View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

TH E FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

MARCH 1988
NUMBER 7

Chicago Fed Letter
D ollar drop helps those
w ho help themselves

terms (based on 1982 prices) exports
were up 10.3 percent (for the first nine
months—the most recent data).

Since its peak in 1985, the foreign ex­
change value of the dollar has dropped
more than 50%. A fall that great
should have dramatically reduced the
deficit in U.S. international trade by
now. It hasn’t.

But imports also increased from 1986
levels. In 1987, the current dollar
value of imports rose 10.7 percent from
the previous year. Increased prices ac­
counted for much of the increase, but
the real volume of imports for the
January—September period was also
up from a year ago—by 4.3 percent.1
The real trade deficit declined but the
nominal deficit continued to increase.

Instead, as of late 1987, the deficit in
U.S. merchandise trade was running
at a record rate, and ended the year in
excess of $170 billion. Why?

which the dollar has stayed strong.
These include Canada (our largest
trading partner) and many newly in­
dustrializing countries of Latin Amer­
ica and the Pacific rim. According to
this view, the dollar has not dropped
as much as is commonly thought.
While this explanation has considerable
merit, most of the debate over how
much the dollar has, or has not, depre­
ciated misses an important element.
Dollar prices of imports to the U.S. have
increased substantially during the past

A depreciation in the exchange value
of the dollar should increase the dollar
price of U.S. imports. In response, do­
mestic consumers should purchase
fewer of those now more expensive im­
ports. If the quantity purchased (“real
imports”) declines by a greater per­
centage than the price increased, then
the total nominal or “current dollar”
value of imports declines. So, a weaker
dollar should reduce the total dollar
value of imports.
On the other side of the theoretical
coin, U.S. exports become cheaper in
terms of the stronger foreign currencies.
Foreign demand for U.S. goods in­
creases as does the dollar value of the
foreign purchases. In theory, then, the
value of U.S. exports increases, the
dollar value of U.S. imports decreases,
and the trade deficit shrinks.
Where theory fears to tread

Any economist would hedge that ex­
planation with the Latin catch, ceteris
paribus, or “other things remaining the
same.” And, that is the catch. Other
things have not remained the same.
True, the value and the volume of U.S.
exports have turned upward. During
1987 the current dollar value of mer­
chandise exports was 11.5 percent
greater than during 1986, and in real

Beyond the “ J” curve

There have been a number of attempts
to make sense out of the situation. The
technical phenomenon called the “J ”
curve is often cited. But it has been
pushed beyond its short-term explana­
tory limits and sheds little light on the
longer-term failure to close the trade
gap significantly.
Another explanation points to the in­
creasing volume of U.S. trade with
countries having currencies against

year. But, what really counts is the
relationship between import prices and
prices for domestically produced com­
petitive goods. A falling dollar can not
itself close the trade gap. More im­
portant is how importers, exporters,
and domestic producers price their
goods, in terms of the falling dollar.
These exchange rate/price relationships
have received little attention, yet they
are basic in measuring the impact of
an exchange rate change on countries’
real trade balances.

Relative prices:
sectors

Tales of three

A depreciating dollar, which makes
imports more expensive, has little effect
in the marketplace if prices for domes­
tic substitutes are also increasing and
imports retain a substantial price ad­
vantage. In some sectors of the econ­
omy, U.S. producers have raised their
prices as import prices have increased.
We should not be too surprised that the
value and volume of imports continues
to increase in these sectors.
The trends represented in Figure 1
support the contention that the declin­
ing dollar is having some impact on
import trade. In particular, the dollar
values of automotive and consumer
durables imports, in real terms, have
leveled off and even declined slightly
since mid-1986.

index, 1980Q 1 = 100
1DU

I
dolla ' peak

Im p ort prices

D o m e stic
— prices
140

1° 0
Im p o rt prices
re la tiv e to
d o m es tic prices
100

_____________ ___ ,____

___

80
_____ I— I__ I__ I__ I__ I__ I__ I__ I__ I__ l_J__ I__ l— 1__1__ 1__ 1__ 1
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984

