Full text of The Dual Banking System in the United States
The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
THE DUAL BANKING SYSTEM IN THE UNITED STATES Material prepared for the information of the Federal Reserve System by the Federal Eeserve Committee on Branch, Group, and Chain Banking Members of the Consnittee E. A. Goldenweiser, Director, Division of Research and Statistics, Federal Eeserve Board, Chairman Ira Clerk, Deputy Governor, Federal Eeserve Bank of San Francisco M. <7. Fleming, Deputy Governor, Federal Eeserve Bank of Cleveland L. E. Sounds, Deputy Governor, Federal Eeserve Bank of Uew York E. L. Smead, Chief, Division of Bank Operations, Federal Eeserve Board J. H. Eiddle, Executive Secretary and Director of Eesearch The Committee was appointed February 2o, 1930» 1Q 7 the Federal Reserve Board " . . . to assemble and digest inforraation on branch banking as practiced in the United States, group and chain banking systems as developed in the United States and elsewhere, the unit banking system of the country, and the effect of ownership of bank stocks by investment trusts and holding corporations." LETTER 0? TRANSMITTAL To the Federal Reserve Board: The Committee on Branch, Group, and Chain Banking transmits herewith a review of legislative and supervisory developments under the dual hanking system in the United States. Respectfully, E. A. Goldenweiser Chairman CONTESTS Page Introduction Chapter I Chapter II The Competitive Status of National and State Banks Prior to. 1913 The Competitive Advantages of State Banks Meeting State Bank Competition by National Legislation Indirect Methods of Meeting State 3ank Competition The Dual Banking System in 1913 The Dual System since the Passage of the Federal Reserve Act Adoption of the Federal Reserve Act State Bank Membership in the Federal Reserve System Extension of National 3ank Powers, 1916-I922 The McFadden Act of 1927 Par Clearance of Checks Relative Strength of Member and Nonmember Banking Systems, 1913-1931 1 3 7 11 13 15 17 17 22 26 2S 32 3k Chapter III State Legislation and the Dual 3anking System The Opening of New Banks Capital Requirements Other Restrictions Powers and Privileges of Banks Loans on Real Estate Ownership of Corporate Stocks Loans to Single Borrowers Loans to Officers and Directors Branch Banking Fiduciary Powers Investment Banking Reserves Against Deposits hj US k& 51 52 52 53 55 55 56 5S 59 60 Chapter IV The Influence of Bankers on Legislation Activities of the American Bankers Association Activities of the State Supervisors 62 66 71 Chapter V Effects of Dual Control upon Bank Supervision National Bank Supervision National Bank Supervision Prior to the Federal Reserve Act National Bank Supervision since 1913 State Bank Supervision State Supervisory Agencies Weakness of State Supervision Excessive Granting of Charters 76 7S 7S gl S6 gg 91 96 CONTENTS (Continued) Page Chapter 71 Motives for Choice of Charters The Effect of Consolidations and Conversions Seasons for Charter Preferences Choice of National Charters Choice of State Charters Fiduciary Powers The iiforcester Case Loan and Investment Powers Supervision Branch and Group Banking Powers Underwriting and Merchandising of Securities Insurance Business Broader Powers in General Economy 102 102 108 111 111 111 115 118 119 119 120 121 121 121 Chapter VII Summary Excessive Chartering of Banks Relaxation of Restrictions on National Banks Dual Control and Supervision State Banks and the Federal Reserve System 122 122 125 129 131 Appendix 13^ Bibliography 1g1 IFTHOXIUCTIOI Hans'- of the problems of commercial "banking in the United States today have arisen from the historical division of responsibility "between the Federal and State Governments in chartering and supervising "banks. Competition "between the two systems has not only "been an important factor in the incorporation of thousands of small "banks, "but has also led to the relaxation of legal regulations and has tended to diminish the effectiveness of supervision. At the time of the Civil ?«*ar an attempt 7?as made to "bring about unified control through the establishment of the national "banking system. A large measure of unified control was temporarily achieved, primarily "because national "banks were accorded the privilege of issuing currency while the notes of State "banks were subjected to a -orohibitive tax. For about twenty years the amount of banking business controlled by State incorporated institutions was negligible. If such a condition had obtained through the subsequent decades, it is likely that supervision, unaffected by the kind of competition that was later to develop, would have been able to maintain a Mghor standard of banking practice. The practice of deposit banking began to develop on so large a scale, however, that State banks found it increasingly profitable to operate without the privilege of issuing notes; and from the early eighties State banks have groma steadily in relative importance. It soon became evident that State banks had many competitive advantages over national banks, notably in the matter of lower minimum capital and other requirements for receiving charters, and in more extensive powers - 2- and privileges, which provided greater opportunities for making profits. The Federal Government was under pressure to grant similar powers and privileges to national banks. The granting of such powers and privileges tended to re- move some of the restrictions previously imposed by the National Bank Act. Thus it was that about the beginning of the present century, or somewhat earlier, there began between the national and the several State systems a form of rivalry which has been described as a competition in laxity. When the Federal reserve system was established in 1913, a second opportunity to consolidate a unified control over commercial banking was presented, but this legislation did not reach the thousands of small State banks. Today only about 800 of the 12,000 State commercial banks belong to the Federal reserve system. Most of the larger State banks have become members of the Federal reserve system and all national banks are members as a matter of law. National banks, however, are free to leave the system by conversion to State charter, and State banks may relinquish their membership upon six months' notice. It is clear, therefore, that all Federal reserve membership is in effect voluntary. This condition weakens the power of the Federal reserve system to exercise effective supervision over the banking system. Nonmember commercial banks, meanwhile, continue to operate under the laws of forty-eight States, CHAPTER I THE COMPETITIVE STATUS OF NATIONAL AND STATE BANKS PRIOR TO 191? Throughout the period extending from the expiration of the charter of the Second Bank of the United States in IS36 to the passage of the National Bank Act in I863, the only incorporated banks in existence operated under State charter. In addition, there were many private hanks in existence which con- tinued to operate even after the passage of the National Bank Act. Information as to the volume of hanking strength represented hy these private concerns is not available, but there were some individual firms of importance. Prior to the Civil War note issue was the principal activity of incorporated banks, although many banks operated without the note issue privilege. When provision was made for national banks of issue, it was hoped that State banks of issue would apply for national charters. The bulk of the State banks, however, did not enter the national system of their own free will, and in 1865 a tax of 10 per cent was levied upon all State bank notes paid out by any bank. In introducing the tax measure Senator Sherman said: (1) "The national banks were intended to supersede the State banks. Both cannot exist together; . . . "If the State banks have power enough in Congress to prolong their existence beyond the present year, we had better suspend the organization of national banks." Congressional Globe, 38th Congress, 2nd Session, February 2], P. 1139. ' - 3- I865, - k~ The tax put an immediate end to State "bank issues, and all but a few State incorporated banks soon disappeared. The great majority of them converted into national banks, liquidated voluntarily, or failed during the Civil War, and most of the newly organized banks obtained national charters. By 1S6S there were 1,6^0 national banks and only 2^7 incorporated State banks reported in existence.C1) Changes in the number of banks in operation are shown in Chart 1, and the resources of State and national banks from IS63 through 1931 in Chart 2. Table I in the appendix gives the figures on which these charts are based. The privilege of note issue continued to be a major influence upon the choice of bank charters until about 1SS0. With the increased use of checks in business transactions, however, the relative importance of bank notes was steadily declining. This decline may be illustrated by the liabilities of national banks. In IS70 about 30 per cent of the currency and deposit liabilities of these banks consisted of bank notes4 but by IS95 this proportion had declined to about 7 per cent, and in 1931 it was less than 3 VCT cent. State banks gradually developed the business of discount and deposit and found that they could operate profitably without the note issue privilege. From about 1SS0, therefore, State banks began to develop again and increased in number almost continuously until 1921. t 1 ' The term "State bank" is used here to include State banks, trust companies, and stock savings banks: that is, all banks incorporated under State laws. It does not include mutual savings banks or private banks. - 5 - CHART 1 NUMBER « t? NUMBER OF COMMERCIAL BANKS AND TRUST COMPANIES IN THE UNITED STATES, 183fc-W31 OF BANKS NUMBER OF BANKS A A A State banks include trust companies and stock savings banks. Mutual savings banks are not included. Figures are as of June 30 of each year or nearest reporting date. 6. - CHART 2 RESOURCES OF STATE AND NATIONAL BANKS 1665-1931 BILLIONS OF DOLLARS BILLIONS OF DOLLARS 40 State banks include trust companies and stock savings banks but exolude private banks and mutual savings banks. Figures are as of June 30 of each year or nearest reporting date. -* 7 ** The Competitive Advantages of State Banks For many years national "banks had two competitive advantages over State 'banks, but these gradually diminished in importance while a number of advantages developed in favor of State banks. One of the advantages in favor of national banks was the note issue privilege, which, while only moderately profitable after 1880, continued to be valued. The other advantage was the fact that in the newly developed sections of the country, especially in the South and West, outside capital had to be depended upon; and since non-resident investors were more familiar with the provisions of the national law than with those of the various States, it was easier to procure capital for a new bank incorporated by the Federal Government. This advan- tage also became of less importance as the years passed and the development of communities made it possible for bank capital to be supplied from local sources.(1) In contrast to these dwindling advantages of national banks, State banks had a number of apparent advantages which grew in importance as time went by. One of the most important of these was the lower capital required of State banks. The minimum capital permitted by the National Bank Act prior to 1900 was $50,000. Many Western and Southern States, on the contrary, permitted the incorporation of banks with a minimum capital as ldw as $10,000, while in at least one State the minimum was placed at $5,000, and in several there were no capital requirements. (2) .»•••..—* M ••••, . I,,I,„I .,, 1, ,, • m ^ «.••-•—,. (1) Cf. George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the national Bank Act, Publications of the National Monetary Conmission, Vol. 711, pp. 232-233. A considerable part of the discussion in this chapter is based on Mr. Barnett1s analysis. (2) Table 10, Ch, Ill, shows the capital requirements in 1909 f° r banks incorporated in the various States. -» o r" The provisions of the State "banking laws relative to the amount of credit which might "be extended "by a particular "bank to a single individual, firm, or corporation were also more literal in most cases than those of the National Bank Act. The national system originally restricted such loans to 10 per cent of paid-in capital and continued to do so up to 1906. State banking laws, however, authorized individual loans when unsecured to an amount ranging as high as 30 P e r cent of capital and surplus and in some States when secured there were apparently no limitations at all. In about a third of the States there was apparently no mention of restrictions either as to secured or unsecured loans.(1) Furthermore, the National Bank Act prior to 1913 - n^t did permit the granting of loans on real estate, while most State "banks could make such loans. In some States the real estate loans of State "banking institutions averaged one-third or more of their total loans and discounts.(2) In I9O9 reserve requirements against deposits were, as a rule, smaller in the State "banking laws than in the National Bank Act. In some States no legal reserves were stipulated, the matter "being left entirely to the discretion of the directors of the "banks. Moreover, several of the State laws permitted lower reserves against savings and time deposits than against demand deposits; while in the national law no distinction was made between demand and time deposits and the comptroller had to require the sane reserves against both types.'3/ Several States, however, required the (1) Samuel A. Welldon, Digest of State Banking Statutes, Publications of the National Monetary Commission, Vol. III. (2) Abstracts of condition reports of State banks published by the Comptroller of the Currency. It is apparent that few State banks fully classify their loans in reports to the Comptroller of the Currency. There are States, however, which in some years have reported more than a third of their total loans and discounts as made on real estate, e.g., New Hampshire, Ohio, and Michigan. (3) Annual Report of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1912, p. 11. -9segregation of savings deposits and their investment in high-grade securities. There were also a number of States which prior to 193-3 permitted the establishment of branches, a privilege held to be illegal under the National Bank Act. (1) In 1909 about a fourth of the States expressly authorized State banks or' trust companies to open branches, while in only about a sixth of the States were branches specifically forbidden. This competitive advantage of the State systems in regard to branches was, however, more potential than actual, for relatively few banks established branches prior to 1913. The number of State banks with branches was only S2 in 1900, and 2#3 in 1910, with 1-lU branches in the former year and 53& in the latter.(2j Moreover, under the amendment to the National Bank Act passed in 1365, State banks having branches, with capital assigned to the head office and branches in definite proportions, could convert into national banks and retain their branches, regardless of the location of those branches. Although it was not lawful for a national bank to invest in the stock of banks and other corporations, the banks and trust companies of a number of States were authorized to do so, and to a considerable extent seem to have taken advantage of the privilege. This made it possible for State banks and trust companies legally to engage in activities from which national institutions were debarred. These legal rights exercisable by certain State (1) The National Bank Act did not specifically prohibit the establishment of branches, but the Comptroller of the Currency had held that it did so by implication. Sse report of Committee on Branch, Group,and Chain Banking, Branch Banking in the United States. Not until I92U was there a court decision to the effect that national banks could not establish branches. This was in the case of First National Bank in St. Louis v„ State of Missouri (263 U. S. 6U0). (2) Branch Banking in the United States. - 10 - institutions, were no doubt in many instances of influence in determining •whether a new institution should obtain a State or a national charter. Trust companies, which developed rapidly after 1300, especially in He?/ England and the Middle Atlantic States, also presented a serious competitive problem to the national "banks, for national "banks could not exercise fiduciary powers prior to 1913* I11 a number of States reserves required of trust companies were as high or higher than those of national institutions, but this was not generally true. In about a fourth of them there were no reserve requirements stipulated in the law for trust companies. Moreover, trust comapnies in many States could make real estate loans and purchase stocks of banks and other corporations. The advantages of the trust companies over national banks were summarized by a leading authority as followsr^1) "A third cause (of the growth of trust companies), and in the writer's opinion by far the most important one in most communities, lies in the wide range of powers which the, trust company may exercise. In most States it may do all of the things that an ordinary "bank may do, except issue notes; and it performs numerous duties that other banks may not undertake. These wide powers attract customers. It is a distinct convenience to most people to have all of their financial business attended tc under one roof. The trust company xrill not only care for their banking business, but will also receive their valuables for safe-keeping, care for their property, manage their estates temporarily or permanently, make investments for them, give financial and legal advice, aid in the preparation of wills and execute the sane after the decease of the customer." Still another factor favorable to the growth of State banks at the expense of national banks was the higher standards of examination and supervision of the comptroller's office as compared with the standard of many State supervisory authorities. Many States had no supervision of banks and trust companies until several years after 1910, while in other cases State Clay Herrick, Trust Companies, p. 32. - 11 - examiners found i t e a s i e r to take a s o - c a l l e d "sympathetic a t t i t u d e " as a r e s u l t of an a l l e g e d intimate knowledge of local conditions, and there was also a g r e a t e r p o s s i b i l i t y of d i r e c t p o l i t i c a l influence under State than under n a t i o n a l c h a r t e r s . Thus a number of factors gave the State hanks, during the period from 1SS0 to 1913» apparent competitive advantages over the national hanks, the most important being smaller capital requirements, more liberal lending and investing powers, smaller legal reserves, less restriction on branches, and less strict supervision. Meeting State Bank Competition by National Legislation The effect of State bank competition began to be marked in the late eighties and early nineties. Especially was this true in the newly exploited regions of the West and South, where banking facilities were lacking, new capital was scarce, and the small capital required of State banks was of considerable importance. In order to meet these conditions by an expansion of the national banking system the Comptroller of the Currency in 1896 urged upon Congress several amendments to the National Bank Act. One of these was the reduction of the minimum capitalization of national banks from $50,000 to $25,000 in places with less than 2,000 inhabitants. Such a change, it was declared, would not only permit the expansion of the national system into the South and West, where the majority of the banks had State charters and where there were few large towns, but would also be of advantage to the communities in those sections of the nation on account of the greater strength of the national system. - 12 - Another recommendation of the Comptroller of the Currency was that national banks, with the approval of the comptroller, should be permitted to establish branches in communities of less than 1,000 inhabitants. This, he stated, would bring outside capital to agricultural and other communities which required it, and would create an outlet for national bank notes in localities where they were most needed. He maintained that small coonunities where independent banks could not operate profitably could be served by branch offices. A third recommendation of the comptroller designed to foster the expansion of the national banking system was that national banks be permitted to issue notes to the full par value of the bonds by which they were secured, instead of the 90 per cent permitted in the original act. This would increase the profitableness of the note issue. These recommendations were repeated with varying emphasis in subsequent reports of the comptroller and sanctioned by the President and the Secretary of the Treasury. (1) It was not until 1900, however, that any of then were acted upon by Congress. In the Currency Act of March 1^-, 1900, it was provided that bank notes might be issued to the full par value of the bonds by which they \vere secured, and that national banks might be organized in places not exceeding 3»000 population with a capital of not less than $25,000. Permission to establish branches was not granted, however. The reduced capital requirement resulted in the organization of a considerable number of new national banks with capital stock of less than $50,000. During the first decade after the passage of the Currency Act, (1) Annual Report of the Comptroller of the Currency, IS96, Vol. 1, pp. 100105; 1897, Vol. 1, p. xvi; 1898, Vol. 1, p. xi; and IS99, Vol. 1, pp. xiv and xx. The Comptroller of the Currency in I896 and in IS97 was James E. Eckels and in IS98 and 1899 Charlesfi.Dawes. - 13 - the number of national "banks increased from 3,731 to 7,138, or by 91 P e r cent, and nearly a third of the total number in 1910 had capital stock of less than $50,000. This expansion in the number of national banks was less, however, than the expansion in the number of State banks, for during the sane decade the State banks increased from approximately 5,000 to more than 14,000, or by more than 180 per cent. The aggregate resources of State banks also increased during the decade more rapidly than those of the national banks. (See Charts 1 and 2 and Table I of the appendix.) In 1905 the Comptroller of the Currency also recommended raising the limit on individual loans from 10 per cent of the paid-in capital to 10 per cent of the capital and surplus. An amendment to the National Bank Act was approved on June 22, 1906, changing the limitation on individual loans as suggested to 10 per cent of capital and surplus, provided the total should not exceed JO per cent of the capital. (1) State banks continued to grow more rapidly, however, both in number and in resources, than the national banks. From 1906 to 1913 the State banks increased 65 per cent in number and 46 per cent in resources; while the national banks increased 24 per cent in number and 42 per cent in resources. Indirect Methods of Meeting State Bank Competition The most important natters in which State banking laws were more liberal than the National Bank Act were not the subject of significant Federal legislation prior to the passage of the Federal Reserve Act; and in most instances the State banks, even after the amendment to the National Bank Act in 1900, still had much lower capital requirements than national banks. (1) Annual Report of the Comptroller of the Currency. 1905, pp. 62-63; 1906, pT^T" - i^- Some of the important powers possessed "by State "banks but not bynational banks during this period were the ability to make loans on real estate, the more liberal provisions regarding loans to single borrowers, the right to engage in fiduciary business, and to purchase or deal in corporate stocks. The State banks were also subject to less stringent examinations and supervision than the national banks. To sone extent these apparent advantages of the State banks were overcome through the affiliation of many national banks with State banks and trust companies. This enabled then to compete successfully with rival State institutions without technically violating the provisions of the national Bank Act. One of the most common means employed was for a national bank and a State bank or trust company to have identical stockholders, or at least for the control of both institutions to be in the hands of the sane stockholders. Directorates of nany national and State institutions were inter- locked. Prior to the Clayton Act, passed in 191*+ and effective in 1916, interlocking was not limited by law in the case of national banks. It was also possible for the stockholders of a national bank to organize a State bank or trust company, which could then purchase and own a controlling interest in the national bank. Affiliated commercial banks, trust companies, and savings banks were thus placed adjacent or close to national banks, and frequently it was a matter of common knowledge that they were operating in cooperation. In the larger cities, such as Hew York, a common device was to enter into trustee arrangements whereby the stock of an affiliated company was made inseparable from the stock of the national bank. A leading example of the use of this device occurred in 19OS when the First National Bank of New York organized an affiliate, the First Security Company. Three years - 15 - later, the National City Bank followed by the establishment of the National City Company. By these and other methods, national banks, State banks, trust companies, and security and real estate corporations chartered under State laws were bound together either directly or indirectly in one community of interest. TUfhile the establishment of such relations did not make it possible to bring all operations of the various institutions under one charter, it did release the national banks from turning over business to a competitor, for it enabled them to refer the things they could not do to an affiliate chartered under State laws. Inequalities in powers between national and State institutions were thus rendered of less consequence, particularly to banks in large cities, and the various advantages of each type of institutior. inured to the benefit of the same group of stockholders. The Dual Banking System in 1913 It is evident from the foregoing discussion that the developments after 1880 nullified the intention of the framers of the National Bank Act that this legislation should develop a uniform, united, nation-wide system of commercial banking. Early experience in the development of the national bank system seemed to indicate that this would be the result, but the rapid growth of State banks after 1880 and the extraordinary development of trust companies after 1900 turned the tide in the opposite direction. During the period from 1880 to 1913 the number of State banks and trust companies increased from about 65O to l6,S^l, while national banks increased from 2,076 to 7*^7 • Thus the number of State institutions was multiplied by twenty-six and that of national banks by three and a half. In 1880 there were only about one-third as many State as national banks, -16- \?ith only about a fourth of the resources. By 1913» when the Federal Reserve Act was under consideration, the number of State hanks was more than twice as great as the number of national "banks, and the aggregate resources of the State hanks were nearly as great as the aggregate resources of national hanks. Instead of a single system of hanking, there was a dual system, with the State chartered part of the system gaining in scope and power. CHAPTER II THE DUAL SYSTEM SINCE THE PASSAGE OF TEE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT There had teen agitation for banking reform in the United States for many years prior to 1913* This agitation was concerned principally with the need for an elastic currency, central "banking facilities, the development of a discount market, the abolition of the independent treasury system, and the introduction of improved methods of clearing and collecting checks. It was recognized that the dual system of independent unit hanks, chartered and supervised in part by the Federal Government and in part by the various State governments, complicated the problem of providing the much-needed banking reforms; but apparently it was not fully realized t>y the proponents of new legislation to what extent the competition between national and State banks would influence the formulation of measures for banking reform or the operation of those finally adopted. Adoption of the Federal Reserve Act Some of the early proposals, such as the Baltimore plan presented before the American Bankers Association in 12>9^» the plan for an asset-secured currency fostered by the Indianapolis Monetary Commission of 1897 and 1898, and the Fowler bill of 1908, included only national banks in their scope. In the Muhleman plan for a central bank, however, and in the Warburg plan for a united reserve bank, no distinctions were made between State and national - 17 - - IS - banks.'-1-' As these and other plans for banking reform were discussed, it came to be realized that it would be necessary to secure the cooperation of the State banks if an adequate and unified banking system was to be developed. However, neither in the Aldrich-Vreeland Act of 1908 which reflected tne influence of the reform movement nor in the original form of the Aldrich plan submitted in January, 1911, by its cnairman to the National Monetary Commission was provision made for the participation of State banks. The reason for this omission in the former case was the emergency character of toe legislation, and in the latter case, the uncertainty as to what recommendations to make. But in the revised form of the Aldrich plan and in the final report of the National Monetary Commission, it was contemplated that State banks and trust companies be permitted to become members of the proposed National Reserve Association, provided they conformed to requirements in respect to capitalization, reserves, examinations, and reports similar to tiiose imposed on national banks. The details of these various plans may be found in the following publications: Maurice L. Muhleman, "A Plan for a Central Bank," Banking Law Journal, Vol. 26, pp. 805-810, 88>390, and Vol. 27, pp. 13-20, 119-126, 211-219; and Monetary and Banking Systems. Charles S. Tippetts, State Banks and t;ie federal Reserve System, ch. 2. Paul M. Warburg, "A Plan for a Modified Central Bank," and "A United Reserve Bank of the United States," Essays on Banking Reform in $he United States. Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science. July, 191^, Vol. IV, No. U, p. 75; and The Federal Reserve System, Vol. I, ch. Ill; Vol. II, pp. 117-l6l. Report of the Monetary Commission of the Indianapolis Convention, Chicago, 189S. - 19 - The National Monetary Commission also recommended that national banks be permitted to make loans secured by real estate up to 50 per cent of the value of the real estate and to a maximum of JO per cent of time deposits.W Supporters of the proposals of the National Monetary Commission believed that the advantages of membership in the National Reserve Association would be so great that State banks would be induced to join the association. Professor J. Laurence Laugnlin, chairman of the National Citizens' League for the Promotion of a Sound Banking System, stated this point of view as followsr2' "In fact, it is one of the best features of the National Reserve plan that it would tend to unify the state and national banking systems. With a definite pattern afforded by federal legislation, with which trie state banks were willing to comply in order that they might be placed upon terms of equality in competing with national banks, it may be expected that progress toward uniformity in banking legislation throughout the country would be much more rapid than ever before. This uniformity would be exceedingly desirable, since it would take away the possibility of evading legal provisions. At the same time it would prevent the transaction of undesirable forms of business that are sometimes undertaken by banks as a result of their being 'played off against one another by designing borrowers. "This tendency would be to segregate and harmonize into one general group all the commercial banks of the country whether organized under state or national laws. Those that did not cnoose to conform to the requirements laid down in the legislation, with respect to reserves, kinds of business done, etc., would remain out of the National Reserve Association and would at once be recognized as belonging to quite a different class of banking institutions. They would exercise in their way as good and as effective a function as that performed by the banks, whether state or national, that load brought themselves into conformity with the provisions of the proposed reform, but their position in the community and the rules of their action would "be quite different. They would be set apart, not as being state institutions, the line of distinction drawn at present, but as being institutions properly classed as not strictly banks in the proper sense of the term." (1/ Report of the National Monetary Commission, Publications of National Monetary Commission. \2) J. Laurence Laughlin, Banking Reform, (Chicago, 1912), pp. 276-277. - 20 - As finally passed, the Federal Reserve Act permitted State banks to become members of the federal reserve system on certain conditions, the more important of which may be s-ummarized as follows: 1; A State bank applicant must have a paid-up, unimpaired capital sufficient to entitle it to become a national bank in the place where situated. 2 , Should conform to laws governing national banks in respect to the limitation of credit to be granted to any single person, firm, or corporation.^' 3. Must conform to the reserve requirements of national banks. U. Must not purchase or loan on its own stock, reduce or impair its capital, or pay unearned dividends. 