View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Brief

June 2017, EB17-06

Does the Fed Have a Financial Stability Mandate?
By Renee Haltom and John A. Weinberg

Governments around the world have devoted increasing attention to maintaining overall financial system stability. Central banks play strong roles in
domestic financial stability policy, but the full scopes of their financial stability mandates are ambiguous. The Federal Reserve appeared to embrace
a stronger role in financial system stability starting in the late 1960s and
accelerating with its unprecedented actions during the 2007–08 financial
crisis. Questions remain, however, about the proper scope and design of a
central bank’s financial stability mandate.
The 2007–08 financial crisis and the Fed’s unprecedented response raised new questions about
the Fed’s role in maintaining the stability of the
U.S. financial system.
Central banks have a natural role in financial stability for several reasons. First, monetary policy
affects financial conditions in ways that can contribute to either stability or instability; erratic
policy or volatile inflation could be destabilizing,
for instance. Second, they obtain and develop insights useful for financial stability policy through
the course of their other functions. Third, financial conditions are among the broad set of factors considered by central banks in assessing the
state of the economy and the appropriate stance
of monetary policy.
But for many central banks, the full scope of
what they’re expected to do in support of financial stability — the extent to which they have an
explicit or implicit financial stability mandate —
is ambiguous. This is important because a central
bank’s policy actions and its responses to developments in the economy and financial markets
are shaped by its understanding of its mandate.

EB17-06 - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

So the nature of the mandate matters for economic outcomes, market expectations (the ex
ante “rules of the game”), and accountability.
One reason this issue is inherently challenging
is that there is no single definition of “financial
stability.” Most recent discussions focus on banking crises like the 2007–08 financial crisis, which
tend to feature failures of large or many financial
institutions, cascading losses, and government
interventions. But central banks also have played
a role in other types of financial market disturbances, for example, sharp asset price declines
(like the Fed’s liquidity assurances after the 1987
stock market crash), sovereign debt crises (like
the European Central Bank’s role in the recent
eurozone crisis), and currency crises (like the
Fed’s role in Mexico’s 1994 bailout).
This challenge is clear in the breadth of a definition for financial stability offered in the latest Purposes and Functions publication from the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System:
“A financial system is considered stable when
financial institutions — banks, savings and loans,
and other financial product and service provid-

Page 1

ers — and financial markets are able to provide
households, communities, and businesses with the
resources, services, and products they need to invest,
grow, and participate in a well-functioning economy.”
The publication further states that a financial system
ought to have the ability to do so “even in an otherwise stressed economic environment.”1
This Economic Brief takes a descriptive look at the
Fed’s role in financial stability, including how that
role has changed over time, and raises some fundamental questions.
What’s in the Law?
In U.S. law, no single agency has sole responsibility for ensuring financial stability. Rather, different
agencies have various responsibilities that support
financial stability.
Certain laws give the Fed, typically in conjunction
with other regulators, specific financial stability responsibilities. This is a relatively new development.
Before the 2007–08 crisis, the supervision and regulation of financial institutions was focused on microprudential risks (those within individual institutions).
Since then, risks concerning the financial system as
a whole — so-called systemic risks — have received
increased focus. This broader view includes the risk
that one institution’s failure will affect another, as
well as the risk that events (such as a market dysfunction) might affect the financial system broadly.
The 2010 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act codified this macroprudential
perspective (without ever using the term macroprudential) for all financial regulators while giving the
Fed a unique role. First, the law added requirements
that regulators consider risks to financial stability in
the course of certain regulatory functions, for example, that the Board consider financial stability in
approving financial institution mergers and acquisitions.2 Second, the law created the Financial Stability
Oversight Council (FSOC), with representation from
all of the regulatory agencies, including the Fed. The
FSOC comes perhaps closest to an agency responsible for financial stability, but the law does not go that
far: FSOC is formally charged with identifying risks

