View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

JUNE 1991
NUMBER 46

Chicago Fed Letter
Futures m argin and
excess volatility
On October 19, 1987, the Dowjones
Industrial Average dropped 22.61%,
its largest ever percentage decline.
The event aroused concern that the
stock market was becoming exces­
sively volatile. The 6.91% decline on
October 13, 1989, heightened these
concerns. Some charge that the
relatively low margin levels required
for positions in stock index futures
contribute to the magnitude of stock
price changes. In particular, accord­
ing to this view, the problem is that
margins required for stock futures
are lower than margins required for
stocks. According to this view,
margin requirem ents for stocks and
stock futures should be equal.
I disagree with this claim. In this
Chicago Fed Letter, I show why the
usual arguments for margin equaliza­
tion, which refer to excessive volatil­
ity, are not convincing. I argue that
margin equalization is an attempt
to maintain the market share of
trades placed by small investors.
However, this attempt will fail be­
cause of competition from alternative
markets.
What are futures markets?

Futures contracts are commitments
requiring settlement based on cashmarket prices at some date in the
future. Thus, futures markets are
derivative markets; i.e., futures prices
derive from the value of their under­
lying cash-market assets. For ex­
ample, futures contracts may be tied
to agricultural products, foreign
exchanges, interest rate obligations
or stock market indexes. This aspect
of the futures market provides

certain advantages. Because futures
positions can be held without provi­
sions for owning the underlying
asset, the cost of entering a futures
position is lower than the cost of the
corresponding position in the cash
market. Investors in futures markets
need not pay financing or other costs
to take positions based on their
forecasts. This lower trading cost
attracts investors to futures markets.
As futures markets respond to the
extent of investor positions, futures
prices reflect the forecasts motivating
these positions. What emerges is a
consensus forecast of prices. Thus,
futures speculations provide the
economy with information about
both expected future prices and risk.
Businesses can use expected price
information in forming plans. For
example, the futures price for Trea­
sury bonds might be useful to under­
writers planning an offering of
interest-sensitive securities. Diverse
forecasts are likely to produce price
swings in the futures market, imply­
ing uncertainty about future pros­
pects. This provides the economy
with a forecast of risk. A diverse set
of forecasts might suggest to manag­
ers that they need to reduce their
firms’ exposure to price changes.
For example, observing increased
volatility in interest-sensitive futures,
underwriters will increase their
measures to prevent losses from
the issue.
The following example illustrates this
price-discovery process. Suppose
that Jamie, an investor, believes long­
term Treasury bonds are underval­
ued; that is, Jamie believes that
interest rates are presently too high.
The cash market position taking
advantage of this insight is purchase
of long-term Treasury bonds. This

long position in bonds ties up invest­
m ent capital. A long position in a
bond-futures contract enables Jamie
to take a related position using less
capital. Thus, with limited supplies
of capital, Jamie can take larger
positions in the futures market than
in the cash market. The marketplace
benefits because the greater extent of
the Jam ie’s position increases upward
price pressure on futures contracts
relative to its effect were Jamie
limited to cash bonds. In turn,
arbitrage between the two markets
assures that whatever information is
reflected in futures contract prices
will quickly be used in pricing the
cash bond. In summary, valuation
forecasts motivate investment. The
choice of investment vehicle is based
on maximum benefit. When futures
contracts lower the cost of invest­
ment, prices respond to new infor­
mation more rapidly. As a result,
prices are more informative.
The link between prices in futures
and in cash markets demonstrated in
the example also illustrates the
second benefit of futures markets:
risk management. Because the
futures and cash prices move closely
together, other investors already
holding bonds, or long cash posi­
tions, can take short positions in
futures contracts to avoid the risk of
price changes. Returns from these
short positions offset the price
changes of the long cash position,
reducing investor risk. This offset
occurs because long and short
positions respond differently to price
changes. Long positions produce
gains when prices rise and losses
when prices fall. Short positions
produce losses when prices rise and
gains when prices fall. Thus, simulta­
neous long cash and short futures
positions produce offsetting returns.

The ability to construct such combi­
nations enables investment managers
to control exposure to price changes.
Of course, managers can always
accomplish risk control by altering
their cash positions. The lower cost
of trading in futures augments this
ability. In summary, futures markets
provide the market with enhanced
price discovery and risk management
facilities.
Why some believe that margins are
related to volatility