5. Must submit to examinations and reports required by the comptroller or by the reserve bank, but the Federal Reserve Board might authorize substitution of State examinations or reports. U-) 6. Must conform to such regulations as the Federal Heserve Board might require for admission to membership, 1> State member bank officers and employees to be subject td the same penalties and punishments for crime as those of national banks. The competition between State and national banks was reflected not only in these provisions regarding State bank participation in the central banking facilities, but also in numerous proposals for liberalizing the powers of national banks. It was desired to make membership attractive to the State banks, but it was realized that this would not be possible if they were as strictly limited in their powers as national banks had been. On the other hand, it was also realized that national banks might consider the compulsory feature of membership onerous, especially in view of the broader powers of State banks, and that there might be a tendency to convert from national to (1) Subsequently modified. - 21 - State tanks. This was all the more to be feared, because to the competitive advantages which State banks had enjoyed for many years was now added the privilege of optional membership in the Federal reserve system. It is probable also that the prospect of extensive revision of the national banking laws was made the occasion for the exertion of pressure on the part of national banks desiring broader powers. Under these conditions, important changes were made in the national Bank Act, enlarging the powers.of national banks. These new powers were briefly as follows: 1. To receive time deposits subject to a reserve of only 5 per cent, as compared with 12, 15, or IS per cent on demand deposits. (1) 2. With the exception of banks in central reserve cities, to make loans, for a maximum period of five years, on improved and unencumbered farm land situated within its Federal reserve district, up to 50 per cent of its actual value and to an aggregate amount of 25 per cent of capital and surplus or to onethird of time deposits. 3. To exercise, with the permission and under the regulations of the Federal Reserve Board, fiduciary powers as executors, trustees, administrators, and registrars of stocks and bonds. U. With the special permission of the Federal Reserve Board to establish, in the case of banks with a minimum capital and surplus of $1,000,000, branches in foreign countries or in the dependencies of the United States. These provisions by no means gave to the national banks all of the powers possessed by State banks. Unless the Federal Reserve Board set more strict standards than those specified in the act, State banks which chose to become members of the system still had broader lending and investing powers, more extensive fiduciary powers, and in many States the privilege of operating branches. State banks not choosing to join the Federal reserve system still (1) Subsequently modified. - 22 - possessed in most States lower capital requirements, were subject to less stringent supervision, and had power to extend a larger volume of loans to particular interests. Nevertheless, as a result of the play of competitive forces in the dual banking system, national "banks were released to a considerable degree from the strict standards of commercial banking which had previously prevailed; and the movement toward "omnibus banking,"^' already well under way in the State systems, spread into the national system. The most significant aspect of these changes is that "omnibus banking" was not advocated as sound or as a desirable innovation, but on the ground of the expediency of expanding the national banking system and of strengthening the competitive position of national banks. State Bank Membership in the Federal Reserve System The Federal Reserve Board began to give consideration to the conditions of State bank membership soon after its organization. In its first report, at the end of the year I91H, it stated:^2' "Prom the opening of the new banks, the Federal Reserve Board has been keenly anxious to settle the conditions upon which State banks may be admitted into the system. The Federal reserve act especially provides for such admission, and it has been supposed in many quarters that the process of admission would involve few difficulties. Investigation has shown that owing to the differences in State laws, the comprehensive character of the charters enjoyed by some State banks, and the complex conditions of competition between such institutions and their national competitors, the determination of these conditions was far from being easy if an equitable adjustment was to be found." (1) The term "omnibus banking" is used here to mean the carrying on of varied types of financial activities, such as the receipt of demand deposits and of time deposits, the making of commercial loans, the investment of funds in bonds and "capital loans," the exercise of fiduciary services, and the dealing in securities by the same institution without the segregation of assets. It is thus to be contrasted not only with pure commercial banking, but alsp with the "departmental" banking in California and with affiliation of separate corporations carrying on, separately, these various activities, (2) First Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board. I91U, p. 20. - 23 - Six months later the Federal Reserve Board expressed its hope that a unified system of "banking would develop tnrough the Federal reserve system, and announced the conditions under which State institutions would he admitted to membe r ship. *• ^ * "A unified hanking system, embracing in its membership the well-managed hanks of the country, small and large, State and National, is the aim of the Federal reserve act. There can he hut one American credit system of nation-wide extent, and it will fall short of satisfying the "business judgment and expectation of the country and fail of attaining its full potentialities if it rests upon an incomplete foundation and leaves out of its membership any considerable part of the banking strength of the country. . . . " In accordance with the attitude taken in this announcement, the regulations issued by the board provided for the admission of State banks to membership with few if any significant requirements other than those expressly stated in the Federal Eeserve Act. The board declared that in passing on an application for membership it would consider the financial condition of the applying bank or ttfust company, the general character of its management, and whether the na- ture of the powers exercised by the bank or trust company and its charter provisions were consistent with the proper conduct of the business of banking and with membership in the Federal reserve system. It stated, however, that subject to such requirements as might be embodied in the certificate of approval, or in regulations of the Federal Reserve Board, and those contained in the Federal Reserve Act, every State bank or trust company while a member of the Federal reserve system would retain its full charter and statutory rights and could continue to exercise the same functions as before admission. While the board thus retained the right to issue further regulations binding upon the conduct of State member as well as national banks, the only (!) Federal Reserve Bulletin. July 1, 1915, p. l*+5. - 2U- regulations actually laid down as a condition of membership were of a general character. They referred to such matters as sufficient limitations on real estate loans or mortgages to avoid the impairment of the hank's liquid condition, the adjustment within a reasonable time of loans in excess of the limitations imposed by the act, and the maintenance of the standard of banking embodied in the certificate of approval. The board further announced that State member banks would be permitted to withdraw upon twelve months' notice; (1) that its examiners would cooperate wherever possible with State examiners; and that the State examinations would, when satisfactory, be accepted in lieu of its own examinations. The Federal Reserve Board thus extended to State banks very liberal terms of admission. Nevertheless, the State banks still hesitated about applying for membership. They were apprehensive regarding the possibility of changes in the attitude of the Federal Reserve Board and the issuance later of more stringent regulations. The necessity of limiting loans to individuals to 10 per cent of capital and surplus, or 30 per cent of paid-up capital, was also considered unduly restrictive. Moreover, the Clayton Act, which was approved on October 15, 191*+» sharply limited interlocking directorates among banks organized or operating under the laws of the United States, and it was feared that banks joining the Federal reserve system would be considered by the courts to be "operating under the laws of the United States," which might seriously interfere with existing affiliations. As a result of these conditions State banks and trust companies continued generally to hold aloof from tne Federal reserve system. By June, 19171 (1) By Act of June 21, 1917» this was changed to six months' notice, «hieh by Act of April 17» 193°» the Federal Reserve Board was em*> powered to waive. - 25 - only 53 State institutions had joined,(*' although a few additional ones had come into the system by converting to national hanks. The number which were eligible for membership, on the basis of capital stock, was approximately 8,500 so that only about 0.6 per cent had taken advantage of the privileges accorded to State member banks. W. P. G. Harding, Governor of the Federal Reserve Board, and Frederic A. Delano, one of its members, met with the executive committee of the State bank section of the.American Bankers Association, and reached an agreement regarding amendments to the Federal Reserve Act, including several relating to State bank membership. (2) The amendments were submitted to Congress and, because of the war emergency, were expedited and became law on June 21, 1917» Most of the provisions in the 1917 amendment dealing with State bank membership followed the spirit of the regulations issued by the board in 1915« which they extended. State bank members were permitted to withdraw from nomber- ship on six months' written notice to the Federal Reserve Board. They retained their full charter and statutory rights subject to the restrictions of the Federal Reserve Act and regulations of the board relative thereto. Their examination and supervision were delegated to the Federal reserve banks and board, which, in turn, were authorized to accept reports and examinations from State supervising authorities in lieu of those of their own examiners. Furthermore, State member banks were relieved of the restrictions upon national banks as to the amount which could be loaned to one person, firm, or corporation, subject to the restriction that no paper of a borrower indebted to the State (l) Fifth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board, 1918, p. 25. (2' American Bankers Association, Proceedings of the Forty-third Annual Convention. 1917, p. 672. - 26 - bank in excess of these l i m i t s could be rediscounted at the Federal reserve hanks. P r i o r to 1917. the reserves required of member banks were lower than those formerly required of national banks, and lower than those required in many States of State banks, iflien f i n a n c i a l resources were being marsnalled for war purposes in 1917# the reserve requirements of a l l member banks were reduced: on time deposits, from 5 to 3 P e r cent; on demand deposits of banks not in reserve or c e n t r a l reserve c i t i e s , from 12 to 7 per cent; on demand dep o s i t s in reserve c i t i e s , from 15 to 10 per cent; and on demand deposits in c e n t r a l reserve c i t i e s , from 18 to 13 per cent. The v?hole of these r e s e r v e s , however, was to consist of non-interest bearing balances with the Federal r e serve banks, vault cash resuirements being discontinued. The 1S17 amendments also c l a r i f i e d the position of member banks with respect to the provisions of the Clayton Act, since i t was expressly declared t h a t they should r e t a i n t h e i r f u l l charter and statutory powers, subject only to the provisions of the amended Federal Reserve Act and the regulations of the board pursuant t h e r e t o . After the United States had entered the World Jar, a special appeal was made to the State barks to join the system on the grounds of patriotism and the d e s i r a b i l i t y of mobilizing the banking resources of the e n t i r e country for purposes of war f i n a n c e . ^ / The number of State members increased from ^3 on June 2 1 , 1917. to 936 on December 3 1 , 191S.( 2 ) Extension of National Bank Powers, 1916-1922 The Federal Reserve Act as passed in 1313> the regulation of tne Federal Reserve Board issued i n 19151 an & the amendments to the Federal Reserve ( ! ) Fourth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board, 1917. P. 9« (2) Fifth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board, 19IS, pp. 25, 26. - 27 - Act made in 191?» placed the State member hanks in an apparently preferred position in the banking structure of the nation. They had all the privileges and advantages of membership in the Federal reserve system, and they also had, in most States, powers much more extensive than those of national banks. A series of amendments to the Federal Reserve and National Bank Acts during the years from 1916 to 19o2 broadened the powers of national banks. ^ ) The first of these amendments was passed on September 7> 1916. This amendment empowered national banks to cross Federal reserve district lines in making loans on farm land, provided such land is within 100 miles of the location of the bank. It also provided for loans, for one year only, on other improved and un- encumbered real estate within 100 miles of the location of the bank. It pro- vided further that national banks in places not exceeding 5>000 population might be authorized by the Comptroller of the Currency to act as insurance agents and as brokers or agents in making loans on real estate located within 100 miles of the bank. The Senate Committee on Banking and Currency, in reporting these amendments, also recommended that national banks, with certain restrictions, be permitted to open not more than. 10 brancu.es within the city or county or within twenty-five miles of the parent bank. This recommendation, like the previous recommendations of the Comptrollers of the Currency and others as to branch banking, was not adopted ~oy Congress. Anotiier amendment to the Federal Reserve Act for the purpose of enabling national banks core effectively to compete with State member banks was passed on September 26, 19IS. This amendment provided specifically that (1) Thjrc was a large number of amendments to both of these acts during the years 1916 to 1922. Only such amendments as directly affected tne competitive position of national and State banks are mentioned here. - 28 - national "banks,under special permission from the Federal Eeserve Board, might engage in any kind of fiduciary activity which State "banks, trust companies, or other corporations coming into competition with national "banks were permitted to undertake under State lav/. There were also amendments liberalizing the limitation on loans by national banks to a single interest. One was enacted September 24, 1918, and anotner October 22, 1919« An amendment designed to enlarge the powers of national banks in order that they might compete more effectively with State banks was passed on July 1, 1922. This legislation provided for the extension of the charters of all existing national banks for a period of 99 years from that date and for the organization of nev/ banks with charters running 99 years from date of organization. The purpose of this act was not only to obviate the formalities required in extending charters for another period of 20 years, but also to enable national banks to undertake trusts and other fiduciary activities which might extend beyond the date of the limitation of national bank charters. The McFadden Act of 1927 During the years from 1923 to 19^6, inclusive, there were no impor- tant changes either in the Federal Reserve Act or the national Bank Act bearing on the pioblem of competition between the national and State bank systems. This lull in legislation was not, however, because powers xiad been so equalized that there was satisfaction on the part of bankers and the public regarding the situation. State institutions had felt adversely the results of the con- cessions made to national banks by Congress. - 29 - But tiae principal subject of controversial discussion during this period was branch banking. on SFovember 7, 1923> The Federal Reserve Board, in a regulation issued ^ and in a ruling; of April 7» 192*4/ ' declared that State member banks must have the approval of the board in opening additional branches, and stipulated as a general principle that new branches should be restricted to the city or adjacent territory of the parent institution. The State banks contended, however, that this contravened the guarantee in the amendments to the Federal Reserve Act of 1917 that State banks joining the system would retain all of their charter and statutory powers. They argued that the guarantees of the board and of Congress had not been kept, and that State banks could not continue their membership in the Federal reserve system in the face of regulations which violated the conditions under which they had entered. Among national banks there was still dissatisfaction, despite the broadening of their powers in the Federal He serve Act and the subsequent amendments to that act and to the National Bank Act. Even these new powers did not give national banks all the advantages of the State member banks, the most serious difficulty being their inability to open branches. The Comptroller of the Currency had attested in 1922 to mitigate this prohibition by permitting national banks to open additional offices in the home office city referred to as "teller's windows" at which only routine business, such as the receipt of deposits and the cashing of checks, was transacted. These were permitted only in States where State banks were permitted branches. This policy was continued in subsequent years, in the face of considerable opposition, but failed to meet the demand for the privilege of branch banking. (!) Federal Reserve Bulletin, December, 1923, p. 1256. (2) Ibid., September, 1924, p. 71o, - 30 - As a r e s u l t of t h i s demand from national t a n k s , and of the other d i s a b i l i t i e s which they s t i l l suffered in comparison with State banks, the McFadden h i l l was introduced into Congress in 1924, I t was intended to equal- ize competitive conditions between national and State tanks. This was recog- nized by both i t s supporters and i t s opponents, and explains the fact that debate over i t s various measures was b i t t e r and i t s passage delayed u n t i l February 25, 1927, 'The chief conflict developed over branch banking. While i t was evident that the national banks would have to be given at l e a s t limited branch banking powers, there was a violent conflict over the precise character of these powers.^ 2 ' As passed, the chief provisions of the act were as f o l - lows: 1. National banks were authorized to e s t a b l i s h new branches within the c i t y or town in which the bank was located, in those States in which State banks had the power to e s t a b l i s h branches. However, no branch could be opened in c i t i e s of l e s s than 25,000 population, only one i f the c i t y had between 25,000 and 50,000 population, and only two if the c i t y had between 50,000 and 100,000 population, while in c i t i e s of more than 100,000 population the comptroller could limit the number of branches. 2. A national bank was authorized to r e t a i n a l l i t s branches in lawful operation p r i o r to the passage of the a c t , and if subsequently a national bank consolidated with another bank, e i t h e r n a t i o n a l or S t a t e , a l l the branches of both i n s t i t u t i o n s which had been in lawful operation at the date of approval of the act could be r e t a i n e d , but t h e i r location could be changed only with the consent of the Comptroller of the Currency. 3. State member banks were governed by the same r e s t r i c t i o n s as national banks in respect to new branches and those in operat i o n a t the date of the passage of tne a c t , and State banks j o i n ing the system could not r e t a i n out-of-town branches established a f t e r the date of the approval of the a c t . k. National banks were given indeterminate instead of 99year c h a r t e r s . (1) Public No. 639. (2) This conflict has been described in another section of the report of the Committee on Branch, Group, and Chain Banking, See Branch Banking in the United States, pp. 121-15U. - 31- 5. The power of national banks to moke loans on the security of real estate was "broadened materially. 6. The limitation on loans to one interest was again relaxed. The most important change allows a national hank to advance larger amounts to one borrower wnen his obligation is secured by certain documents of title. 7. The capital required for the organization of national banks in outlying districts of large cities was reduced. 8. National banks were given legal sanction to the practice of merchandising bonds by regulating and limiting their purchase and sale of evidences of indebtedness. 9. National banks were authorized to invest up to 15 per cent of their capital and surplus in the stock of State corporations engaged in the safe deposit business. 10. National banks were empowered to issue their stock in less than $100 denominations and to issue stock dividends. 11. State banks were authorized to consolidate directly with national banks without, as formerly, being required first to convert into national banks, A later amendment, June 251 193^» authorizes national banks in ^7hich public funds of any State or any political subdivision thereof are deposited to give security for such deposits in the form required by State law. (1) This merely gave legal sanction to a practice of long standing. Even these extensions of power, however, did not give the national banks all the powers enjoyed by many of the State banking institutions. State member banks and trust companies in many States still had advantages in respect to the making of real estate loans, the ownership of corporate stocks, the amount which could be loaned to one borrower, exemption from the Clayton; Act prohibition upon interlocking directorates, the ability to withdraw from the Federal reserve system on six months> notice,i2) and in many States, to less (1) Public No. U3I. (2) in practice national banks can withdraw from the Federal reserve system without any notice whatever, merely by conversion to State charter. But this means, of course, that by so doing tney also lose their membership in the national system. - 32 - rigorous examinations and control. State banks and trust companies which were not members of the system still retained certain advantages which they possessed over both the State member banks and the national, banks, andin.particular were now the only class of banks which could open branches (in those States permitting them) in places outside of the town or city in which the main office was located. Furthermore the decision of the Supreme Court in the case of the Worcester County National Bank on May 13, 1929 was somewhat disturbing to national banks. In that decision, it was held that a national bank absorbing a trust company could not succeed to the trust business under the Massachusetts State law without obtaining, in so far as such trusts were subject to the approval of the court, a reappointment by the court for each trust. This decision, a reaffirmation by the United States Supreme Court of judgments handed down by the probate court of Worcester County, and the Supreme Judicial Court of Massachusetts, thus added uncertainty to the powers of succession of national banks to trusts held by a State bank or trust company, in case a merger should be consummated.^ ' Par Clearance of Checks After the passage of the Federal Reserve Act measures were initiated for the development of a system of universal par clearance, so that any check drawn upon a commercial bank in the United States would be paid without discount upon presentation. The Federal Beserve Board first made the par collection of checks optional, but subsequently the .Federal reserve banks in some instances resorted ' ' See ch. VI of this report. - 33 - to the device of presenting over the counter checks drawn on "banks which failed to remit in full. Many of the smaller banks of the South and West had derived a considerable portion of their income from the remittance and collection charges which they deducted from payments of checks drawn by their own depositors and presented for payment through the mail. The practice of presenting checks over the counter, therefore, aroused the resentment of these hanks. In eight States the opposition of the State "banks to par remittance resulted in legislation during 1920 and 1921 expressly legalizing the practice of making exchange charges. The attitude of the State banks was also expressed in litigation directed against the Federal reserve banks. (1) Partly as a consequence of such legislation and litigation, the pressure of the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal reserve banks to bring all the banks of the country into the par clearance system has been withdrawn. In 1920 par clearance had been extended to all but 1,755 banks, or less than 6 per cent of the banks in the country. (2) In July, 1932, there were 3,108 banks which were not on the par list, as compared with 6,9^7 member banks and S,UUS nonmember banks clearing through the Federal reserve banks at par.w) At present checks on only about 8*+ per cent of the banks are collected through the Federal reserve par clearance system. The banking system is therefore still far from unified in this phase of banking operations. (!) Annual Reports of the Federal Reserve Board, 1920, pp. 64-65, 327-33U; 1921, pp. 68-72, 357-35S. (2) Ibid., 192U, p. 10D. (3) Federal Reserve B u l l e t i n , Vol. XVIII, September, 1932, p . 60S. -3^~ Relative Strength of Member and Honmember Banking Systems. The period since 1913 ^ a s been characterized by constant conflict of interest between the three classes of banks operating in each State: national banks, member State banks, and nonmember banks. National banks have sought powers similar to those of State institutions, which, in many States, operate under more liberal laws. They have especially felt the need of obtaining powers similar to those enjoyed by member State banks. State banks at the same time have opposed the extension of the powers of national banks in some directions. This rivalry between the State systems and the national system has resulted in the exact opposite of the unification intended by the advocates of banking reform in the early years of the century. Under the prevailing conditions the Federal Government has found it impossible to formulate and maintain any consistent banking policy of its own. Since 1913, in fact, the majority of important changes in the Federal law have been made in an effort to place national banks in a position to meet the competition of institutions operating under the less exacting requirements of some of the States, or to induce State banks to become members of the Federal reserve system. The standards of commercial banking practice formerly required in the national system have been relaxed, and the whole banking structure has suffered the consequences. Yet in spite of all the so-called "liberalization" of the powers and privileges of national banks which has occurred since 1913, national banks have continued to grow less rapidly in number and resources than - 35 - the State chartered banking institutions. The resources of national tanks in 1931 were two and one-half times as great as those in 1913f while the resources of State banks in 193* were three times as great as those in 1913. Although many more State "banks than national banks had suspended during this interval, State banks at the beginning of 1932 were still more than twice as numerous as national banks; and the aggregate resources of State banks, which in 1913 kacL been slightly less than those of national banks, on June 30, 1931 > surpassed the resources of national banks by 12 per cent. (See Charts 1 and 2*) Unification has been somewhat more nearly approximated by mem- bership in the Federal reserve system, for some State banks have become members of the reserve system. On June 30, 193^1 the loans and invest- ments of all member banks amounted to $33»9^3»000»000 as compared with $10,53^»000,000 for all nonmember commercial institutions. Bat the unification of the banking structure achieved in this manner is more apparent than real. On the above date Federal reserve membership was made up of 6,800 national banks and only 982 State banks, while 13,3^1 State banks remained outside the system. Furthermore, all membership in the Federal reserve system is in effect voluntary, since national banks can leave the system by conversion to State charter and member State banks can withdraw by giving notice. Chart 3 and Table 1 show the number of member and nonmember banks from 191U through 1931, and Chart h and Table 2 show the'loans and investments of these banks fro,n 191^ through 193I. 36 - CHART 3 NUMBER OF MEMBER AND NONMEMBER BANKS NUMBER OF BANKS 25,000 19lH~19o1 NUMBER OF BANKS Nonmember banks do not include private banks or mutual savings banks. .Figures are as of June 30 each year and December 3 1 , 1931. 25,000 - 37 - Table 1 - Number of Banks in the United States, Exclusive of Mutual Savings Banks and Private Banks (1) 1914-1931 Nonmember ( State banks (exAll State clusive of mutual All State and national State National Total savings and banks banks private banks) Member banks Date (June) 191^ 1915 1916 1917 191S 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 . 192S 1929 1930 1931 1931 (Dec.) 17 3^ 53 513 1,042 1,37^ 1,595 1,648 1,620 1,570 1,472 1,403 1,309 1,244 1,177 1,06s 982 878 7,51S 7.614 7,605 7,652 8,212 1 8,821 9,398 | 8,150 9,745 j8,244 9,892 8,236 9,856 8,080 9,650 8,066 9,538 7,972 9,375 7,790 ; 9,099 7,685 , 8,929 7,530 j 8,707 7,247 j 8,315 6,800 j 7,782 6,368 i 7,246 7,51S 7,597 7,571 7,599 7,699 7,779 8,024 17,498 17,731 18,219 18,657 18,891 18,604 19,261 19,672 19,14-1 19,034 18,458 18,101 17,591 16,810 16,196 17,498 17,748 18,253 18,710 19,404 19,646 20,635 21,267 20,789 20,654 20,028 19,573 18,994 18,119 17,440 16,728 ! '• | '• .' 15,551 14,730 13,341 15,79s 1^,323 -: 11,921 12,799 25,016 25,3^5 25,824 26,309 27,103 27,425 28,659 29,417 29,033 28,890 28,108 27,639 26,966 25,909 25,125 24,258 23,045 21,123 19,167 Banks in continental United States only. "All State banks," "national banks," and "all State and national banks" were taken from the Comptrollers' abstracts and annual reports, except that for December, 1931, the State bank figures were compiled by the Division of Bank Operations of the Federal Reserve Board from State bank abstracts. State bank members were compiled from Federal Reserve Board abstracts andcaLl reports, and nonmember banks were derived by deducting member banks from the total of national and State banks. - 38 - CHART4 LOANS AND INVESTMENTS OF BANKS IN THE UNITED STATES 1W-1931 MILLIONS Or DOLLARS MILLIONS OT DOLLARS ^tQOOO Loans and investments of nonmember banks do not include those of private banks or mutual savings banks. Figures are as of June 30 each year and December 31, 1931. -39- Table 2 - Loans and Investments of Banks i n the U n i t e d S t a t e s E x c l u s i v e of Mutual Savings Banks and P r i v a t e Banks 19llj-193lU) (in millions of dollars) yiember bani:s Date (June) State 19 l 4 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 192S 1929 1930 1931 1931 (Dec.) "76 229 556 4,594 6,530 8,012 8,226 3,477 9,702 10,109 11,225 12,025 12,519 12,999 Ik,25k 13.907 13>09S n.usi National Total 8,313 8,688 10,086 11,897 13.913 15,712 17,547 15,895 15,705 16,805 17,058 18,293 19,159 20,237 22,062 21,457 21,7149 20,825 19,09^ 8,313 8,764 10,315 12,453 18,507 22,242 25,559 24,121 24,182 26,507 27,167 29,518 3L184 32,756 35,061 35,711 35,656 33.923 30,575 Nonmember S t a t e "banks (exc l u s i v e of mutual s a v i n g s and p r i v a t e "banks) 8,410 8,582 9,972 11,248 8,727 9,4o4 10,712 10,090 9,677 10,590 10,93s 11,694 12,263 12,331 12,374 13.132 12,638 10,53*+ 8, oOO All State "banks S,4l0 8,658 10,201 11,804 13,321 15,93^ 18,724 18,316 18,154 20,292 2i,o47 22,919 24,288 24,850 25,873 27,386 26,545 23.632 20,081 All State and n a t i o n a l "banks 16,723 17.346 20,287 23,701 27,234 31,646 36,271 34,211 33.859 37,097 38,105 41,212 43,447 45,087 47,935 48,843 48,294 44,457 39,175 (1) See note, Table 1. Table 3 gives by size groups the number of commercial banks, both national and State, within and without the Federal reserve system in 1920 and in 193O. - ko - Table 3 - Membership in the Federal Reserve System, June 30, 1920 and 1930, by Size Groups Number of banks (1) ! P e r c e n t a g e of t o t a l number t h a t 1920 1930 Mem~ j SonMem- j Honwere members b e r s ( 2 ) j members b e r s ( 2 ) members 1920 1930 Size group l o a n s and i n v e s t m e n t s Under $500,000 500,000 - 2,000,000 2,000,000 - 10,000,000 1 0 , 0 0 0 , 0 0 0 - 50,000,000 69 50,000,000 and over i • • 1 , , . , , 1 1 10,U02 3,096 915 128 • 10 3 9,39S Total . 15,048 2,913 3,630 3,4lg 7U2 1,567 6k 326 3,591 ^,094 1,339 305 8,315 13 Ml -i , , i 1^,551 • 1 21.9 19*3 53.0 52.5 63.1 64*3 82.7 ! 71.8 95.8 i 904 ! 