and Interest Rate Targeting

inv_sfixed_medium
inv_Mfixed_large

Source: Authors’ calulations based on the model developed in Zachary Bethune, Guillaume Rocheteau, Tsz-Nga (Russell) Wong, and Cathy Zhang,
“Lending Relationships and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 20-13, September 2020.
Notes: In the interest rate panel, the solid red, blue, and green lines overlap at two percentage points reflecting interest rate targeting. The y-axis
on the aggregate-investment chart does not represent a specific measure. It is simply calibrated to give readers an idea of the relative performance
of the two policy approaches given different severities of lending-relationship contraction.

Page 3

in aggregate investment under the liquidity-targeting policy is nearly double the decline in investment under the interest rate targeting policy. (See
the right panel of Figure 1.)

targeting, aggregate investment does not decline
sharply immediately following the shock. Compared
with interest rate targeting, aggregate investment
recovers faster.

Optimal Monetary Policy after a Crisis
Alternatively, the central bank can achieve both objectives by reducing the interest rate at the onset of a
crisis, to allow unbanked firms to access cash at a low
cost, and then using “forward guidance” to commit to
increasing the interest rate in the future, a policy that
would encourage banks to create new lending relationships with firms. This policy response maximizes
the welfare of both the banks and the firms. Under
this forward-guidance approach, the central bank
reduces the interest rate in the short run, increases
it above its long-run value in the medium run, and
gradually decreases it to its steady-state value in the
long run. This policy creates a hump-shaped path for
the interest rate that becomes more pronounced depending on the size of the shock. (See the left panel
of Figure 2). Under the forward-guidance policy,
aggregate investment declines sharply immediately
following the shock but gradually recovers. (See the
right panel of Figure 2). Compared with liquidity

If the central bank cannot commit to future interest rates, then the optimal policy solution becomes
very different because banks would not believe
the forward guidance. Therefore, if the shock were
small, then it would be optimal to keep the rate
low, but if the shock were large, then it would be
optimal to initially increase the rate to encourage
the creation of new lending relationships before
gradually decreasing it over time. (See the left panel
of Figure 3 on the following page.) Compared with
the forward-guidance approach, the interest rate
path is lower without commitment. The inability to
commit leads to aggregate investment decreasing
initially and then recovering gradually. (See the
right panel of Figure 3 on the following page.) The
researchers’ model predicts the half-life of a recovery following a 60 percent contraction to be twenty
months when the central bank can commit and
twenty-seven months when the central bank cannot
commit. The inability to commit causes firms to be-

Figure 2: Results of Policy Response with Initial Rate Reduction and the Promise of Higher Future Interest Rates

Interest
Rate
Annual
Interest
RateSpread
(Percent)

Aggregate
Investment
Aggregate Investment

88

0
0.140

0
0.136

66

0
0.132

44
0
0.128

22

25

50

75

100

s_small

Months

s_medium

s_large

10% Contraction

0
0.120

0

25

50

75

100

1
6
11
16
21
26
31
36
41
46
51
56
61
66
71
76
81
86
91
96
101

0

1
6
11
16
21
26
31
36
41
46
51
56
61
66
71
76
81
86
91
96
101

00

0
0.124

35% Contraction

inv_small

Months

inv_medium

60% Contraction

inv_large

Source: Authors’ calulations based on the model developed in Zachary Bethune, Guillaume Rocheteau, Tsz-Nga (Russell) Wong, and Cathy Zhang,
“Lending Relationships and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 20-13, September 2020.
Note: The y-axis on the aggregate-investment chart does not represent a specific measure. It is simply calibrated to give readers an idea of relative
performance given different severities of lending-relationship contraction.

Page 4

come stuck in a liquidity trap and decreases banks’
desire to enter the credit-supply market due to a
lack of central bank credibility. The combination of
these two effects prolongs economic recovery and
generates a welfare loss between 0.90 percent and
0.98 percent of consumption, depending on the
size of the shock.

months. If the lockdown lasts only three months,
banks have incentives to create relationships with
firms because they expect production will return to
normal quickly. If the lockdown lasts six or twelve
months, then the optimal policy consists of reducing the rate at the onset of the lockdown but then
increasing it before the lockdown ends to prevent
banks from becoming discouraged about creating
relationships with firms.

Implications for the COVID-19 Pandemic
The researchers adapt their model to determine
the optimal policy response following a temporary
business lockdown, such as the one caused by the
COVID-19 pandemic. Assuming an unexpected
40 percent decrease in investment opportunities
for all firms,4 and that between 25 percent and 55
percent of small businesses would close or likely
would close, the researchers analyze the impact of a
lockdown lasting three, six, and nine months before
returning to prepandemic levels. If the central bank
can commit to future interest rates and the lockdown lasts three months, then the optimal response
consists of reducing the interest rate close to zero,
keeping it low following the lockdown, then gradually returning it to normal after approximately twenty

Conclusion
Wong, Bethune, Rocheteau, and Zhang demonstrate
that the formation of lending relationships is critical for small businesses to finance their investment
opportunities. The researchers’ model shows the
central bank’s optimal responses following a banking crisis under different levels of commitment. If the
central bank can commit to setting future interest
rates, then the optimal response is to employ forward guidance by setting the rate close to zero at the
onset of the crisis and increasing it over time as the
economy recovers. If the central bank cannot commit
to setting future rates, then the interest rate remains
low, and the recession lasts longer.

Figure 3: Results of Policy Response with No Promise Regarding Future Interest Rates

Chart Title

ChartRate
Title(Percent)
Annual Interest

Aggregate Investment

0.1
0.140

1
1.0

0.1
0.138

0.8
0.8

0.1
0.136

0.6
0.6

0.1
0.134
0.4
0.4

0.1
0.132

0.2
0.2

20
30
40
50
60
10 3 5 7 910
11131517192123252729313335373941434547495153555759
s_small

Months
s_medium

0.128
0.1

0

s_large

10% Contraction

50

100

150

200

1
9
17
25
33
41
49
57
65
73
81
89
97
105
113
121
129
137
145
153
161
169
177
185
193
201

00

0.1
0.130

35% Contraction

inv_small

Months

inv_medium

60% Contraction

inv_large

Source: Authors’ calulations based on the model developed in Zachary Bethune, Guillaume Rocheteau, Tsz-Nga (Russell) Wong, and Cathy Zhang,
“Lending Relationships and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 20-13, September 2020.
Note: In the interest rate panel, the blue and green lines overlap after six months, and all lines overlap after about two years. The y-axis on the
aggregate-investment chart does not represent a specific measure. It is simply calibrated to give readers an idea of the relative performance
given different severities of lending-relationship contraction.

Page 5

Russell Wong is a senior economist and Hailey Phelps
is an economics writer in the Research Department
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Endnotes
1

U.S. Census Bureau, 2017 County Business Patterns, released
on March 6, 2020.

2

 oard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Occasional
B
Staff Studies, “2003 Survey of Small Business Finances.”

3

 achary Bethune, Guillaume Rocheteau, Tsz-Nga (Russell)
Z
Wong, and Cathy Zhang, “Lending Relationships and Optimal
Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working
Paper No. 20-13, September 2020.

4

 etLife and U.S. Chamber of Commerce, “Special Report on
M
Coronavirus and Small Businesses,” April 3, 2020.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its
entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the
italicized statement below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF RICHMOND
Richmond Baltimore Charlotte

Page 6