1

1 1
1985

1

1 1 1
1986

1 1__ 1__ l _ l ______________
1987

But, Figure 1 shows quite a different
picture with respect to capital equip­
ment, which accounts for more than
one-fifth of the total value of merchan­
dise imports. Gains in real capital
equipment imports appeared to slow in
the last half of 1986 only to increase
sharply again during recent quarters.
Let’s examine the trends in relative
prices of imports as compared with do­
mestic producer prices for these three
major categories, to see why gener­
alizations fail to explain the slow re­
sponse to the declining dollar.
The tale of autos

During the 1979-1980 period rapidly
advancing oil prices boosted demand
for fuel-efficient foreign autos, resulting
in upward pressure on prices. Then,
the Japanese government began to
limit the number of cars shipped to the
United States in April 1981—to parry
U.S. threats of import restrictions. To
maintain the dollar value of their sales
Japanese auto-makers shifted the ex­
port product-mix toward more expen­
sive models. Thus, despite the appre­
ciation in the exchange value of the
dollar from mid-1980 to early-1985,
auto import prices continued to in­
crease (see Figure 2).
As prices for foreign autos went up,
U.S. auto producers elected to increase

prices and restore profits rather than
attempt to recover market share from
foreign producers. Throughout the
period 1980 to early 1985 prices of do­
mestic and imported cars moved up­
ward virtually in “lock-step.” As a
result, the relative prices of imports to
domestics remained steady.
The sharp weakening of the dollar in
early 1985 began to show up in an ac­
celeration in import prices relative to
domestic prices later that year. But,
despite the relative reduction in U.S.
car prices, foreign producers have con­
tinued to increase market share, sug­

gesting that U.S. producers have not
yet become competitive on the non­
price component of the auto market.
The tale of consumer durables

A somewhat different and thankfully
more favorable picture emerges for
prices of imported and domestic con­
sumer durable goods, such as consumer
electronics, (see Figure 3). As the dol­
lar strengthened during the first half of
the 1980s the dollar price of imports
declined. Later, as the dollar weak­
ened, the dollar price of imports rose.

' .

. Si: . '• "i .

the ratio in 1980, before the appreci­
ation of the dollar began.12
index, 1980 Q1= 100
dolla \p eak

^
'

|——m D o m e stic
prices

—

1 o0

......

----------------------- *--------------—

Im p ort prices

■^

80
Im p o rt prices
re la tiv e to
d o m es tic prices

60
--------- 1— I— I__ I__ I__ I__ l__ 1__ 1__ 1__ 1__ 1__ i I l__ 1
1980
1981
1982
1983

i

i i
1984

Domestic prices, on the other hand,
moved upward during the period.
The decline in the relative-price ratio
of imports to domestic consumer dura­
bles indicates that during the first half
of the 1980s the U.S. competitive posi­
tion deteriorated. Declining import
prices reduced U.S. competitiveness
and increases in domestic producer
prices compounded the problem.
Following the dollar’s peak and subse­
quent decline in 1985 the dollar price
of imported consumer durables in­
creased, more than offsetting the con­
tinued increase in domestic prices.
Thus, from the relative price ratio we
see an improvement in the competitive
position of the United States for con­
sumer durable goods (see Figure 3).
As expected, the recent decline in the
exchange value of the dollar has in­
creased import prices for consumer du­
rables. But, because of concurrent
increases in domestic prices, the impact
of higher import prices has not been as
large as would otherwise be expected
because it is the relative import/domestic
price relationship that is important.
The tale of capital equipment

The data presented in Figure 4 indicate
that dollar prices for imported capital
equipment, such as machine tools, fol­

Moral of the tales

The potential price effects on trade re­
sulting from an exchange rate change
cannot be looked at in isolation from
the domestic price developments for
competing goods. So long as domestic
producers in search of improved profit
margins increase prices and thus offset
the potential gains in market share
from the dollar depreciation, it will be
difficult to reestablish a strong compet­
itive position for U.S. goods in the do­
mestic market against their foreign
counterparts. In short, unless U.S.
producers realign their priorities, a sig­
nificant reduction in the deficit by re­
ducing imports is not in the cards.

