View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 1997

Volume 3 Number 4

Bad Debt Rising
Donald P. Morgan and Ian Toll

Charge-offs on credit card loans are rising sharply. While many analysts blame this trend on
an expanding supply of credit cards, a closer look reveals the importance of two demand
factors—wealth and the share of the population at peak borrowing age—in explaining the
increase in bad debt.

Credit card charge-offs—the loans that banks write off
as uncollectible—are on the rise. Although this trend
has only recently made news, it has been under way for
more than a decade. From 1971 to 1983, commercial
banks charged off just 2.3 percent of their credit card
loans on average. Since 1983 the charge-off rate has
averaged 3.8 percent and is now approaching 5 percent.
This increase in charge-offs parallels the trend in the
household debt burden, which has climbed steeply
since the early 1980s.
What is behind the rise in bad debt? Most analysts
tend to blame lenders, arguing that banks are granting
credit cards to riskier borrowers without raising rates
to compensate. That supply-side focus is easy to understand given the aggressive marketing of credit cards
in recent years, but it overlooks another possibility:
perhaps rising demand for credit is driving up debt burdens
and charge-offs.
This edition of Current Issues weighs both supply
and demand explanations for the rise in bad debt.
Beginning with the supply side, we ask whether continued growth in credit card balances—despite growing
risk—reflects a greater willingness on the part of credit
card lenders to gamble on risky borrowers. Although
several developments in the credit card industry have
the potential to expand the supply of credit card lending, we find no evidence that a supply shift has

occurred. Interest rate spreads on credit cards have not
fallen since the early 1980s, nor have charge-offs on
credit cards risen faster than charge-offs on other consumer loans.
Our look at the demand side of the story is more
revealing. Our analysis shows that changes in two
important demand factors—wealth and the share of
heavy borrowers in the population—have influenced
the growth of debt burdens. Before 1983, these variables moved in offsetting directions, tending to stabilize credit demand and the debt burden. Since 1983,
however, wealth and the share of heavy borrowers in
the population have increased together. Using regression analysis, we show that the combined force of these
two demand shifts does a good job of explaining the
rise in debt burdens and bad debt.
Charge-offs and the Household Debt Burden:
Parallel Trends
The rise in charge-offs closely mirrors the trend in the
overall household debt burden, defined as the ratio of
total debt to income (Chart 1).1 These parallel trends
are no mere coincidence; a mounting debt burden
causes higher charge-offs because heavily indebted
borrowers are more exposed to income shocks such as
layoffs, illness, and divorce. Credit card borrowers are
especially sensitive to such shocks because credit cards

CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

Chart 1

rowers into securities and sell them to investors.
Securitization allows the lenders to specialize in their
comparative advantage—screening and monitoring—
while shifting some of the risk to investors.5 Specialization, in turn, could lower the cost of producing credit
and thus increase the supply of lending. Securitization

Credit Card Charge-offs and the Household Debt Burden
Debt/income
1.0

Percent
6
5

0.9

4
0.8
Charge-offs
Scale

0.7

3

Several developments in the credit card industry
could lead one to suspect a supply shift.

2
0.6

1

Debt/income
Scale

0.5
1971

0
75

80

85

90

95

might also expand the credit card lending of banks, in
particular, by reducing the amount of capital they
must hold to satisfy the requirements imposed by bank
regulators.6

Sources: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Reports of
Condition and Income; Ausubel (1995); Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts.