36* U 32.5 ' 11 1 (1) The 1920 figures include 386 banks in Illinois which were classed as private banks on June 30 of that year, but which had nearly all been converted to State banks by the end of the year in compliance with a law prohibiting the operation of private banks after January 1, 1921. In classifying active State banks by size groups, whenever individual reports for June 30 were not obtainable, figures for the nearest available date were used. For this reason the totals given here differ somewhat from similar figures elsewhere in this report and in the reports of the Comptroller of the Currency. The State bank figures used were either supplied by the State banking departments or compiled from their published reports. (2) national and State. Only a third of all the commercial banks in the nation were members of the Federal reserve system in 1920, and the percentage was not very much larger in 1930. The proportion of members among the large banks was very high in 1930 though not so high as 10 years earlier. There were 138 nonmembers out of a total of 555 with over $10,000,000 of loans and investments in 1930f as compared with only 67 out of kkl in 1920. Table U gives by size groups the aggregate loans and investments of member and nonmember banks in 1920 and in I93O. - Ul- Table k - Loans and Investments of Member and ITonmember Banks (of the Federal Be serve System), June 30, 1920 and 1°30, "by Size Groups Size group l o a n s and i n v e s t m e n t s Under $500,000 500,000 - 2,000,000 2 , 0 0 0 , 0 0 0 - 10,000,000 1 0 , 0 0 0 , 0 0 0 - 50,000,000 5 0 , 0 0 0 , 0 0 0 and over Total Aggregate loans and i n v e s t m e n t s ( l ) (000.000 o m i t t e d ) 1920 1910 UonNonMember'2) Member'^) member member banks banlcs "banks banks $ 1,079 M27 5.U02 6,183 8,868 $ 3.027 3.253 $25,559 $10,591 2,8^1 1,182 28S P e r c e n t a g e of tine t o t a l in the reserve system 1920 1930 6,Uo2 6,372 IS,497 $ 2,078 2,921 3.555 2,^59 1,39*+ 26.3 55.3 65.5 83.5 96,9 28.9 5^.8 6U.3 72.2 93.0 $35,656 $12,UO7 70,7 7^.2 $ 8H6 — * » , C3-) See note (1), Table 3. (2) national and State. Owing to the fact that most of the larger State banks and trust companies are members of the Ifederal reserve system while most of the small banks are not, the percentage of the total banking resources embraced within the system is far greater toan the percentage of banlcs within the system. This percentage, wnicn was 70.7 in 1920, increased to 7'+.2 during tne decade from 1920 to 1930. As in t.ie case of the numbe::- of banks, however, a larger proportion of the business of the large banlcs wa~ outside the system in 1930 than ten years earlier. Table 5 shows the number of State member and nonmember banks and trust companies in 1920 and 1930 by size groups, and the percentage of the total that were members in each of taese years. - te- Table 5 - State Bank and Trust Company Membership in the Federal Reserve System, June 30, 1920 and 1930* "by 3 i z e Groups Size group loans and investments BFuraber of banks(l) 1920 1930 HonState NonState members members members members k$S Under $500,000 500,000 - 2,000,000 2,000,000 - 10,000,000 10,000,000 - 50,000,000 50,000,000 and over Total W ^5 26S 121 15.0US 3,630 7^2 Sk 3 2S6 363 246 1,37^ 19,^7 1,06S 12k Percentage of State "banks that were members 1920 1930 a.,7 10,1+02 3,096 915 12S 10 3.0 12.D 26.5 65.4 91.4 10.5 21.2 U9.2 83.1 14,551 6.6 6.8 See note (1), Table 3, In all size groups the percentage of the State banks and trust companies which were members of the Federal reserve system declined between 1920 and 193°« DuQ» however, to changes in the number of banks in the various size groups, the percentage of the total number of State banks and trust companies that are members of the system was almost the same in 1930 &s in 1920, that is, 6.8 per cent as compared with 6.6 per cent. Only one State chartered banking institution out of fifteen is a member of the Federal reserve system. In 1920, 1+3 per cent of the loans and investments of all State banks and trust companies was within the system, and in 1930, 53 per cent. This is shovm in Table 6. -43- Table 6 - Loans and Investments of Member and Nonmember State Banks (of the Federal Reserve System), June 30, 1920 and 193°. by Size Groups Size group loans and investments Aggregate loans loans and investments investments U ) 1 Percentage Aggregate omitted) . . . 000.000 omitted) .... of the t o t a l ((000.000 1920 ! 1930 i n State State NonNonState member banks member member member member 1920 1930 banks banks banks banks Under $500,000 500,000 - 2,000,000 2,000,000 - 10,000,000 10,000,000 - 50,000,000 50,000,000 and over Total 77 $ 2,078 2,921 394 3.555 1,154 2,459 2,556 9,726 137 501 1,186 2,549 3,639 $ 3,027 3,253 2,84l 1,182 288 $ $8,012 $10,591 $13,907 $12,1+07 $ 4.4 13.3 29.5 68.3 92.7 U3.I 3.6 11.9 24.5 51.0 ?7- 5 52.9 t 1 ) See note (l), Table 3. Table 7 shows for 1920 and for 1930 the aggregate loans and investments of national banks, member State banks, and nonmember banls grouped by size. Table 7 - Distribution of Aggregate Loans and Investments of Commercial Banks and Trust Companies, June 30, 1920 and 1930, by Size Groups Size group loans and investments Aggregate loans and investments (000,000 omitted) 1 Member State IToninember State National All State and banks and t r u s t banks and t r u s t banks national banks companies companies J 1920 ! 1930 1920 | 1930 1920 1930 1920 1930 • Under $500,000 $U,io6 $ 2,924; $ 942 500,000 - 2,000,000 6,460' 3,526 7,280 2,000,000 - 10,000,000 9,957 4,216 8,243 10,000,000 - 50,000,000 8,831 ; 3,634 7,365 9,156 19,891 5,229 50,000,000 and over Total $ 769 3,145 5,248 3,816 8,771 $36,15C #18,063 $L7,547 $2L,749 137 * 77 $ 3,027 $ 2,078 2,921 394 501 3,253 3,555 1,186 , 1.154 2,S4l 2,459 2,556 1,182 2,549 1,394 9,726 288 3,639 $ $8,012 $13,907 $10,591 $12,407 .. 44 - Table S shows the changes during the decade in the loans and investments of the "banks in these size groups, "both in millions of dollars and in percentages. Table 8 - Changes in the Aggregate Loans and Investments of Commercial Banks and Trust Companies from 1920 to 193°, hy Size Groups Size group loans and investments Under $500,000 500,000 - 2,000,000 2,000,000 - 10,000*000 10,000,000 - 50,000,000 50,000,000 and over Total of d o l l a r s Percentage changes Nonmember Member lonmember State banks Ifetional State banks State banks and t r u s t banks and t r u s t and t r u s t companies companies companies Changes in m i l l i o n s Member MatictBl State banks banks and t r u s t companies -174 -381 +1,032 +1S2 +3,542 -60 -107 -32 +7 +6,087 +4,202 + 5,895 : -9U9 -332 + 71+ +1,277 +1,106 -18.4 -10.8 + 24.5 + 5.0 +67.7 -+3.8 -21.4 -2.7 + 0.3 +I67.3 -31.4 -10.2 + 25.1 +108.0 + 384.0 +1,816 +23.9 +73-6 + 17.1 These tables indicate that among banks with less than two million dollars of loans and investments, national, State member, and nonmember State banks all lost banking strength during the decade. Those with national charters have lost less aggregate banking strength than those with State charters. This has resulted principally from the higher suspension rate among State banks. A somewhat different situation exists with respect to banks with from two to ten million dollars of loans and investments. Those with national charters and those with State charters but without Federal reserve membership grew at a moderate rate. Member State banks, on the contrary, lost loans and investments. The changes among banks with more than fifty million dollars of loans and investments are the most striking. Loans and investments of all -45- three classes of 'banks grew rapidly during the decade, with those of member State hanks and trust companies increasing at a more rapid rate than those of national "banks. The nonmember banks and trust companies, however, showed the greatest percentage growth. Further light on the changes in State hank and trust company membership in the Federal reserve system may he obtained from an examination of the number and resources of State banks and trust companies admitted to and withdrawing from membership. These figures are given in Table 9» Table 9 - Number and Aggregate Resources of State Banks and Trust Companies Admitted to and Withdrawing from Membership in the Federal Reserve System, 1921-193l(l} Withdrawn Absorbed by from membership nonmember banks Resources Resources Resources Number Number Humber (000 omitted) (000 omitted) (000 omitted) Admitted to membership Year ! 1 • 204 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 32 29 23 27 is -21 Total 59S 95 66 4i 4o $ 224,958 280,190 137.S30 60,771 139,265 SS,379 62,876 48,445 1)48,130 41,109 119.126 $1,351,679 61 34 ^5 48 47 20 $ 10,872 24,842 139,222 67,081 32,340 54,215 59,i4i 73,429 l4i,385 189,564 23.461 384 $815,552 19 13 30 27 4o 2 1 - 3,823 3,603 - 16 13 8 2,4o6 13,768 1,163 7,o42 32,996 ^33,733 24r-930 66,822 7S $590,286 5 | I $ 14 4 6 9 (1) Based on revised data furnished by the Division of Bank Operations, Federal Reserve Board, supplemented by Rand McNally Bankers Directory. Since the Directory figures appear only every six months, resources at time of admission or withdrawal may have differed from those included above in some cases. The above figures do not give all of the changes in State bank membership since 1920. They do not include changes resulting from bank - 1(6- suspensions, voluntary liquidations, absorptions of member State "banks by national banks, conversions of member State banks to national banks, nor changes in member resources due to absorption of nonmember banks by member banks. They embrace only changes where State banks were admitted to or withdrew from the Federal reserve system. It will be noted that for several years after 1920, the admissions were more numerous than the withdrawals and the absorptions by nonmember banks. Since 1924, however, admissions to membership have been less than the losses on account of withdrawals and absorptions by nonmember banks. The same situation is generally true in respect to resources since 1926. CHAPTER l\l STATE LEG-ISLATIOH A|D THE DUAL EAHKIITG SYSTEM Two main opposing trends are apparent in the development of State banking legislation in recent years.^' On the one hand, the recognition of weaknesses in many State systems, as revealed especially "by the numerous failures of "banks since 1920, has been followed "by attempts to improve hanking standards. On the other hand, the States have endeavored to improve the com- petitive position of their banks and prevent the conversion of their institutions to national banks. Thus the States have attempted to strike a balance between the desirability of strengthening their systems from the viewpoint of safety to depositors, and of increasing the numbers and resources of their banks by making State charters attractive. With forty-eight different States involved, there have been wide variations in the banking standards actually adopted and maintained from time to time. In a few instances the State laws appear to have become fully as effective as the national laws in the matter of requiring sound banking practices. Moreover, certain extensions of powers and privileges to State banks have resulted in no apparent diminution of safety to depositors. But in the great majority of the States banks nave been and still are chartered without adequate capital and other requirements, and various practices are permitted ' 1 ) This brief summary of State banking legislation is based principally upon the following: (1) Digests of particular aspects of State laws made from time to time by counsel of the Federal Reserve Board; (2) Digest made in 1909 by the National Monetary Commission; (3) Replies to questionnaires procured from State banking departments by the twelve Federal reserve banks; and (k) Text of the banking laws of the various States. - 47- - Us - which have r e s u l t e d in lower standards of safety than those prevailing i n the n a t i o n a l system. The Opening; of Hew Banks One of the chief e v i l s of the dual hanking system and the accompanying competition for numbers and resources has been manifested in the organizat i o n of new hanks. Numerous i n s t i t u t i o n s have been chartered which should never have been allowed to commence business. In t h e i r subsequent f a i l u r e l i e s a large part of the explanation of the deplorable safety record of our banking structure. Charter requirements d i f f e r considerably in the several States* and some improvements have been made in recent years; but the s t a t u s in t h i s respect i s s t i l l far from s a t i s f a c t o r y , especially in view of the competitive s i t u a t i o n which prevents the enforcement of more adequate requirements in e i t h e r the national or the State systems. Capital Requirements. - I t was noted i n an e a r l i e r chapter that in 1900, when Congress reduced the minimum c a p i t a l i z a t i o n of national banks from $50,000 i n places under 6,000 to $25,000 in places of under 3,000 population, many States permitted banks to organize with only $10,000 of p a i d - i n c a p i t a l . Since then the majority of the States have recognized the e v i l s r e s u l t i n g from the excessive granting of charters during the e a r l y years of the century and have taken some measures e i t h e r l e g i s l a t i v e or administrative to l i m i t the number of primary organizations. In part t h i s has been accom- p l i s h e d by the adoption of higher c a p i t a l requirements. A comparison of the laws in force in 1909 indicates that in only about 13 States were the minimum c a p i t a l requirements as hign as the minimum requirements for national banks, and in over half of the States i t appears that banks could be organized in - *Q- small r u r a l coiamunities with $10,000 of c a p i t a l or l e s s . ' * ) At present 36 States require a minimum c a p i t a l of $25,000 or more for i n s t i t u t i o n s doing a commercial banking "business, and 8 of these require a minimum of $50,000. In 11 of the other 12 S t a t e s , however, the requirement s t i l l i s less than $25,000, varying from $10,000 to $20,000, while in one State no minimum i s specified in the law. Table 10 shows the minimum c a p i t a l requirement for i n s t i t u t i o n s en- gaged in commercial banking by States around 1909 and i n 1932. Table 10 - Minimum Capital Requirements for Establishment of I n s t i t u t i o n s Engaged in Commercial Banking, 1909 and 1932( 2 ) State Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine (7) Maryland Massachusett s(7) Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire Minimum capital requirements 1909(3) 19T2W $ 15,000 _ 25,000 10,000 - 15,000 25,000 10,000 25,000 25,000 io,000(0) 10,000 15,000 10,000 25,000 50,000 100,000 20,000 10,000 10,000 10,000 20,000 10,000 10,000 - $25,000 25,000 25,000 50,000(5) 25,000 50,000 25,ooo(5) 25,000 25,000 25,000(5) 50 ,ooo( 5) 25,000 25,000 20,000 15,000 25,000 50,000 25,000 50,000 20,000(5) io,ooo(5)(s) 25,000 15,000 25,000(5) 25,000, 50,000(5) 25,000 (1) Samuel A, Welldon, Digest of State Banking S t a t u t e s , Publications of the National Monetary Commission, Vol. I I I . - 50 - Table 10 - Minimum Capital Requirements for Establishment of Institutions Engaged in Commercial Banking, 1909 and 1932(2) (Continued) State New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Ehode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont (7) Virginia Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Minimum capita]. reauirements 1909(3) i9 ^ft; $50,000 30,000 25,000 5,000 10,000 25,000 10,000 10,000 25,000 _ _ 10,000 - 10,000 10,000 - 10,000 10,000 25,000 10,000 10,000 $50,000 25»ooo(5) 25,000 25,000 i5,ooo(5) 25,000(5) 10,000 25,000 25,000 — 10,000(5)(9) i5,ooo(5) 20,000 17,500 25,ooo(5) 25,000 50,000 i5,ooo(5) 25,000 25,000 £5,ooo(5) (2) These minimum requirements do not apply necessarily to all cities and towns, hut in many cases only to the smallest communities. (3) Source: Samuel A.tfelldon,Digest of State Banking Statutes. Text of various State laws and data supplied by State hanking departments. In a very few cases where data for 1932 were not available, data for the latest available year preceding were used. (5) In addition, banks in these States must have a paid-in surplus of from 10 to 100 per cent of capital before they may open for business. (6) Savings banks doing commercial business. Minimum requirement for commercial banks, $25,000, (7) Trust companies doing a commercial banking business. No commercial banks chartered. (2) In communities with less than 500 population where no bank is located. Otherwise, $20,000. (9) "Depo sitaries" may be organized with capital of $2,500. - 51 - The changes shown in Table 10 do not indicate the full measure of improvement in the matter of minimum capital requirements since 1909• In the former year a great many of the States did not require the whole of the minimum capital to he paid up before the hank commenced business, while at present this appears to be required in practically all the States. On the other hand, the minimum capital requirement in all but S States remains far below the minimum for national banks prior to 1900 when the competition of State systems forced it down. This fact undoubtedly has constituted a serious obstacle to any improvement of national banking standards in the matter of requiring capital adequate for safety. Other Restrictions. - Eestrictions upon the opening of new banks, other than minimum capital requirements, are mainly a matter of banking supervision. This subject will be dealt with in a later chapter. Here it will be sufficient to observe that in the early part of the present century supervisory officials in many States were allowed but little discretion in the granting of charters to new banks. In most cases no power of refusal was lodged in the hands of banking boards or commissioners. In only a few States were such boards or officials specifically empowered or required to consider the public convenience and necessity in granting charters, or even to investigate the integrity and reliability of the proposed incorporators. Since 1929, however, the banking board, commissioner, superintendent, or other charter-granting authority has had almost complete discretionary power in most of the States to grant or refuse applications for bank charters, subject in a number of States to appeal or review by courts or special boards. In over three-fourths of the States the bank commissioner, superintendent, or banking board is expressly instructed by law to consider the public convenience or public necessity for the proposed bank.(I) (1) See Table 13, ch. V. - 52 - Powers and Privileges of Banks This discussion will "be limited to some of tlie more important powers and privileges accorded to the banks of the various States: namely, loans on real estate, the ownership of corporate stocks, loans to individual borrowers, loans to officers and directors, "branch banking, fiduciary business, and investment banking, whether directly or througu affiliated companies. The laws, administrative rulings, and banking customs vary in so many points in the different States and are so numerous and complicated in the aggregate that a survey of this nature can make only general comparisons. It would be exceedingly difficult to present an accurate picture of detailed differences. Moreover the information is of a type that does not lend itself readily to statistical summary, and has been used only for the purpose of making general comparisons of the powers and privileges of banks. Loans on Heal Estate. - Until 1913 national banks were forbidden to make loans upon the security of real estate. In 1909 the State laws did not have this prohibition, although in a few instances real estate loans were limited in aggregate amount, and in a considerable number of others they were restricted to first liens or to given percentages of tne value of the land.^ ' Much the same situation with respect to State banks exists today, although several additional States have laid down restrictions as to the kind and amount of mortgages which may be taken and the aggregate amount of real estate loans which may be made. All the States still permit their banks to make real estate loans, but since national banks are now also permitted to make such loans, there is less difference in this respect than formerly between t:ie national and (1) George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the National-Bank Act, Publications of the National Monetary Commission, Vol. VII, pp. 100-103. -53- the State systems. National tanks, however, were granted the privilege of making loans on real estate primarily in order to enable them to meet tne competition of State chartered institutions, and tneir powers in this respect have "been extended from time to time for the same reason. Apart from limits on loans to single borrowers or to officers and directors, about one-half of tae States appear to have no restrictions whatever on the making of real estate loans, either as to the kind of mortgages taken as security or the aggregate amount of such loans. There appears to be nothing in the laws of such States to prevent banks from investing the whole of their available funds, whetner represented by time or demand deposits, in long-term real estate mortgages, which may even be second or third liens. Moreover, in several of the States which limit the aggregate amount of real estate loans, the limitation applies to percentages of both time and demand deposits, and such percentages, taken together, usually make up a considerably larger proportion of total deposits than is permitted in the case of national banks. The sum total of all the privileges still existing in the majority of the States with respect to the making of real estate loans therefore appears to be much more liberal than even the extended powers of the national banks. An immediate cause of banking difficulties in recent years, particularly in agricultural areas, was loans based either immediately or ultimately on real estate values. This class of business is the commonest example of the extension of the activities of banks beyond the traditional field of commercial banking and into the field of capital financing. Ownership of Corporate Stocks. - In addition to the power to purchase and hold bonds and other interest bearing obligations, which national banks also have, the institutions chartered ~oy many States have long had the power to pur- - 54- chase and hold corporate stocks. This is especially true with respect to trust companies. It is difficult to tell exactly what the status is in some States, hut roughly speaking it appears that in about 17 States trust companies are specifically or implicitly permitted to purchase corporate stocks, in about 11 they are permitted to do so under specific limitations either as to amount or kind, in about 10 they are specifically forbidden to purchase them, and in about 10 there is either no mention of the matter or information is unavailable. The actual practice of course frequently depends not only upon the law but also upon administrative regulation. (1) State chartered commercial banks, as it happens, are not so frequently authorized to purchase corporate stocks, less than one-fourth of the States specifically or by implication granting the privilege, over one-third specifically forbidding it, a few placing restrictions upon the amount or type of purchase, and the remaining States have no legislation on the subject.'2) Inasmuch, however, as in the great majority of the States trust companies can by law and usually do engage in commercial banking, the differences in the privileges of the two classes of institutions are not important. The power of State chartered banks and trust companies to purchase corporate stocks is a competitive advantage primarily because it gives a greater flexibility to investment policies and provides greater opportunities for speculative profits than those available to banks without the privilege. National (1) For 1909» Samuel A. Welldon, Digest of State Banking: Statutes, Publications of the National Monetary Commission, Vol, III; for 1932» Digest of State Laws Relating to the Purchase of Corporate Stocks by Banks and Trust Companies. prepared by the office of the counsel of the Federal Reserve Board. (2) Ibid. - 55 - tanks have to some extent met the situation by having their stockholders organize State chartered affiliates under identical control, and have thus, indirectlybeen enabled to take advantage of the more extensive privileges permitted to State institutions. Loans to Single Borrowers. ( D - It is not possible in a brief space to compare the limitations placed on loans to single borrowers by the various States with the limitations placed on such loans by the National Bank Act, or to summarize the changes which have been made in State laws over a period of time. The chief reason for this is the complexity of the limitations and of the exceptions. However, there is not so much difference at present between the powers of national and State banks to lend to single borrowers as there was two decades ago, partly on account of stricter requirements in many of the States and partly on account of the extension of lending powers granted to national banks. Loans to Officers and Directors/^ - The National Bank Act has never contained any limitations on loans to officers and directors of the bank, except those which apply to all borrowers. Comptrollers of the Currency have frequently recommended restrictions on such loans, but they have never been enacted by Congress. On the other hand, about two-thirds of the States had some kind of special regulations regarding loans to officers and directors as early as 1909« These were of three types: (a) the requirement that a majority, or more, of the board of directors should approve the loan; (b.) a limitation on the amount (1) Sources of information on this subject: for 1909• Samuel A. Welldon, Digest of State Banking; Statutes, Publications of the National Monetary Commission, Vol» III; for 1932, text of the various State laws and data supplied by State banking departments. (2) Sources of information on this subject: for 1909. Barnett, op., cit., p* 98; for 1932, text.of the various State laws and data supplied by State banking departments. - 56- of sucli loans more stringent than that to other persons; and (c) the requirement that loans to officers and directors should be secured. At present nearly all States have limitations of some kind on loans to officers and directors and, in some cases, on loans to employees of hanks and trust companies, in addition to those upon loans to single borrowers, although in many cases it is doubtful whether the restrictions are of much practical effect. In about half a dozen States loans to certain active officers are actually prohibited. At present more States appear to have specific restriction on loans to officers and directors than in 1909. About two-thirds of the States require that such loans, at least in excess of certain amounts, be approved by a majority or more of the board of directors or of the discount committee, ia many cases the applicant not voting* Most of the others either have special limitations upon the amount loaned or stipulate the kind or amount of security required. In a few instances the restrictions are extended to loans to partnerships or corporations of which officers or directors of the banking institution are members or which they control. Branch Banking. - As previously noted, some States have for many years permitted banks and trust companies to establish branches, although two decades ago this advantage over national banks was more theoretical than practical, since relatively few branches were established. In 1909 branch banking was of so little practical importance in most sections of the country that more than half of the States had no legislation regarding it. During the past twenty years, however, there has been a definite movement toward the establishment of branches of banks within the corporate limits of the larger cities, and in California, on a state-wide scale. This development has been followed by the passage of laws either permitting or prohibiting - 57 branches in most of the States previously without legislation on the subject,Nevertheless, there has been no general movement toward the extension of statewide branch banking. The new legislation, for the most part, has either prohibited branch banking, or authorized it only within limited areas, such as the city, town, or county in which the parent bank is located, or at least to cities, towns, or counties contiguous thereto; The extent of these changes in State legislation regarding branch banking may be seen from Table 11, which summarizes branch banking legislation in 1909> 192*+, and 1932. Table 11 - State Branch Banking legislation in 1909, 1924, and 1932(1) Numbe r of States 1909 1924 1912 States permitting state-wide branch banking^) States; permitting branch banking within limited a r e a s O ) States p r o h i b i t i n g branch banking(^) States with no l e g i s l a t i o n regarding branch bankingv.5) 9 12 9 4 8 7 17 14 lg 27 12 7 (1) Based on sfelldon; op_. cit.; and Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1925, PP. 122-157, and July, 1932, p< ^55. (2/ including 3 States in 1924 in whicn there was no express provision for branches, but in which they were implied in certain provisions of the law; and 1 State in 1924 in which the law autnorized brancn banking but the commissioner of banks and banking did not sanction their operation. (3) Limited areas include same city, tovra, county, or other local area as the loce^tion of the parent bank, and in a few cases, contiguous cities, towns, or counties. Includes 1 State in 1909 which allowed limited branches to trust companies but made no provision for general commercial banks to have branches. Includes 1 State in 1932 which permitted "stations" in towns deprived of other banking facilities. (4) Includes 1 State in 1932 which allowed mercantile companies doing a banking business to operate branches. (5) Includes 1 State in 1924 and in 1932 in which agencies for the receipt of deposits and the cashing of checks were permitted by court decisions. -58- Of the 8 States which prohibited all branch banking in 1909» none has since authorized state-wide operation, 2 have authorized branch banking within limited areas, and 1 has authorized the establishment of agencies in towns in the same county without banking facilities. Of the 9 States which per- mitted state-wide branch operation in 1909. 