View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES
	

	 THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK	
OF CHICAGO

AUGUST 2013
	 NUMBER 313

Chicag­ Fed Letter
o
How does a federal minimum wage hike affect aggregate
household spending?
by Daniel Aaronson, vice president and director of microeconomic research, and Eric French, senior economist and research advisor

This article finds that a federal minimum wage hike would boost the real income and
spending of minimum wage households. The impact could be sufficient to offset increasing
consumer prices and declining real spending by most non-minimum-wage households
and, therefore, lead to an increase in aggregate household spending. The authors calculate
that a $1.75 hike in the hourly federal minimum wage could increase the level of real
gross domestic product (GDP) by up to 0.3 percentage points in the near term, but with
virtually no effect in the long term.

A central part of President Obama’s
2013 State of the Union address was a
proposal to gradually raise the hourly
federal minimum wage from $7.25 to $9.
Proponents of a higher minimum wage
argue it provides economic stimulus by
putting money into
1. 2012 distribution of wages in U.S. economy
the hands of people
who are especially
	
Number of		
Total wage	 Share of
Worker	
workers 	
Share of	 payments	
wage
likely to spend the excategory	
(in millions)	 workers	 ($ billions)	 payments
tra income.1 Oppo$6–$7.25/hour	 2	 0.02	 23	0.00
nents say a higher
minimum wage forces
$6–$9/hour	
15	 0.13	 204	0.04
firms that employ
$6–$10/hour	
22	
0.19	
338	
0.07
minimum wage workAll hourly workers	
69	
0.59	
2,165	
0.43
ers to cut jobs or
All workers	
117	
1.00	
5,073	
1.00
raise prices on goods
Notes: Sample weights are used to make the Current Population Survey (CPS) responand services. In this
dents comparable to the work force of the U.S. economy aged 16 years and older. Workers paid below the minimum wage of $7.25 per hour appear in the CPS mostly on account
Chicago Fed Letter, we
of measurement errors in self-reported data. Workers whose reported wages fall below
$6 per hour are excluded. Note that tips are included in the wage payment calculations.
use estimates from our
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics,
research to analyze
Current Population Survey.
both arguments.2

We begin by assessing the number of
workers whose wages would be affected
by a $1.75 hike in the hourly federal minimum wage. Next, based on our prior research, we predict the likely effects of an
increase in the hourly federal minimum
wage on total household income, consumer prices, and aggregate household

spending. We show that a $1.75 increase
in the minimum wage could raise real
GDP by about 0.3 percentage points
over the short run (first year). Allowing
more workers to lose their jobs or allowing
the spending response to be smaller than
our baseline estimates lowers our projected impact of the minimum wage hike
on real GDP over the short run. In addition, we predict the hike’s impact on real
GDP to be close to zero over the long run.3
We view the minimum wage as essentially
a “tax and transfer” program. Firms that
have to pay higher wages to their workers respond by raising prices on their
goods and services. Higher prices on
goods and services offset the income
benefit for minimum wage workers and
reduce the real income of non-minimumwage workers who did not get a wage
increase. Still, an increase in aggregate
household spending can arise if minimum
wage workers have a higher propensity
to spend—particularly in the short run—
than non-minimum-wage workers.
Whose wages are affected by a
minimum wage hike?

Figure 1 highlights the low end of the
U.S. wage distribution using data from

the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics’
Current Population Survey (CPS). Approximately 2 million workers, or 2% of the
work force, were paid at or just below
the current hourly federal minimum
wage of $7.25 in 2012. Roughly 15 million workers, representing 13% of the
work force, made $6–$9 per hour (i.e.,
at or somewhat below the proposed
new federal minimum). Employers are

National Income and Product Accounts of
the United States for that year. Most likely
this difference arises from an understatement of the earnings of high-income
individuals in the CPS, because such
individuals are difficult to reach via
household surveys. If aggregate wage
income has been understated, figure 1
overstates the share of total wage payments going to low-wage individuals.

