View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

MAY 2006
NUMBER 226a

Chicago Fed Letter
State and Local Government Public Pension Forum:
A conference summary
by Richard H. Mattoon, senior economist and economic advisor

As growing numbers of their work force approach retirement age, state and local governments
are taking a hard look at their pension funds to see if they are prepared for this exodus.
This one-day conference brought together policymakers and experts to weigh the state
of these funds.

The future of state and local government

public pension systems and related health
care liabilities was the subject of a conference held at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago on February 28. The conference was cosponsored by the Bank,
the Civic Federation, and the National
Tax Association and brought together
pension experts from law, accounting,
and economics to discuss public pension dynamics and future liabilities.

Any strategy to fix pension
shortfalls or reduce benefits
must recognize the sensitivity
many government employees
have about their retirement
benefits.

Lance Weiss and Tim Phoenix from
Deloitte Consulting began the program
by discussing the influence that pension
structure and benefits can have on recruiting and retaining talent in the public sector. While public sector leaders
often recognize that an aging government work force is a significant issue,
they are often at a loss on how best to
manage pension obligations to meet
the needs of both government employees and taxpayers. Public sector demographics suggest that a large portion of
government workers are approaching
retirement age, and this could lead to a
significant talent gap. To manage this
issue, Phoenix suggested governments
look at their work force supply and demand strategies to ensure that they have
the appropriate knowledge capital to
meet their needs. The supply strategies
include targeted strategies for improving
attraction and recruitment, as well as

realigning retirement and reward programs to retain and potentially extend
the longevity of key employees. They also
include better talent development programs and transferring knowledge from
experienced workers before they retire,
as well as investigating flexible employment options. On the demand side, various productivity enhancing strategies are
key. These include expanding use of
automation, investigating outsourcing,
and providing self-service for customers.
Lance Weiss followed with an overview of
pension fund dynamics. Weiss stressed
that the public pension environment has
changed radically, driven by new accounting requirements, such as Government
Accounting Standards Board (GASB)
No. 45, that force governments to recognize health care and other nonpension
expenses and changing expectations
for the role of the employer in providing
retirement benefits. These nonpension
expenses are referred to as “other postemployment benefits” (OPEB). The
era of employer paternalism is being
replaced by one of employee empowerment, with the risk of saving for retirement shifting to the employee. Weiss
suggested that states have two basic options for addressing a pension funding
shortfall. First, they can cut costs by reducing basic and/or ancillary plan benefits, or trim administrative expenses.

Second, they can increase investment returns or find alternative funding sources.
They can defer costs by changing funding policies, changing actuarial assumptions or funding method, or changing
the asset valuation method. Weiss
stressed that deferral strategies will do
little to address fundamental drivers of
pension fund solvency. Weiss concluded
that any strategy to fix pension shortfalls
or reduce benefits must recognize the
sensitivity many government employees
have about their retirement benefits.

demographics, stock market declines in
2000 and 2001, and the enhanced pension benefits during the strong revenue
growth years for many states in the 1990s.
The aggregate funded ratio for state governments went from 100% in 2000 to
84% in 2004. Noting that pension and
OPEB obligations will be with state and
local governments for some time to
come, he suggested that policies will
likely need to address both the asset and
liability side of the balance sheet. For example, the state of Oregon undertook

States with younger state and local government employees
will be slower to feel the bite of pension payouts.
Richard Ciccarone of McDonnell Investment Management moderated a panel
of major rating agencies. Ciccarone
noted that, from the perspective of an
institutional investor, the key questions
in the public finance market are: Do the
ratings provided by the rating agencies
provide investors with sufficient warning
of deteriorating financial condition?
Second, do bond prices reflect the risk
of the issuer? In both cases, Ciccarone
suggested that even within the same
rating category, the issuing governments
often appear to have widely differing
underlying financial strength. For example, public debt instruments rated
as AA include those of states such as
Illinois, West Virginia, Rhode Island,
and Connecticut. All of these states have
pension funds with funding ratios below
75%, and yet there is little effect on
their debt rating. He also noted that
investors have been willing to purchase
riskier bonds, such as the Illinois pension
bond offering of 2004, without requiring
the bonds to pay a premium, suggesting
that the market does not do a better job
at pricing risk. He concluded that some
of this might be due to bond insurance
that often makes the underlying quality
of the issuer immaterial to the investor.
The first of the presentations by the
rating agencies was John Kenward of
Standard & Poor’s. Kenward noted that
the deterioration in public pension
solvency has been very rapid and driven by the confluence of unfavorable