1 __ 1__ i__ 1__ i__ i__ i__ 1__ i__ i__ i__ 1______________
1985
1986
1987

low the expected path during periods
of strengthening and weakening
dollars—very much the path traced by
consumer durables. The amplitude of
the movement was substantially larger,
however. During the period when the
dollar was rising (1980-Q3 to 1985-Qj)
the price index for imported capital
equipment declined nearly 15 percent.
At the same time, however, domestic
capital equipment prices rose 21 per­
cent. In terms of price competitiveness
the decline in the position of domestic
capital equipment was substantial.
The ratio of import prices to domestic
prices fell by more than 35 percent
during this period (by comparison, the
decline in the comparable ratio for
consumer durables was 20 percent).
To make matters worse, with the dollar
now weaker, U.S. price competitiveness
in capital equipment has not improved
appreciably. The index of dollar prices
for capital equipment imports has in­
creased since the dollar began to de­
preciate in early 1985—by 13 percent
through the third quarter of 1987. But,
domestic prices continued to increase,
helping to offset the price incentive for
U.S. buyers to substitute domestic pro­
ducts for the higher priced imports.
The net effect is that by the third
quarter of 1987 the ratio of import
prices to domestic prices for capital
equipment was still 27 percent below

—Jack L. Hervey

1 T h e d e p reciatio n o f the d o llar has
boosted im p o rt prices. A ccording to U .S.
D e p a rtm e n t o f L a b o r estim ates, in the
fo urth q u a rte r o f 1987 im p o rt prices w ere,
on av erag e, n early 15 p ercen t above a
year-ago. E x p o rt prices, on the o th er
h a n d , w ere up a b o u t 7 percent.
A fact th a t m ust be kep t in m ind th ro u g h ­
o u t is th a t in the absence o f the d o llar d e­
p reciatio n the tra d e deficit w ould have
been la rg e r th a n th a t recorded.
2 T h e ratio o f im p o rt prices to dom estic
prices for consum er d u rab les in the thirdq u a rte r o f 1987 was only 9 p ercen t below
the 1980 figure. F or autos the ratio m oved
in favor o f dom estic p roducers w ith the
im p o rt-to -d o m estic ratio up 10 percent.

K arl A. Scheld, Senior Vice President and
D irector o f R esearch; David R. A llardice, Vice
P resident and Assistant D irector of R esearch;
E dw ard G. N ash, E ditor.
C hicago Fed L etter is published m onthly by the
Research D ep artm en t of the Federal Reserve
Bank o f C hicago. T h e views expressed are the
au th o rs’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System. Articles m ay be rep rin ted if the
source is credited and the R esearch D ep artm en t
is provided with copies o f the reprints.
C hicago Fed L etter is available w ithout charge
from the Public Inform ation C enter, Federal
Reserve Bank of C hicago, P.O . Box 834, C hicago,
Illinois 60690, or telephone (312) 322-511 1.

ISSN 0895-0164

Manufacturing activity in the nation rose 0.2 percent in December after two
months of solid gains, according to the Federal Reserve Board’s Index. Declines
in transportation equipment and machinery production accounted for much of the
overall slowdown.
The national pattern of two strong months followed by a weak December was
reflected in Midwest manufacturing activity. Because of the importance of
transportation equipment and machinery in the industrial structure of the Mid­
west, the Midwest Manufacturing Index declined 1.2 percent in December. Pri­
mary metals, which has been a major factor in the acceleration of manufacturing
activity throughout the nation during the last year, edged up by 0.1 percent in
the Midwest during December.

Chicago Fed Letter
F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F C H IC A G O
P u b lic In fo rm a tio n C en ter
P .O . Box 834
C h ica g o , Illin o is 60690

(312) 322-5111

N O T E : T h e M M I is a com posite index o f 15
m an u factu rin g industries and is constructed from
a w eighted com bination o f m onthly hours
worked, and kilow att hours d a ta . See “M idw est
M an u factu rin g Index: T h e C hicago F ed ’s new
regional econom ic in d icato r,” Economic Perspectives,
F ederal Reserve Bank o f Chicago, Vol. X I, No.
5, S ep tem b er/O cto b er, 1987. T h e U n ited States
represents the F ederal Reserve B o ard ’s In d ex of
In d u strial P roduction, M anufacturin g .