View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Brief

March 2011, EB11-03

The Earned Income Tax Credit: Recipients, Labor
Force Participation, and Credit Constraints
By Kartik B. Athreya and Aaron Steelman

There has been a longstanding debate in the United States about how to
assist low-income families. The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is designed
to augment income while encouraging work: The tax credit increases with
earnings for low levels of household income, but declines and ultimately is
phased out as incomes rise. The EITC appears to have increased labor force
participation but its effects on hours worked is ambiguous. Given the low
levels of net wealth of most EITC recipients, it is likely that many are credit
constrained and unable to smooth their consumption patterns.
The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), originally
introduced in 1975 and made permanent in
1978, has become the federal government’s
largest cash-assistance program for low-income
families. Approximately $43 billion was allocated to 22 million families in the United
States in 2007 through the federal EITC. This
compares to $16.5 billion that was allocated
through more traditional assistance programs
such as Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF).1 Indeed, during the period when
TANF replaced Aid to Families with Dependent
Children as a result of welfare reform in 1996,
the United States experienced a 50 percent
reduction in welfare rolls; one study suggests
that much of that drop can be attributed to
the EITC and reduction in welfare benefits.2 The
perceived success of the federal EITC has led
to the development of similar programs in 23
states and the District of Columbia.3 Moreover,
the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act
of 2009 increased the credit for families with
three or more children and expanded eligibility for married couples.

EB11-03 - The Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

EITC Structure and Recipients
In practice, the EITC functions as a negative
income tax—that is, people with earnings below
a certain level do not pay taxes on their wages
but instead effectively receive a subsidy. The
program is structured in three stages, depending on the recipient’s income. In the phase-in
stage, the credit increases with earnings; in the
plateau stage, the credit reaches a maximum and
levels off; and in phase-out stage, the credit falls
as the recipient’s earnings rise. Both households
with children and those without are eligible for
the EITC. In a recent paper, one of the authors of
this Economic Brief (Athreya) and two co-authors,
Devin Reilly of the Richmond Fed and Nicole B.
Simpson of Colgate University, used data from
the Current Population Study to examine how
the structure of the EITC program affects households of varying characteristics.4 For example,
for households with two or more children and
low levels of income, the marginal tax rate is
-40 percent for both single and married filers,
which represents the phase-in stage of the EITC.

Page 1

As incomes reach $13,000, the marginal tax rate is
zero, meaning it has reached the plateau stage. And
as incomes increase beyond $13,000, the marginal
tax rate becomes positive and rises quickly. A similar
pattern emerges for married and single households
with one child, but for childless households the
negative income tax effect is not as large and the
increase in marginal tax rates is not as extreme.
The EITC benefits are relatively high for households
headed by young adults (ages 18-25), fairly constant
for households in their 30s, and then decline sharply
for households in their late 30s and beyond. By the
time households are in their 50s and 60s, the average amount of the EITC is slightly more than $500.
The interaction of qualification requirements with
the benefit structure, however, ensures that the EITC
remains a relatively constant fraction of recipients’
earnings for most of their lives, approximately 15
percent. Perhaps surprisingly, the EITC represents an
even larger proportion of the income of older EITC
recipient households, roughly 18 percent for those
in their late 50s. This is perhaps due to the fact that
households that qualify for the EITC at this age have
very low incomes since they likely face the income
thresholds applicable to those with no children.
EITC recipients tend to have not only relatively low
annual income, but also relatively low net worth.
Using data from the Federal Reserve Board of Governors’ Survey of Consumer Finances, Athreya, Reilly,
and Simpson find that EITC recipients, on average,
hold only one-fifth of the wealth of non-EITC recipients. In fact, the bottom quartile of EITC recipients
hold negative wealth on average, while the bottom
quartile of non-recipients have small, positive wealth
holdings. In the second quartile, EITC recipients hold
$3,489 in net wealth, compared to $75,329 for nonEITC recipients; in the third quartile the comparison
is $24,038 to $253,637; and in the top quartile, the
comparison is $404,272 to $1,991,197. Only in the top
quartile do EITC recipients hold significant wealth,
with those recipients tending to be older and often
homeowners. Also noteworthy, married households
that are eligible for the EITC hold more wealth than
single households, and wealth holdings decrease
with the number of children in the household.