2 have since limited branches to restricted areas, and 3 have prohibited the establishment of new branches. Of the 27 with no legislation in 1909 regarding branch banking, 30- now prohibit branches, 5 authorize the establishment of state-wide branches, 5 permit branches within limited areas, and 7 still have no legislation regarding brandies. The whole subject of branch banking in the United States ia dealt with in other volumes of the Committee's report, where branch operation in relation to the competitive position of national and State banks is examined in considerable detail. Fiduciary Powers. - The greatest variety exists among the various States in respect to trust and other fiduciary powers. The relations between commercial banks and trust companies also differ markedly from State to State. There has been a pronounced tendency since 1909» however, to authorize State chartered institutions to perform the functions of both banks and trust companies. At the same time the number of States requiring either complete or partial segregation of the two classes of business has been reduced. Since national banks also may now be authorized by the Federal Reserve Board to exercise fiduciary powers, the trend towards a complete intermixture of banking and fiduciary functions in the same institutions is general and nation-wide. This aspect of dual control of the banking structure, in fact, is no longer so - 59 - important a matter of competition between the national and the State systems as in the past, although, as will "be made clear in a later chapter, (1) questions regarding the succession of national banks to the trust business of State institutions have sometimes been an obstacle to the conversion of State banks to national charter. Moreover, national banks have been accorded the privilege of exercising in each State only the fiduciary powers permitted to State institu—tions operating there. Consequently the national banking legislation on the subject of fiduciary powers is not uniform, but varies from State to State, Investment Banking. - With respect to the underwriting and merchandising of securities, neither the national banking laws nor those of most of the States are very clear or specific. In general there appears to be nothing in the law to prevent banks, whether national or State, from underwriting and merchandising such securities as they are permitted on their own account to purchase and hold. Except for a few very large institutions, however, they do not generally engage in underwriting in their own name or under their own charter* Merchandising, on the other hand, has become an increasingly important activity of commercial banks in recent years. Numerous banks, both national and State, often buy for resale such securities as they themselves are permitted to own. This class of business, of course, is to be distinguished from the older practice of acting in behalf of customers as agents for the purchase or sale of securities. The only essential difference between the privileges of State and national banking institutions in the matter of merchandising securities appears to be the wider powers of ownership of the former. The most important extension of the activities of commercial banking institutions into the field of investment banking in recent years has occurred (1) See ch. ¥1. « 6o - through the use of affiliated companies, organized and controlled by the same interests as the hanking institutions for the express purpose of underwriting and merchandising securities. In recent years the operation of securities af- filiates has become common among large State hanking institutions as well as among national hanks. Beserves Against Deposits Prior to the passage of the Federal Reserve Act, national banks were required to carry a certain proportion of their deposits in cash in their own vaults and in most cases as balances with other banks. This proportion varied with the locality of the bank. State statutes had analogous provisions, but it was usually true that reserves against deposits required of national banks were higher than those required of State banks of the same size and in the same situation. It is not desirable here to go into all the manifold variations in these requirements from one State to another or from one locality to another. The reserve requirements of national banks were reduced by the original Federal He serve Act and subsequent amendments* In general, however, the States have tended to reduce commensurably their requirements for State institutions i and the process has operated in the direction of lower banking standards without any stable competitive gain to national banks. Among many small banks today, membership in the Federal reserve system is considered unattractive, largely because of the regerve requirements. The State law may require that the! small State bank in question carry as much reserve in its own vaults or as balances with correspondent banks as it would have to carry with the Federal reserve bank if it were a national bank, The fact, however, that the Federal reserve bank pays no interest on bank balances while the correspondent banks do, as a - 6l- rule, is an important consideration in causing a bank's management to prefer a State to a national charter. With the passage of the federal Reserve Act it was hoped that State hanks,and trust companies engaged in commercial hanking, would "become members of the system. State banks joining the Federal reserve system, however, faced the possibility of being required to conform to two separate bodies of legislation governing reserves. Since the amendment of June 21, 1917» to the Federal Reserve Act, the required reserves of member banks have been kept entirely in the form of balances with the Federal reserve banks. At the time of the amendment, however, a large number of the States required the maintenance of vault cash reserves. In a number of States, therefore, membership in the system meant the maintenance of primary reserves greater than those required of State nonmember banks or of national banks. Since that time the majority of the States have enacted legislation permitting State banks which become members of the system to substitute the Federal reserve member bank requirements for the State requirements. In most of the remaining States the actual vault cash re- serve required is so small that it is not in excess of the needs for daily operation, and the required vault cash plus balances held with the reserve bank, which constitute balances with approved depositories under State law, is not larger than the member bank reserves plus the minimum vault cash necessary for daily operations. In these States the actual required reserves may be higher for State member banks than for nonmember banks, but they are not higher than those for national banks. CHAPTER IV TEE INFLUENCE OE 3AMERS Oft LEGISLATION One of the principal activities of the State banks through their various agencies has been directed against legislative proposals designed to place national "banks on a competitive parity with State "banks. Especially has this "been true with respect to the extension of fiduciary powers and "branch banking privileges to national banks. The original central banking plan submitted by the National Monetary Commission in 1911 provided for ''national trust companies,"'1' but there was (l) Suggested Plan for Monetary Legislation, Publications of National Monetary Commission, p. 17. - 62 - - 63vigorous opposition on the part of State chartered trust companies, and the proposal did not appear in the commission's final recommendations. The Federal Reserve Act, however, despite the opposition of the State bankers, authorized the Federal Reserve Board to grant "by special permit to national "banks, when not in contravention of State law, the right to act as trustee, executor, administrator, or registrar of stocks and "bonds, under such rules and regulations as the board might prescribe. Opposition by trust companies to the granting of these powers to national banks by the Federal Reserve Board, (1) was manifested not only in States in which banking and fiduciary functions were separated, but also in States in which trust companies engaged in commercial banking in direct competition with national banks. In 19lH the Mew York State Legislature enacted a statute restricting the exercise of fiduciary powers to trust companies or-* ganized under State laws. (2) Similar laws existed in Colorado, Florida, Missouri, and North Carolina in 1915 and attorneys general in at least twelve other States interpreted the laws to deny fiduciary rights to national banks. (3) That same year representatives of the Trust Company Section of the American Bankers Association went to Washington to protest to the Federal Reserve Board that the authorization in the Federal Reserve Act was unconstitutional. About the same time litigation was initiated in attempts to prevent the national banks from exercising the fiduciary powers granted them, the expense of the litigation being borne by individual trust companies. On the other hand, there 1 C ) A comprehensive review of the litigation over the fiduciary powers of national banks is pontained in an article by Charles S. Tippetts, "Fiduciary Powers of national Banks," American Economic Review, September, 1925, Vol. XV, pp. U17-U3U. (2) Federal Reserve Bulletin. January, 1918, p. 12. (3) Commercial and Financial Chronicle, American Bankers Association Supplement, September 18, 1915. PP. 1^0-1^1. (*0 Ibid.. pp. lU2, lUg. - 6H- were some States wnich adopted enabling acts designed to remove various disabilities under which the national banks labored in their exercise of fiduciary powers. (1) On June 11, 1917 the Supreme Court rendered a decision in First National Bank of Bay City vs. Fellows which settled in principle the constitutionality of trust powers exercised by national banks under the provisions of the Federal He serve Act, (2) but left some question as to the adequacy of the law in certain particulars. Thus it appeared still to be of doubtful effectiveness in face of statutes such as existed in Hew York State. In connection with the latter the Attorney General of the United States said that "The power of Congress to determine how far national banks may be subject to State control is settled. . . . But in this case Congress has not exerted its powers.M'3) The inadequacy of the existing statute was removed by an amendment of September 26, 1918 to the Federal Reserve Act, providing specifically that the exercise of fiduciary powers by national banks should "not be deemed to be in contravention of State or local law" when such powers were authorized for State banks. Even this did not end the agitation and litigation. Diffi- culties continued particularly in States which required trust companies to deposit securities with the State authorities. Attorneys general in at least two of these States are reported to have held that the authorities had no right to accept such securities from national banks. On the strength of an opinion of the attorney general of Wisconsin still maintaining that national banks had no right to exercise trust powers, the legislature enacted in 1919 a law forbidding them to do so, but the Supreme Court of the State declared it unconsti- (1) I b i d . , p . 140. (2) 2kk u . S. Ul6. See Federal Reserve B u l l e t i n , A p r i l , 1917, P. 25^; J u l y , 1917, PP. 5 3 ^ 5 3 8 . (3) Opinions of the Attorneys General, 1916-1919> Edited by George Eearn«y, Vol. 31, pp.TSF-188. See Federal Reserve B u l l e t i n , January, 1918, pp. 12-13* (^) Public No. 218, 65th Congress. See Federal Reserve Bulletin, October, 191B, p . 9^8. - 65tutional. (1) It is obvious that though the national banks had their constitutional rights confirmed by unquestionable authority they were in practice being discouraged from exercising them, for besides the suits and the adverse State laws that had to be fought, they also found probate courts unwilling to grant their appointments. (2) In several States litigation on this account continued, therefore. A number of these cases established the rights of national banks under various conditions. In one of them in which a Missouri probate court had refused the appointment of a national bank as executor, the State Supreme Court sustained the refusal and the case came before the United States Supreme Court, where, April 28, 1924, a decision was rendered reversing the Missouri court's judgment. The United States Supreme Court declared that "the State can not lay hold of it's general control of administration to deprive national banks of their power to compete that Congress is authorized to sustain. ..(3) In I896, as previously noted, the Comptroller of the Currency recommended that national banks be permitted to open branches in small towns. Congress, however, did not adopt this recommendation. The proposal was vigorously opposed by the banks generally, but more especially by the smaller institutions. In the more recent movement toward branch banking by national banks the pressure of State bankers has been directly evident. The prolonged consideration of the McFadden bill, lasting from 1924 to early 1927, was due principally (1) Journal of the American Bankers Association, May, 1919» PP» 60I-602. Also July, 1919, P. 19. 2 ( ) 179 H. Y. Supp. pp. 179-190; 110 Atl. 54; 178 N. W. Rep. 310. Also Federal Reserve Bulletin, November, 1919, pp. 1059-lOoO; June, 1920, pp. 6lO-6ll; July, 1920, pp. 700-701. For general discussion see Charles S. Tippetts, "Fiduciary Powers of National Banks," American Economic Review, September, 1925, Vol. XV, p. 428 ff. (3) State of Missouri ex rel. Burnes National Bank of St, Joseph v. Duncan, 265, U. S. 17, 44 Sup. Ct. 427, decided April 28, 1924. See Federal Reserve Bulletin. May, 1924, pp. 4l8-4l9. - 66 - to the controversy over the so-called Hull amendments. These were sponsored by the State banking interests, and were designed to prohibit forever any member of the Federal reserve system, either national or State, from establishing branches in States which, at the time of the passage of the McFadden bill, did not provide for b»anch banking. This would have given nonmember State banks and trust companies a permanent advantage over national and State bank members of the Federal reserve system in regard to the future development of branch banking, in States then prohibiting it but thereafter adopting branch banking. Activities of the American Bankers Association The American Bankers Association, including in its membership most of the country's banks, is composed of semi-autonomous divisions representing State banks, national banks, trust companies, and savings banks. Consequently it is sometimes difficult for the varied elements to agree on matters of policy, because of conflicting interests. Nevertheless, the association has generally been able to agree on important issues, although the final decisions have undoubtedly been compromises. The association itself and its various divisions have legislative committees to which are entrusted the duties of informing the membership of legislation in which they would be interested, in sponsoring bills considered favorable and opposing those considered prejudicial to the interests of the members. In 1905 the Committee on Federal Legislation of the American Bankers Association was appointed. (1) It has since been actively engaged in presenting the views of the association to influential government officials and legislators (l) American Bankers Association, Proceedings of the Thirty-second Annual Convention, 1906, p. lU2. - 67in Washington. Also, the general counsel of tne association nas been active in keeping in close touch witii all Federal hanking legislation. Associated with the Committee on Federal Legislation is the Federal Legislative Council, which has a State chairman in each State, and subcommittees in each Congressional district. The latter are immediately advised by the committee in case it decides that the need has arisen to take action. In the words of a chairman of the council, "Then, if an emergency arises, distress calls are made upon the great subcommittee and all the solicitude of the banking public is aroused. ..(1) The State bankers in the American Bankers Association have consistently advocated the perpetuation of the dual banking system. As far back as 1913 the then president of the Irust Company Section stated :(2) ". . . our State governments are far better able to govern our affairs than if we are regulated under any National act, something which I think many of us fear is surely on the way," At the 1930 convention the State Bank Division passed a resolution which read in part: (3) "Whereas, the prevailing dual system of banking has contributed substantially to the remarkable economic development of our country, therefore be it "Besolved, That we believe our present State and National banking systems should continue working in cooperation, thus assuring the endurance and permanency of individual initiative and the free play of personalized enterprise which history has proven so desirable." President M. Plin Beebe made extensive remarks of like tenor at the (1) Commercial and Financial Chronicle, American Bankers Convention Section, Vol. CXXI, October 17, 1925, P. 96. (2) Aias rican Bankers Association, Proceedings of the Thirty-ninth Annual Convention, 1913, PP. 35S-359. (3) Commercial and Financial Chronicle, American Bankers Convention Section, Vol. CXXXI, October IS, 1930, p. $k. - 6S - 1931 convention. (1) At the 1932 convention the State Bank Division passed a resolution in still stronger terms, reading in part as follows:'2' "Further, be it resolved, That we are unalterably opposed to the so-called unification of all "banking under Federal control in place of the present dual system of State and National banks which is being promulgated for the purpose of destroying the State supervised banking systems. It is almost unbelievable that such a movement could attain success, but it is being supported by such powerful interests that desire to being the entire banking business of this country under the control of a single Washington bureau as to constitute a serious menace to our State banks." The report to the 1932 convention of the Economic Policy Commission, representing the American Bankers Association as a whole, took a somewhat less uncompromising view of the question of unified control, although reiterating previous endorsements of the dual system. Pertinent passages of this report are as follows: (3) "Another line of thought argues that tne great reform in banking by means of law that is needed is in the direction of a single, unified system for the country as a whole under Federal Government supervision. It is the theory in this proposal that this plan would make for better supervision, a more compact and better co-ordinated banking structure, a nationally higher standard of management for all banks and a credit mechanism that would be subject to greater control in the national interest. "Fnile we are wholly in sympathy with the basic purposes envisioned in this argument, we believe, as we have brought out in previous reports and will not repeat in detail here, that they can be attained under the present dual system of State and National charters, that this dual system has additional virtues in itself, particularly along the lines of maintaining local financial independence and credit sympathies free from the domination of over-centralized Federal Government, and that the dual system should be strengthened rather than destroyed. (1) Ibid.. Vol. CXXXIII, October 24, 1931, pp. 60-62. (2) Ibid., Vol. CXXXV, October 22, 1932, p. 60. (3) Ibid., p. 33. - 69 - "Specifically, we have in mind the material enlargement of the sphere of influence of the Federal Eeserve System in the present dual hanking structure, which is particularly favored "by the reduction of the "banking picture to its present dimensions and character. The changes this has involved have promoted unity in the operating aspects of our commercial hanking systems embracing "both State and National banks, witnout abrogating their respective charter rights or nullifying the advantages of our dual system." The National Bank Division lias been concerned to no little extent with attempting to stem the tide of losses to the national system through conversions to State cnarters, by advocating "liberalization" of the Federal laws. A resolution passed by this division at the 1929 convention read in part:'*) "Members of the National Bank Division have observed with increasing concern the withdrawals of banks from the National System for the purpose of operating under State laws. This movement, which has gained considerable momentum in some sections of the United States, and which shows no evidence of subsiding, indicates unmistakably the necessity for some change which will inject more attractiveness into National charters and stay the decline in National bank resources* "...Th0 National Bank Division . . • • is . • . guided by ization that to be acceptable to those engaged in banking al charters must be free fr^.m restrictions which handicap competition with banks operating under the broader powers State laws." the realNationthem in of sound The division pledged itself to exert its efforts to bring about such needed change. In 1929, when the need of new Federal legislation became more apparent, the Committee on National Bank Research was formed. This committee recommended among other things that small national banks be permitted to withdraw from the Federal reserve system if they so desired, and that each national bank be allowed to own 66 2/3 per cent or more of the stock of one trust company and one securities company.(2) These recommendations to meet the competition of State U ) Ibid., Vol. GXXIX, October 19, 1929, p. 100. (2) Ibid., Vol. CXXXI, October IS, 1930, p. 82. - 70 - institutions would, if enacted, have added further to the list of measures of relaxation of the National Bank Act which have been passed for the same purpose. In the fight over the granting of trust powers to national hanks the American Bankers Association clearly showed its dual composition. While the State hank and trust company members actively opposed this extension of the rights of their national bank competitors, the latter naturally took a contrary view, and sponsored the development of such powers. The Trust Division was the most antagonistic and took the lead in the legal fight which sought to restrict or prevent the exercise of these powers.^/ Perhaps in no other phase of the competitive struggle did the American Bankers Association play a more important role than in that concerning the extension of branch banking powers to national banks. Here again the national and State bank divisions found their interests opposed to some extent, although the small national banks probably feared branch banking about as much as their State competitors. Compromise was necessary, and when the climax of the contest was readied during the deliberations over the McFadden Act, the association finally approved provisions giving national banks the right to increase branch operations to a limited extent. This approval, which had been withheld while still more rigid restrictions were advocated, apparently assured the passage of the measure. In the par clearance controversy, all divisions of the American Bankers Association found a policy of opposition upon which they could unite. Special (1) American Bankers Association, Proceedings of the Forty-third Annual Convention, 1917, pp.385-386. - 71 - committees were appointed which attempted to prevail upon the Federal .Reserve Board to alter its regulations, and failing in that, to persuade the hanking committees of Congress to initiate changes in the law.^' The Committee on Federal Legislation supplemented the work of these committees.'2' Activities of the State Supervisors State hank supervisors have reflected the point of view of State banking institutions. In constant touch with State hank officials, and also interest- ed in a professional way in Federal hanking legislation and supervision, they have been quick to detect proposals to improve the competitive position of the national banking system, and to assist in mobilizing the State banking and political forces for the purpose of defeating such proposals. They have considered it their duty on such occasions to take the initiative in opposition to proposed Federal legislation, and to form special organizations to exert their influence in behalf of the State banking interests. At the annual convention of the supervisors of State banks in 1919> a resolution protesting against the exercise of fiduciary powers by national banks was adopted. As introduced the resolution memorialized Congress "to repeal the existing law conferring fiduciary powers upon national Banks," but as passed it was confined to a protest against the action that Congress had taken, on the ground, among other things, that it was ". . .an invasion, in spirit, of the constitutional rights of the States. ..(3) The interest of the supervisors of State banks in Federal legislation was also shown in the hearings in Congress (1) See Committee of Five of the American Bankers Association, Report on Exchange and Collection Charges, 1918. (2) American Bankers Association, Proceedings of the Annual Convention, 1917, P. 160; 1918, p. 339. (3) National Association of Supervisors of State Banks, Proceedings of the Eighteenth Annual Convention, 1919» PP« 96-97. 112. - 72 - on branch banking in the spring of 1930» They insisted that the unit system of hanking should he protected from brancn hanking, even though in several States branch banking is permitted to State institutions. In recent conventions they have protested both to the Fed- eral Heserve Board and to Congress, and have invoked the aid of the American Bankers Association, in an effort to combat the possibility of national banks being permitted to maintain branches over wider limits than State lines, or in States where branch banking is not permitted to State chartered institutions* In this controversy the merits or demerits of branch banking have not been the main consideration. The question has been reduced essentially to that of the maintenance of certain banking systems. Hot only have the State supervisors expressed their own protests against Federal legislation, but they have also assisted in organizing the State banking interests for the purpose of lobbying at Washington. The National Association of Supervisors of State Banks as early as 1916 passed resolutions commending the Kansas State Bankers' Association for creating an organization to be known as the National Association of State Banks. It was clearly implied that such an agency was needed to look out for the interest of State banking institutions before Congress and the State legislatures.(!) During their conven- tion in the following year the need for political action was further discussed and a committee appointed to formulate definite plans. (2) A member from New York expressed the a t t i t u d e of the a s s o c i a t i o n quite frankly by saying:\3J " . . . I t i s c e r t a i n , however, that the only way t h a t State i n s t i t u t i o n s can procure p r o t e c t i o n from unjust n a t i o n a l l e g i s l a t i o n i s through a n a t i o n a l body and co-operation t h e r e . " (1) I b i d . , 1916, pp. 66-67, 163. ( 2 ) I*>id., 1917, PP. 109-112. (3) I b i d . , p . 112. - 73- At the 191S convention, this committee reported that the National Association of State Banks had been organized, and recommended that each superbvisor organize his own State. It was thereupon resolved that each supervisor should call a conference of the State banking institutions for the purpose of organizing State associations, and that the president of the association of supervisors appoint a committee to cooperate with the State banking associations in the formation of a "National Council of State Institutions. Tnese reso- lutions were carried out, and the "United States Council of State Banking Associations" was organized. In November, 191S, it opened a Washington office, and sent to all State chartered banks and trust companies an announcement promising:^' "'When legislation is introduced in Congress which affects or may affect State chartered institutions an endeavor will be made to furnish the appropriate committee of Congress with the information it should have in order to reach a proper conclusion, and this office will also endeavor to keep the State institutions informed of any proposed legislation which may affect their interests; so that through the medium of the Council the views of those affected may be presented for consideration.1" Since that time a legislative committee of the National Association of Supervisors of State Banks has been appointed. In I92U the secretary of the association declared that this legislative committee was more powerful than the State Bank Section of the American Bankers Association, and that the possibility of marshalling the interested forces in regard to legislation on financial affairs was lodged in it to a greater extent than in any other place. (3) This mobilization of the State bankers by the State supervisors was no doubt from their own point of view thoroughly wise. Its significance lies in tiie fact that because the country has a dual banking system, administrative (1) Ibid., 1918, p. 78. < 2 ) Ibid. • 1919, PP. *A-U5. (3) Ibid.. 192U, p. 119. - 7H- officials of the various States devote their energies to defeating legislation in the Congress of the United States, and are constantly engaged in efforts to bring about competitive advantages for their institutions. From the foregoing survey of the influences which have been brought to bear upon the development of banking legislation, some of the worst evils of the dual system should be apparent. Except the general public with the safety of its deposits at stake, all parties concerned—whether bankers, supervisory agencies, or legislative authorities of the States and of the nation—are involved willy-nilly in a sort of rivalry which frequently can only take the form of competition in laxity. Sincere efforts have been made by most of the States to improve the standards of banking safety, and some improvement in legal safeguards has certainly been achieved; but the possibility of losing banks to the national system constantly intervenes to prevent the measures of reform which have been shown by the record of bank failures to be urgently necessary. The dilemma of State author- ities is well illustrated by the following remarks of the commissioner of banks of Massachusetts in 1 9 2 9 : ^ " . . . What steps are to be taken to protect the state banking system? I am a firm believer in harmony and I dislike to see the question always arising as to how the national banks can win friends from the state banking system, and on the other hand, how the state banks can get ahead of the national banks, I wish the question could be settled, so the banks could attend solely to the business in which they are engaged. . . (1) Ibid., 1929, P. 85. - 75 - "We are also careful in passing state legislation that nothing will he done to drive out the state hanks that are now doing a good and legitimate "business, If they find that the State Legislature is inclined to be a little harsh on them, it will he very simple for them to convert into a national bank and be received with open arms, . ." CHAPTER V EFFECTS OT DUAL CONTROL UPON BANK SUPERVISION The effects of dual control of commercial banking have not been confined to legislation. The supervisory machinery and the standards and practices of both State and national supervisory authorities have also been greatly influenced by competition between the two systems. In order to mats this clear, it will be necessary in the present chapter to examine in some detail the origin and development of the various types of bank supervision now in operation, as well as their practical results in the matter of maintaining adequate standards of banking practice. Daring the first half century after national independence was achieved there was little governmental supervision of banks in any part of the United States. The filing of reports with Government officials was often a requirement inserted in the bank charters granted by legislatures; but only in isolated instances is there any record of penalties attached to failure to make reports, and very rarely were any Government officials specifically designated for making bank examinations. Experiences during this period led to two types of State supervision. One type was inaugurated in several of the New England and Middle Atlantic States, where "free banking" was developing. Banking departments or boards of bank commissioners were created, some of which have had a continuous existence down to the present time. These supervisory authorities had varying degrees of power. The banking committee established in - 76- - 77 - Connecticut in I836, for example, consisted of the State treasurer, comptroller, and commissioner of the school fund. It had power to inspect all books and papers of hanks and to examine hank officials under oath. Two commissioners were appointed in the place of this committee the next year. In Massachusetts, on the contrary, the hoard of commissioners established in 1838 was to make annual examinations of all hanks in the Commonwealth and to render special reports if requested by the governor. It was also author- ized to procure an injunction from the Supreme Judicial Court if the condition of any bank was hazardous to the public or its depositors, or if it had exceeded its powers or violated the banking laws.(l) Another type of bank supervision developed in the agricultural States of the Mississippi Valley, notably in Indiana, Missouri, Ohio, and Iowa. Indiana, for example, established in 183^ a State Bank, of which the central board of directors and the officials were not operating executives and did not directly conduct any banking business. Rather, they constituted a supervisory authority over the "branches," which were semi-independent banking offices carrying on the actual functions of banking, in which the public held stock, and of which local boards of directors were the operating heads. But since the board of directors of the State Bank had almost unlimited control over the branches, its supervision was far more direct and effective than that of bank superintendents or boards of bank commissioners in the "free banking" systems of the Northeast. These State bank systems were successful in furnishing adequate and safe banking facilities, but they were all liquidated soon after the passage of the national Bank Act in IS63, many of the branches becoming independent national banks. v 1 ) Davis R. Dewey, State Banking Before the Civil War, Publications of National Monetary Commission, Vol. IV, pp. 126-135. - 7S - A large number of the States, ho-'eVer, had neither of these types of "bank supervision in force when the national Bank Act was passed. With the introduction of the national banking system it was expected that the State banks would be driven out of existence, and this expectation was al~ most realized. For many years, therefore, no significant attempts were made either to improve the State bank systems or to extend the scope of State bank supervision. It was not until State banks generally became able to operate profitably without the note issue privilege that the States again attempted to raise banking standards and practices by means of supervisory agencies. For the most part, therefore, present types of State supervision over banking institutions have been a development of the period since I8S5, and especially since the beginning of the present century. National Bank Supervision The estalishment of the national banking system carried with it the beginnings of a system of supervision. This supervision had become a significant element in the strength of the national banking system before the movement toward the creation of State supervisory agencies had made much headway. It is therefore appropriate to discuss the type and character of national bank supervision since IS63 before treating the development of State supervision. National Bank Supervision Prior to, the Federal Reserve Act. - The original provisions of the National Bank Act were largely influenced by the assumption that the act was a currency measure. The office of the Comptroller of the Currency was created and detailed regulations were laid down with respect to the issues of notes by the national banks. Subject to the approval of the Secretary of the Treasury, the comptroller was authorized to appoint - 79 - examiners. Provision was made for examination "into all the affairs of the association," although the most important duty of the examiners was to ascertain whether the condition of the "banks was such that their notes would he honored when presented. As time went on, however, the experience of the comptroller's office made it increasingly clear that the scope of supervision must he constantly enlarged and the duties of the examiners made more exacting. Public opinion from the outset tended to blame the comptroller's office for failures or defalcations. As the deposit phase of "banking came to "be of greater importance than the note issues, it "became increasingly important to investigate all of a "bank's assets in the interest of depositors as well as noteholders. national "bank supervision, however, was far from adequate when in 190S and 1909 "the National Monetary Commission made its study of the banking structure. Examiners were subjected to no tests before appointment, and members of Congress made recommendations to the comptroller regarding applicants. While the comptroller and the Secretary of the Treasury made appoint- ments as far as possible on the basis of experience and fitness, political pressure was considerable. Examinations were paid for by the banks according to a fee system, varying in amount according to the capital of the bank. Assessments were levied and the proceeds were turned over to the examiners, who received no other official compensation. Out of these gross receipts, assistants' wages, travel, and other expenses were paid. Thus the net compensation of the ex- aminers was subject to considerable variation, though it was estimated to be about one-third less than their gross receipts. The fee system unduly - so hastened the work of examination and reduced its effectiveness. In order to minimize travel expense, the examiners usually followed the same route, and the "banks were often able to learn in advance the approximate date of their arrival and could make preparations accordingly. The geographical assignments of the examining force were such that the examiners rarely had any contact with each other. As a consequence, there was little or no uniformity in the method of examinations, in the judgment of examiners as to the value of various types of assets, or the propriety of "banking practices. Still another handicap to effective super- vision was the fact that the assistants were appointed and paid by the examiner alone, and did not come under the comptroller's direction. Other difficulties were caused by the slight amount of power possessed by the comptroller. Then as now, he had no authority to require bar,.'