The advent of credit-scoring models could also cause
a shift in the supply of credit cards. These models enable
lenders to use the credit histories of millions of borrowers to predict the default risk of loan applicants. By
automating the credit-screening process, these computerized models could increase the supply of credit card
loans by lowering the costs of producing credit. The
models may also allow more accurate screening, so
lenders can target narrower risk classes and price their
cards accordingly. This ability to slice and price the
market more precisely could expand credit card lending.

provide revolving loans that are usually not secured.
When income drops, the revolving feature of credit
card loans allows cardholders to slow the repayment of
their debt—or even run up their balances.2 As their debt
accumulates, borrowers are then tempted to default on
their credit card debt because these loans are rarely
secured by collateral.
Despite this rising risk of charge-offs, credit card
balances have expanded dramatically—in real terms, by
11.5 percent per year between 1984 and 1996.3 Why are
analysts so quick to suggest that the rapid growth in
credit card debt reflects expanding supply? Several
developments in the credit card industry could lead one
to suspect a supply shift. As we explain below, the
potential for high profits, the securitization of credit
card loans, and the use of credit-scoring models to
assess the risk of borrowers could encourage lenders to
take on more risk.

A Look at the Evidence
But have these factors created a supply shift? If so, we
would expect to see interest rates on credit card loans
falling relative to other interest rates. Yet credit card
spreads have actually trended upward over the past fifteen years (Chart 2). The spread shown in the chart is

Chart 2

Supply-Side Developments
Profitability in the credit card industry has been two to
three times higher than in the overall banking system
since the early 1980s, when credit card rates were
deregulated. Ausubel (1991) argues that profits in the
industry are higher than one would expect in a competitive industry, even allowing for the higher charge-offs
and the other risks associated with credit card lending.
If he is correct, competition for those profits would
drive up charge-offs as new lenders who were willing to
gamble on riskier borrowers entered the market.4

Credit Card Rate and Spread
Percent
20
Credit card rate
15
Spread
10

A more recent development that could be expanding
credit card lending is securitization. Until the late
1980s, credit card lenders had to screen potential borrowers, monitor the credit, and bear the risk. Today,
lenders can package the loans made to individual bor-

FRBNY

5
1982

84

86

88

90

92

94

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, G.19 Statistical
Release “Terms of Credit at Commercial Banks and Finance Companies.”
Note: The spread is the credit card rate less the one-year Treasury bill rate.

2

96

simply the difference between the credit card rate and
the one-year Treasury bill rate, which measures the cost
of funds to lenders. While the credit card rate has fallen
in recent years, the spread is a more relevant measure
because it reflects the compensation lenders require for
the risks they are taking.7 Apart from cyclical variation,
the spread has clearly moved upward—from 6.1 percentage points in the second quarter of 1982 to 11 percentage points in the first quarter of 1996. This trend
parallels the climb in charge-offs shown in Chart 1,
indicating that banks have been raising the spread to
compensate for the rising risk of charge-offs.8

theory and the life-cycle theory. According to the permanent income theory, spending and the demand for credit
will rise along with wealth. Suppose home values double.

The uniform rise in all consumer charge-offs
steers us toward another explanation: perhaps
rising demand for credit is raising debt burdens,
making borrowers riskier, and forcing up
charge-offs across the board.

Another way to identify a supply shift in the credit
card market is to examine charge-offs on non-creditcard consumer loans. If lenders have become more
willing to gamble on credit card loans than on other
consumer loans, credit card charge-offs should be rising at a faster rate. The charge-off rates on credit card
loans and on other consumer loans, primarily installment
loans, are shown in Chart 3. Contrary to the supply-side
story, charge-offs on other consumer loans have risen at
virtually the same rate as credit card charge-offs.

To consume some of this new wealth without selling
their homes, homeowners can simply take out a loan. If
debt increases more than current income, households’
debt burden—the ratio of debt to income—rises.
The second theory relates the demand for credit to
borrowers’ age. According to this life-cycle theory,
people try to maintain a stable standard of living over
time, even though incomes tend to rise over a person’s
working life. To smooth consumption, younger individuals borrow against future income and then work down
their debt as they grow older and their income rises.

Although developments in the credit card market
might lead one to suspect that a supply shift is causing
the rise in charge-offs, the evidence presented here contradicts that story. Moreover, the uniform rise in all
consumer charge-offs steers us toward another explanation: perhaps rising demand for credit is raising debt
burdens, making borrowers riskier, and forcing up
charge-offs across the board.