The idea that margins are related
to volatility is exceptionally long
lived given the lack of evidence
supporting this point of view. The
reasoning behind this idea is that
margin requirements determine
speculation levels; and by controlling
speculation, market volatility can
be controlled. I call this the Exces­
sive Volatility Argument. There are
a num ber of objections to this
argument.
Initial stock margins are set by the
Federal Reserve Board of Governors.
Since 1975, initial stock margins have
been 50%; i.e., investors holding
margined stock positions must have
an initial equity stake in the position
of 50%. Prior to 1975, the Board
revised stock margin requirements
intending to quiet markets. By
raising the cost of speculating in
stocks, it was hoped that volatility
could be controlled. Repeated
examination of the use of margin
rules to control volatility indicates
that it was not successful. There are
good reasons for the lack of success.
First, the extent of margin positions
is too small. Regulation affecting
only a small portion of trading
activity is unlikely to have much of an
impact. Second, margin rules restrict
the use of stock as collateral. This
restriction is readily avoided by
basing the loan on other assets.
Third, as Franco Modigliani and
Merton Miller demonstrated years
ago, the m ethod of financing does
not alter the fundam ental perfor­
mance of assets. The fact that chang­
ing margin requirem ents failed to
reduce volatility explains why, de­

spite retaining the authority, the
Board has opted to leave initial
margin requirem ents unchanged
since 1975.
This well docum ented failure of
regulation in the stock market
suggests that the use of margins to
reduce volatility in the futures mar­
ket will fail as well. Even if margin
regulation did reduce volatility in the
stock market, it would not necessarily
work in the futures market because
margin serves a distinctly different
purpose in the futures markets.
Whereas stock margins serve as
collateral for loans secured by stock,
futures margins are security deposits
maintained daily to ensure perfor­
mance of the contract holder. The
guarantee that futures exchanges
provide to the counterparties in
contracts traded on the exchange
places the exchange at risk. The
exchange faces the risk that contract
terms will not be performed. Margin
balances manage exchange risk in
two ways. First, as long as the margin
deposit exceeds a zero balance,
futures traders failing to perform
lose their margin deposits. This loss
threat provides them with an eco­
nomic incentive to fulfill contract
terms as long as the cost of perfor­
mance is less than the amount
remaining in the margin account.
Second, should nonperform ance
occur, the exchange uses available
margin to reduce its cost of complet­
ing the contract terms.
In my research, there is no evidence
that raising margins reduces subse­
quent volatility.1 On the contrary,
the evidence indicates that futures
exchanges raise margins when
volatility increases. Thus, just as the
above arguments predict, exchanges
act prudendaily. They raise margins
when the risk of nonperform ance
increases.
The Excessive Volatility Argument
also assumes that speculation in­
creases volatility. However, the
opposite result is more likely. Specu­
lators often take positions against the
market. For example, betting that
the market price is too low, specula­

tors will buy. Thus, markets re­
garded as declining attract specula­
tors who place buy orders, guessing
the market to be too bearish. Specu­
lation then, tends to reduce volatility.
The lower margin requirem ents of
futures markets probably does attract
speculators, but it does not follow
that these speculators increase
volatility.
Lastly, is the stock market really
more volatile since futures began
trading in 1982? It might seem that
the answer is yes, given what hap­
pened in the Octobers of 1987 and
1989, but these were very short-term
events. It is inappropriate to charac­
terize long periods of time by short­
term results. Figure 1 graphs quarterto-quarter percentage changes in the
Standard and Poor’s 500 from 1952
to 1990. According to the Figure,
the magnitude of up and down price
changes does not suggest that an
im portant change in volatility has
occurred since 1982. Even the price
swings in the last quarters of 1987
and 1989 are less dramatic than
those during 1974. In fact, statistical
studies examining the effect on
volatility from the introduction of
stock index futures find the opposite
has occurred. Volatility has declined
since their introduction. Thus, stock
index futures did not raise volatility.
Is there another explanation?

Both logic and evidence run counter
to the claim that futures margins
need to be increased. Why then does
the debate continue? A better
explanation for the interest in raising
futures margins can be gleaned from
Figure 2. This graph compares the
levels of new equity issues with direct
ownership of equities by households.
Since 1975, the two series steadily
diverge, indicating that households
began decreasing their shares of
direct equity holdings.
Households are the retail customers
of the stock exchanges. Their de­
creased participation implies an
increase in holdings of institutions
such as pension funds and insurance
companies—the wholesale customers

1. Volatility o f equity returns
percentage price change (quarter-to-quarter)

of the stock exchanges. As the graph
indicates, the shift from direct
household investment to indirect
holdings through intermediating
institutions accelerated during the
mid-1970s. On May 1, 1975, the
NYSE de-cartelized the brokerage
industry by letting competition
determine fees charged by brokers.
The result was a retail-wholesale
segmentation of customers. Broker­
age fees obtained from these two
different customer bases differ
predictably. Retail customers are
charged higher amounts for two
reasons. First, retail trades are
smaller and more costly to handle.
This extra handling justifies a higher
charge per transaction. Second,

retail customers have fewer alterna­
tives. While wholesale customers can
shop off-exchange for lower transac­
tion fees, retail customers lack the
trading volume to justify the expense
of this search. Failure to discount
the transactions of wholesale custom­
ers will push these institutions to
alternative markets. The lack of
alternatives for small investors lessens
the pressure to offer them discounts.
Consequently, though trades by small
investors represent less than 15% of
average trades by volume, these are
the highest markup trades in today’s
market.2
Retaining these high-markup custom­
ers is vital to the present day trading