to financial stability, promoting market discipline by
reducing the expectation of government bailouts,
and responding to emerging threats to the financial system (emphasis added). The FSOC also must
identify “systemically important financial institutions”
(SIFIs) whose failure or distress could threaten the
financial system. Third, the law made SIFIs, along with
bank holding companies (BHCs) with total assets of
$50 billion or more, subject to regulation by the Fed.
Prudential standards applied to SIFIs and these large
BHCs must be tighter than for other institutions.
Fourth, the law required the Fed, along with the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, to evaluate
the credibility of SIFIs’ living wills (plans the firms
must create explaining how their operations can be
wound down in bankruptcy with minimal disruption
to the financial system).3
Dodd-Frank almost made the Fed legally and singularly responsible for the nation’s financial stability.
A near-final version of the Act indicated that, “the
Board of Governors shall identify, measure, monitor, and mitigate risks to the financial stability of the
United States.” This language was dropped in conference between House and Senate members.4 But its
earlier inclusion suggests that at least some lawmakers believe financial stability should be the Fed’s
responsibility.
The Fed’s primary mandated functions — monetary
policy, payments system operations, and banking
supervision, often called the “three legs of the stool”
— inherently play a role in financial stability. So it is
perhaps unsurprising that the Board of Governors
formally acknowledged a role in overall financial
stability despite the absence of an explicit mandate,
even before the 2007–08 financial crisis brought increased attention to the issue. Its first public strategic
plan, which covered the 1997–2002 period, included
relevant language under sections describing the
Fed’s supervisory role.5 This language was relatively
strong, indicating a responsibility for “maintaining
the stability of the financial system.” More recently,
financial stability has been its own independently
listed function. For example, the Board’s 2005 Annual
Report and language added late that year to the “mission” listed on its website describe financial stability

Page 2

separately from other functions. In these broader
contexts, the language is typically more general,
referring to a role in “promoting” financial stability.
The current mission statement on the Board’s website includes five bullet points: one for each leg of the
stool, one for consumer protection, and one saying
that the Fed “promotes the stability of the financial
system and seeks to minimize and contain systemic
risks through active monitoring and engagement
in the U.S. and abroad.”6

reservoir of water used to put out fire, was thoroughly
misleading and erroneous. [Properly designed central
banks] are not comparable to reservoirs suddenly
drawn upon to put out fire; they are far more nearly
to be compared to fireproof construction whose
purpose it is to prevent combustion.”

What’s in the Air?
In practice, the Fed has adopted an increasingly
broad financial stability role. Financial stability was
part of the Fed’s initial purpose but in a limited and
specific way. The Fed was created to provide a currency supply that could expand and contract quickly
with the needs of commerce. The lack of such a supply before the Fed led to frequent currency shortages, which fueled banking panics and seasonal spikes
in interest rates (the cost of borrowing money).7

paragraph 10(b) to the Federal Reserve Act temporarily authorizing lending to member banks on
otherwise ineligible collateral.

The Fed’s ability to address broader financial stability concerns was fairly circumscribed in the original
Federal Reserve Act. Fed credit could be extended
only to member banks. (A member bank could route
Fed credit to a nonmember bank, but this required
special Board approval.) In particular, the Fed could
not lend directly to many of the institutions at the
heart of previous panics, such as trusts. Eligible collateral was limited to what today is akin to highly
rated commercial paper, that is, very safe short-term
obligations secured by goods already in transit.
This collateral structure reflected the “real bills doctrine,” the guiding principle of the day, which sought
to limit money creation to the amount needed to
fund commerce, as opposed to speculation or longterm investment.8 This approach suggests that
central bank lending was envisioned primarily as a
means to adapt the supply of currency to the needs
of commerce, as opposed to a tool for responding to
panics. Indeed, it was widely believed that the Fed’s
structure would prevent panics to begin with. As H.P.
Willis, the Fed’s first secretary, described: the “illustration so often used during the banking reform struggle wherein a central reserve bank was likened to a

This structure did not last long, however. Fed lending
powers expanded in the Great Depression. Specifically (emphasis added):

• I n February 1932, the Glass-Steagall Act added

• I n July 1932, the Emergency Relief and Construc-

tion Act added paragraph 13(3) opening the discount window to nonbanks “in unusual and exigent
circumstances.”

• I n March 1933, the Emergency Banking Relief

Act added paragraph 13(13) authorizing lending
beyond member banks (to individuals, partnerships,
and corporations, the latter including nonmember banks) for 90 days against broader collateral
(that is, obligations of the U.S. government).

• I n 1934, the Industrial Advances Act added para-

graph 13(b) allowing advances of working capital to
established businesses if they were unable to find it
“from usual sources.”