-' directors and officials to correct unsatisfactory conditions, unless the capital of the "bank was actually impaired. He could institute measures to revoke a "bank's charter, "but this was so severe a penalty that as a practical matter it could "be used only after the most flagrant violation of law. Banks were also able to transfer bad and illegal assets to other banks or corporations during the period of an examination, especially when State chartered affiliates were operating in the same buildings. Securities could be borrowed so as to prevent examiners from obtaining a correct knowledge of the condition of the bank. Moreover, the condition of the affiliate itself might impair the solvency of the bank, while the examiner would be unable to discover the true situation because the affiliated corporations were beyond the jurisdiction of the national supervisory agencies. But despite all these limitations, the examinations conducted by the cornptroller were an important force in the maintenance of relatively - SI - high banking standards in the national system, and of the greater prestige enjoyed "by national hanks as compared with state chartered institutions. National supervision in other respects also was of a fairly high order, notably in the natter of chartering new hanks. This was particularly true -prior to 1900, when mininua capital requirements were lowered, and even in later years "before the competition of the various State systems oaused the successive comptrollers to exercise their discretionary power to charter more new institutions in an effort to maintain the relative importance of the national system in terms of numbers and resources. Hational Bank Supervision since 191,5» - While there was no general revision of the national "banking laws at the time of the establishment of the Federal reserve system, one of the most urgently needed reforms in the character of supervision was accomplished. The payment of examiners was changed from a fee to a salary system, with salaries fixed "by the federal Reserve Board upon the recommendation of the Comptroller of the Currency. It was provided further that the costs of examinations were to he assessed against the "banks "by the comptroller according to the assets or resources of the banks examined. The power of appointment of examiners was vested in the comptroller subject to the approval of the Secretary of the Treasury. Under these new provisions as to compensation, the former tendencies toward hasty and superficial examinations were partially eliminated. The method of paying examiners no longer prevented them from taking the time necessary to examine each bank thoroughly and as frequently and in as great detail as might be deemed necessary. The comptroller's authority was at first extended to all banks in the Federal reserve system, but in 1917 the authority to examine State bank and trust company members was transferred to the Federal Reserve Board. - S2 - Selections of bank examiners are made on the basis of ability and experience, although no competitive examinations are held. Additions to the examining forces are, as a rule, recruited from the staffs of banks examined, and selected through the regional or local bank examiners who have acquired a knowledge of their training and experience and are in a position to obtain accurate knowledge of an applicant's character and personality. All original appointments are made to the position of assistant examiner, and these receive their preliminary training when working with experienced examiners. While the salaries of examiners are more adequate than in former years, the complaint is still constantly made by the comptroller and his assistants that it is impossible to retain the best trained and most valuable examiners. Bankers with whom they are brought into contact recognize their qualifications and offer them salaries which the comptroller's office cannot meet. The Comptroller of the Currency is given unrestricted authority in regard to the examination of national banks and to the banking standards which he may suggest as adequate, but he has little power to compel bank officials to adhere to these standards or to adopt the recommendations made by the examining forces. He has the power to enter suit for the forfeiture - S3 - of charters on account of unlawful practices, or he may appoint a receiver for failure to make good impaired capital or failure to redeem notes. Otherwise, however, the comptroller has no direct powers for changing the methods and practices of hank management, so long as they are technically in conformity with the law. Neither can he remove recalcitrant or incompetent bank officials who may persistently engage in unsound practices. He may remonstrate and call their acts to the attention of their superiors or to the directors, hut beyond this point he cannot go, except to sue for forfeiture of the bank's charter. Moreover, the comptroller does not have the power to order impaired assets to be written off, or frozen and slow loans to be taken care of by elimination or the setting up of reserves. A bank may hold in its portfolio large amounts of "frozen" paper, the ultimate repayment of which is doubtful, without an appropriate write-down being reflected in the bank's statements to the public and to its stockholders. Likewise, drastic depreciation of security holdings may occur, such as lias taken place since the autumn of 1929. and the comptroller must rely upon "moral suasion" only to force any writing down of such assets. The absence of powers intermediate between calling the atten- - su tion of directors and officials to unsatisfactory conditions, and the closing of a bank in the case of actual insolvency, sometimes creates a serious situation. It both prevents adequate supervisory protection being given to depositors and places an unfair responsibility on the comptroller, who can neither prevent a bank from pursuing policies that are likely to result in insolvency, nor inform stockholders or depositors that their funds are likely to be endangered. If all banks were under one supervisory authority, it would be possible for the supervisor, even without further powers, to be much more stringent in his admonitions to bank directors, more prompt in closing banks on account of insolvency, and more exacting in the conservative valuation cf assets in condition statements. Bank officials and directors are apt to resent "interference" and "moral suasion," and the ease with which they may escape national supervision by becoming State banks or trust companies greatly reduces the actual effectiveness of suggestions made by examiners and the comptroller's staff. Prom the establishment of the national banking system in I863 to the present time, the Comptrollers of the Currency have placed before Congress recommendations for reform of the system of supervision by specifying certain banking standards and by providing adequate powers and penalties for their enforcement. Thus it was recommended in I863 that the failure of a national bank be declared prima facie fraudulent and that the officers and directors be made personally responsible as well as punishable criminally unless upon investigation it was found that the bank's affairs had been honestly administered; in 1887 that penalties be imposed for making loans - 85 - contrary to law; in 1895 "blia'fc tlle comptroller be authorized, with the approval of the Secretary of the Treasury and after a hearing, to remove officers and directors for mismanagement or violations of law; in 19l4 that the comptroller "be authorized to penalize "both "banks and their officers "by appropriate fines for failure to comply with his regulations; and in 1931 that a "board composed of the Secretary of the Treasury, the governor of the Federal Reserve Board, and the comptroller, should have power to remove officers or directors of "banks who persistently violated the law or who continued unsafe and unsound practices. None of these recommendations have "been adopted "by Congress, "but it appears probable that had there "been no fear of driving banks out of the national and into the State system, most of them would have been long since enacted into law. However, some of the most harmful effects of the dual banking system upon national supervision have occurred, not so much from the lack of legal powers on the part of the Comptroller of the Currency, as from the chartering of new banks, over v/hich he is vested with almost complete discretionary authority. Apart from minimum capital and a few other requirements of the law, the comptroller has full power to grant or refuse a charter on the basis of his judgment as to the probable soundness and stability of the new institution. But he has also been forced to choose in many cases between refusing a national charter,, on the one hand, with certain knowledge that the applicants will then obtain a State charter, and on the other hand, granting the national charter perhaps against his best judgment. Many charters have, as a matter of fact, been granted to national banks which could not hope to survive except in periods of unbroken prosperity. This has been pointed out by the Comptroller of the Currency in his annual report for 1927. - go - State Bank Supervision The manner in which State ban-cs "began in the late eighties to recover from the effects of the Federal tax upon their note issues and to increase rapidly in number and resources has "been discussed earlier in these pages. Here it will "be sufficient to note that this new development was soon followed "by evidence of the need of supervision. The actual putting into effect of supervisory measures, however, was not so rapid as might have "been expected, in view of the example of the national "banking system. In Table 12 the initiation of hank supervision in the various States is indicated "by the year in which regular examinations of "banks were authorized and the year in which permanent authorities were established for the particular purpose of supervising "banking institutions. Complete accuracy in determining when a given status of supervision originated is not always possible, but it is believed that the table is substantially correct. The status of supervision shown by this table may be summarized briefly as follows: By 1870, k States authorized regular examinations of banks and 3 States had established supervisors'- authorities. In all these States examinations and supervisory authorities had been established -prior to the Civil War, for the most part between IS30 and 18^0. Six of these States were in Hew England, and the other 2 were New York and Ohio. During the fifteen years from IS70 to 1835, 6 more States had authorized regular examinations of banks, but only one more had established a definite supervisory authority. During the following fifteen year period, from I8S5 to 1900, however, 21 additional States provided for regular examinations and 3 established separate supervisory authorities, while 2 others established what were essentially banking departments within the offices of other supervisory agencies. - 87 Table 12- The Initiation of Bank Supervision in the Various States(l) Year regular examinations were authorized Prior to IS70 ~ Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, Now Hampshire 1873 - Indiana, Iowa lgjU - Vemont I878 - California, Minnesota 1S84 - New York 1887 - Illinois, Michigan 1888 - Utah, Wyoming 1889 - Florida, Georgia, Nebraska, New Jersey, North Carolina 1890 - North Dakota 1891 - Kansas, Pennsylvania, South Dakota, West Virginia 1895 - Missouri, Montana, Wisconsin 1897 - Arizona, Oklahoma 1898 - Louisiana, Maryland 1903 - Alabama, Delaware, New Mexico 1§05 - Idaho, Texas 1906 - South Carolina 1§07 - Colorado, Nevada, Oregon, Washington 1908 - Ohio, Rhode Island 1910 - Virginia 1912 - Kentucky 1913 _ Arkansas, Tennessee 191^+ - Mississippi Year separate or virtually separate supervisory authority was established(2) Prior to 1S70 - Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, Ne\7 Hampshire, New York, Ohio, Rhode Island, Vemont I87S - California 1888 - Michigan IS9I - Florida,(3) Kansas, New Jersey, Wyoming I892 - Pennsylvania I89J+ - Wisconsin 1895 - Nebraska 1897 ~ Illinois^) IS98 - Louisiana 1901 - West Virginia 1905 ~ South Carolina, North Dakota 1906 - Idaho, Oregon, 19C7 - Colorado, Oklahoma, Washington 1909 - Minnesota, Missouri, Nevada 1910 - Maryland, Virginia 1911 - Alabama, Utah 1912 - Kentucky 1913 - Arkansas, Tennessee 191^ - Mississippi 1915 ™ Montana, New Mexico, South Dakota 1917 - Iowa 1919 - Delaware, Georgia, Indiana 1922 - Arizona 1§23 - Texas 1931 - North Carolina(5) Sources: George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the National-Bank Act, Vol. VII, pp. 1^8^156 and 17S-1S1, Publications of National Monetary Commission. H. Parker Willis, Report of an Inquiry into Contem-iorary Banking in the United States, Appendix B (unpublished), and various State banking statutes. (2) Date of establishment of a banking department, board of commissioners, bank commissioner, bank examiner, or other board or official with substantially no other duties excopt the examination and supervision of banks. In some States, where banks, prior to the date given, were under the supervision of State auditors or other officials having other duties, there may have been assistants devoting full time to bank supervision at earlier dates than those stated. (3) In Florida bank supervision is under the State comptroller, who published the first report on banking in 1891. In Illinois bank supervision is under the State auditor, with the earliest report available published in 1897. (5) In North Carolina supervision was under the Corporation Commission until 1931» when a separate banking department was established. _ S8 By 19lH, all the States had provided for .regular examinations, hut it was not until 1931 that a11 States had also established either separate supervisory agencies or agencies within the offices of other State departments. State Supervisory, Agencies. - The scope and powers of the supervisory agencies of the forty-eight States have varied greatly. In many cases numerous changes have "been made from time to time. No attempt has "been made hy the Committee to outline the history of these State supervisory agencies, or to trace in detail the growth of their powers and the changes in their character. It has "been felt desirable, however, to summarize briefly the status of State supervision at the time of the National Monetary Commission's investigation of banking conditions, and then to examine briefly the changes which have taken place since that date. More than half of the States had set up separate or virtually separate banking departments prior to 1910, but several of these were comparatively new and were not well established. Moreover, many of them did not have adequate powers, especially in the handling of insolvent institutions, and in regard to the maintenance of sound assets as a means of preventing insolvency. The chief supervisors in almost all cases were political ap- pointees, holding office in fact at the pleasure of the governors or of boards composed of their associates. The control of the supervisors over new charter applications was especially weak, as they either did not have discretionary power in granting them or else wore subject to direct, or indirect but nevertheless potent, political influence. Their terms of office were also often too short to permit either the development of efficient organizations or a thorough acquaintance with the real problems and details of their duties and responsibilities. The salaries available for examiners, as well as the uncertain terms of office, were not sufficient to attract men of the proper qualifications to these positions. Because of inadequate funds - S9 and forces, bank examinations could not "be made as frequently in some States as necessary. Finally, standards of "banking practice and of supervision in general were more lax in most of the States than in the national system. Nevertheless the tendency toward creating single departments, or supervisors clothed with full authority to act without deferring to a "board or other official, and entirely divorced from other administrative activities, was "becoming quite narked. The principal changes in the character of State supervisory authorities since 1909 are summarized in Table 13. (See also appendix Table II.) Table 13- The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and I929-I932U) Number of States 1909(2) 1929-1932 1. Supervisory agency (a) Separate or virtually separate (b) Under other department 28 18 ^6 37 1 32 10 3 6 2 2. Type of supervisory authority (a) Single official in charge of banking (b) Single official, supplemented ~bj banking board (c) Single official,, appointed by or under the control of an executive banking board or other board (d) Board, or two or three commissioners in charge of department (e) No specific arrangement for supervision 5 2 - 19 1 in 3. Method of selecting commissioner or supervisor (a) (b) (c) (d) k. Appointment by governor Election by popular vote Selection by banks, or from panel named ~by banks In other vt&ys Term of office of supervisor (a) Three years or less (b) Four years (c) Jive or six years (d) Indefinite term - 2 2 2 3 12 IS 2 1 10 30 23 7 ik 28 1 6 k h 5. Salary of supervisor (a) Under $5,000 per year (b) $5,000 to $10,000 per year (c) $10,000 or over per year 6. Method of selection of examiners (a) Civil service (b) By supervisory agency solely (c) By supervisory agency with approval of the governor or board — 6 15 31 1 11 - 90 - Table 13 - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932(1) (Continued) i ITumber of States 1909(2) 7. Po?/ers relative to the organization of new "banks (a) Principal discretionary power in passing on applications for new charters (l) Exercised by commissioner (2) Exercised by banking board (b) Must be assured of legitimate purpose and/or integrity of applicants (c) Must take into consideration the public need and convenience for banking facilities 8. Powers relevant to banking operations (a) Examinations (1) Required to conduct annual examination (2) Required to conduct examinations more than once a year (3) Authorized to conduct examinations at any time (b) May require stockholders to make good impairment of capital (c) May limit borrowing by banks (d) May require removal of undesirable and/or illegal assets (e) May order removal of offioers or employees (f) May order removal of directors (g) May recommend removal of officers or employees (h) May recommend removal of directors 9. Powers relevant to insolvent banks (a) May liquidate the bank (b) May appoint a receiver (c) May apply for appointment of a receiver 1929-1932 k 31 17 Ik 3^ 6 38 21 15 17 29 39 l&(3) 31 kk 5 12 2 k 15 12 - 6 l g - 3 9 3 37 35 13 k 21 Sources: 1909. George E. Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the National-Bank Act, Vol. VII; and Samuel A. Welldon, Digest of State Banking Statute s. Vol. Ill, Publications of national-.Monetary Commission. 1929-1932, State bank division, American Bankers Association, Results of Questionnaire on Bank Supervision. 1929, prepared by the various State banking departments; and banking statutes of the various States. (2) In many instances data for 1909 only partially available. (3) In kO of these States, at present, regular examinations are also required, while in the other k the frequency of examinations is discretionary. (*> In several States the supervisory authority has the option of liquidating the bank or of applying for the appointment of a receiver, while in one State the option is between appointing and applying for the appointment of a receiver. - 91 - It is apparent from this tabulation that there have been substantial changes in the degree and character of State bank supervision during the past twenty years. It will be clear, also, that in most States the supervisory agencies now have about as much power over the organization of new banks, over the operation of active banks, and over insolvent banks as the Comptroller of the Currency has over national banks. In actual operation it is not to be ex- pected that all State banking' departments would be, at the present time, as effective as the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. Some of these depart- ments are relatively new, and have not yet had time to build up so well trained a staff or so carefully worked out a procedure in regard to examinations and other aspects of supervision as has been done in the comptroller's office. Weakness of State Supervision. - Political pressure has been an important influence in State banking departments. In many States the pay is meager, and the terms of office of supervisors and length of appointment of examiners too short and uncertain to attract capable, qualified men. Some States have too few examiners to examine the banks adequately. In most States, as in the case of national bank supervision, there is no statutory power in the hands of the supervising authority to require the removal of bad assets. Also, few supervisory authorities have any power to enforce the banking laws of the States except by the arbitrary closing of insolvent banks. In some States the liquidation of failed banks is still handled by the courts rather than through the departments of banking, and this has prevented prompt disposal of insolvencies and the development of a good technique for liquidation. - 92 - While the foregoing tabulation indicates in a general way the chief elements of strength and weakness of bank supervision in the various States, a clearer conception of some of these elements may be gleaned from statements of the supervisors themselves. In 1929 the American Bankers Association sent a questionnaire to the supervisory authorities of the forty-eight States which elicited a considerable amount of factual material as to the status of these agencies and their powers, with particular reference to those features which had contributed most to efficiency and those which had weakened effective supervision. The matter of adequate funds with, which to meet the expenses of the banking departments received especial attention. 7/hereas some Statesreported both ample salaries and provision for an adequate staff, about a third stated that they were inadequately financed. One supervisor complained of the rigidity of salaries fixed by statute. Another stated: "Salaries have not been increased to keep step with increases in other walks of life, and it is very difficult to get qualified examiners." Several suggested salary scale revisions for their offices, with increases ranging as high as 100 per cent. In support of these recommendations, it was held that compensation was markedly out of proportion with the degree of responsibility assumed, and that it was impossible to keep capable men in office, for they were continually being attracted to other employment by higher pay. One comment was: - 93 - "Salaries of senior examiners, chief examiner and deputy commissioner should be on a graduating scale equal to the salaries of vice-presidents and treasurers cf large "banking institutions. This will have a greater tendency to hold permanently the men filling these positions, for the reason that experience in this work is an important qualification." A number of supervisors reported thr.t political influence on their departments was strong. One result of this influence was the in- stability of the tenure of office of supervisors, as illustrated by the following re-ply to the questionnaire: "With the exception of 192S no governor has ever been elected for two successive terms which has resulted necessarily in new appointments (of banking department officials) being made every t',70 years." In a number of States stdps were taken to lessen political influence by making the term of office of the supervisor longer than that of the governor, so that the former does not automatically go out of office with the latter. In two States the supervisors were nominated or selected by the bankers, and the examiners in a few States were selected solelj>- on the basis of their experience and fitness. In a number of States the supervisor has duties other than the administration of the banking lav;. In many States he is charged with the supervision of building and loan associations, credit unions, etc., and in some cases with the auditing of public accounts. The effect of such a situation was expressed by one of the supervisors as follows; "The principal element of weakness lies in the fact that the commissioner's duties extend to the administration of the Fraud Act and the supervision of institutions other than banks. It would make for greater efficiencj'- if this department confined its activities to the supervision of banks only," - 91+- In about a third of the States applications for new charters are passed upon by a board, instead of a single official. But no matter what the type of authority, political influence has too often been brought to bear. This state of affairs is described in the following extract from an address delivered in 1923 by Mr. E. H. Wolcott, bank commissioner of Indiana: (1) "In Indiana all applications for a charter for a new bank must be presented to the charter board. When an application is made for a charter the duty of the commission is to have an investigation made to see whether the situation is desirable and whether the men are responsible and capable. That is presented to the charter board when application is made and action is taken. I have been absolutely opposed to certain conditions in banking. One of the conditions that causes us concern in Indiana is the establishment of two small banks in a small town. The competition is too heavy and eventually one bank or the other goes under. We have two banks in towns with only kOO people in it. (sic.) Think of that J Most of the board are candidates for office. An application for a charter is scarely ever made in Indiana unless it is presented by some distinguished lawyer who has influence with some one connected with the charter board. Usually the charter is granted. We are striving to correct that condition and I feel that as the banking department is responsible for the conditions of these banks that the charter should be granted ~by the Commissioner of Banking. » The general impression conveyed by the answers to the questionnaire of 1929» a s well as by other comments of State supervisors, is much the same as that conveyed by the tabulation given Above. That is to say, most of the State supervisory authorities appear to be about as well equipped with legal powers as the national authorities. With a few exceptions, however, there seems to be considerable difference in the exercise of such powers. The quality of supervision may be illustrated for one State by the report of the attorney general after conducting an investigation of the National Association of Supervisors of State Banks, Proceedings of the Twenty-second Annual Convention, 1923, p. 106. _ 95 - department of "banking and finance ordered by the Legislature of South Dakota. In the introduction £° ^ s report the attorney general made the following significant statement:t1' "This" report will show that for the past ten years the true spiriu and intent of .our laws relating to banking have been ignored by the persons' in charge of their administration. The purpose of the Ian iia& been completely subverted. Instead of administering the law for protection of the public it has been administered sole?<y for the benefit of the individual bank corporation. Banks which were hopelessly insolvent have been kept open by deposits of the pttW.ic money, fictitious valuation of assets, and in utter disregard of the plain provisions of the law requiring tanks in unsafe condition to be closed. Liquidation ddt-iylpsed banks has been slow and expensive. Funds of closei banjsshare been used for bolstering up other insolvent bank phere they, were later lost a second time. Dividends were witHssLd from depositors accordingly. The whole system lias been badly infected with politics. The superintendent of banks now in office has, in utter disregard of the spirit of his trust, kopt large sams of closed bank .noney upon deposit in banks at Flatte, South Dakota, on account of his interest in one of said banks; and has deliberately tried to conceal the true facts of Siich deposits from the legislative investigating committee. The Bankers1 Association of the state, aided by the superintendent of banks, lias conducted a vicious legislative lobby during every segsion of the state legislature and as a result every important tanking lav.' enacted since 1915 vrhen the Association was given official recognition has been a law in the interests of the individual bank corporation and against the interests of the public. "We realize.that the foregoing statement is strong and pointed. The following report shows that every statement made is supported by reliable evidence." " ' South Dakota, a/ttorney general, Report and Supplemental Heport to the Legislature of $he Investigation of the Department of Banking and Finance, February 27. 1S3°- _96- It would be impracticable to make anything like a general appraisal of the merits or demerits of State bank supervision. As in the case of banking legislation, wide variations exist among the different States. In a few instances there is some reason to believe that both the State banking laws and the State supervision are of a quality equal to those of the national banking system, but in many States this is not the case. Excessive Granting of Charters One of the most obvious defects in State banking supervision has been manifested in connection with the chartering of new banks; It is true that minimum capital and other legal requirements are beyond the control of supervisory authorities, but in most instances they have considerable discretionary power to grant or refuse charters. State supervisors in general have been in a position to discourage or to further the multiplication of small banks according to their own judgment of sound public policy. But their judgment has been subject to the pressure of the constantly existing competition for numbers and resources of banks between the national and the State systems. The simplest method of increasing the relative importance of their own systems lias been to grant charters for the opening of new State institutions. This phase of competition was described by P. H. Smith, Superintendent of Banks of South Dakota, as follows: (1) (l' National Association of Supervisors of State 3anks, Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention, 1SH9, p; 90* - 97 - "I think perchance one of the greatest dangers that confronted the hanking industry in South Dakota was a contest and conflict "between the national and state systems some five years ago. Each system was fighting the other and, in an effort to win, each was granting charters beyond the interests of the communities. That fight was responsible for much of the failure of banks in the State of South Dakota," Numerous examples can be cited of the overbanked condition which resulted from the excessive granting of charters prior to 1920. A toira. of 1,300 population in Iowa had four banks in 1921. By 1931 only one bank remained in business. A town in South Dakota with a population of 300 had one bank with a State charter when the Comptroller of the Currency granted a national charter for another. The result was two crippled banks. Another South Dakota town of 600 inhabitants had three banks. All failed. One county in North Dakota with a population of 10,000 had IS banks. By the end of 1931 it had. only three. In one Montana county of 1^,000 inhabitants where all towns but the county-seat were under 500 population there were 21 banks, of which only two remained in 1931 > a-1^ both of them were in the county-seat town. The instances cited above are not isolated cases; they are typical of conditions in many agricultural States around 1920, particularly in the Northwest and in the South. In the Western Grain States,(1) for example, the number of incorporated banks (State and national) increased from 2,760 in 1900 to 8,992 in 1920. By the end of 1931 the number had been reduced to ^,878, partly by consolidations but mainly by bank failures. In the South- eastern States (2) the increase was from 519 in 1900 to 2,793 ia 1920, and the number had been reduced by the end of 1931 to 1,389 institutions. The t 1 ' Minnesota, North Dakota, South Dakota, Iowa, Nebraska, Missouri, Kansas. t 2 ' North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Alabama, Mississippi. - 92 - record is of the same character in the Southwestern States, (1) where the number of incorporated hanks rose from 4US in 1900 to 3»2ol in 1920 and then declined to 2,102 by the end of 1931. In 1920, IS States had less than 3»000 persons per bank, and half of these less than 2,000. The latter 9 States constitute a solid block in the Middle West and Northwest, including Minnesota, Iowa, Kansas, Nebraska,. South Dakota, North Dakota, Montana, Wyoming, and Idaho. In 2 of these States, the Dakotas, the population per bank was less than a thousand. This would roughly indicate an average of only two or three hundred individual customers per bank. The great increase in the number of banks took place during a period of rising prices and land values. Under such conditions banks were apparently able to operate regardless of size or the quality of management. This growth in numbers occurred chiefly among State banks which were four times as numerous in 1920 as in 1900, as is shown in Chart 1. The great majority of banks in existence in 1920 were small institutions. Over 6,500 of them had loans and investments of less than $150,000 each, and nearly 19,000 had loans and investments of less than $500,000 each. About S3 P e r cent of these 19,000 small banks were operating under State charter. In addition there were 1, 353 private banks in operation at that time, most of which were also small institutions. Small communities boasted of the number of banks in their midst. In North Dakota the attempt to check the opening of new banks by raising the $10,000 minimum capital requirement was defeated in every legislative session for eight years prior to 1915 on. the ground that existing banks were trying (1) Lovdsiana, Texas, Arkansas, Oklahoma. - 99 - to monopolize the "banking "business. In 1915* however, a compromise "bill was enacted requiring a minimum of $15,000 instead of the $20,000 recommended by the governor in his message.