system used by the stock exchanges.
Proponents of the Excessive Volatility
Argument claim that volatility ex­
cesses cause small investors to leave
the stock market. However, if this is
true, the investment dollars placed by
small investors do not disappear.
They are re-routed through interm e­
diating firms. This re-routing shifts
trades from the retail market into the
wholesale market. This insight
clarifies the concerns of the stock
exchange: replacing the highmarkup end of its business with more
low-markup business implies losses.
Thus, margin equalization is in­
tended to retain this im portant
customer base by controlling excess
volatility. However, as previously
pointed out, raising futures margins
does not lower volatility.
Margin equalization does affect the
retail customer base in other ways.
Intermediary institutions offer
return-enhancing and risk-manage­
m ent services to individuals. These
services are uneconomic for small
investors. For example, a pension
fund can use index arbitrage to
enhance the retirem ent accounts of
its membership. Individuals will
generally find that returns net of
transaction costs are insufficient to
justify this strategy. Similarly, portfo­
lio insurance is generally uneco­
nomic for individuals, but usefully
provided by intermediaries. In­
creased trading costs brought on by
higher margins diminish the ability
of intermediary institutions to offer

Karl A. S cheld, S en io r Vice P re sid e n t a n d
D irecto r o f R esearch; David R. A llardice, Vice
P re sid e n t a n d A ssistant D irecto r o f R esearch;
C arolyn M cM ullen, E ditor.
Chicago Fed Letter is p u b lish e d m o n th ly by th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t o f th e F ed eral Reserve
B ank o f C hicago. T h e views ex p ressed are th e
a u th o r s ’ a n d are n o t necessarily th o se o f th e
F ed eral Reserve B ank o f C hicag o o r th e
F ed eral R eserve System. A rticles m ay b e
r e p rin te d if th e so u rce is c re d ite d a n d th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t is p ro v id ed w ith copies
o f th e rep rin ts.
Chicago Fed Letter is available w ith o u t ch arg e
fro m th e Public In fo rm a tio n C e n te r, F ed eral
R eserve B ank o f C hicago, P.O . Box 834,
C hicago, Illinois, 60690, (312) 322-5111.

ISSN 0895-0164

these services to customers. Thus,
equalizing margin stems the shift
from retail to wholesale trades by
making the benefits from trading
futures inaccessible to small investors.
Suppose futures and stock margins
are equalized?

Raising futures margins to the present
levels required for initial stock posi­
tions will raise the cost of futures
trading, reducing the economic
benefits from futures trading. Com­
petition ensures that efforts will be
made to re-establish these benefits
using products from alternative
markets. The low-markup clients of
the stock exchanges will continue
seeking low-cost routes for their
trades. Trading volume at computer
facilities which match trades in the socalled off-exchange market will rise.
Also, foreign exchanges will not
hesitate to offer contracts replacing
those presently trading in the futures
markets of New York, Kansas City, and
Chicago. These trades will be moti­
vated by competition between inter­
mediaries to increase the effectiveness
of risk m anagement and return
enhancement.
As substitutes for futures trading are
developed in off-exchange and

overseas markets, wholesale firms will
re-establish intermediary services.
The presence of substantial whole­
sale-retail cost differentials assures
these wholesalers of a market for
these services. Strategies such as
portfolio insurance and index arbi­
trage will remain uneconomic for
high-markup customers. Continued
underperform ance of self-managed
investments relative to institutionmanaged portfolios will motivate
further shifts from self-managed
investments.
Thus, attempts to forestall the loss of
retail trades by raising the cost of
trading in alternative markets will
fail. High mark-up customers at­
tracted by the investment services
offered by intermediaries will con­
tinue to place investments through
intermediaries. Low mark-up cus­
tomers seeking to lower the cost of
providing these services will move
more trading to alternative markets.
In combination, the stock exchanges
will lose business to institutions
facilitating increased returns and
lower risk from trading activity.
Conclusion

The Excessive Volatility Argument
links trading costs to excessive

volatility from speculative activity.
Proponents of margin equalization
hope to raise the cost of trading
futures to solve this problem. I have
shown that the Excessive Volatility
Argument fails because margin
increases do not lower subsequent
volatility.
The proponents of margin equaliza­
tion may have another goal in mind.
By raising the cost of trading strate­
gies designed to enhance returns and
manage the risk of stock positions
held through intermediaries, the
exchanges seek to retain highmarkup customers. I have argued
that competition from alternative
markets to provide the investment
vehicles which enable these strategies
ensures that margin equalization
will ultimately fail to achieve this goal
as well.
—James T. Moser
^ e e m y fo rth c o m in g artic le in Economic
Perspectives, J u ly /A u g u s t 1991.
2T h is is b a se d o n a n average v o lu m e o f
S u p e rD O T tra d e s o f ju s t over 85% since
J a n u a ry 1988. S u p e rD O T tra d e s are
h ig h v o lu m e tra d e s w h ich a re m u c h
m o re likely to b e p la c e d by in stitu tio n s.

IIIS-S2S (ZI£)
06909 s io u in i ‘o § E 3 iq 3

HS

Od

J3UI33 u o n e u u o j u i ^ y iq n j
O D V D IH D J O 3 N V 9 3 A t f 3 S 3 tf 3 V ^ 3 < 3 3 3