The objective of these expansions was to provide
credit to two specific groups: nonmember banks and
industry. The former didn’t have regular access to the
discount window until 1980. For the latter, inclusion
was motivated by a desire to provide capital for business production; as it was envisioned, the Fed would
begin to operate the nation’s industrial lending
policy, a role that did not materialize.9
Over time, the Fed system more strongly recognized
the ability of central bank credit to not just support
industry, but to influence credit conditions more
broadly. The Banking Act of 1935 marked a permanent shift away from the real bills doctrine, which by
then had been discredited. First, the Act made the
relaxed collateral conditions of 10(b) permanent.
Though the Senate preferred to retain some restrictions, some parties — including the Board, as noted

Page 3

in its 1937 Annual Report and amendments that year
to Regulation A, which governs the discount window
— interpreted that Congress intended to allow the
Fed to lend against any sound assets. Second, the
Act directed the use of open market operations with
consideration to “the general credit situation in the
country,” not just narrowly to the needs of banks. This
marked the beginning of both the process and the
macroeconomic focus behind monetary policy as it
stands today.
With the 1951 Fed-Treasury Accord, the Fed stopped
purchasing government bonds to suppress government borrowing rates. As noted in a 1973 history of
Fed lending by Howard Hackley, then the Board’s
general counsel, central bank lending through the
discount window became subservient to open market operations (the buying and selling of government securities in a market for government debt
that had become competitive with the Accord) as
the primary tool of monetary policy. Central bank
lending became a tool for allocating credit.10
These policy and intellectual shifts regarding the
role of central bank credit arguably did not mark
the Fed’s adoption of a broader financial stability
role, however. That adoption started to emerge in
the late 1960s. In 1968, the Federal Reserve System
published a report by a committee appointed to
reappraise the discount window, in part a recognition
that strains in the banking system’s ability to adjust
reserves could hamper monetary control. The committee’s report included what is perhaps the Fed’s
first formal articulation of a “lender of last resort”
role in the context of systemic distress, noting:
T he role of the Federal Reserve as the ”lender of
last resort” to other financial sectors of the economy may, under justifiable circumstances, require
loans to institutions other than member banks. …
In contrast to the case of member banks, however,
justification for Federal Reserve assistance to nonmember institutions must be in terms of the probable impact of failure on the economy’s financial
structure. It would be most unusual for the failure
of a single institution or small group of institutions
to have such significant repercussions as to justify
Federal Reserve action.11

This represented another shift in attitude, Hackley
argued.12 The 1968 report described in detail how existing laws could enable emergency lending beyond
member banks, though specifying the role was not
intended as a “bail-out operation” that might prevent
firms from bearing the costs of their risk-taking. A
1973 amendment to Regulation A also noted for the
first time a role in extending credit to nonmember
institutions on an emergency basis, that is, when
“credit is not practically available from other sources
and failure to obtain such credit would adversely affect the economy.”
Whether by coincidence or design, the Fed soon
began acting on this stance, taking unprecedented
actions in the name of broader financial stability.
After the $82 million default of Penn Central railroad
in 1970, the Fed supported commercial paper markets by encouraging banks to borrow and use the
proceeds to lend to other commercial paper issuers.
In 1974, the Fed supported domestic certificate of deposit and eurodollar markets by lending $1.7 billion
to Franklin National Bank, assuming $725 million in
its foreign exchange positions, and accepting deposits from its foreign branch as collateral. Policymakers
later stated they knew the bank was likely to fail, thus
the support was about protecting broader markets.
The bank Continental Illinois also received substantial
support from the discount window in 1984, even as it
was receiving emergency capital from the FDIC due
to concerns that its failure could call into question
the health of other large banks. After the 1987 stock
market crash, the Fed made credit available to banks
supporting broker dealers, among other actions.
When hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management
(LTCM) faced mounting losses in 1998, the Fed coordinated private lenders to provide emergency funding
in order to avoid the large losses policymakers feared
would have spread through the financial system had
LTCM failed. And during the 2007–08 financial crisis,
the Fed extended unprecedented emergency loans
to investment banks and created liquidity facilities to
support entire markets for specific assets.
Comparing Central Banks
The Fed is not alone among central banks in having
a financial stability mandate that is largely implicit

Page 4

in law or based in tradition. Several recent studies
compare financial stability roles across central banks,
including a 2011 Bank for International Settlements
study based on a 2009 survey of thirteen central
banks and a 2016 Bank of Canada working paper.13
Before the crisis, few central banks had explicit

financial stability mandates distinct from their mandates for other functions, and the most explicit financial stability mandates existed under the payments
umbrella. (See Table 1.) To the extent that central
banks have responsibilities related to overall financial stability, they are typically less codified than

Table 1: Central Banks’ Roles in Financial Stability
Central Bank

LOLR?1

Primary Prudential Regulator?

