View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Brief
AUGUST 2009, EB09-08

recent Fiscal Policy
and the Manipulation
of Aggregate
Economic Activity
By Kartik B. Athreya and renee courtois

It is widely believed that public sector
spending and investment can restore
aggregate economic activity to efficient
levels. But some policy responses are
likely to be more successful than others.
In particular, directly targeting frictions
in capital, labor, and insurance markets
arguably provides the best chances
of improving welfare.

EB09-08 - ThE FEdErAl rESErvE BAnK oF richMond

A substantial portion of recent fiscal policy is predicated on the idea
that increased public sector spending and investment can restore
aggregate economic activity to efficient levels by stimulating current
consumption, current production, or both. Understanding the likely
impact of stimulative fiscal policies is currently of considerable importance, in particular because a debate now exists on the effectiveness
of the stimulus package enacted earlier this year, and as a result
whether a second installment may be warranted.
In this Economic Brief, we make three points with regard to recent
fiscal policies that have been enacted to deal with the recession. First,
declines in measured output, employment, and consumption are not
necessarily indicative of an inefficient response to economic fundamentals. Second, there are reasons to think that the current contraction in economic activity is indeed inefficiently large. This is likely due
to certain specific market frictions present in labor, insurance, and
capital markets. As a result, policies that target those frictions directly
may have the best chances of improving welfare. Third, the extent to
which recent fiscal policies directly address the frictions currently in
play is mixed.
FindinG A ProdUcTivE rolE For Policy FollowinG A dEclinE in MEASUrEd oUTPUT
Before confronting the ideas mentioned above, it is worth a brief detour
to first understand the source of economists’general enthusiasm for
leaving unfettered the choices of individual households and firms
interacting via competitive markets in which prices adjust to equate
supply and demand. A key result of economic theory known as the“First
Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics”asserts it is these prices
— which both constrain and influence individual actors — that allow
the economic decisions of self-interested households and firms to be
entirely consistent with an efficient allocation of resources. By efficient,
we mean: in ways that leave no gains from trade unrealized. It is this
property that leads many economists to be wary of interventions in the
economy that aim to improve aggregate outcomes by modifying the
decisions of individual actors, such as firms, households, or even
sectors of the economy. The real relevance of the First Welfare Theorem
is not as a description of reality, but rather as a useful point of departure
for policy analysis: It suggests that one generally needs to point to a
missing or noncompetitive market in order to justify a given policy.

The preceding result implies that in a well-functioning competitive
market system, the adjustments made by individuals and firms in
response to a shock to economic fundamentals, even when they are contractionary, will be efficient. If something bad has happened to the ability
of firms to produce output (say, a shock to the financial sector that hinders
the allocation of labor and capital to their best uses), then each hour of
labor becomes less productive. In this case, it makes little sense for firms
to continue producing, or for workers to work, at previous levels. After a
storm, for example, a fisherman may find that each hour spent in the
boat produces less fish; an efficient response is for him to spend less time
fishing (hire less labor) and more hours consuming leisure (or, perhaps
working on boat maintenance and repair), given that the cost of leisure
or other activities, measured in terms of fish foregone, has fallen.
ThE nEEd To idEnTiFy FricTionS
The preceding example also makes clear that an efficient response to a
shock does not mean that shocks themselves are good. Recessions clearly
are associated with hardship, and it would clearly have been better if there
had been no storm. Nonetheless, it may still be true that it is not possible
for policy to improve welfare of some households without hurting others.
We make this point to argue that it is not sufficient to simply observe a
fall in aggregates and conclude that policy action is warranted. To the extent that the downturn represents an efficient reaction to underlying declines in productivity, policy can at best help some households by hurting
others. Moreover, if we cared only about measured aggregate economic
activity, then any means of increasing it (for example, simply destroying
capital equipment while subsidizing new investment) could technically
“solve”the problem. But such policies, by not being directly targeted at
the problems faced by households and firms, may not mitigate the actual
hardship created by a decline in productivity. Therefore, finding a productive role for policy entails first asking whether there are frictions that
make declining economic activity in response to the shock inefficiently
large, and then crafting policy to address those frictions directly.
There are indeed good reasons to think that the current recession is
characterized by significant inefficiencies. In particular, lower levels of
employment, rather than reflecting a sensible scaling back of costly
work effort in the face of lower productivity, likely reflect important
frictions in capital, labor, and insurance markets.
ThE (in)EFFiciEnciES in cAPiTAl And lABor MArKETS
Frictions in capital and labor markets hinder the allocation of factors
of production to their best uses. In the case of capital markets, the
problems being faced by banks recently arguably have impeded their
efforts to discover good investment projects, and then raise the
resources to invest in them.