(1) In Iowa somewhat later a committee of hankers ("both State and national) undertook to persuade the State legislatv,re to restrict the chartering of new "banks, "but the legislature in effect laughed at the committee and took the position that more competition was desirable. It did, however, enact a war emergency measure temporarily authorizing the superintendent to restrict the grant of new charters. (2) Supervisory authorities in this situation might have "been expected to use at least the discretionary power at their command to restrict the excessive organization of new "banks. In some cases they did foresee the dangers of too many small institutions. Occasional notes of warning of an overbanked condition "began to appear in the annual reports of the supervisors in certain States as early as 1910. Similar expressions of apprehension, coupled with recommendations that more power "be given the supervisors to refuse charters, were more frequent in later reports.(3) CJuite apart from the sometimes inadequate powers of the supervisory authorities, ho\7evcr, they were subjected not only to the pressure of public opinion, "but often also to strong political influence in behalf of would-be bankers. Moreover, in the absence of authority to permit large banks to establish branches in small communities, it was frequently the case that such communities could be provided with the banking service they wanted only through the opening of new local banks. Thus the supervisory authorities were often (1) The North Dakota Banker, July, 1915, p. 7. ^2) n , n . Preston, History of Banking in Iowa, p. 199 ff• O ) See, for example, reports of State banking departments: Oklano-na, 1910 and 19lU; Souta Dakota, I9I3-I91U; Minnesota, 1912, 1913-I91H, and 1915; Missouri, 1912; North Dakota, 19lU. - 100 - faced with difficult problems, even without the competitive situation inherent in the dual control of banking. With that competitive situation added, the proper performance of their duties was rendered well-nigh impossible. Promoters of ne-w "banks were sometimes able to play one supervisory agency against the other. One authority was made to understand that if he refused a charter the proposed institution would he opened in any case with a charter from the other supervisory authority. All too often, consequently, a charter was issued for a community which could not support a bank or in which banking facilities were already ample. Many charters were granted with little or no regard to the qualifications of the applicants. Frequently the men running the new institutions knew very little about the principles or practices of banking. Many banks of this sort were not only foredoomed to failure but they were also likely to imperil the existence of other banking institutions. Some of the results of indiscriminate chartering of banks and the resulting competition were stated as follows "by the Study Commission for Indiana Financial Institutions: (1) "Authorities are unanimously agreed that the indiscriminate chartering of banks has been one of the major causes for the difficulties through which we have recently passed. Receivers, liquidating agents, and other persons familiar with the affairs of failed banks suggested, in 41 instances, that bank failures in Indiana have been due to improper chartering. . . . Intimate knowledge of individual failures, however, leads to the inescapable conclusion that many of the practices leading to bank failures, were directly caused "by 'cut-throat' competition which sprang up in various communities as a result of too many banks or of the chartering, often for direct or indirect political reasons, of 'spite' banks. "Instances are known in Indiana of new bank charters being sought and obtained by church groups, lodge groups, or political groups antagonistic to the church group, lodge group or political ^ Report of Study Commission for Indiana Financial Institutions. 1932, p. S7. - 101 - group in control of the existing institutions. In numerous instances from 1920 to 1932, villages of less than 500 people had two or more hanks operating. Competition in such communities necessarily was hitter "because it was nothing less than a death struggle between the contending business groups, and consequently desperate chances were taken nearly always making for "bad hanking practice. In some instances, hankers with long records of successful management were driven "by the emergency in which they found themselves to take 'long' chances and to indulge in practices not sanctioned by sound banking management. "Many of the new banks that were chartered between 1910 and 192U were chartered by groups not in sympathy with the conservative or anti-inflationary policies of existing institutions. Daring this period in which the most rapid increase in "banking units took place in Indiana, much •inflation-madness' was apparent throughout the state. If certain groups were unable to satisfy their demands for banking facilities at one bank, they would threaten to take their business to competing banks where perhaps more agreeable treatment in the matter of borrowing awaited them. Many customers borrowed from several banks, but allowed each banker to think that he alone was advancing them credit. If all the bankers in a community were 'old-fashioned' and 'unreasonable', the usual procedure was to start a new bank by way of protest, a bank that would be unfettered by 'old fogey ideas' as to the caution with which banks should be operated. "As time went on and inflation increased, deposits in all institutions mounted steadily, iunds accumulated faster than loan applications were made, and consequently competition for loans was keen. Equities seemed always to increase. As a result the new and oftentimes untried and unsound bank executive appeared to succeed as well or even better than the more experienced and conservative executive. It was not surprising, therefore, that many seasoned bankers were swept into this mad maelstrom of reckless and 'cut-throat' competition." CHAPTER VI MOTIVES FOR CHOICE OF CHARTERS It was indicated in Chapter II, Table 8 particularly, that the growth of loans and investments of State "banks was considerably greater in the decade from 1920 to 193^ than the growth of the loans and investments of national hanks. The greatest growth was among State member banks and trust companies, the loans and investments of which increased $5»395»000,000 against $4,202,000,000 for national banks, and $1,216,000,000 for nonmember State banks and trust companies. On a percentage basis the greater growth of the State member banks was even more striking. Their loans and investments increased nearly 7^ per cent, while those of national banks increased only about 2k per cent and those of nonmembers increased only 17 per cent. In all these cases the greatest growth was among the largest banks. The Effect of Consolidations and Conversions As a means of obtaining a partial measure of the extent to which the shifting of banks from one system to the other has been responsible for differing rates of growth of various classes of banks, a list has been made of the more important instances of conversions since 1920 from national to State charter, and vice versa* This list, which is given in the appendix (Table III) includes not only direct conversions from national to State or from State to national charter, but also mergers of national and State banking insitutions. In view of the difficulty of obtaining data regarding the mergers of small banks, or the absorption of small banks by large banks, the list has - 102 - - 103 "been limited to the larger institutions. All consolidations and conversions are included in which the disappearing hanks had $5,000,000 or more of loans and investments. from this list a tabulation has "been made et aggregate loans and investments lost to the national system and gained hy the State system through conversions from national to State charters and through the absorption of national hanks by State chartered institutions.; and likewise, of the aggregate loans and investments lost by the State systems and gained by the national system as a result of conversions from State to national charter and of the absorption of State banks and trust companies by national banks.^-W results of these tabulations are given in Table ih e lh. Table l4 - Aggregate Loans and Investments of Large Banks Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, by States, 1921-193l(2) State geographic division New England Maine Massachusetts Rhode Island Connecticut Middle Atlantic New York New Jersey Pennsylvania Maryland District of Columbia North Central Michigan Wisconsin Illinois Indiana Ohio (in thousands of dollars) National charters given up State charters given up By By By By conversion consolidation confersion consolidation 75,784 7,327 20,775 19,ISO 28,442 2.305,1+03 2,027,114 93,15^ 125,747 59,328 8.109 8,109 •>• 1 20,476 13,786 6,690 ••• *•• *•• 4M* 54,646 1,031,693 671,938 305,109 178.955 20.56S 166,596 20,568 12,359 1.158,783 1,009,524 57,133 82,54l 15,835 15,835 *•* 9,585 826.269 472,696 34,126 234,418 15,930 69,099 31,064 10,713 20,351 vl' The shrinkage of loans and investments often experienced upon the consolidation of banks has not been taken into consideration. Because of this shrinkage the gains to each system are probably less than the respective losses to the other. - io4 - Table l4 - Aggregate Loans and Investments of Large Banks Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, "by States, 1921-193l(2) (Continued) State *y geographic division (in thousands of dollars) State charters given up National charters given up By By By By conversion consolidation consolidation conversion 57,356 Southern Mountain Virginia Kentucky Tennessee 44,424 12,932 : 1+7,062 Southeastern North Carolina South Carolina Georgia Florida Alabama Mississippi ...19.585 13,484 26,309 6,101 26,309 61,237 74,645 . 27,973 20,952 12,312 50,754 24,219 9,132 13,711 | •Ml Southwestern Louisiana Texas 29,282 10,514 19,368 Western Grain Minnesota Iowa Missouri Kansas 10,878 13,013 20,192 •Ml mm mm 20,192 186,766 186,766 95,395 13,89^ 6,863 74,638 mm 31,447 26,233 mm 5,214 Rocky Mountain Colorado mm Pacific Coast Oregon California UNITED STATES 258,824 ** 258,824 t Total 1921-1930 Occurring in 1931 Total 1921-1931 (iy Table 8,970 mm 3.992,770 28,585 •3,291,526 129.829 4,021,355 I 891,944 18,195 273,7^9 541,517 3,232,168 770,547 541.517 3,504,172 4,002,715 based on data concerning banking changes collected by the Committee on Branch, Group, and Chain Banking, supplemented by records of the Federal Reserve Board, Division of Bank Operations, and Hand McNally Bankers Directory. Since the Directory figures appear only every six months, loans and investments at time of consolidation or conversion may have differed from those included above in some cases. Table includes only those banks with loans and investments of $5,000,000 or more at the time of conversion oaf consolidation. - 105 - While neither the period nor the data covered by Ta"ble lk are identical with those covered "by Table 8 (Chapter II), they are nearly enough alike to give a rough indication of the degree to which charter changes account for the changes in the aggregate loans and investments of State and of national tanks, respectively. The total growth during the decade from June 30» 1920, to June 30, 1930, in the loans and investments of large State banks (those shown in Table 8 with more than $10,000,000 of loans and investments) amounted to approximately eight and a half billion dollars, and that of large national banks to nearly four billion dollars. In comparison with this, the net gains to the State banks, and conversely, the net losses to national banks, from charter changes during the decade from January 1, 1921 to December 31, 1930, as indicated by Table lh, amounted to less than half a billion dollars. It is evident therefore that the greater growth of State banks xias not accounted for by the shift of banks from national to State charter. In the list of charter conversions and consolidations referred to above there were 119 national banks absorbed by State banks or trust companies and k converted directly from national to State charters, with loans and investments of $3,992,770,000 and $28,585,000, respectively. All four of the converted banks became nonmembers, and 29 of the absorbed banks were consolidated with nonmembers. The loans and investments of the banks lost to the Federal reserve system by these conversions and consolidations amounted to $hl6,770,000. Accordingly, of the $^,021,355,000 of loans and investments which Table lk shows wa3 lost by the national banking system, only $Ul6,770,000, or about 10 per cent, was also lost by the Federal reserve system. About sixty per cent of the State - 106 - "banks turning to national charters *©re already members -of the system. The regional character of the shift from national to State, and from State to national charters is also shown by the figures in Table lh. The net loss to the national system was greatest in New York, Illinois, and Ohio in the eleven year period because of conversions and consolidations. The State systems lost most heavily in California and Michigan* Ho special investigation has been made to determine the type of State charters taken out in the case of conversions from national charters, nor the type of State charter held "by the institutions absorbing national banks. In all but a very few cases, however, the succeeding institution had the word "trust" in its title, indicating that in nearly all cases the charters issued were of the trust company rather than the commercial bank type, or at least that the new institution possessed fiduciary powers. The McPadden Act, passed in 1927, was designed to stop the movement of banking business from national to State banks by giving national banks a number of additional powers, and making their charters of indeterminate length, instead of ninety-nine years. This latter provision was expected to be of considerable advantage in the exercise of fiduciary powers, for the fact that national banks had not been chartered in perpetuity had militated against their appointment as trustees. To indicate what the effect of the McFadden Act has been, the basic data shown in Table lk are presented in Table 15 by years, instead of by States. - 107 - Table 15 - Aggregate Loans and Investments of Large Banks Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation- and Conversion: "by Years, 1921-1931(1) Year 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 National cll a r t e r s given up S t a t e c h a r t e r s given up Loans and Loans and Number Number investments investments (000 omitted) (000 omitted) 11 3 12 Total 1Q21-1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 Total 1927-1931 $ $ 57.6U2 84,035 104,073 108,850 91,001 169,228 6 4 565,^23 70J24 23SJ52 123,500 93,272 2k 359,533 50 $i,45i,204 32 $614,829 9 16 27 15 $ 15 18 17 8 7 4 I J. 117,177 309,773 1,844,416 153,951 129,829 JL $ ,982,070 356,248 637,359 913,666 498,543 73 $2,560,151 65 $3,387,886 TTJ Banks with loans and investments of $5,000,000 or more at time of conversion or consolidation. Source of data same as for Table l4. It will be seen that, measured in loans and investments, the losses suffered by the national system through surrender of large bank charters in the six years prior to the passage of the LIcFadden Act were counterbalanced by an almost equal gain in the succeeding five years. In the six years pre- ceding passage of the act, the national system suffered a net loss of $846,375,000 through conversion of large banks (i.e., the difference between $1,461,204000 belonging to large banks which gave up national charters, and $614,329,000 belonging to larger banks which gave up St: ;e charters); whereas in the six succeeding years, the State systems suffered a net loss of $327,735,000 (i.e., the difference between $3,387,886,000 belonging to large banks vhich gave up State charters and $2,560,151,000 belonging to large banks which gave up ~ lOg - national charters). This "bears out what has already "been said to the effect that charter conversions of large banks do not account for the relatively larger growth of State "banks and trust companies compared to national "banks in the eleven year period. The greater growth of State "banks as a whole, therefore, must have "been due to new organizations and to the more rapid growth of individual institutions with State charters. Eeasons for Charter Preferences Although the factors which have "been responsible for the more rapid growth of State "banks have not led to wholesale conversions of national hanks into State institutions, it is possible to determine in a general way some of the more important of these factors by listing the motives for the charter changes which have occurred. To secure aa accurate information as possible in regard to the reasons for charter preferences, the Committee has made special inquiries in the case of a considerable number of charter conversions and consolidations of national banks with State banks or trust companies. These inquiries were addressed to the various Federal reserve agents, and forwarded in many cases to officials of the banks concerned. In other cases the Federal reserve agents were sufficiently familiar with the circumstances to reply directly to the Committee's inquiry. The cases of charter conversions and consolidations were chosen from the list referred to in the preceding paragraphs and reproduced in full in the appendix.(1) They included all cases in that list of direct conversion from State to national, or national to State charter, and all consolidations in which the consolidating banks were approximately the same size or in which the charter of the smaller bank was retained. - 109 - After omitting the instances in which the motive for consolidation had no apparent connection with the competition "between the various classes of hanking institutions, 6l cases remained. Of these 6l cases, State charters were chosen or retained in the case of 45, and national charters in the other l6. Inquiry was not made as to whether the State charters chosen or retained were trust company charters or "bank charters. The titles of the banks, however, and the character of the correspondence indicate that most of them were trust company charters. In only 2 cases did the succeeding insitution fail to have the word "trust" in its title. The motives given for the choice or retention of national or State charters, respectively, are indicated in Table 160 In most of the cases several motives were involved, and in only a few cases has it "been possible to he sure which was the primary one. The table shows, therefore, only the number of times each motive was reported to have been a significant influence. Because of the extensive changes in the powers of national banks made early in 1927 by the passage of the Mcfadden Act, the conversions and consolidations during the period 1921-1926 have been separated from those during the period 1927-1931* - 110 ~ Table l6 - Motives for the Choice of National or State Charters in 6l Conversions and Consolidations, I92I-I93I 1921-1926 1927-1931 Total Direct Direct Consoli- conver- Consoli1921-1931 converdations sions dations sions National charters; chosen Humber of cases Number of times the following motives appeared: Prestige of national banks Prospective branch banking Economy (taxation) To escape State supervision Good-will value of name 16 1 1 7 7 10 — 7 3 3 2 1 - 1 - 1 1 - k 1 - _. "5 u 1 State charters chosen Number of cases Number of times each motive was mentioned: Branch .and group banking: Branches Ownership of bank stocks Loan and investment powers? Real estate mortgage loans Limits on individual loans Ownership of corporate stock or other investment privileges Non-banking powers: fiduciary powers Securities underwriting and merchandising Title insurance Broader powers in general: Under special charters Under trust company charters Economy: Nonmembership in Federal reserve system Taxation Changes in forms To escape federal supervision Good-will value of name *5 2 23 10 2 - 11 - g 2 ,, 3 3 19 - 2 IS 6 1 3 - - 2 1 - 2 1 2 1 )i t 10 - 9 2 2 ,, - 2 1 _ — 3 - 3 8 ~ — 12 Lt 1 — k 1 l 1 13 „ «• 1 tt - 1 »•* - — 2 k 2 7 — 5 5 2 — 1 - Ill - Choice of National Charters According to this analysis, the most important motive for choosing a national instead of State charter is the greater prestige of the national banks. Out of the 16 banks which chose to convert from State to national banks, or upon consolidation, to retain national rather than State charters, 10 mentioned the superior standing of the national banks in the eyes of the communities and customers to be served. In k cases the name of the specific national bank was believed to have more good-mil value. In 7 cases where banks chose to operate under State charter the good-will of the name was mentioned. Choice of State Charters Fiduciary Powers. - The motive most frequently mentioned for choosing a State charter was the greater or more secure fiduciary powers held by State banks, this having been mentioned in 19 out of the U5 cases. Of these, 10 were conversions or consolidations occurring prior to 1927 » and 9 occurring since the beginning of 1927«> Preference for exercising fiduciary powers under State charter appeared as a motive more often in Hew York and Ohio than elsewhere. The predominance of this motive may appear surprising, in view of the amendment to the Federal Reserve Act of September 26, 19IS, and especially in view of the clause relating to trust powers in the McFadden Act. It is desirable, therefore, to consider somewhat more fully than hither- to the fiduciary powers of national banks. The amendment to the Federal Reserve Act approved on September 26, 1913, provided for additional trust powers to national banks. ^ ' Fifth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board, 1918, p.262. It gives the - 112 - Federal Reserve Beard power: "(k) To grant by special permit to national "banks applying therefor, when not in contravention of State or local law, the right to act as trustee, executor, administrator, registrar of stocks and bonds, guardian of estates, assignee, receiver, coiranittee of estates of lunatics, or in any other fiduciary capacity in which State banks, trust companies, or other corporations which come into competition vith national banks are permitted to act under the laws of the State in which the national bank is located. "Whenever the laws of such State authorize or permit the exercise of any or all of the foregoing powers by State banks, trust companies, or other corporations v/hich compete with national banks, the granting to and the exercise of such powers by national banks shall not be deemed to be in contravention of State or local law within the meaning of this act." There appear to have been several important questions which arose in regard to the exercise of fiduciary powers by national banks under the provisions of this act. In the first place, the phrase, "when not in con- travention of State or local law," led to difficulties because of the applicability to national banks of various State laws regarding duties imposed upon trustees or other fiduciaries. A second problem arose because of the limited charter of national banks, which at that time was for twenty years only. National banks could not accept trusts for a period of time beyond the expiration date of their charters, since they had no power to enter into contracts to perform any kind of service after those dates. After the passage on July 1, 1922, of the amendment extending the charters of national banks to 99 years, this difficulty became less serious, since most trusts would be completely terminated within that time. But it was not even then possible to accept trusts of indeterminate length, particularly those which might extend beyond the charter period. This difficulty was not, therefore, entirely removed until - 113 - the passage of the McFadden Act, which made national hank charters perpetual. Moreover, the question as to whether or not the corporate identity of a State chartered trust company ceased when it was absorbed by a national bank was an important one. If it did cease, all trusts naming the trust company as trustee automatically became vacated, and the court would have to make new appointments of trustees. Upon this question there appears to have been disagreement. The Comptroller of the Currency, in 1927, in reply to an inquiry from a bank which wished to take out a national charter, stated that he had no doubt but that "all the trust business automatically goes over under the national jurisdiction. . . . The courts have held that the corporate entity of the State bank continues, there being only an exchange of jurisdictions."") The contrary opinion is expressed in the following quotation from a letter written in January, 1927, by the legal advisor to a trust company that was contemplating a merger with a national bank. "If the Trust Company, a (State) Corporation, went into voluntary liquidation as would necessarily be the case if it were absorbed by or merged with the National Bank, we are clearly of the opininion (as was Mr. i when this matter came up for discussion at various times during the past eight or nine years) that all Wills and Trust agreements now executed naming the ( Trust Company, would, if not voluntarily changed so as to specifically name the national Bank, be of no value so far as the , . ^ Trust Company is concerned. This is true because the National Bank could in no sense be considered as the same Corporation as the Trust Company ******** nor could the National Bank be considered as a successor of the Trust Company so as to be entitled, or claim to be the company designated in such Wills and Trust agreements as the Trust Company. In addition, if the Trust Company went '•*•) In support of this opinion the comptroller cited the following three cases: Metropolitan National Bank v. Claggett 1^1 U. S. 520; City National Bank of Poughkeepsie v. Phelos 97 N. Y. kk; and In re: (Turner^ Estate, 120 Atl. 701. - Ilk- into liquidation "by reason of an absorption or merger as above outlined, automatically all of the Trusts which it now administers as the Trust Company would he without a Trustee, and it would then he up to the Probate Court to appoint a successor Trustee, and as you very well see, the Probate Court might or might not appoint the National Bank in our arrangement, in view of the fact that the Trust Company had voluntarily disqualified itself from administering such Trusts, a very considerable portion of such business would be lost to the National Bank. " Other comments in this connection are the following: "On account of a peculiarity of the law, as relating to private trusts, it, in the event the trust company should be succeeded by another institution, would give to the beneficiaries of a trust, the right to change the trustee, and for this reason, it would probably be necessary, when the consolidation was effected, to liquidate the national Bank." "The Trust Company of i had a large volume of trust bu.sincsa and a number of Wills in their vaults which could not then or now be transferred to a national bank without the consent of the parties interested." When the McFadden Act was drafted, it was hoped that provisions could be included which would solvo some of these questions. The act included the following language: (1) "• • . any bank incorporated under the laws of any State, or any bank incorporated in the District of Columbia, may be consolidated with a national banking association located in the same county, city, town, or village under the charter of such national banking association. . . all the rights, franchises, and interests of such State or District Bank so consolidated with a national banking association in and to every species of property, real, personal, and mixed, and choses in action thereto belonging, shall be deemed to be transferred to and vested in such national banking association into which it is consolidated without any deed or other transfer, and the said consolidated national banking association shall hold and enjoy the same and all rights of property, franchises, and interests including the right of succession as trustee, executor, or in any other fiduciary capacity in the same manner and to the same extent as was held and enjoyed by such State or District bank so consolidated with such national banking association . . . No such consolidation shall be in contravention of the law of the State under which such bank is incorporated. fourteenth Annual Report of the federal Reserve Board, 1927, pp. 258, - 115- "The words 'State "bank,* 'State banks,' 'bank,' or 'banks,' as used in this section, shall be held to include trust companies, savings "banks, or other such corporations or institutions carrying en the hanking "business under the authority of State laws." The Worcester Case. ~ The question dealt with in this statute was promptly tested "by the Worcester County national Bank case in Massachusetts in 1923-1S29. The Pitchburg Bank & Trust Company, a State institution of Massachusetts, and the Merchants National Bank of Worcester had consolidated on June 27, 1927, under the name of the '.forcester County National Bank. In the spring of 192S the Worcester County National Bank filed in the probate court of the county an account of its executorship of one of the wills of which the predecessor trust company had "been executor. The question was then raised as to whether the national "bank had automatically succeeded to the executorship, when it had absorbed the trust company, or whether the executorship had been vacated by the disappearance of the predecessor trust company, which had been named as executor. It is clear that the McFadden Act intended that national banks should succeed automatically to trusteeship in cases of consolidation. The case filed in the Massachusetts courts involved the question whether or not, under the State law, this succession was true in practice. There were two parts to this question. In the first place, the McPadden Act provided that no consolidation between a national bank and a State bank or trust company should be in contravention of the State law under which such bank was incorporated. The State law regarding bank consolidations had therefore to be examined, to see whether it forbade the succession of these powers. In the second place, the property of deceased persons is a matter subject to the jurisdiction of State lav/, and the laws regarding trusteeship of such property had to be - n6 examined, to see whether the succession of the national bank to the trusteeship conformed to Massachusetts law. In regard to the consolidation of banks, the Massachusetts law read as follows! "The charter of a trust company, the business of which shall, on or after July 1, 1922, be consolidated or merged with, or absorbed by, another bank or trust company, shall be void except for the purpose of discharging existing obligations and liabilities." In the light of this law, the Supreme Judicial Court of Massachusetts held that the trust company had gone out of existence and all of its property had become the property of the consolidated bank, which was an enlargement of a continuously existing national bank. That is, the corporate identity of the trust company had not been continued, but had been extinguished. The ques- tion still remained, however, whether the trusteeship was property which had become the property of the national bank, or whether its exercise was a continuance of an obligation or liability existing at the time of consolidation. With respect to these questions the court held that the appointment of an executor is a strictly confidential relationship, is not contractual, is not a property right of the fiduciary, and involves no pecuniary interest on the part of the fiduciary. The succeeding national bank had, therefore, no obligations or liabilities in respect to the executorship, flowing from its succession to the property of the trust company, no longer in existence. In regard to the law governing the trusteeship of the property of a deceased person, the Supreme Judicial Court of Massachusetts held that the appointment of an executor is a function of the probate court. This authority before appointing an executor, administrator, trustee, or other fiduciary must inquire carefully as to his character, integrity, soundness - 117 - of judgment, and general capacity. An appointment should follow only after a favorable finding, regardless of whether the fiduciary is an individual or a trust company or a national "bank. The probate court had never made such an examination of the Worcester County National Bank, and had not appointed that hank as executor. The decision held, moreover, that the appointment of fiduciaries to administer trusts and the settlement of estates is a subject within the exclusive jurisdiction of the States. No clause of the Constitution of the United States confers upon Congress any such power, which is among those reserved to the States "by Article 10 of the amendments. The automatic recognition of the Worcester County National Bank as executor of the estate would amount to the appointment of an executor by Congressional legislation. This would be in contravention of Massachusetts law, under which the State judiciary is the only authority with ptwer to appoint. The Supreme Judicial Court of Massachusetts thus held that the executorship was vacated at the time of the absorption of the Fitchburg Bank and Trust Company, and that the Worcester County National Bank was not the executor of the estate in question. The national bank could apply for appointment as executor, and the probate court could, if it so desired, make the appointment. The case was appealed to the Supreme Court of the United States, (1) which confirmed the decision of the Massachusetts court. In several consolidations occurring since 1927, this decision has influenced bank officials to choose a State charter for the amalgamated institution. The following statements indicate this* "We were influenced largely by the 'Massachusetts Case,1 fearing we could not, by a national charter for the new instiC 1 ) Ex parte Worcester County National Bank of Worcester, 279 U- -S. 3^+7, on appeal from 2S3 Mass. wkt 1S2 N. E. 217, and. the Federal Reserve Bulletin. Vol. XV, June, 1929, p-o. 407-409. - 118 - tution, protect and conserve successor executorship and successor trusteeship." "It was hoped that the merger might be effected under the national hank charter • . ., hut this has "been found impracticable on account of the decision of the Supreme Court of the United States in