These two theories lead us to look for shifts in
wealth and demographics that could be driving up the
debt burden—and charge-offs. We measure wealth with
net worth per capita in 1983 dollars. Our age variable is
the percent of the population in the peak borrowing age
of twenty-five to fifty-four. We identified these as the
peak borrowing years on the basis of data from the
Federal Reserve Board’s periodic Survey of Consumer
Finances; the surveys for 1989 and 1992 reveal that the
debt burden is highest across those age groups (Canner,
Kennickell, and Luckett 1995).

The Demand-Side Story
Our demand-side explanation draws on the two leading
theories of household borrowing—the permanent income

Chart 3
Chart 4

Relative Charge-off Rates for Credit Card
and Other Consumer Loans

Wealth and the Share of the U.S. Population Aged
Twenty-Five to Fifty-Four

1984:1=1
4

Percent
44

Other
consumer
loans

3

2

Credit card
loans

42

1983 dollars (thousands)
45
Percent aged 25-54
Scale
40

40

35

38

1

Real net worth
per capita

36

Scale

1984

86

88

90

92

94

96

32

15
1956

Source: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Reports of Condition
and Income.

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds
Accounts; U.S. Bureau of the Census.

Note: Series are scaled by their first-quarter 1984 values.

3

25
20

34

0

30

CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

Chart 6

Although there have been several notable swings in
the net worth and age variables over the last forty years,
before 1983 the variables usually moved in opposite
directions (Chart 4). Between 1956 and 1972, the share
of the population at peak borrowing age was falling or
level while net worth was rising or stable. When net
worth began to fall in 1973, the share of heavy borrowers

Actual and Predicted Credit Card Charge-offs,
Based on Predicted Debt Burden
Percent
6

Predicted
charge-offs

4

The combination of rising net worth and the
increasing share of heavy borrowers can
account for the mounting debt burden.

2
Charge-offs

0
1971

The debt burden predicted by the wealth and age
variables can, in turn, explain the rise in charge-offs
(Chart 6). 10 To demonstrate this relationship, we

Actual and Predicted Debt Burden,
Based on Wealth and Age
Debt/income
1.0
Debt/income
Predicted
debt/income

70

75

80

85

90

95

Finding no evidence of a supply shift, we then consider demand-side developments that many analysts
have overlooked. Two variables that drive household
borrowing, wealth and the share of heavy borrowers in
the population, moved in offsetting directions before
the early 1980s, keeping demand in check. Since
1983, however, these two variables have moved in one

0.6

65

90

Conclusion
Why are credit card charge-offs rising? Many analysts
blame lenders for supplying cards to riskier borrowers
without raising rates to compensate. Although we consider developments that could expand credit card lending, we find no evidence that the rise in charge-offs
reflects a supply shift. Credit card spreads have risen
along with charge-offs over the past fifteen years, suggesting that lenders are charging for the extra risk they
face. Moreover, charge-offs on other consumer loans
are rising just as fast as credit card charge-offs, suggesting that some other force is driving up bad debt.

Chart 5

60

85

regressed the charge-off rate on the level of the debt
burden we predicted using the wealth and age variables
(shown in Chart 5). We included the annual rate of job
growth in the regression to capture cyclical influences.
If a supply shift had occurred, the charge-off rate would
consistently exceed the rate we predicted using only the
demand-side and cyclical variables. Charge-offs were
somewhat higher than predicted in the early 1990s, but
that deviation likely reflects the added effect of the
recession in 1990-91. Since 1993, however, charge-offs
have actually been a bit lower than predicted. Overall,
the predicted rate tracks the actual rate very closely,
confirming the role of the demand-side factors in
explaining the increase in charge-offs.11

The combination of rising net worth and the increasing share of heavy borrowers can account for the
mounting debt burden. Indeed, these two variables predict most of the variation in the debt burden over the
last forty years (Chart 5).9 The debt burden increased
only moderately between the late 1950s and the early
1980s, a period when the movements of the wealth and
age variables partially offset one another. Since the
early 1980s, the combined forces of rising net worth
and an increasing share of heavy borrowers have driven
up the household debt burden.