PAgE 2 EB09-08

In the case of labor, work is allocated by a decentralized process. When
one loses a job, regaining employment entails a costly search process.
There is the risk that workers and firms cannot find each other, and even
when they do, they may not find the match to be mutually beneficial. As
a result, many workers may find that it takes long periods and sustained
search effort to find a match that may entail moving or other disruptions.
Moreover, what is arguably most problematic about declines in
employment is that the adjustment of labor input comes in very
uneven ways: Employers tend to engage in layoffs rather than make
an equivalent cut in hours across the board. For a variety of reasons,
most jobs in the data are clustered around either 20 or 40 hours per
week. For example, fixed costs in labor use, both on the employer’s side
(for instance, training) and the worker’s side (for instance, commuting
costs) will tend to make both parties unwilling to consider wider mixes
of hours. If instead firms could adjust to the shock by making all
workers take an individually small reduction in their labor hours,
recessions would be less problematic for households: Most could still
afford necessities, make their mortgage payments, keep their children
in daycare, and suffer relatively little disruption to their lives. This is
the main reason we talk about recessions: A distinct subset of the
workforce faces a rather severe adverse outcome while there is no
major change for the rest of the workforce.
ThE (in)EFFiciEncy oF PrEcAUTionAry SAvinGS
The absence of a smoothly functioning labor market, the uneven nature
of individual labor market outcomes, and the conspicuous absence of
direct private market insurance against unemployment will all persuade
consumers to be prudent and scale back consumption when recession
adds uncertainty to their future prospects. Put differently, households
facing the risk of unemployment will wish to increase“precautionary”
savings as a form of private insurance to reduce the effects of uncertainty. Indeed, at the aggregate level, the national savings rate has
surged to the highest point in at least a decade.
It is crucial to recognize that the increase in precautionary savings is a
prudent decision on the part of each individual consumer, and thereby
does not immediately warrant policy intervention. However, to the extent that the increase in savings arose from a need to overcome frictions
in both labor markets and insurance markets, it is possible that households’ increased precautionary savings could lead, in the aggregate, to
an inefficiently large reduction in aggregate consumption. In turn, such
a decrease may itself contribute to additional employment declines,
further adding to the labor market uncertainty faced by households.
The preceding suggests there may be a role for policy. However, it also
suggests that productive policies will likely be those which directly

address the specific frictions in capital, labor, and insurance markets that
make the observed decline of aggregate consumption inefficiently large.
The existing policy responses in capital and insurance markets both constitute efforts to directly address clearly identified frictions. In the case of
capital markets, the Federal Reserve’s and the Treasury’s various financing facilities created over the last two years constitute efforts aimed
directly at addressing these frictions. As for insurance markets, fiscal
policy routinely, including in the current downturn, buttresses the public
safety net through policies such as extended unemployment insurance
and health insurance for laid-off workers. Such efforts seem productive.
However, several additional efforts to address labor market frictions
have been very indirect. government spending stimulus attempts to
address the frictions in labor markets by encouraging hiring in other,
government-sponsored areas. In particular, some sectors of the
economy will receive production subsidies, which in turn will increase
demand for labor in these areas. The presumption in this approach is
that such an increase in demand will make job finding easier, and will
attenuate the increase in precautionary savings.
The preceding responses do not directly address the fundamental labor
market frictions themselves. No attention is given to improving the ways in
which firms and workers match with each other, or to mitigating any of the
features of labor markets, such as fixed costs, that seem to preclude the
smooth adjustment of labor hours. In turn, current spending-based stimulus, while it may marginally increase the probability of a laid-off worker
regaining employment, will also likely draw employed workers away from
other productive uses — further hindering efficient resource allocation.
We think a more promising approach would be to expand the provision
of unemployment insurance and related safety net programs. There is
already a rich infrastructure in existence for the delivery of both. Such an
approach would directly address the hardship faced by households who
have lost employment, and simultaneously temper the need for precautionary savings, thereby attenuating the likelihood of inefficiently large
drops in consumption and further employment declines. An additional

benefit of this approach is that it could improve the matching process
between employers and workers by reducing the extent to which a
displaced worker must accept the first available opportunity. Moreover,
if policy were redirected toward this approach, resources currently
devoted to indirect policy responses could be applied instead to ramp
up monitoring efforts to address the increased moral hazard associated
with any expansion in the social safety net (in this case, to make sure
that recipients continue to search for new employment).
conclUSion
Sound justification for fiscal policies that attempt to manipulate
economic activity should be provided in advance by those proposing
such policies. Identifying that aggregate economic activity has fallen,
even if severely, is a necessary but not sufficient condition for enacting
a given policy to address that decline.
Recent fiscal policy appears interested in addressing declines in
aggregate employment and consumption via public spending. In this
Economic Brief, we argue that fiscal stimulus is not likely to be successful
in addressing this problem. If the decline in labor and capital hours in
this current downturn is efficient, such policies will necessarily be welfare reducing. If, instead, the current decline in activity is a result of
frictions in labor, capital, or insurance markets, which appears to be
the case currently, a successful policy must be targeted specifically and
directly at these frictions. Many recent fiscal policy actions, however, do
not seem to deal pointedly with such frictions. We think a more fruitful
approach would be to leverage the existing unemployment insurance
and social safety net infrastructure to better insure the unemployed
while more strictly monitoring their job search efforts.


Kartik B. Athreya is a senior economist at the Federal reserve
Bank of richmond. renee courtois is a writer in the Bank’s
research department.
The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not
necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal
Reserve System.

www.richmondfed.org



EB09-08 PAgE