the Worcester County national Bank case." In other cases the situation created by this decision has been important, even though the decision was not specifically mentioned by bank officials in giving their motives for choosing State charters. The following are examples: "Our reason for withdrawing from the System is the fact that there is some considerable doubt in the minds of our Counsel as to whether or not we can legally transfer the trust estates of the Trust Company into a national Bank, Both on account of the amount involved, which is considerable, and of the duty we owe to the beneficiaries of the trusts, we cannot take any changes." "The impelling reason was that the latter bank (a State trust company) had a great many trust funds, a number of which were quite large, and some of its leading officers and directors were of the opinion that it would be better to continue to have such trusts administered by an institution organized and operating under the laws of this State." The actual effect of the decision in the Worcester County national Bank case differs from State to State. Some State laws provide that upon the consolidation of State banks and trust companies with each other and with national banks, the successor bank shall inherit the banking and fiduciary powers of the absorbed institution and that the corporate identity of the absorbed bank is not extinguished by such consolidation. In these States the problem of successor executorship or successor trusteeship in the case of a national bank is not as important as in those jurisdictions where the legal situation is analogous to that in Massachusetts. Loan and Investment Powers. - In 11 out of the U5 cases where State - 119 - charters were chosen or retained, the less severe reetrSctions on real estate or mortgage loans were mentioned as a reason for preferring the State charter. Of these, 8 were prior to and 3 subsequent to the passage of the McFadden Act enlarging the powers of national hanks in making real estate loans. In 3 of the 45 cases, 2 in the same State, the larger limit permitted on loans to single borrowers was mentioned. Three mentioned the privilege of o\7ning corporate stock or the wider latitude allowed in bank investments. Supervision. - Escape from Federal supervision is given as a cause for the choosing of State charters in 13 cases, and escape from State supervision in 1. The latter case was one where State supervision was objected to not because it was in general to strict, but because according to allegation it was grossly unfair to the bank in question. Only part of the 1J cases in which escape from Federal supervision is listed were so reported by the banks concerned; in others it was simply remarked that the requirements of the State examiner were less severe than those of the national examiner. This category also includes cases where the examination records of the national banks showed that the banks had been unwilling to accept the recommendations of the national examiners, and cooperate with the office of the comptroller in the maintenance of banking standards. In many of these cases the national banks *>7ere in bad condition at the time of the merger as a result of policies persisted in despite the recommendations of the national examiner and the office of the comptroller. Branch and Group Banking Powers. - Of the ^5 conversions and consolidations which obtained or retained State charters, branch banking was an important element in 10 cases. Of these, 6 occurred prior to the passage of - 120 - the MclFadden Act, and were, apparently, mostly cases where it was desired to open additional hanking offices within the city of the parent hank. The other k have occurred since the beginning of 1S27, and have heen cases where the consolidating hanks were located in different towns and wished to retain all offices, or where the amalgamated hank wished to establish out-of-town branches. In 2 of these cases the bank officials added that they much pre- ferred to operate under national charter^ and regretted that consolidations could be made only by means of State charters. In 2 cases the power to hold bank stocks, so as to head a group of banks, was an important element. Among those choosing national charters, there were 3 cases where the prospect of broader branch banking powers being given to national banks appeared as a motive. In one of these cases a group banking system operated in a State which prohibited s^sta-wide branch banking, and the bank managers were of the opinion that they would be able to convert their subsidiary banks into branches through a modification of the Federal law sooner than through a modification of the State law. Branch banking power was a motive for choosing a State charter in New York in several cases. One case involving this motive appeared in each of 6 other States. Underwriting and Merchandising of Securities. - In 2 cases the broader po-aers of State banks in respect to the underwriting and merchandising of securities were mentioned, one of them emphasizing the underwriting of securities and the other the business of dealing in securities. In view of the wide extent of the practice of dealing in securities by banks and the limitations upon these powers in the McFadden Act, it is noteworthy that this reason was mentioned only twice. - 121 - Insurance Business. - Two banks mentioned title insurance departments which had "been maintained "by the merging State institution. Broader Forcers in General. - In 15 cases the "broader powers which could "be exercised under State charters wore mentioned in general terms. These include: ,(*) cases in which no specific powers were mentioned; ("b) cases in which one or more specific powers were mentioned, and the phrase "broader powers" or its equivalent added; and (c) cases where more liberal lending and investing powers were mentioned, without specifying the point of liberality. These broader powers undoubtedly refer in most cases to powers mentioned elsewhere in the table. In 3 of the 15 cases the broader powers were those exercised under charters granted by special acts of State legislatures early in the century. It is possible that this is true also in other cases. In all the other cases, the State institution was operating under a trust company charter or at least used the word "trust" in its title. It is clear that in nearly all, if not all, of these cases the broader powers were those granted to State trust companies, rather than to State commercial banks. Economy. - One bank stated that as a national bank it would escape certain taxes imposed on State banks, and that this entered into the decision to operate under a national charter. Three banks, on the contrary, reported economies in continuing to operate under State charter* one on account of smaller taxes, one because of the relinquishment of Federal reserve membership and the cost of maintaining idle reserves, and the other because of the cost of making the necessary changes on all of the forms used in the trust division of the bank's operations. CHAPTER VII SUMMABT The division of authority "between, the national and State governments in chartering and supervising hanks has "been an important factor in: (l) the granting of an excessive number of charters and the consequent establishment of too many small "banks; (2) the relaxing of the standards set up in the National Bank Act for commercial banks and the gradual extension of the powers of national banks; (3} the retarding of the development of effective standards of supervision in both State and national systems; and (h) the hampering of the work of the Federal reserve banks in maintaining proper standards for membership and in promoting sound banking policy. Excessive Chartering of Banks The rapid growth in the number of banks in the country between the middle eighties and 1920 resulted in part from a number of favorable economic factors and in part from the competition between the State and national banking systems in the granting of charters. Prices and land values were rising during the greater part of the period and the agricultural communities were increasingly prosperous. Bank profits were relatively high during the early years of this century. The growth in the number of small banks had legislative encouragement in the lax provisions of State laws, permitting in some States the organization of incorporated banks with capital as low as $10,000, and in one State with a capital of only $5,000. In fact several States had no capital requirements at all for many years. There was little restraint upon - 122 - 121 - the number of new tank organizations. .Authorities in several States were without legal power to deny an application for a charter, even where they felt it was desirable to do so. In some States there was no hanking depart- ment until well into the present century, and charters might be issued by judges or other officials whose main responsibilities lay in other fields. An important factor in the increase in the number of small banks, however, was the competition between the State and national systems in the granting of charters. One of the first efforts of the national system to meet the competition of State banks was the reduction in 1Q00 of the minimum capital requirement from $50,000 to $25,000. After that there was a rapid growth in the number of both national and State banks but the number of State banks continued to increase more rapidly, as shown in the chart on page 5» By 1920 there were two and one-half times as many State banks In operation as national banks. The national supervisory authorities, as well as those of some of the States, have long been empowered to refuse charters at their discretion, if for any reason the proposed banks were not deemed reasonably certain of becoming sound and stable institutions. Bat both classes of supervisory agencies have been solicitous for the relative importance in numbers and resources of the banks under their respective jurisdictions, and this fact has had an important bearing upon the exercise of their dis-* cretionary powers. Too many banks were chartered in communities which could not support a bank or in communities in which banking facilities were already ample. Many towns ranging in population from 200 to 1,000 had two or three banks or even more. In fact this was not an uncommon condition in many - 124 - agricultural States around 1920. In the entire TTestern Grain States, for example, the population per "bank was only 1,3^3 ^cL i n ^e two Dakotas the population per bank was less than 1,000 as contrasted with a population of nearly 10,000 per "bank in Hew England. The great majority of "banks in existence in 1920 were small institutions. Over 6,500 of them had loans and investments of less than $150,000 each, and nearly 19,000 had loans and investments of less than $500,000 each. About S3 -per cent of these 19,000 small banks were operating under State charter. In addition there were about 1,350 private banks in operation at that time, most of which were also small institutions. Charters were granted frequently with little or no regard to the qualifications of the applicants. In many cases the men running these banks knew little about the principles or practices of banking. Many of the new banks wore not only foredoomed to failure but yore also li^ly to imperil the existence of other banking institutions. The establishment of such largo numbers of small banks has in itself presented many problems, the principal of which are the difficulties of mailing adequate earnings, of providing reasonably competent management, and the inherent difficulties of exercising proper supervision over a large number of small institutions. Some indication of the consequences of the small capital requirements for banks may be had from the fact that, of the 1,33^ national banks which suspended in the eleven year period 1921-1931» no less than 5ty}, or over ko per cent of the total, were institutions with capital of under $50,000, Of the combined total of S,9l6 national and State banks which suspended during the same period, 5§927» or over 6~[ per cent, had capital - 125 - of less than $50,000. The assumption would not "be justified that all these smaller "banks would have avoided suspension had their size "been larger; there have "been other elements of weakness in the "banking structure, attributable also in large part to dual control, which have affected large and small "banks alike. Many fairly large institutions, with capital up to $500,000 and more, have suspended? but the fact remains that the very small "banks have "been particularly vulnerable. In chartering large numbers of small institutions the banking departments have created vested interests which now make up the strongest element in opposition to the measures proposed for strengthening the banking structure. Numerically the small banks are the dominant part of the various banking associations and their political influence is great. Banks with loans and investments of less than $500,000 each still constituted well over half of the banks in the country in I93O when the latest classification of all banks by size was made. Relaxation of Restrictionsi on National Banks Lowering the minimum capital requirement in 1900 was the first important measure of the national banking system to meet the competition of State banks. Another occurred in 1913 when the Federal Reserve Act authorized national banks not situated in reserve or central reserve cities to make loans on improved and unencumbered farm land within their Federal reserve districts. Prior to 1913 national banks had ^eon forbidden to make loans, against the security of real estate. State banks everywhere could do so» ~ 126 - however, and in most instances without any stipulated restrictions as to the amount of the loans, their duration, or the quality of the mortgages securing them. The prohibition against real estate loans "by national hanks was removed in 1913 with respect to farm land, and in the course of the ensuing fourteen years, culminating with the passage of the Mcfadden Act in 1927, restrictions were further relaxed, until finally all national hanks were permitted to make loans against any kind of improved real estate for periods up to five years and in aggregate amounts up to $0 per cent of their time deposits. While the tendency to invest funds in long-term loans of a capital nature was accelerated "by the growth of time deposits in hanks doing "both a commercial and savings "business, these deposits have almost invariahly "been payable and actually paid on demand. This is true not only in the United States "but also in England and Canada, In the latter countries, however, the fact that time deposits in commercial banks are in effect payable on demand is recognized as of basic importance in determining the manner in which such deposits are invested. In England bank loans of a capital nature are frowned upon as a matter of traditional principle; in Canada the banking laws contain prohibitions against loans secured by real estate and other capital assets, similar to the prohibition of real estate loans by national banks in the United States prior to 1913* ^-e significance of the removal of this restriction upon national banks lies in the fact that definite legal sanction has been given to a departure from the principles originally laid down as necessary for sound commercial banking practice. Other measures of relaxation have occurred in connection with loans to single borrowers. Prior to I90S the amount of such a loan by a national bank was limited to 10 per cent of the paid-up and unimpaired capital - 127 - of the "bank. In many States there were no limitations of this character upon State chartered institutions; in others the limitation applied to "both capital and surplus. To improve the competitive position of national "banks the Federal law was amended in 1906 so as to make the 10 per cent limitation apply to both capital and surplus, provided the amount did not exceed JO per cent of the capital stock alone. Most of the State laws, however, provided numerous exceptions to such limitations for State "banks. To meet this situation the restriction on national "banks was further relaxed "by a series of amendments in 1918, 1919, and 1927. These relaxations from the original National Bank Act have grown out of State "bank competition. The less stringent laws of many of the Sta.tes have "been inducements for "banks to operate tinder State charter, to such an extent that the resulting development has threatened to destroy or weaken the power of the national system. The Federal Government has elected, not to preserve the spirit of its own institutions through restraining the action of the States, "but to attempt to solve the problem by removing restrictions on national banks. In two other important matters Federal legislation has followed the lead of the States; namely, in the granting of fiduciary powers and branch banking privileges. In both cases, however, the powers granted to national banks are not uniform throughout the country but are adjusted to the standards set by the various States. In 1913» with the passage of the Federal Reserve Act, the Federal Reserve Board was authorized to grant limited trust powers to national banks "when not in contravention of State or local law." As a result of this act and a series of amendments in 191S, 1922, and 1927, all the varied fiduciary functions of trust companies are now commonly performed by national banks. - 128 - Fiduciary "business as an additional activity of commercial banks is today an important element in the competition between the national and the various State banking systems. The laws governing executorships and trusteeships are not Federal but State; they are made and administered by State legislatures, State judges, and other State officials. In view of this fact many bankers transacting a large amount of fiduciary business believe that they are in a sounder position in the administration of such business if their banks are State rather than Federal instrumentalities, Consequently the State charter has been retained after many consolidations between national and State banks, which accounts in part for the relatively more rapid growth in recent years of the State systems. The Worcester County National Bank case in Massachusetts, litigated in 1928 and 1929, is of importance in this connection. In that case it was decided by the State courts and confirmed by the Supreme Court of the United States that the national bank could not automatically succeed to an executorship held by the State bank which had been merged with it, but that a new appointment as executor would have to be made. Since this decision especially, doubts have arisen in other States as to the right of a national bank to inherit the fiduciary business of a State chartered institution, and the question involves difficult problems whenever State institutions are converted into national banks. The McFadden Act of 1927 provided that national banks in those States which permit branch banking may establish branches in the head office cities. This change in Federal legislation, like the grant of fiduciary powers, was made for the express purpose of improving the competitive position of national banks. Bx-anch banking in this limited form does not appear to have led to any lowering of safety standards. - 129 - Various other changes in Federal legislation have removed restrictions on national banks or extended their powers. Among these are; the authorization for national banks in towns of under 5,000 inhabitants to act as insurance agents and as brokers for real estate loans; the lowering of reserve requirements against both time and demand deposits; and the authorization for Federal reserve members, including national banks, to issue bankers' acceptances. All these measures have been passed at least in part for the purpose of enabling national banks to compete with State chartered institutions. This purpose, in fact, has dominated the development of Federal banking legislation to such an extent that most of the important amendments to the national banking lav; since 1913 have been enacted in response to the competitive situation inherent in the dual banking system. Dual Control and Supervision Bank officials and directors are likely to resent criticism and the ease with which they may escape existing supervision by changing from one system to the other greatly reduces the effectiveness of examining authorities. While there can be no doubt that bank supervision in general is on a higher plane than it was twenty years ago, it is nevertheless a fact that dual control of banking has tended to keep down the standards of supervision, as well as of banking law. Effective supervision has been handicapped largely by two factors. In the first place, the supervisory authorities, whether national or State, have not been endowed with adequate powers; and in the second place, they have been unable to make full and effective use of such powers as have been granted them. To what extent the failure of legislative bodies to grant - 130 - adequate powers is due to the dual system is difficult to determine, "but the inability of supervisors to make full and effective use of such powers as they have arises out of the fact that hanks are able to avoid the supervision of one system by leaving it and entering the other. From the establishment of the national "banking system in I863 to the ipresent time, successive Comptrollers of the Currency have placed before Congress recommendations for the improvement of banking supervision, by specifying certain standards and providing adequate powers and penalties for their enforcement. Thus it was recommended by the first comptroller that the failure of a national bank be declared prima facie fraudulent and that the officers and directors be made personally responsible as well as punishable criminally unless upon investigation it was found that the bank's affairs had been honestly administered. In 188~f it was recommended that penalties be imposed for the making of loans contrary to law; in 1895 thsrt the comptroller be authorized, with the approval of the Secretary of the Treasury and after a hearing, to remove officers and directors for mismanagement or violations of law; in 191*+ that the comptroller be authorized to penalize both banks and their officers ''oy appropriate fines for violation of the law and failure to comply with his regulations; and in 193^ that a board composed of the Secretary of the Treasury, the governor of the Federal Reserve Board, and the comptroller should have power to remove officers or directors of banks who persistently violated the law or who continued unsafe and unsound practices. Congress has adopted none of these recommendations. An important duty of both national and State supervisory authorities is to recommend legislation designed to improve the safety standards of banking. They are hampered, however, by the competitive situation into - 131 - which they are forced by the existence of dual control. The dilemma of State supervisors in recommending banking legislation was described by the connissioner of banks of Massachusetts when he stated in 1929 that in passing State legislation care is exercised that nothing is done to drive State banks into the national system. That similar considerations have frequently influenced the Congress of the United States is evident from the record of legislation actually passed and the proposed measures defeated. State Banks and the Federal Eoserve .System Soon after its organization the Federal Reserve Board expressed its hope that a unified system of banking would develop through the Federal reserve system, and stated that, "There can be but one .American credit system of nation-wide extent, and it will fall short of satisfying the business judgment and expectation of the country and fail of attaining its full potentialities if it rests upon an incomplete foundation and leaves out of its membership any - 132- considerable part of the banking strength of the country."^ ' The "board extended liberal terns of admission to State "bantes, including the right to rrithdravr from membership on twelve months* notice. The State hanks, however, uore apprehensive of changes in the attitude of the board and hesitated about applying for membership. By June, 1917> only 53 State institutions had joined. Consequently certain amendments were passed hj Congress in 1917 to encourage applications for membership by State banks. Most of the provisions in the 1917 amendments dealing with State bank membership followed the spirit of the regulations issued by the board in 1915» which they extended. State bank members were permitted to with- draw from the system on six months' written'notice to the Federal Reserve Board. They retained their full charter and statutory rights subject to the restrictions of the Federal Reserve Act, and regulations of the board relative thereto. Their examination and supervision were delegated to the Federal reserve banks and board, which, in turn, were authorized to accept reports and examinations from State supervisory authorities in lieu of those of their own examiners. Furthermore, State member banks were relieved of the restrictions upon national banks as to the amount which could be loaned to one person, firm, or corporation, subject, however, to the restriction that if the State bank had loaned to any one borrower more than the limitations governing a national bank, none of the paper of the borrower so accommodated could be rediscounted at the Federal reserve banks. In spite of these concessions, only about S00 of the 12,000 State commercial banks belonged to the Federal reserve system in 1932. These 800 ^ Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1, 1915, p. 1^5. - 133 - members included most of the very large State banks, however, and had about 58 per cent of the loans and investments of all State banks and trust com*panies. It is noteworthy, on the other hand, that in the large size groups the number of nonmember banks has grown faster since 1920 than the number of member State banks. From 1920 to 1930 tlie number of nonmember banks with loans and investments of $10,000,000 to $50,000,000 increased from Sk to 12S, while member State banks in the same size group increased from 121 to 12!+. The number of nonmember banks with loans and investments of $50,000,000 and over increased from 3 to 10 during the same period, while member State banks of that size increased from 32 to k$» Competition between the two banking systems, resulting in an overbanked condition and relaxed standards, has materially hampered the effective functioning of Federal instrumentalities, i.e., the national banking system and the Federal reserve system. This has been in some measure re- sponsible for the development of unsound banking practices, the ineffectiveness of supervision, and the serious banking difficulties during the past twelve years. / dt APPENDIX - 135Table I - Commercial Banks and Trust Companies in the United States IS3L1-I93I (resources in millions of dollars') Year Stat< s banks Number Resources Natior i a l banks Number Resources S t a t e and n a t i o n a l banks Number E e s o u r c e s All banks Number Private banks Number i 18 34 1235 1836 1837 I838 I839 is4o lS4l 1842 18^3 1844 1845 is46 1847 1848 1849 1850 1851 1852 1853 1854 1855 1856 1857 1858 1859 I860 1861 1862 1863 1864 I865 1866 I867 1868 I869 1870 1871 1872 1S73 1374 1875 IS76 1S77 506 704 713 7SS 829 340 901 784 692 691 696 707 707 715 751 782 824 S79 815 750 1,208 1,307 1,398 l,4l6 1,422 1,476 1,562 1,601 1,492 1,466 1,089 349 297 272 247 259 325 452 566 277 36s 53b 671 631 1,185.4 725.9 165.8 154.8 151.9 154.6 156.0 201.5 259.6 264.5 173.9 237.4 395.2 405.9 506.9 66 467 1,294 1,634 1,636 i,64o 1,619 1,612 1,723 1,853 1,963 1,933 2,076 2,091 2,078 lb.8 252.2 1,126.5 1,476.3 1,494.5 1,572.1 1,564.1 1,565.7 1,703.4 1,770.3 1,351.2 1,351.8 1,913.2 1,325.7 1,774.3 506 704 713 783 829 840 901 734 692 691 696 707 707 715 751 782 824 879 315 750 1,208 1,307 1,398 l,4l6 1,422 1,476 1,562 1,601 1,492 1,532 1,556 1,643 1,931 1,908 1,337 1,873 1,937 2,175 2,419 2,245 2,351 2,662 2,762 2,709 1,202.2 972.1 1,292.3 1,631.1 1,646.4 1,726.7 1,720.1 IJ67.2 1,963.0 2,035.3 2,030.1 2,039.2 2,303.4 2,231.6) 2,231.2 1 2,432 1 | 5,i4i - 136 Table I - Commercial Banks and Trust Companies in the United States 183*1-1931 (Continued) Year 1878 1879 1880 1881 1832 1883 1884 1885 188b 1887 1888 1889 1890 1891 1892 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 189 S 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 19 08 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 (resources in millions of dollars) , , ' StC-te and S t a t e banks ITatior l&ln banks .. n a t i o i it-1 "banks ifuafoer Be s o u r c e s Iftimber Besources Nuuiber Eesources 510 648 650 083 704 788 852 1,015 891 1,471 1,523 1,791 2,250 2J43 3,773 4,188 4,188 4,369 4,279 4,420 4,486 4,73S 5,007 5,651 6,171 6,890 7,970 9,018 10,220 11,469 12,803 13,421 14,348 15,322 16,037 16,841 17,493 17,748 is,253 18,710 19,404 19,646 20,635 21,267 388.8 2,056 427.6 2,043 481.8 2,076 575.5 j 2,115 633.S 2,239 2,417 724.5 2,625 76o.9 802.0 2,689 807.0 2,809 3.014 1,003.9 3,120 1,055.4 1.237.3 3.239 1,374.6 3,484 1,442.6 3,652 1,999.5 3,753 2,168.7 3.S07 3.770 2,071.7 2,251.6 3.715 3,689 2,255.9 3,610 2,273.9 2,534.0 3.5S1 3,582 2,957.7 3,375.3 3,731 4,034.6 4,163 4,557.4 4,532 5,084.3 4,935 5,55S.5 5,327 6,417.0 5,664 7,048.6 6,046 6,422 7,657.1 7,330.6 6,817 6,886 8,031.3 8,684.4 7,13S 9,237.0 7,270 9,923.2 7,366 7,467 10,321.9 10,967.2 7,518 11,433.8 7,597 13.510.4 7,571 15,694.3 7,599 17,119.4 7,699 20,664.7 7,779 8,024 23,490.3 8,150 22,627.7 1,770.4 2,013.8 2,035.4 2,325.8 2,3^.3 2,364.8 2,282.5 2,421.8 2,474.5 2,637.2 2,731.4 2,937.9 3,061.7 3,H3.4 3,493.8 3,213.3 3,422.1 3.470.6 3,353.3 3,563.4 3.977.6 4,708.6 4,944.0 5,674.2 6,007.0 6,284.7 6,653.3 7,325.2 7,780.5 8,472.0 8J10.0 9,364.0 9,891.9 10,378.5 10,856.9 11,031.5 11,476.8 11,789.8 13.319.7 16,283.3 18,346.3 21,226.1 23,401.6 20,509.5 2,566 2,696 2,726 2,798 2,943 3,205 3.477 3.704 3.700 4,485 4,643 5,030 5,734 6,335 7,532 7,995 7.95S 8,034 7,968 8,030 8,067 8,320 8,738 9,814 10,703 11,825 13,297 14,682 16,266 17.S91 19,620 20,307 21,48b 22,592 23,403 24,308 25,016 25,345 25,824 26,309 27,103 27,425 23,659 29,417 2,159.2 2,447.4 2,517.2 2,901.3 2,978.1 3,089.3 3.043.U 3.223.8 3.281.5 3,641.1 3,786.8 4,175.2 4,436.3 4,556.0 5,493.3 5,382.0 5,%3.8 5,722.2 5,609.7 5.S37.3 6,511.6 7,666.3 8,313.3 9,708.8 10,564.4 11,369.0 12,211.8 13,742.2 14,829.1 16,129.1 16,040.6 17,395.3 18,576.3 19,615.5 20,730.1 21.353.4 22,444.0 23,223.6 27,430.1 3L977.6 35,465.7 41,890.8 46,891.9 43,137.2 Private banks Number All banks lifamber 2,586 2,545 2,573 2,799 3,107 3,306 3,458 3,456 3.6S9 3,966 4,o64 4,215 4,305 4,230 4,004 4,031 3,844 3,324 3,810 3,806 3.853 4,l6s 5,187 5,060 4,976 5 Ml 5,484 5,291 4,823 4,947 4,57b 4,407 3,669 3,683 3,406 3,213 3,062 2,737 1,968 1,852 1,846 1,817 1.736(1) 1,242 5,152 5,2Ui 5,293 5,537 6,050 6,511 6,335 7,i6o 7,3^9 8,451 8,707 9,245 10,039 10,625 11,536 12,026 11,302 12,003 11,77* ll,S3b 11,920 12,433 13,925 14,874 15,679 17,242 18,781 19,973 21,089 22,838 24,19b 24,714 25,155 26,275 26,809 27,521 23,078 28,032 27,792 23,l6l 23,949 29,242 30,395 30,659 - 137 Table I - Commercial Banks and Trust Companies in the United States 183*4-1931 (Continued) Year 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 192S 1929 1930 1931 (resources in millions of dollars) State and National "banks State banks n a t i o n a l banks Number Ee sources • Number Eesources Number Ee sources 20,789 20,654 20,028 19,573 13,994 18,119 11 Mo 16,728 15,79S 1^,323 8,244 S.236 8,080 8,066 7,972 7,790 7,685 7,530 7,247 6,800 22,912.5 25,191.6 26J83.3 29,352.7 30,682.4 32,082.5 32.899.3 34,217.6 3^,219.0 30,981.0 20,697.9 21,502.2 22,555.3 24,338.8 25,302.6 26,566.5 28,492.9 27,425.2 29,072.4 27,59S.6 29,033 28,890 28,108 27,639 26,966 25,909 25,125 24,25S 23,045 21,123 43,610.4 46,693.8 49,338.6 53.69L5 55,991.0 58,649.0 61,392.2 61,642.8 63,291.4 58,579.6 Private banks Number All banks Number 1,157 1,080 1,008 915 30,190 29 ,970 29,116 23,554 27,826 26,701 25,862 24,943 23,643 21,627 s6o 792 737 685 598 504 1 (1) Includes 386 private banks in Illinois, most of which converted to State banks before the end of the year because of a law prohibiting private banks after January 1, 1921. Sources of Figures in Table £ National Banks. - Figures for national banks are taken from the annual reports of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1931, PP. 3 ai*d 5 (for years I863 to 1891, inclusive); 1920, pp. 279 et s§£. (for years 1892 to 1920, inclusive); and 1921 to 1931 (for years 1921 to 1931, inclusive). Banks in Alaska and insular possessions are excluded. State Banks. - Figures for State banks are taken from the annual reports of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1909, p. 912 (for years from I834 to 1862, inclusive, the figure for 1852 being interpolated); 1931, pp. 3 and 5 (for years from I863 to 1891, inclusive); and IS92 to 1931 (for years from 1892 to 193l» inclusive). Banks in Alaska and the insular possessions are excluded. Mutual savings banks are excluded. Loan and trust companies and stock savings banks are included, save that stock savings banks do not appear to be uniformly included prior to 1892. For most of the earlier years the figures both of number and resources are lower than the true figures, on account of the incompleteness of reports by State authorities to the Comptroller of the Currency. There are, moreover, differences among the States in the types of institutions under State supervision, and therefore in tiie bases of the reports; and many States had no department or official responsible for banking statistics until recent years. For the years from 1877 to 1909, inclusive, more complete figures than those given in this table are available for the number, but not for the resources, of State banks, in the Publications of the National Monetary Commission. Vol. 7, p. 248. The figures of the Monetary Commission have not been used here because of the desirability of using figures for the number of banks which correspond with those fox" resources. - 133 - Private Banks. - The figures for private "banks are for most years only approximations. Those for 1877 to 1909> inclusive, are taken from the Publications of the National Monetary Commission, Vol. 1, p. 250, and are based on lists in Komans' Bankers Almanac, otherwise entitled, The Bankers Directory: Eomans' and Sharp & Alleman's