In the near term, a minimum wage hike can stimulate economic
activity by putting money into the hands of people who are
especially likely to spend it.
not required to raise the wages of workers already earning above the new minimum wage. However, in practice they
may. Therefore, we include an additional 7 million workers who made
slightly more than the proposed new
federal minimum wage—i.e., those
earning $9–$10 per hour.
Although a substantial share of workers
would be affected by minimum wage
legislation, its effect on wage payments
would be relatively smaller. We estimate
that in 2012 roughly $200 billion, or
4% of total CPS-reported wage payments,
went to workers earning $6–$9 per hour,
and $338 billion, or 7% of total CPSreported wage payments, went to those
earning $6–$10 per hour.
When inferring the likely impact on total
household income, consumer prices,
and aggregate household spending
from the proposed federal minimum
wage hike, we face two important issues.
First, 19 states and a handful of cities
currently offer a minimum wage above—
and sometimes well above—the federal
minimum wage. So, if the hourly federal
minimum wage were raised by $1.75,
these states and cities might raise their
hourly minimum wages above $9. To
partly account for this, we allow earnings and spending to rise somewhat for
the wage group earning $9–$10 per hour.
Second, the aggregate wage income of
$5.07 trillion computed from the CPS
for 2012 is lower than the aggregate
wage income of $6.88 trillion reported
in the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis’s

Accounting for this possible overstatement reduces the share of total wage
payments going to those making $6–$9
per hour from 4% to 3%.
Household income

Next, we compute what happens to total
household income as a result of an increase in the hourly federal minimum
wage from $7.25 to $9. In Aaronson,
Agarwal, and French (2012), we used
data from three large, representative
data sets—the CPS, the U.S. Census
Bureau’s Survey of Income and Program
Participation, and the U.S. Bureau of
Labor Statistics’ Consumer Expenditure
Survey—to estimate the impact of a minimum wage hike on household income
with adult minimum wage workers. We
found that the average real income of
households with adult minimum wage
workers rose by $250 per quarter during the first few quarters in response to
a $1 increase in the minimum wage.4
If we assume that 15 million workers
earning $6–$9 per hour in 2012 receive
a $1.75 hourly wage increase and that
the income response is proportional to
what we found before, aggregate income
will rise by $250 × $1.75 × 15 million =
$6.6 billion per quarter, or roughly
$26 billion during the year immediately
following the hike. Those making
$9–$10 per hour likely receive a smaller
income increase than those making less.
Assuming that the income increase for
those earning $9–$10 per hour is only onethird of that for those earning $6–$9 per
hour (or $250/3 = $83), we find that

those earning $9–$10 per hour would
receive $83 × $1.75 × 7 million = $1 billion
per quarter, or $4 billion per year. We
also found in Aaronson, Agarwal, and
French (2012) that the income response
to a minimum wage increase is isolated
to the groups of workers at and just
above the minimum wage. Therefore,
the total income gain for all workers is
approximately $30 billion per year.
Our analysis in Aaronson, Agarwal, and
French (2012) was of adult minimum
wage workers—specifically, minimum
wage workers who are a household’s head
and spouse aged 18 and older (or in the
absence of a spouse, another working
household member aged at least 18).
Teenagers (unless they happen to be
counted as one of their household’s two
adult workers) and low-skilled workers
without jobs prior to the minimum wage
increase were omitted from our analysis.
There is some evidence that minimum
wage hikes might make it harder to get
a job, especially for teenagers, who represent 23% of the minimum wage labor
force.5 We return to this issue later.
Consumer prices

Using a variety of U.S. and Canadian
data, we demonstrated in Aaronson
(2001) and Aaronson, French, and
MacDonald (2008) that immediately
after a minimum wage increase, limitedservice restaurants (i.e., fast-food restaurants) employing minimum wage workers
pass close to 100% of the higher labor
costs on to consumers in the form of
higher prices.
We conjecture that other (nonrestaurant)
firms employing minimum wage workers
or using intermediate inputs requiring
minimum wage labor also pass close to
100% of the higher labor costs on to
consumers in the form of higher prices.6
A simple way to predict how a $1.75 increase in the hourly federal minimum
wage affects the price level is to compare
the increase in earnings resulting from
the hike to the level of real GDP (for
aggregate prices) or to the level of total
household consumption (for aggregate
consumer prices) under the assumption
of no disemployment effects. Based on
our estimate of a $30 billion earnings
impact in the first year, we calculate

that aggregate prices would rise by
0.19% (= $30 billion/$15.685 trillion
of 2012 real GDP) and aggregate consumer prices would go up by 0.27%
(= $30 billion/$11.12 trillion of 2012
total household consumption).7
Aggregate household spending