a sweeping reform of its pension program that included closing the defined
benefit program to new hires. It also
sold $2 billion in pension obligation
bonds and created a new hybrid program
for new employees. Finally, Kenward
stressed that Standard & Poor’s will continue to examine management, financial condition, and debt level, as well as
macroeconomic factors, in determining governments’ creditworthiness.
Paul Nolan of Moody’s Investor Service
spoke about OPEB exposure. He stressed
that, in the long term, the OPEB requirements will improve the financial
transparency of government but will
create several short-term headaches. The
GASB No. 43 and No. 45 will require
governments to go from a pay-as-yougo system for funding nonpension retiree benefits (largely health care) to
a structure in which future liabilities
must be reflected on the government’s
accounting statements. In assessing the
ability of any particular government
to meet its OPEB liabilities, Moody’s
will look at the size of the liability relative to potential revenues and to peer
governments. Like Standard & Poor’s,
it does not anticipate wide-scale credit
reductions, assuming that most governments will have a reasonable plan for
meeting liabilities. Nolan anticipates
that governments will begin to prefund
health care expenses as well as consider issuing OPEB bonds to meet obligations. Depending on the contractual

requirements, reductions in benefit
coverage will also be considered.
Joseph O’Keefe of Fitch Ratings noted
some other considerations pressuring
public pensions. First, attempts to change
benefit levels are becoming increasingly
critical in any labor negotiations, and
attempts to shift from defined benefit
to defined contribution pension programs are frequently met with resistance
from public employee unions. Second,
new state employees are often receiving
less generous pension options than
vested employees. Finally, many actuarial
studies suggest that contribution rates
are lagging benefit costs, suggesting that
the problem will become worse before
it improves. O’Keefe noted that many
governments are increasingly looking
for external financing options. In particular, pension bonds have been growing
in popularity. He stressed that while issuing bonds is often an appropriate strategy, it has some distinct risks. Since it is
based on an arbitrage strategy of capitalizing on higher investment returns from
the bonds’ assets relative to the cost of
the issued bonds, market timing is critical. In addition, in using bonds, the government takes a “soft” debt (i.e., one that
it has flexibility in funding) and turns
it into a “hard” debt that requires meeting annual defined payouts.
Michael Moskow, President and CEO of
the Chicago Fed, offered his perspective
on pension issues and their regional
implications. To begin, Moskow noted
that public pensions are not subject to
the same ERISA (Employee Retirement
Income Security Act) rules that govern
private pensions. This has made it easier
to increase pension benefits to public
sector retirees without assuring adequate
funding. In addition, private pensions
have been radically restructured. Only
11% of private firms continue to offer
defined benefit programs in which retirees are guaranteed a monthly income for
the rest of their lives. Nearly 90% of
public pensions are still defined benefit
plans, and many of them include annual
cost of living increases that increase liabilities even further. In contrast, private
firms have moved to defined contribution plans and 401(k) programs where
retirement payouts are based on the

employee and company contributions
to the plan. A key issue is whether defined benefit plans are the best mechanisms for providing state and local
employee pensions, or whether a move
toward defined contribution plans would
be appropriate.
Moskow suggested that pension issues
are even more acute in many midwestern states. In states with high population
and personal income growth, future increases in tax revenues may allow these
states to catch up on their pension imbalances. In addition, states with favorable demographics and younger state
and local government employees will be
slower to feel the bite of pension payouts. Unfortunately for some of the
Midwest, state and local pensions are
similar to the legacy costs that domestic
automakers face. They are a financial
burden that may hurt the competitiveness of these states in the future.
To address this issue, Moskow observed
that we need to have a better sense of
the size of the pension obligation. More
uniform accounting standards are likely
needed to evaluate the true health of
public sector pensions. Beyond this, it
is likely that pension plans will need to
be structurally changed, including
identifying new funding sources and
restructuring pension payouts. This will
be no easy matter, given that many state
and local government pensions have
strong legal protections that make restructuring current plans difficult, if not
impossible. Finally, solving the pension
problem is more than an accounting
exercise. Pensions must be recognized
as part of any employee’s total compensation program. Pensions have been
structured to meet firms’ and organizations’ goals of retaining key staff and
building a productive work force. The
human capital dimension is an important consideration in redesigning pension programs of today’s employees. For
private firms, the movement to defined
contribution and 401(k) programs recognizes the increased mobility of today’s
work force. Pension portability better
meets the needs of today’s private workers. Pension programs need to reflect
the needs of organizations in meeting

their human capital requirements. No
one-size-fits-all plan will be appropriate.
Next, Fred Giertz of the University of
Illinois and the National Tax Association contrasted the condition and structure of state and local government
pensions to those of social security
and private pensions. The magnitude
of the financial liability of the programs
is significantly different. The future liability for Social Security and Medicare
is $38 trillion, which represents 362%
of gross domestic product (GDP). The
high-end estimate of state and local
pension funding liability is at $700 billion or 6% of total gross state product
(GSP). Even in states with particularly
acute problems, such as Illinois with an
unfunded liability of $38 billion, this
represents only 6% of that state’s GSP.
Private sector pension exposure is estimated at $450 billion (4.3% of GDP),
and some of that exposure is limited
by the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation (PBGC).
Giertz next turned to resources available to meet the problem. The federal
government has the broadest resources
with both broad monetary and tax powers. While states have reasonably broad
taxation powers, they are limited by interstate competition in exercising them
too aggressively. They also can increase
revenues through fees and other nontax sources. Private pension resources
must draw from company operations or,
in the case of a bankruptcy, the PBGC.
Giertz noted institutional constraints
that might interfere with appropriate
actions. For Social Security, solving the
problem has been likened to the third
rail of American politics. There is no
solution that will not cause significant
pain to a given constituency, making it
easier to simply defer the problem. State
governments similarly have used pension
underfunding for implicit borrowing
to fund other programs. As such, it is
often the manifestation rather than the
cause of state fiscal problems. Giertz
noted that pensions are often targets
of political influence. This can range
from outright corruption to more subtle limitations that reduce returns by
raising administrative costs to limiting
investment options.