Edition. The figures given in this directory are stated to include "hankers and brokers at New York City, Chicago, Boston, Philadelphia and Baltimore"; but in most years tae figures given by the National Monetary Commission are smaller than those given in the directory, indicating that an effort was made to omit those doing only a brokerage business. Figures for the years from 1910 to 1919» inclusive, are taken from the Rand McNally Bankers' Directory. The sharp decrease between 1909 and 1910 is apparent father than real, being due to the fact that after 1910 the Band McNally directory listed a smaller number of private banks than Eomans1. Figures for the years from 1920 to 1931. inclusive, were collected by the Committee on Branch, Group, and Chain Banking with the cooperation of the Federal reserve banks and the State banking departments. The marked decrease from 1920 to 1921 is due primarily to the outlawing of private banks in Illinois on January 1, 1921. For all banks, figures are as of June 30, or the nearest reporting date. In the early years, however, no uniform date can be assumed; and those relating to private banks for some of the recent years have been obtained by averaging year-end figures. - 139 - Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932(1) 1. Supervisory agencies (a) Separate or virtually separate 1909 1929-1912 California Colorado Connecticut Idaho Kansas Louisiana Maine Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Missouri Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jeisey New York North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina Vermont Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Georgia Idaho Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklaaoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming (b) Under other department 1929-1912 1909 Alabama Arizona Delaware Florida Georgia Illinois Indiana Iowa KentuckyMaryland Mississippi Montana New Mexico North Carolina South Dakota Texas Utah Virginia Florida Illinois ! - 140 - Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932(1) (Continued) 2. Type of supervisory authority (a) Single official in charge of bankings 2) 1929-1912 1909 Mississippi Alabama Arizona Missouri California Iviontana Hew Jersey Colorado Delaware New Mexico Hew York Florida Georgia Ohio Idaho Oklahoma Illinois Pennsylvania Indiana South Carolina South Dakota Iowa Texas Kansas Utah Kentucky Louisiana Vermont Elaine Washington West Virginia Maryland Massachusetts Wisconsin Wyoming Michigan Minnesota (c) Single official, appointed by or under control of an executive banking board or other board 1929-1912 j 1909 Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Nevada Nebraska North -Dakota Nevada Oregon New Mexico North Dakota Oregon Virginia Connecticut Nebraska New Hampshire North Carolina Virginia (b) Single official supplemented by banking board 1929-1912" 1909 Khode Island Alabama Michigan Minne so ta Iowa Mississippi Kansas Missouri New York North Carolina Montana Hew Hampshire Oklahoma Hew Jersey Ehode Island Ohio South Dakota Pennsylvania Texas South Carolina Wisconsin Tennessee Utah Vermont Washington West Virginia Wyoming s . (I) Board, 01 two or three commissioners in charge of department 1909 1929-1912 (e; Ho specific arrangement for supervision 1909 Arkansas Tennessee 1929-1912 SW Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932(1) (Continued) 3. Method. of selecting commissioner or supervisor (b) Election by popular vote 1929-1932 1909 (a) Appointment by governor 1909 Arizona Washington California Wyoming Ian s as Louisiana .assachusetts Minnesota iontana levada lew Hampshire lew Jersey lew Mexico Uew York Pennsylvania rftiode Island 3outh Dakota Jtah Virginia 1929-1932 Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Georgia Idaho Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Missouri llontana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey Hew Mexico New York North Carolina ¥orth Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Texas Utah Vermont West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming North Carolina Florida Illinois (c) Selection by banks or from panel named by banks 1909 1929-1932 1909 1929-1932 Mississippi Tennessee Nebraska Oregon 2 r e g o n . («> (d) In other ways C3> Virginia , Washington^ /¥£- Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and I929-1932U) (Continued) k. Term of office of supervisor (h) Four years (a) Three years or less 1929-1932 1909 1929-1932 1909 California Arizona Idaho Maine Massachusetts Colorado Connecticut Massachusetts Michigan Idaho New Jersey Minnesota Kansas Nevada New Mexico Louisiana New Hampshire New York Michigan Hew Jersey Ohio Missouri New Mexico Rhode Island Montana New York Texas Ohio North Dakota Vermont Oklahoma Rhode Island Oregon Vermont Pennsylvania South Carolina South Dakota Washington West Virginia Wyoming (c) Five or six years 1929-1932 1909 North Carolina Minnesota Nebraska ?fisconsin New Hampshire Wisconsin 1 , Alabama Arizona Arkansas Colorado Connecticut Delaware Florida Georgia Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisana Maine Maryland Mississippi Montana North Carolina North Dakota Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Utah Washington West Virginia Wyoming (d) Indefinite term 1929-1932 1909 Utah California Missouri Nevada Virginia /fj Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-I932U) (Continued) 5. Salaries of supervisors (a) Under $5,000 per year (b) $5,000 to $10,000 per year 1929-1932 1929-1932 1909 1909 Alabama Arizona Colorado Connecticut Idaho Kansas Louisiana Maine Michigan Missouri Nebraska New Hampshire New Mexico Oklahoma Oregon Ehode Island South Carolina South Dakota Utah Vermont Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Delaware Idaho Kentucky Maryland Minnesota Missouri Nevada New Mexico South Carolina South Dakota Utah Vermont Virginia Wyoming Massachusetts Minnesota Nevada New Jersey New York Ohio Pennsylvania Alabama Arizona Arkansas Colorado Connecticut Florida Georgia Indiana Iowa Kansas Louisiana Maine Kassachusetts Montana Nebraska New Hampshire New Jersey North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Ehode Island 1 (c) $10,000 or over per year 1929-1932 1909 California California Illinois Michigan Mississippi New York Pennsylvania Tennessee Texas Yfashington West Virginia Wisconsin /-^ Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932C1) (Continued) 6. Method of selection of examiners (a) Civil service 1909 1929-1932 • » California Colorado Maryland Mew Jersey New York Ohio (b) By supervisory agency solely 1909 Arizona California Florida Illinois Indiana Iowa Minnesota Missouri Hew Mexico New York North Carolina Ohio Oregon Texas Tirginia 1929-1932 Alabama Arkansas Connecticut Delaware Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Iowa Kansas Kentucky Maine & Massachusetts^) Michigan Minnesota Mississippi (c) By supervisory agency with approval of governor or board 1929-1932 1909 Missouri Maryland Arizona Indiana Montana Nevada Louisiana New Hampshire Nebraska New Mexico North Dakota North Carolina Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Ehode Island South Dakota South Carolina Utah Tennessee Vermont Texas .7 Wyoming Virginia^ *' Washington West Virginia Wisconsin /f-5 Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1§09 and 1929-1932(1) (Continued) 7. Powers-relative to the organization of new panics (a) Principal discretionary powers in passing on applications for new charters (1) Exercised by commissioner (2) Exercised by hanking board 1929-1932 1929-1932 1909 l$VHp)*. Alabama Arkansas California Illinois Colorado Maine Delaware Michigan Florida Minnesota Georgia New Jersey Idaho New York Ohio Illinois Iowa Oklahoma South Dakota Kentucky West Virginia Louisiana Maine Wisconsin Maryland Michigan Missouri Montana California Florida Nevada New Jersey New Mexico North Carolina Ohio ^ Oregon J Pennsylvania^) South Carolina Tennessee Utah Vermont Washington West Virginia Wyoming, (b) Must be assured of legitimate purpose and/o r integrity of applicant 1909 1929-1932 California Florida Illinois Michigan Minnesota Nebraska New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma South Dakota West Virginia Wisconsin Alabama New Mexico New York Arizona North Carolina Arkansas California North Dakota Florida Ohio Georgia Oklahoma Oregon Idaho South Carolina Illinois Indiana South Dakota Tennessee Kansas Kentucky Texas Louisiana Utah Virginia Maryland Washington Michigan Minnesota Wisconsin Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada Massachusetts Arizona Nebraska ! Connecticut North Carolina Indiana Rhode Island i Kansas Massachusetts !Minnesota Mississippi 1 Nebraska New Hampshire New York !North Dakota Oklahoma Rhode Island South Dakota Texas i t Virginia Wisconsin ! (c) Must take into consideration the public need and convenience for banking facilities 1909 1929-1932 Maine Massachusetts New Jersey New York Rhode Island South Dakota Alabama Arizona Arkansas California Connecticut Florida Georgia Idaho Indiana Kansas Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oregon Rhode Island South Dakota Tennes see Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington Wisconsin Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932(1) (Continued) 8. Powers relevant to banking operations (a) Examinations (2) Required to conduct examinat ions (l) Required to conduct more than once a<. year annual examinations 1929-1932 1929-1932 1909 1909 Alabama Arizona Florida Idaho Illinois Maine Maryland Massachusetts Missouri Montana New Hampshire New Mexico North Carolina North Dakota Oregon South Carolina Utah Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Arkansas California Connecticut Delaware Illinois Kentucky Maine Massachusetts Missouri Montana New Hampshire North Carolina Pennsylvania Washington Wisconsin California Colorado Connecticut Georgia Kansas Louisiana Michigan Minnesota Nebraska Nevada New York Ohio Oklahoma Rhode Island South Dakota Texas Vermont Alabama Arizona Colorado Florida Georgia Idaho Kansas Louisiana Maryland Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Nevada New Mexico New York North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Veimont Virginia West Virginia Wyoming (3) Authorized to conduct examinations at any time 1909 1929-1932WAlabama Arizona California Colorado Delaware Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico Alabama New York Arkansas North Carolina California North Dakota Colorado Ohio Connecticut Oklahoma Delaware Oregon Florida Pennsylvania Georgia Idaho Rhode Island South Dakota Illinois Texas Indiana Utah Iowa Vermont Kansas Ttirgiaia Kentucky Washington Louisiana West Virginia Maine Wisconsin Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Dakota Tennessee Texas Vermont Virginia Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming /¥7 -Till Table I I - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies 1909 and 1929-1932^ 1 ' (Continued) 8. Powers relevant to "banking operations (continued) (c) May limit borrowing (b) May require stockholders to make good by banks impairment of capital 1929-1932 1929-1932 1909 1909 California Colorado Florida Georgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Missouri Nebraska Nevada New Mexico New York North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Alabama Oregon Pennsylvania Arizona South "Dakota Arkansas California Texas /o Utah(#) Colorado Connecticut Virginia Washington \ Delaware West Virginia' Florida Georgia Wisconsin Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi (d) May require removal of undesirable and/or illegal assets 1909 1929-1932 "forth Dakota Alabama Ohio Arkansas Delaware Florida Idaho Montana Nebraska North Dakota Ohio Oregon South Dakota Utah West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New. Hampshire New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Virginia Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Kansas Michigan Oklahoma South Dakota Wisconsin Arizona California Idaho Kansas Michigan Montana North Dakota Oregon South Dakota Virginia Washington Wyoming (e) May order removal of officers or employees 1909 iq2q-iq^?2 Kansas Nevada Oklahoma South Dakota Florida Georgia Idaho Kansas Montana Nebraska New Hampshire North Carolina Oklahoma Oregon South Dakota Wyoming -»iv Table II - The Status and Powers of State Supervisory Agencies, 1909 and 1929-1932(1) (Continued) S. Powers relevant to "banking operations (continued) (f) May order removal (g) May recommend removal (h) May recommend of directors of officers or employees removal of directors 1929-1932 1929-1932 1929-1932 1909 1909 1909 Florida Idaho Montana North Carolina Oregon South Dakota 1909 Missouri Arkansas Colorado Massachusetts Missouri New York Utah Washington Wisconsin Massachusetts Missouri New York 9. Powers relevant to insolvent banks^' " (a) May licruidate the bank (b) May appo m t a receiver 1929-1932 1929-1932 1909 California Alabama Michigan Arizona Minnesota Arkansas California Jew York Oklahoma Colorado ihode Island Georgia South Dakota Idaho Iowa rexas Kentucky ifisconsin Louisiana Maryland. Massachusetts Minnesota Oregon Kansas Mississippi Pennsylvania Maryland Rhode Island Yifest Virginia Missouri Montana South Dakota Nebraska Tennessee Nevada Texas Utah New Jersey Vermont New Mexico New York Washington North Carolina Wisconsin Wyoming Ohio Oklahoma Florida Illinois Kansas West Virginia (c) May apply for the appointment of a receiver 1929-1932 1909 Alabama iriaona Colorado Connecticut Delaware Florida Seorgia Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Massachusett*3 Michigan Missouri Montana Nebraska Oregon Pennsylvania Nevada New Hampshire Rhode Island New Jersey Texas Vermont New Mexico Virginia New York North Carolina Washington North Dakota West Virginia Wisconsin Ohio Alabama Missouri Connecticut Nebraska Delaware New Hampshire Illinois New Mexico Indiana North Dakota Rhode Island Iowa Kentucky South Carolina Maine Tennessee Michigan Texas Vermont Minnesota Virginia ^ ' Sources: 19091 Barnett, State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the National-Bank Act, and Welldon, Digest of State Banking Statutes, Publica- ~ 1U9 tions of the National Monetary Commission, Vols. VII and III, respectively; 1929-1932, State lank Division, American Bankers Association, Results of Questionnaire on Bank Supervision, 1929, prepared by the various State banking departments; and banking statutes of the various States. In many instances data for 1909 were only partially available. (2) Several of these States have charter "boards, whose sole function is to consider applications for new charters. (3) Appointed by State banking board. (*+) Appointed by State corporation commission. (5) Appointed by director of taxation and examination. (6) in 1932, appointment is by supervisory agency with approval of the director of personnel. (7) Deputies and other employees appointed by corporation commission. '^) In North Dakota discretionary power was exercised by the Secretary of State. (9) In 1932> new charters must also be approved by the governor. (10) Secretary of State could apply for receiver if capital was impaired. (11) In several States the supervisory authority has the option of liquidating the bank or of applying for the appointment of a receiver, while in one State the option is between appointing and applying for the appointment of a receiver. •itvii-»- Table IV - Baiiks with Loans and Investments of $5»000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems "by Consolidation and Conversion, "by States, 1921-1931 ( i n thousandss of do].lars) L o c a t i o n and name of bank National charters State charters given up Year given up of By By By By change consolida- conver- consolida- convertion sion sion tion 75,784 IBff ENGLAND STATES - TOTAL MAINE Bangor F i r s t N a t ' l Bk, Portland Chapman Nat' 1 Bk. 192S 8,109 MASSACHUSETTS Boston Am. T r . Co. Beacon T r . Co. Commonwealth T r . Co. F e d e r a l T r . Co. I n t e r n a t ' l Tr. Co. Jamaica P l a i n Tr. Co. Mass. Tr. Co. Nat' 1 Union Bk. F a l l Hiver Massasoit Pocasset N a t ' l Bk. Worcester Park Tr. Co. 8.109 8,109 7,387 1930 1930 1923 1923 1923 1931 1925 1925 15,156 192S 5,619 24,999 3^58 29,607 20,568 44,769 5,884 20,3^7 1 1922 Total EHODE ISLAND Providence N a t ' l Exch. Bk. 6.5^52 20,775 1926 Total 166,596 19,180 19,180 CONNECTICUT Bridgeport City N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. Hartford Phoenix N a t ' l Bk. U. S. Security Tr. Co. Total 20,568 7,387 1929 Total 178,955 1929 13,976 1926 1927 14,466 12,^59 28,442 12,359 20,568 f 5/ Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the national and State Banking Systems *by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-193I (Continued) ( i n thousandss of dollars) National charters State charters given UP Year given UP Location and name of "bank By of By By By change consolida- conver- consolida-< convertion sion sion tion MIDDLE ATLANTIC STATES - TOTAL NEW TOEK Albany F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. Buffalo Community N a t ' l Bk. Lafayette N a t ' l Bk. Mfgs. & Traders N a t ' l Bk. Jamestown Am. N a t ' l Bk. Lockport N a t ' l Exch. Bk. Mt. Vernon Am. N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. New York City Am. Exch.-Pacific N a t ' l Bk. Am. Express Bk. & Tr. Co. Atlantic N a t ' l Bk. Bank of America Bank of N. Y.— N. B. A. Battery Park N a t ' l Bk. Bowery Bank of N. Y. Broadway N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. Brooklyn N a t ' l Bk. of N. Y. Bronx N a t ' 1 Bk. Capital N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. Central N a t ' l Bk. Chemical N a t ' l Bk. Coal & Iron N a t ' l Bk. Com'l Exch. Bk. Com'l Exch. Bk. of N. Y. Com'l Tr. Co. Equitable Tr. Co. Fifth Nat'1 Bk. F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. (Brooklyn) F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. (Jamaica) Fordham N a t ' l Bk. in N. Y. (Bronx) Franklin N a t ' l Bk. in N. Y. Gotham N a t ' l Bk. 2,305,^03 20,1+76 1926 10,899 1929 192U 1925 20,980 8,075 46,6i4 1931 5.330 1926 1,137,202 6,067 1930 7,380 1926 1931 1922 192S 1922 1923 1925 1930 1931 192S 192S 1930 1929 1926 1921 1928 192U 1930 1925 1928 1926 1929 1927 1925 167,089 32,381 i6,4os 94,883 42,648 12,3^7 5,069 5,920 8,162 7,671 23,795 12,61+3 205,865 21,0^0 8,1+96 19,899 10,700 496,351 19,1+20 20,669 8,014 5,365 5,375 17,082 15,831 — g i g •» Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-193I (Continued) ^in thousands of do]Liars) National charters State charters siven up Year given up Location and name of bank of By By By By change consolida- conver- consolida- convertion sion tion sion New York City (Continued) Greenwich Bk. Hamilton N a t ' l Bk» Hanover N a t ' l Bk. Importers & Traders N a t ' l Bk. I n d u s t r i a l N a t ' l Bk. I n t e r s t a t e Tr. Co. Irving N a t ' l Bk. I t a l i a n Discount & Tr. Co. Liberty N a t ' l Bk. Lincoln Tr. Co. Longacre Bk. Longacre N a t ' l Bk. Mercantile Tr. Co. Metropolitan 3k. Metropolitan Tr. Co. Murray H i l l Tr. Co. Mutual Bk. N a t ' l km. Bk. N a t ' l Bk. of Commerce N a t ' l Butchers & Drovers Bk. Pacific Bk. Peoples Tr. Co. (Brooklyn) Ridgewood N a t ' l Bk. (Qq.eens) Seaboard N a t ' l Bk. Seventh N a t ' l Bk. Seward N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. of N. Y. Straus N a t ' l Bk. and Tr. Co. of N.Y. United N a t ' l Bk. W. H. Grace & Co.'s Bk. 1927 1928 1929 1923 1931 1930 1923 1927 1921 1922 192S 1928 1922 1921 19 24 1930 1927 1926 1929 1926 1925 1926 1921 1929 1928 1931 1931 1928 192U lev; York City - Total Niagara P a l l s Bank of Niagara N a t ' l Bk. of Niagara & Tr. Co. North Tonawanda State N a t ' l Bk. Rochester N a t ' l Bk. of Rochester 24,655 17*362 1U3.I82 35,016 7,662 45,36o 194,782 5,673 103,203 22,5^6 7,256 8,181 18,977 ^3,031 39,909 11,345 15,248 9,661 532,191 14,213 35,760 62,383 7,615 162,533 12,152 6,287 9,006 14,033 8.579 992,666 1,876,592 1927 1929 6,677 11,1^5 1926 1928 7,719 17,881 l 15,835 (33 Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems "by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-193I (Continued) (in thousands of dollars) Location and name of bank Utica F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. Utica N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. Yonkers Yonkers Tr. Co. National charters State charters given UP given UP Year By of By By By change consolida- conver- consolida- convertion sion sion tion 1926 1930 10.181 1929 Total HEW J2RS3Y Bloomfield Bloomfield N a t ' l Bk. Elizabeth Peoples N a t ' l Bk. Hoboken Second N a t ' l Bk. Jersey City Lincoln Tr. Co. of N. J . Union Tr. Co. of N. J . Newark Am. N a t ' l Bk. Guardian Tr. Co. of IT. J . Merchants & Mfgs. N a t ' l Bk. North Ward N a t ' l Bk. Union N a t ' l Bk. Passaic Passaic Tr. & Safe Deposit Co. Paterson Paterson Safe Deposit & Tr. Co. 16,433 5,785 13,786 1,009,524 2,027,ll4 1929 6,420 1930 7,582 1926 6,690 7,494 9,129 1929 1923 1927 1923 1927 1930 1921 16.10*3 23,183 21,193 12,7% 23,527 1922 11,207 1921 6,115 Total 6,690 93,154 57,133 PENNSYLVANIA Philadelphia Am. Bk. & Tr. Co. Bank of North Am. ( N a t ' l Bk.) Broad Street N a t ' l Bk.. N a t ' l Bk. of Commerce N a t ' l Bk. of North Philadelphia N a t ' l Security Bk. & Tr. Co. Ninth N a t ' l Bk. 1929 1923 192S 1927 192S 1930 1923 5,655 23,4oo 9,^79 9,05S 5,270 io,Ui7 n,55l i . 15,835 Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems "by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-1931 (Continued) ( i n thousands of d o l l a r s ) National charters State charters Year g i v e n up ^ i v e n up Location and name of bank By By of By By change consolida- conver- consolida- conversion sion tion tion P h i l a d e I p h i a (Cont inued) Northern N a t ' l Biz. Oxford Bk. & T r . Co. Tenth N a t ' l Bk. T e x t i l e N a t ' l Bk. Union Bk. & T r . Co. Union l a t ' l Bk. Pittsburgh Farmers Deposit Svgs. 3 k . Scranton County Svgs. Bk. Wilkes-Barre Luzerne County N a t ' l Bk. Williamsport West Branch N a t ' l Bk. 1929 1928 1929 1930 1929 1927 9,262 7,964 9,012 5.-S7^ 27,786 12,903 192S 12,^35 1927 7,120 1923 5,217 1927 s.-soU Total 60,960 125,7^7 MARYLAND Baltimore Drovers & Mechanics N a t ' l Bk. Farmers and Merchants N a t ' l 3 k . N a t ' l Bk. of B a l t i m o r e N a t ' l Exch. 3 k . N a t ' l Union Bk. of Md. 1930 1930 1930 1923 1929 Total DISTRICT d r COLUMBIA Washington Merchants Bk. and T r . Co. 13.179 6,9^3 15,953 13,930 9.W 59.3SS 1930 9,585 Total SIOIKEH CENTRAL STATES - TOTAL MICHIGAN Detroit C e n t r a l Svgs. Bk. G-riswold-Eirst S t a t e Bk. G-riswold N a t ' l Bk. 9.5S5 1,031,693 1928 1929 1927 826,269 33,700 39,318 15,096 31.06U /C5"J5T Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000 t 000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems "by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-1931 (Continued) ( i n thousands of do!.lars) National charters State charters given up Year given up Location and name of hank of By 3y By By change consolida- conver- consolida- conversion tion sion tion Detroit (Continued) Guardian Detroit Bk. Merchants N a t ' l Bk. Peoples Wayne County Bk. Grand Rapids Old N a t ' l Bk. Port Huron Federal Com'l & Svgs. Bk. 25,878 1929 13.672 301,125 6,852 1930 Total WISCONSIN Milwaukee Am. Exch. Bk. Second Ward Svgs. Bk. 91.701 1931 1929 1931 54,646 1924 192S 10,713 34,126 Total ILLINOIS Chicago Cont'l and Com'l Tr. and Svgs. Bk. Cont'l N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Cc. of Chicago Corn Exch. H a t ' l Bk. Haagan State Bk. (State He. of Chicago) N a t ' l Bk. of Commerce i n Chicago N a t ' l Bk. of the Republic of Chicago Peoples Stock Yards State Bk. Rawson State Bk. (Union Tr. Co.) Standard Tr. & Svgs. Bk. Straus Tr. Co. 34.126 1927 1929 192U 1929 1927 1931 1929 1929 192S 1928 Total INDIANA Fort Wayne Lincoln Tr. Co. Tri-State Loan & Tr. Co. 10,713 96,332 490,823 si,960 53.417 5,773 93.382 14,892 68,558 16,111 5,459 671.93S 192S 1929 Total U72,696 234,418 6,001 9,929 15,930 20,351 /£ L Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-1931 (Continued) (in thousands1 of dollars) National charters State c h a r t e r s given up given up Year Location and name of bank of By By By By change consolida- conver- consolida- conversion tion sion tion OHIO Akron F i r s t - S e c o n d N a t ' l Bk. N a t ' l City Bk. Cincinnati Citizens N a t ; l Bk. & Tr. Co. Fiftn-Third N a t ' l Bk. Fourth K a t ' l Bk. Cleveland Engineers Nat'1 Bk. F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. Union Commerce Nat' 1 Bk. United Bkg. & Tr. Co. Columbus F i r s t Citizens Tr. Co. F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. Dayton City N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. City Tr. & Svgs. Bk. Toledo N a t ' 1 Bk. of Commerce Northern N a t ' l Bk. Second N a t ' l Bk. 1923 1929 13,220 1927 1926 1923 16,792 41J43 SJ86 1930 1921 1921 1929 17,761 6OJ6S 63.729 33,157 29,79^ 1931 192S 11,322 1930 192S 15,365 1921 1924 1924 i4,703 10,47s Total •0UTHERN MOUNTAIN STATES - TOTAL VIRGINIA Norfolk Citizens Bk. Trust Co. of Norfolk Richmond Am. N a t ' l Bk. N a t ' l State and City Bk. Planters N a t ' l Bk. iss125 6,l4s 12 ..317 305,109 57,356 1928 1927 1928 1922 1926 Total 16,437 11,668 16,319 44,424 Total 1929 19,585 26,309 7,o6l 6,423 KENTUCKY Louisville Louisville N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. 69,099 12.932 12,932 13,484 /*7 ••». a a i v —• Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5>000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-1931 (Continued) ( i n thousands of do!.lars) National charters State charters Year given up givon up Location and name of "bank of By By By By change consolida- conver- consolida- conversion tion sion tion TENNESSEE Chattanooga Chattanooga Svgs. Bk. & Tr. Co. Memphis Union & Planters Bk. and Tr. Co. 6,101 1929 26,309 1929 Total SOUTHEASTERN STATES - TOTAL TOSTH CAROLINA Greensboro Am. N a t ' l Bk. & Tr. Co. Raleigh Citizens N a t ' l Bk. Wilmington Murchison N a t ' l Bk. U7.062 1929 7,610 1929 7,1^9 1929 9,460 Total SOUTH CAROLINA Charleston Peoples-First N a t ' l Bk. Total Total 61,237 74,645 9,132 9,132 1929 1924 1923 5,344 22,629 13,711 50,754 1927 Total FLORIDA Miami Com'l Bk. & Tr. Co. of Miami Miami Bk. & Tr. Co. 26,309 24,219 1930 GEORGIA Atlanta Atlanta Tr. Co. Lowry Bk. & Tr. Co. of Ga. Lowry N a t ' l Bk. Savannan Citizens & Southern Bk. 6,101 13.711 1926 1926 27,973 6,ogg 14,864 20,952 50,754 /53 j«fc—aSiriT'" Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, "by S t a t e s , 1921-1931 (Continued) ( i n thousands of dollars) National charters State c h a r t e r s given UP Year given up Location and name of "bank of By By By By change consolida- conver- consolida- conversion tion tion sion ALABAMA Birmingham Am. Tr, & Svgs. Bk. Mobile Merchants Bank 12,312 1927 10,878 1927 Total MISSISSIPPI Clarksdale Planters Bk. 12,312 1922 13,013 Total 13.013 29,882 SOUTHWESTERN STATES - TOTAL LOUISIANA New Orleans Canal-Com'1 N a t ' l Bk. 1921 Total TEXAS Dallas Guaranty Bk. & Tr. Co. Mercantile Bk. & Tr. Co. Mercantile N a t ' l Bk. Galveston Texas Bk. & Tr. Co. San Antonio City N a t ' l Bk. 10,51^ 6,1+26 6,Ui6 10,867 7,350 192U 1929 Total 20,192 10,51^ 1922 1925 1929 i/ESTEBN GEAIN STATES - TOTAL MINNESOTA Minneapolis St. Anthony F a l l s Bk. S t . Paul State Svgs, Bk. Total 10,878 8,%1 19.368 20,192 186J66 95,395 3 1 , ^ 7 1922 5,33^ 1931 8,560 13>S9^ Hf Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems by Consolidation and Conversion, by S t a t e s , 1921-1931 (Continued) ( i n thousands5 of dollars) National charters State charters given up given up Year Location and name of bank of By iy By By change consolida- conver- consolida- convertion sion sion tion IOWA. Des Moines Des Moines S v g s . Bk. & T r . Co. 1929 6,86l 6,863 Total MISSOURI Kansas City N a t ' l Bk. of Commerce S t . Louis Boatmans Bk. Central N a t ' l Bk. Farmers & Merchants Tr. Co. Franklin-Am. Tr. Co. I n t e r n a t ' l Bk. Liberty Central Tr. Co. Merchants-Laclede ITat'l Bk. N a t ' l Bit. of Commerce N a t ' l City Bk. State N a t ' l Bk. 1921 1926 1921 1928 1931 1928 1929 1929 1929 1930 1929 Total KANSAS Topeka Bank of Topeka 51,852 20,473 20,808 5,760 29,098 7,74o 37,800 17,7^5 66,673 12,268 17,420 186,766 74,638 26,233 1925 5,214 Total 5.214 iOCKY MOUNTAIN STATES - TOTAL 8,970 COLORADO Denver Am. Bk. & Tr. Co. 1924 8,970 Total 2,970 PACIFIC COAST STATES - TOTAL 25s,824 8 9 1 , 9 ^ 5^1,517 OREGON Portland Ladd & Tilton Bk. 1925 Total 18,195 18,195 f£,o Table IV - Banks with Loans and Investments of $5,000,000 and over Lost to the National and State Banking Systems "by Consolidation and Conversion, by States, 1921-1931 (Continued) ( i n thousands of dollars) National c h a r t e r s State charters given up Year given up Location and name of bank By of 3y By By change consolida- conver- consolida- convertion sion tion sion CALIFORNIA Fresno F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. Long Beach F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. Long Beach N a t ' l Bk. Los Angeles Citizens Tr. & Svgs. Bk. Hellman Com'l Tr. & Svgs. Bk. Merchants N a t ' l Tr, & Svgs. Bk. N a t ' l City Bk. of Los Angeles Pacific-Soutiiwest Tr. & Svgs. Bk, Security Tr. & Svgs. Bk. Oakland F i r s t N a t ' l Bk. Oakland Bk, Sacraaoento Farmers and Mechanics Bk. Peoples Bk. San Diego F i r s t Tr. & Svgs. Bk. San Francisco Am. N a t ' l Bk. Bk. of Am. of Calif. Bk. of I t a l y Merchants N a t ' l Bk. Wells Fargo-Nevada N a t ' l Bk. 1921 S.922 1929 19 24 5,0^3 6,225 1928 1926 192S 192S 1927 1929 123,896 8,624 192U 1929 9,445 39,793 65,420 179.033 230,788 53,767 1 192S 1927 i 1927 7,143 7,46o 5,629 t 18,4341 i 1923 1930 1927 1923 1923 541,517 8,024 70,211 Total 258,824 'TNITED STATES - TOTAL 284,716 873,749 541,517 3,992,770 |28,585 3,210,5S7 770,547 • 1 — „ i, , Sources: Data on bank changes collected by Committee on Branch, Group and Chain Banking, supplemented by records of Federal Reserve Board, Division of Bank Operations, and Rand McNally Bankers Directory. Since the Directory figures appear only at six-month intervals, loans and investments at time of consolidation or conversion may have differed from those given above in some cases. - 161 ^ BIBLIOGRAPHY American Bankers Association. Pp. 16. Proceedings of the Annual Conventions. Committee of Five. 1918. 1913-1932* Beport on Exchange and Collection Charges. Eanking Laws of the Various States. BARHETT, GEORGE E. State Banks and Trust Companies Since the Passage of the National-Bank Act. Vol. VII. Publications of National Monetary Commission, Part I: Pp. 366. Washington: Government Printing Office. 1911. Commercial and Financial Chronicle. American Bankers Convention Section. 1925, 1929, 1930, 193L and 1932. Congressional Globe. 1915* February 271 I865. DEtfEY, DAVIS R. State Banking Before the Civil War. Vol. IV. Publications of National Monetary Commission. Part II: Pp. 226. Washington: Government Printing Office. 1910. HERRICK, CLAY, Trust Companies, Their Organization. Growth and Management. 2d ed,, rev. and enl. Pp. 502. New York: Bankers Publishing Co. 1915. Indianapolis Convention of Board of Trade, Chamber of Commerce, etc. Report of the Monetary Commission. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. I898. KEARNEY, GEORGE E., Ed. Opinions ojf the Attorneys General of the United States, 1916-1919. Vol. 31. Washington: Government Printing Office. 1920. IAUGHLIN, J. LAURENCE. League, 1912, MUHLEMAN, MAURICE L. Banking Reform. Pp. 428. A Plan for a Central Bank. Chicago: National Citizens' Banking Law Journal. Vol. xxvi: Pp. 805-gio,~*88>890; Vol. xxvil: Pp. 13-20, 119-126, 211-219. Monetary and Banking Systems. Publishing Co. 190S. Pp. 218. New York: Monetary - 162 - national Association of Supervisors of State Banks. Conventions. 1910-1931. Rand McNally Bankers Directory. Band McNally Co. Proceedings of the Annual 1920-1932. South Dakota, Attorney General. Report and Supplemental Report to the Legislature of the Investigation of the Department of Banking and Finance. February 27. 1930. State Banking Departments. Reports of the various States. Indiana. Study Commission for Indiana Financial Institutions. Indianapolis: Dm. B. Burford Printing Co. 1932. Report. Pp. Xjk. TIPPETTS, CHARLES S. Fiduciary Powers Q£ National Banks. American Economic Review. Vol. XV, No. 3: Pp. kllJiyi. September, 1925. State Banks and the Federal Reserve System. York: D. Van Nostrand Co. Inc. 1929. U. S. Comptroller of the Currency. Government Printing Office. U. S. Federal Reserve Board. ment Frinting Office. Annual Report. Annual Report. Federal Reserve Bulletin. Printing Offica. Pp. 393. 1863-1931* 191^-1931* 1915-1932. Hew Washington: Washington: Govern- Washington: Government U. S. National Monetary Commission. Report. Publications of National Monetary Commission. Part I: Pp. 72. Washington: Government Printing Office. 1912. Suggested Plan for Monetary Legislation. Publications of National Monetary Commission. Part II: Pp. 20; Part III: Pp. 2k, Washington: Government Printing Office. 1911• WARBURG, PAUL M. Essays on Banking Reform in the United States. Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science. Vol. IV, No. hi Pp. 2>-29, 75-115. July, 1914. The Federal Reserve System. The Macmillan Co. 1930. 2 vols: Pp. 853, 899. New York: VffiLLDON, SAMUEL A. Digest of State Banking S t a t u t e s . Vol. I I I . Publications of National Monetary Commission. Pp. fkSt Washington: Government Printingoffice. 1910. rfllLIS, H. PARKER. The federal Reserve System. Ronald Fress Co. 1923« Pp. 1765. Hew York: The and o t h e r s . Report of an Inquiry into Contemporary Banking.in the United S t a t e s . 7 v o l s ; U appendices. 1925* Unpublished. (On f i l e Columbia University Library). COURT DECISIONS Metropolitan National Bank v. Claggett, lUl U. 5. 520. (1891) F i r s t National Bank in S t . Louis v . State of Missouri at the Information of B a r r e t t , Attorney General, 263 U. S. 6H0, (1923) State of Missouri at the Relation of the Bumes National Bank of St. Joseph v, Duncan, Judge of the Probate Court of Buchanan County, Missouri, 265 U. S. 17» i+U Sup. Ct. Rep. U27. (1924) Ex parte Worcester County National Bank of Worcester, 279 U. S. 3U7 (1928), on appeal from 263 Mass. Wi, 162 N. S. 217. Hamilton et a l v . S t a t e , Sk Conn. 61+8, 110 A t l . 5!+. (1920) City national Bank of Fougbkeepsie v. Phelps, 97 N, Y. kk. In re Mollineaux, 109 Misc. Rep. 75. 179 N. Y, S. 90. In re Turner's E s t a t e , 277 Fa. HO, 120 A t l . 701. (1919) (1923) In re Stanchfield's E s t a t e , 171 iYis. 553. 178 N. tf. 310. {lS8k) (1920)