Role in Macroprudential Regulation

Publication of FS Reports

Federal Reserve
(United States)

Yes

Yes. One of several prudential
regulators.

Chair is voting member of Financial Stability Oversight Council, and Fed regulates
“systemically important” institutions.

Not independently, but
through FSOC since 2011

Bank of Canada

Yes

No. Office of the Superintendent
of Financial Institutions is primary
prudential regulator.

Member of Senior Advisory Council, a
nonstatutory body that discusses macroprudential policy. The BOC also oversees
financial market infrastructures and prominent payment systems.

Since 2002

Bank of England

Yes

Yes. BOE’s Prudential Regulation
Authority shares primary prudential
responsibility with the Financial
Conduct Authority, including use of
prudential tools.

BOE leads and hosts Financial Policy
Committee that gives direction on use of
macroprudential tools to prudential
regulators.

With other agencies since
1996, own report since 2006

Bank of Japan

Yes

No. Financial Services Agency is
primary prudential regulator.

In 2014, BOJ and FSA established task force

Since 2005

to exchange views on financial stability. BOJ
is responsible for operation and oversight of
payment and settlement systems.

European
Central Bank

No 2

No. Separate regulatory authorities
in each nation are responsible for
prudential regulation.

ECB and national central banks make up
majority of voting members in European
Systemic Risk Board, which provides
macroprudential oversight within the
European Union.

Since 2004

Norges Bank
(Norway)

Yes

No. Financial Supervisory Authority of Norway is primary prudential
regulator.

Shares macroprudential responsibilities with
other institutions. Publicly issues advice to
the Ministry of Finance.

Since 1997

Reserve Bank
of Australia

Yes

No. Australian Prudential
Regulation Authority is primary
prudential regulator.

Chairs Council of Financial Regulators, a
forum for identifying financial system issues
and trends. RBA has specific regulatory
authority for payments system stability.

Since 2004

Reserve Bank
of New Zealand

Yes

Yes. One of several prudential
regulators.

A memorandum of understanding with
the government gives RBNZ authority over
macroprudential measures.

Since 2004

Riksbank
(Sweden)

Yes

No. Financial Supervisory
Authority is primary prudential
regulator.

Participates in Financial Stability Council,
a forum to discuss financial stability and
financial imbalances. Riksbank also is responsible for promoting safe and efficient
payment system.

Since 1997

Swiss National
Bank

Yes

No. Swiss Financial Market
Supervisory Authority is primary
prudential regulator.

Responsible for proposing activation,
modification, or deactivation of the
countercyclical capital buffer without
ultimate authority over it.

Since 2003

Lender of last resort to banks 2 Central banks of European Monetary Union members serve as LOLRs in their respective nations.
Source: Adapted from Cunningham and Friedrich (2016), BIS (2011), and central bank websites.

1

Page 5

mandates for banking or payments, perhaps reflecting that financial stability is a less-developed area of
study and a less easily defined goal. In the majority
of cases, the mandate is directional and not easily
measureable, including language such as a responsibility to “promote” or “support” financial stability.
Financial stability mandates that cover the broader
financial system as a whole are not necessarily clearer
in their objectives. Mandates for crisis response —
that is, the lender of last resort function, whether
standing facilities or emergency assistance — tend to
be codified firmly in law but with significant differences in rules and how they have been used.
Central banks do not always play a major role in
banking supervision, but mandates to potentially
support banks in times of crisis via lender of last
resort practices are widespread. Banks with greater
regulatory responsibilities are more likely to see
themselves as having broader financial stability
responsibilities, even when the latter are not formalized. They are also more likely to deploy macroprudential instruments, though in the BIS study the use
of macroprudential instruments correlated more
strongly with an emerging market economy status
than with having major regulatory responsibilities.
In the BIS survey, only Thailand came close to including financial stability explicitly as part of its monetary
policy mandate, though all central banks reported
having analytical frameworks for monetary policy
that considered financial market developments. In
some cases these frameworks are explicit: both the
European Central Bank and the Bank of Japan formally identify longer-term risks to monetary policy that
provide a channel through which financial stability
concerns may enter monetary policy analysis. A 2015
Bank of Canada study of ten central banks found that
those that have a stronger financial stability mandate
but less influence over regulatory and macroprudential tools (such as countercyclical capital surcharges,
asset concentration limits, and limits on interbank
exposures, among others) were more likely to use
monetary policy tools to address financial stability
risks. That is, they were more likely to raise interest
rates to lean against credit expansions viewed as
excessive.14