0.4
1956

80

Sources: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Reports of
Condition and Income; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow
of Funds Accounts; authors’ forecasts.

had already begun to rise. According to the theory,
these counter movements should tend to offset the
effect on credit demand and debt burdens. In the early
1980s, however, net worth turned up, and both variables
have since risen together steadily.

0.8

75

95

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds
Accounts; U.S. Bureau of the Census; authors’ forecasts.

4

FRBNY

9. The ratio of debt to income was predicted using the following
regression equation, estimated with the forty-one annual observations between the first quarter of 1956 and the first quarter of 1996:
debt/income = -.064 + .007 (share aged 25 to 54) + .019 (real net
worth per capita). The coefficients were both significant at 5 percent or lower. The adjusted R-squared is .91. If a trend is included,
the age variable is insignificant, but wealth is still highly significant. We are inclined against including a trend, however, because
the life-cycle theory suggests that the demographic variable should
help explain the trend in the debt burden.

direction—up. This convergence has fueled the demand
for credit and has driven up debt burdens, making borrowers riskier. As a result, bad debt is on the rise.

Notes
1. The charge-off series in Chart 1 has two parts. The series since
1984 is from the Federal Financial Institutions Examination
Council’s Reports of Condition and Income (commonly known as
Call Reports), which are filed each quarter by all U.S. banks. The
series before 1984 is from Lawrence Ausubel (1995), who derived it
from publications by Visa International. The two series had a correlation of .97 in the period when they overlapped (1984-1991:2), so
we simply combined them to generate the series in Chart 1.

10. The equation used to predict charge-offs, estimated using annual
observations between second-quarter 1971 and first-quarter 1996,
was as follows: charge-offs = -2.61 + 8.39 (predicted debt-toincome ratio) – .193 (annual job growth). The predicted debt-toincome ratio is plotted in Chart 5, and the equation used to predict
that ratio is described in note 9. All the coefficients are significant at 5 percent or lower and the adjusted R-squared is .80.
Including lagged charge-offs eliminates the serial error in the
forecast and raises the adjusted R-squared to .94.

2. Borrowers are subject, of course, to a minimum payment and a
maximum credit limit. The revolving or open-ended feature distinguishes credit card lending from closed-end lending, such as installment loans, which require fixed payments over a specified term and
do not allow additional borrowing.

11. If the demand for credit is increasing, wouldn’t the risk-adjusted
spread, described in note 8, be rising? Not necessarily, because the
demand factors we have identified—wealth and age—should
increase demand across the board, not just the demand for credit
card loans. Even if the relative demand for credit card loans were
increasing, the risk-adjusted spread would increase only if the supply of credit card loans were inelastic. If the supply is elastic,
lenders can accommodate the increased demand for loans without
raising the risk-adjusted spread.

3. The growth of credit card balances does not explain rising debt
burdens because credit card debt remains a small portion of total
household debt.
4. Not all analysts accept Ausubel’s (1991) arguments; Ausubel
(1995) addresses his critics.
5. Although this shifting of risk would appear to tempt lenders to
offer cards to riskier borrowers, bankers report that the charge-off
rate on the loans they hold is about the same as that on securitized
loans (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 1996).

References

6. Banks are required to hold capital against their assets; securitization reduces banks’ assets and thus their required capital.

Ausubel, Lawrence. 1991. “The Failure of Competition in the
Credit Card Industry.” American Economic Review,
March: 50-81.