Finally, to quantify the aggregate household spending response to a federal
minimum wage hike, we need to consider the spending of both minimum
wage and non-minimum-wage earners
in response to the minimum wage hike.
Minimum wage earner spending

In Aaronson, Agarwal, and French
(2012), we found that real spending in
households with adult minimum wage
workers rises, on average, by approximately $700 per quarter during the first
few quarters following a $1 hike in the
hourly minimum wage. This additional
spending, which exceeds the immediate income gain of $250 per quarter, is
primarily on durable goods, particularly
new vehicles (financed with credit).
Our research shows that these patterns
can be partly reconciled by augmenting
a standard dynamic model of consumer
behavior to allow for the ability to borrow against durable goods. The intuition
for this result is simple. Suppose a household must make a 20% down payment
on an auto purchase. The existence of
this borrowing opportunity implies an
extra $250 per quarter in income can
be leveraged up to $1,250 ($250/0.2 =
$1,250) in additional spending. This
amount of spending is well beyond what
we find in the actual data, perhaps because some minimum wage households
cannot finance nondurable purchases
with credit.
The spending estimate of $700 per quarter
in response to a $1 hike in the hourly
minimum wage applies to households
with adult minimum wage workers. It
seems likely that teenagers, who make
up 23% of all minimum wage workers,
have less access to credit and therefore
will not be able to leverage their earnings. Instead, let us assume that teenage minimum wage workers spend all
their income as they earn it. Given the
number of teen and adult workers who
are likely affected by a $1.75 hike in the

hourly federal minimum wage (including
those earning $9–$10 per hour), we calculate that spending among minimum
wage households could add as much as
$73 billion to the economy in the year
following the hike, which is 0.47% of
real GDP and 0.66% of total household
consumption in 2012.
Non-minimum-wage earner spending

Workers who earn above the minimum
wage may decrease their real spending
as a consequence of a minimum wage
hike because they typically face higher
product and service prices without the
benefit of an earnings boost. Suppose
that the spending propensity of nonminimum-wage workers is such that they
reduce their real spending by $800 for
every $1,000 of real income lost.8 Those
losing the $1,000 of real income through
higher prices may not reduce their spending by the full $1,000 but may instead
reduce their savings. We predict that
this loss for non-minimum-wage earners
results in a $25 billion decline in real
spending in the year following the minimum wage hike.
Total spending

Combining the estimates for minimum
wage earners and non-minimum-wage
earners, we predict that an increase of
$1.75 in the hourly federal minimum
wage raises aggregate household spending by roughly $48 billion in the year
following the minimum wage hike, or
0.3% of 2012 real GDP.
However, a few words of caution are in
order. First, as we mentioned already,
our analysis is based on household income and spending responses from
samples of adult minimum wage workers who had a minimum wage job before the hike. There is some evidence
that minimum wage hikes might make
it harder to get a job, especially for teenagers. Additionally, some workers, particularly teenagers, may lose their jobs
as a consequence of a minimum wage
hike. For these reasons, we introduce
“disemployment elasticities” of –0.5 for
teenagers and –0.25 for adults (i.e., for
every 10% increase in the minimum
wage, the employment of teenagers and
adults making the minimum wage would
fall by 5% and 2.5%, respectively). Our

reading is that these elasticities are at
the high end of the literature. Nevertheless, allowing for disemployment of
these magnitudes reduces the aggregate
spending gain following a $1.75 hike in
the federal minimum wage to $28 billion, or 0.2% of 2012 real GDP. The
aggregate spending gain would decline
to zero if we assume a disemployment
elasticity of –0.7 for both teens and
adults. Therefore, while more disemployment than we allow for is certainly
plausible and would clearly lower our
estimate of the spending response, it’s
unlikely to completely eliminate the
entire boost to aggregate spending.
Additionally, for those with low income
and poor credit scores, it may be harder
to purchase cars on credit after the financial crisis than it was during the sample
period of 1980–2008, which we used to
estimate the spending response. Indeed,
our estimated aggregate spending response is high relative to the rest of the
literature. Instead, if we assume that
the marginal propensity to spend (i.e.,
the propensity to spend the next dollar)
for households with adult minimum
wage workers is half as large in the year
following a minimum wage hike as what