Like the 2010 Dodd-Frank Act in the United States,
many countries enacted financial reform legislation
after the crisis, with a trend toward greater macroprudential regulation and analytics, often with
special roles for the central bank. Some countries
have created new financial stability oversight entities, such as FSOC in the United States, but some
(like FSOC) focus on institutions while others focus
only on overall risks. The United States is unique in
that the formal analytic function (assigned to the
Office of Financial Research in the U.S. Treasury) is
not primarily housed in and does not directly involve
the central bank. To the authors’ knowledge, in no
case has reform made traditional monetary policy
objectives subservient to financial stability.
In most cases, the financial stability accountability framework is similar to monetary policy in that
it happens largely through transparency, though
with steps that are less explicit. Most central banks
publish information on financial stability actions
with discretion and historically have not released
the recipients of emergency lending (at least not
immediately) due to stigma considerations. Financial stability reports tend to be less frequent than
monetary policy reports, and less information tends
to be provided on financial stability actions than on
monetary policy actions, perhaps because objectives
and metrics of success for financial stability are less
well-defined and may be based in counterfactuals
(such as a crisis that didn’t occur). Reforms since the
crisis, such as those in the United States and the
United Kingdom, have tended to enhance disclosures of the recipients of emergency lending. Many
of the newly developed financial stability oversight
groups, which are typically housed in central banks,
must report periodically to lawmakers.
Overall, the objectives of financial stability responsibilities remain unclear. Financial market variables
can and should fluctuate, sometimes rapidly, with
underlying fundamentals. Does stability refer to the
resilience of the system to such fluctuations or minimizing the costs that follow? The absence of broad
crises? Managing the credit cycle? These questions
have critical implications for the design, governance,
and accountability of financial stability policymak-

Page 6

ing institutions.15 Moreover, achieving any of these
objectives could require the use of tools designed for
other purposes, potentially creating conflicts among
goals. How central banks and other agencies should
weigh these trade-offs remains for the most part an
open question.
Some Implications for Monetary Policy
Many studies have explored outstanding issues concerning how financial stability policy, whether or not
it is housed in the central bank, may affect the central bank’s other functions.16 Despite relatively vague
financial stability deliverables, it is very likely that
lawmakers and financial market participants expect
the Fed to take strong actions to achieve financial
stability. This raises some potential problems that
remain unresolved.
An expectation that the Fed will provide emergency
lending could breed moral hazard. The central bank’s
stance regarding financial stability affects beliefs
about how the central bank will respond to crises,
and these beliefs affect the extent to which financial
market participants engage in risky behavior in the
first place. Ambiguity in the mandate is less problematic if markets place zero probability on financial rescues, but that is unlikely to be the case now given past
actions. Measures to reduce that probability must
carry legal or reputational weight to be effective.17
Lack of clarity over the Fed’s role could leave room
for political pressure that would jeopardize monetary
policy goals. Monetary policy and financial stability
concerns often will have consistent implications for
monetary policy settings, but at times they may be
in opposition, as might be the case if inflation were
contained but asset prices were rising. But if the
central bank believes it will be held accountable for
asset bubbles, it may feel obligated to divert from
standard monetary policy objectives. Monetary
policy tools are easier and faster to implement than
some regulatory tools and may have wider-ranging
effects. They “get in all the cracks,” as former Fed Governor Jeremy Stein has noted — a sentiment echoed
by the Conference of Presidents in a recent tabletop
exercise — even though monetary policy tools are
blunt and not necessarily well-suited to addressing