7. The credit card rate shown is the rate most commonly charged by
banks. Because banks now seem to offer a wider range of rates, we
were concerned that this mode rate might overstate the average rate
in recent years. To address this concern, we calculated the average
rate (interest income on credit card lending at all banks/credit card
balances at all banks) using data available since 1986 and found that
it tracked the mode rate very closely. Another consideration was
that banks might be lowering fees rather than spreads. Although
Ausubel (1991) notes that fees have declined steadily since the early
1980s, he also observes that lenders have raised late charges and
other “hidden” fees to compensate.

———. 1995. “The Credit Market Revisited.” Unpublished paper,
University of Maryland, July.
———. 1997. “Credit Card Defaults and Credit Card Profits.”
American Bankruptcy Law Journal. Forthcoming.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1996. Senior
Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices, May.
Canner, Glenn, Arthur Kennickell, and Charles Luckett. 1995.
“Household Sector Borrowing and the Burden of Debt.” Federal
Reserve Bulletin, April: 323-38.

8. We regressed the spread and the charge-off rate on a constant and
a trend term. The trend coefficients, .189 and .195, were both significant (at 5 percent or lower) but did not differ significantly. By
comparing the spread with charge-offs, we accounted for the loss of
principal resulting from charge-offs but not the loss of interest. To
account for both, we used the risk-adjusted spread = rc – rt – p –
p (rc – rr ), where rc denotes the credit card rate, rt the Treasury bill
rate, p the charge-off rate, and rr the recovery rate on charge-offs,
which is about 15 cents per dollar charged-off (according to the Call
Reports). Using that figure, we calculated the risk-adjusted spread
between 1982 and 1996 and found it was essentially trendless. This
result is not sensitive to the assumption of a constant recovery rate,
because the term prr is an order or two smaller than the other terms.

Laderman, Elizabeth. 1996. “What’s Behind Problem Credit Card
Loans?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic
Letter, July 19.

5

FRBNY

CURRENT ISSUES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

About the Authors
Donald P. Morgan is an economist and Ian Toll a former financial analyst in the Banking Studies Function
of the Research and Market Analysis Group.

The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.

Recent Current Issues
Date

Vol./No.

Title

Author(s)

5/96

2/6

Understanding Aggregate Default Rates of High Yield Bonds

Helwege, Kleiman

6/96

2/7

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of U.S. Recessions

Estrella, Mishkin

7/96

2/8

Consolidation and Competition in Second District
Banking Markets

Jayaratne, Hall

8/96

2/9

Securitizing Property Catastrophe Risk

Borden, Sarkar

9/96

2/10

Repo Rate Patterns for New Treasury Notes

Keane

10/96

2/11

Has the Stock Market Grown More Volatile?

Laster, Cole

11/96

2/12

New York State’s Merchandise Export Gap

Howe, Leary

12/96

2/13

Bank Branches in Supermarkets

Radecki, Wenninger, Orlow

1/97

3/1

1997 Job Outlook: The New York–New Jersey Region

Orr, Rosen

1/97

3/2

The Effects of Price Limits on Trading Volume:
A Study of the Cotton Futures Market

Evans, Mahoney

2/97

3/3

Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending

McCarthy

Readers interested in obtaining copies of Current Issues in Economics and Finance through the Internet
can visit our site on the World Wide Web (http://www.ny.frb.org). From the Bank’s research publications
page, you can view, download, and print any edition in the Current Issues series, as well as articles from
the Economic Policy Review. You can also view abstracts for Staff Reports and Research Papers and order the
full-length, hard-copy version of any paper in these series electronically.

Current Issues in Economics and Finance is published by the Research and Market Analysis Group of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. Dorothy Meadow Sobol is the editor.
Editorial Staff: Valerie LaPorte, Mike De Mott, Elizabeth Miranda
Production: Graphics and Publications Staff
Subscriptions to Current Issues are free. Write to the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N.Y. 10045-0001, or call 212-720-6134. Back issues are also available.