Giertz concluded that political will is
the key to addressing state and local
pension shortfalls. This is a large but
manageable problem; however, to ensure
that state and local governments do not
revert to their old ways, some structural
reforms to pension administration may
be worth examining.
James Spiotto of Chapman and Cutler
provided a legal perspective on pension
fund issues. A key question is whether
pensions are a vested right of the employee or a voluntary gratuity provided
by the employer. As a vested right, many
governments include nonimpairment
clauses that make it difficult to restructure pension or OPEB benefits if the
plan is under financial duress. However,
there are varying levels of protection,
ranging from strict constitutional rights
to general statutory provisions, that
might allow for some renegotiation of
benefit levels in light of adverse conditions affecting the pension fund.
Spiotto noted that the difference between
“unwillingness to pay” and “inability to
pay” is important in understanding how
governments should deal with their pension issues. Governments with an inability to pay face a major public finance
problem that will require restructuring

Michael H. Moskow, President; Charles L. Evans,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas
Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies; David
Marshall, Vice President, macroeconomic policy research;
Richard Porter, Vice President, payment studies;
Daniel Sullivan, Vice President, microeconomic policy
research; William Testa, Vice President, regional
programs and Economics Editor; Helen O’D. Koshy,
Kathryn Moran, and Han Y. Choi, Editors; Rita
Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the
authors’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2006 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
on the Bank’s website at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

government programs and revenues to
meet their obligations. This might
even lead to governments seeking bankruptcy protection from the court. Spiotto
noted that states cannot go bankrupt;
however, they can repudiate debt.
Local governments have more options.
They can file for a Chapter 9 bankruptcy
that allows adjustment of debt or debt
payments; however, this requires state
authorization. Courts have permitted
the alteration of pension benefits under
Chapter 9 filings. Spiotto concluded
that pension obligations can best be
met when funding is clearly identified
(and even specifically dedicated) to meet
obligations.
Hank Sheff of the Association of Federal, State, and Municipal Employees
(AFSME) Council 31 offered organized
labor’s perspective on pension funding.
Sheff noted that public employee unions
strongly favor defined benefit programs.
Not only do these better meet the needs
of public employees, but Sheff argued
that they are more cost effective to operate. He noted that pensions are more
critical to many public workers, given
that nearly one-quarter of them do
not receive Social Security benefits.
Sheff noted that many public pension
plans are in fact well funded but that
only those with the greatest problems
make the national media. Illinois, for

example, has one of the most comprehensive problems that can largely be
blamed on systematic underfunding of
pension liabilities over an extended
period of time. Underfunding pensions
allowed the state to mask other fiscal
problems, including a tax structure that
has failed to grow fast enough to meet
state obligations. While Illinois has adopted a plan to restore pension solvency,
Sheff noted that it requires ver y steep
state contributions that would reach
almost 23% of total payroll by 2011.
Sheff concluded that the Illinois pension’s future looks bleak unless new taxes
are considered. For public employees,
solutions that would diminish benefits
for future workers or cut state programs
would be draconian solutions.
Lise Valentine of the Civic Federation
presented recent research on the structure of pension boards. Valentine suggested that pension boards should be
structured to be free of political influence and focus entirely on safeguarding
the assets of the fund through prudent
investment and effective management.
In particular, pension boards should not
engage in advocating for a particular
group of stakeholders.
Valentine’s research suggested that bestpractice states require the participation
of citizen members who are not fund

beneficiaries and/or independent financial experts. Examples include the
Maryland State Retirement System, the
Texas Teachers System, and Virginia’s
state program. These programs balance
employee and management representation and have a structure that requires
independent citizen participation. They
also have financial experts and focus
on optimal stewardship for fund assets.
Valentine urged that Illinois pension
funds adopt such a structure.
Conclusion

Conference participants generally concluded that pension and OPEB liabilities
will prove to be a major fiscal challenge
for state and local governments for some
time to come. While the depth of the
problem will vary from place to place,
these liabilities will pressure government
balance sheets and require many governments to take a hard look at available
revenues and expenditures to meet the
retirement needs of their employees
and still maintain government functions.
The Chicago Fed will continue to investigate pension issues. Please visit the conference website at www.chicagofed.org/
news_and_conferences/conferences_
and_events/2006_government_pension_
agenda.cfm to download conference
presentations and share ideas on our
pension blog.