specific risks.18 And to the extent that reconciling
trade-offs involves the political process, monetary
policy objectives are likely to be compromised for
time-inconsistency reasons.
Similarly, the central bank could face pressure to use
its lending powers too liberally, especially if bailouts
are politically expedient or if the central bank perceives it would be criticized later for not acting. The
latter may be more likely when the mandate is vague
since it provides wider scope for interpretation over
perceived failures in financial stability goals. Since
emergency lending powers overlap some with traditional monetary policy tools, backlash could threaten monetary policy independence — either overtly
through legislation or through political pressures.
There is indeed evidence that the Fed has factored
congressional scrutiny into its monetary policy
decisions.19
These are by no means the only issues concerning
how a financial stability mandate may affect monetary policy. Overall, there remains a lot to learn about
the role of the central bank in financial stability. The
economics profession spent much of the last half
of the twentieth century developing the scientific
components of monetary policy, and that work is
just beginning for financial stability policy.
Renee Haltom is the editorial content manager and
John A. Weinberg is a senior vice president and special advisor to the president at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond.
Endnotes
1

 oard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Purposes
B
and Functions, 10th Edition, March 2017.

2

S ection 163 of the Act states that “the Board of Governors
shall consider the extent to which the proposed acquisition
would result in greater or more concentrated risks to global
or United States financial stability or the United States
economy.”

3

S ection 165 of the Act states that the Board of Governors and
FDIC must determine whether the resolution plan “is not credible or would not facilitate an orderly resolution of the company under title 11, United States Code.” For more on living
wills, see Arantxa Jarque and Kartik B. Athreya, “Understanding Living Wills,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly, Third Quarter 2015, vol. 101, no. 3, pp. 193–223.

Page 7

4

This text is visible in what was then section 1108(b) of the bill.

5

T he Board’s strategic plans are available on its website along
with associated performance plans and reports.

6

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “About the
Fed,” accessed on May 31, 2017.

7

 ne interpretation is that the Fed’s purpose was monetary
O
stability as opposed to financial stability. See Renee Haltom
and Jeffrey M. Lacker, “Should the Fed Have a Financial Stability Mandate?” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond 2013
Annual Report, pp. 4–25.

8

F or additional background, see Robert L. Hetzel, “The Real Bills
Views of the Founders of the Fed,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly, Second Quarter 2014, vol. 100,
no. 2, pp. 159–181.

9

S ee Tim Sablik, “Fed Credit Policy during the Great Depression,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Brief No. 13-03,
March 2013.

10

 oward H. Hackley, Lending Functions of the Federal Reserve
H
Banks: A History, Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System,1973, pp. 185–188.

11

 oard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Reappraisal
B
of the Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism,” Report of a System Committee, 1968.

12

Hackley 1973, pp. 194–195.

13

 ank for International Settlements, “Central Bank Governance
B
and Financial Stability: A Report by a Study Group,” May 2011;
and Rose Cunningham and Christian Friedrich, “The Role of
Central Banks in Promoting Financial Stability: An International
Perspective,” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper
No. 2016-15, July 2016.

14

 hristian Friedrich, Kristina Hess, and Rose Cunningham, “MonC
etary Policy and Financial Stability: Cross-Country Evidence,”
Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2015-41, November
2015.

15

F or a brief overview of some of these issues, see Paul Tucker,
“The Objectives of Financial Stability Policy,” Vox, September 28,
2016.

16

I n addition to BIS 2011 and Bank of Canada 2016, see Viral
Acharya, “Financial Stability in the Broader Mandate for Central
Banks: A Political Economy Perspective,” Hutchins Center on
Fiscal and Monetary Policy at Brookings, Working Paper No. 11,
April 2015; and International Monetary Fund, “Monetary Policy
and Financial Stability,” Staff Report, September 2015.

17

T he Dodd-Frank Act attempted to limit bailouts by requiring
that 13(3) lending be made broadly available and not extended only to one firm, but many observers have noted that this
requirement would not prevent the Fed from creating a broad
lending facility with the intention of rescuing specific firms.

18

T obias Adrian, Patrick de Fontnouvelle, Emily Yant, and Andrei
Zlate, “Macroprudential Policy: Case Study from a Tabletop Exercise,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 742,
Revised December 2015.

19

F or example, see Gregory D. Hess and Cameron A. Shelton,
“Congress and the Federal Reserve,” Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking, June 2016, vol. 48, no. 4, pp. 603–633 (article
available with subscription); and Charles L. Weise, “Political
Pressures on Monetary Policy during the US Great Inflation,”
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, April 2012,
vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 33–64 (article available with subscription).

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its
entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the
italicized statement below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF RICHMOND
Richmond Baltimore Charlotte

Page 8