The EITC and Labor Force Participation
While the EITC is designed to encourage work among
low-income households, there are two relevant
dimensions of that decision to examine: (1) whether
to enter the workforce at all, and (2) how many hours
to work. On the first dimension, it appears that the
EITC does, in fact, increase labor force participation,
especially among single mothers; that was especially
true in the 1980s and 1990s.5 On the second dimension, the evidence is less clear. This is due, in part, to
the structure of the EITC program.
Remember, as income increases, the EITC benefits
decrease or are even phased-out altogether. Thus,
households must decide how much to work. At low
levels of income, the benefits of work (income received both from labor and from the EITC) are unambiguously positive. This is not true at higher levels of
income. Households must make decisions about labor output as they reach the plateau and phase-out
stages: On the margin, are more hours worked worth
the diminished amount of EITC benefits received?
How households respond is ambiguous not only
theoretically but also empirically. One study suggests
that since most households receiving the EITC fall in
the plateau or phase-out region, it is likely that the
overall effect of the EITC on hours worked is negative.6 However, other studies have shown that while
higher-income households are sensitive to marginal
tax rates, lower-income households are less so.7 This
may be due to lower-income workers holding jobs
that do not permit them to easily adjust their work
hours.8 If it is true that lower-income workers are not
particularly responsive to marginal tax rates, the EITC
probably has little or no effect on their number of
hours worked, a finding that seems to be generally
held among labor economists.
Credit Constraints and EITC Recipients
As noted above, EITC recipients, on average, tend
to have relatively low levels of net wealth. In addition, they are more likely than non-EITC recipients to
frequently have late debt repayments and relatively
low credit scores. These factors, by themselves, likely
constrain their ability to borrow and thus smooth
their consumption of goods relative to non-EITC
recipients. The EITC may mitigate this issue to some

Page 2

degree, as it would be relatively clear to lenders that
this benefit is forthcoming and the loan could be repaid. But that may be true for only a segment of EITC
recipients—those who do not possess characteristics
that typically make lenders wary of extending credit.
On balance, it would appear that EITC recipients have
different access to credit markets than non-recipients
and hence use those markets in ways (probably more
limited) than the population more generally.
Conclusion
Economists and policymakers have long considered
ways to assist low-income people. On net, there
is a strong presumption among economists that
the most efficient way to accomplish this goal is
to simply allocate lump-sum payments to those
households who would qualify and let them use
the payments in ways they deem most effective
in meeting their goals. For a variety of reasons,
however, such a proposal seems unpalatable to
many and, hence, other policies have been pursued.
The EITC, which links assistance to work, appears
to not only have gained widespread acceptance
but also to have been relatively effective at assisting
those in need. There are still open questions, however, about how sensitive the supply of labor among
EITC recipients is to the way benefits are structured.
In addition, it appears that EITC recipients, like most
of the poor or relatively poor, do not have similar
access to credit markets as non-EITC recipients. To
the extent that such differential access is undesirable
and improvements can be made without distorting
credit markets, policymakers may wish to address
this issue.
Kartik B. Athreya is a senior economist and research
advisor and Aaron Steelman is director of publications at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

Endnotes
1 

Nada Eissa and Hilary Hoynes, “Taxes and the Labor Market Participation of Married Couples: The Earned Income Tax Credit,”
Journal of Public Economics, August 2004, vol. 88, iss. 9-10, pp.
1,931-1,958.

2 

Jeffrey Grogger, “Welfare Transitions in the 1990s: The Economy,
Welfare Policy, and the EITC,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Autumn 2004, vol. 23, no. 4, pp. 671-695.

3 

Jason Levitis and Jeremy Koulish, “State Earned Income Tax
Credits: 2008 Legislative Update,” Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities, October 8, 2008.

4 

Kartik B. Athreya, Devin Reilly, and Nicole B. Simpson, “Earned
Income Tax Recipients: Income, Marginal Tax Rates, Wealth,
and Credit Constraints,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, Third Quarter 2010, vol. 96, no. 3, pp. 229-258.

5 

Bruce D. Meyer, “Taxes, Welfare, and Work by Single Mothers,”
National Bureau of Economic Research Reporter OnLine, Fall
2001.

6 

V. Joseph Hotz and John Karl Scholz, “Not Perfect but Still Pretty
Good: The EITC and Other Policies to Support the U.S. LowWage Labour Market,” OECD Economic Studies, April 2000, no.

31/II, pp. 25-42.
7 

See, for example, Michael Keane and Robert Moffitt, “A Structural Model of Multiple Welfare Program Participation and
Labor Supply,” International Economic Review, August 1998, vol.
39, no. 3, pp. 553-589; and Jon Gruber and Emmanuel Saez,
“The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications,”
Journal of Public Economics, April 2002, vol. 84, no. 1, pp. 1-32.

8 

Jennifer L. Romich, “Difficult Calculations: Low-Income Workers
and Marginal Tax Rates,” Social Service Review, March 2006, vol.
80, no. 1, pp. 27-66.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its
entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, and include the
italicized statement below.
The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Page 3