Charles L. Evans, President  Daniel G. Sullivan,
;
Executive Vice President and Director of Research;
Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic
Advisor ; David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial
markets group  Daniel Aaronson, Vice President,
;
microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Richard
Heckinger,Vice President, markets team; Anna L.
Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A. Testa,
Vice President, regional programs, and Economics Editor ;
Helen O’D. Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors  ;
Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors 
;
Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2013 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

we estimate in the data, the aggregate
spending response to a $1.75 increase
in the hourly federal minimum wage
would be only $4 billion, or 0.02% of
2012 real GDP. This result highlights
the mechanism of our prediction—any
additional consumer spending from a
minimum wage hike arises from differences in the propensity to spend
among different income groups.

Finally, it’s important to stress that the
aggregate household spending response
discussed in this article is relevant for
only the first few quarters after a minimum wage hike. Beyond that time frame,
households must pay off debt they incurred in the short run by spending less.
Thus, a minimum wage hike provides
stimulus for a year or so, but serves as a
drag on the economy beyond that.

Conclusion

1	 See, e.g., New York Times Company, 2013,

3	 For further explanation of the calculations

5

in this article, see www.chicagofed.org/
digital_assets/others/people/research_
resources/aaronson_daniel/aaronson_
french_cfl_313_calculations.xlsx and
www.chicagofed.org/digital_assets/others/
people/research_resources/aaronson_
daniel/aaronson_french_cfl_313_
calculations_documentation.pdf.

“From the bottom up,” New York Times,
February 17, available at www.nytimes.com/
2013/02/18/opinion/wages-from-thebottom-up.html.

2	 Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and

Eric French, 2012, “The spending and
debt response to minimum wage hikes,”
American Economic Review, Vol. 102, No. 7,
December, pp. 3111–3139; Daniel Aaronson,
Eric French, and James MacDonald, 2008,
“The minimum wage, restaurant prices,
and labor market structure,” Journal of
Human Resources, Vol. 43, No. 3, Summer,
pp. 688–720; and Daniel Aaronson, 2001,
“Price pass-through and the minimum wage,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 83,
No. 1, February, pp. 158–169.

	 To put this estimate into perspective, note

4

that adult minimum wage employees work,
on average, roughly 300 hours per quarter.
Under three assumptions—there is no disemployment (i.e., job loss) due to the minimum wage hike, all workers who are paid
close to the minimum wage are covered
by minimum wage laws, and there is no
measurement error—we anticipate a $1
minimum wage hike to increase each
adult minimum wage employee’s quarterly
earnings by $300.

Proponents of minimum wage increases
often claim that minimum wage hikes
will significantly boost the economy. We
are skeptical that minimum wage hikes
boost GDP in the long run. Nevertheless,
we do find evidence that putting money
into the hands of consumers, especially
low-wage consumers, leads to predictable
increases in spending in the short run.
	 U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2012, “Char-

acteristics of minimum wage workers: 2011,”
report, Washington, DC, March 2, available
at www.bls.gov/cps/minwage2011.htm.

	 Prices and incomes might also rise follow-

6

ing a minimum wage hike because of the
increase in aggregate demand for goods
and services. We do not account for this
possibility in our analysis.

	 Real GDP and total household consump-

7

tion data are from the U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis.

	 See, e.g., Jonathan A. Parker, Nicholas S.

8

Souleles, David S. Johnson, and Robert
McClelland, 2011, “Consumer spending
and the economic stimulus payments of
2008,” National Bureau of Economic
Research, working paper, No. 16684,
January, available at www.nber.org/papers/
w16684.