View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Foreword

The year just past has been
m e m o r a b le fo r th e
American people. The Bicentennial was, all in all, a
good year. It was a year of fresh insights and
rediscovery. It was a year during which Americans
had the opportunity—and the motivation—to reflect
upon the roots of their society, to consider their past.
And in thinking about their origins, Americans were
provided with some new perspectives on where they
might and ought to be going.
In particular—and quite naturally so—the in­
stitutional framework of the American system of
government was in the spotlight during 1976.
Americans looked at their governmental system and
were reminded how unique it is—not only in its
peculiar institutional arrangements but in its relative
longevity as the cornerstone of a democratic soci­
ety. They retraced that system to its origins and
found them in the philosophies and hopes and even
in the fears and suspicions of the founding fathers.
They discovered that even though the nation’s cir­
cumstances have changed dramatically in the past
200 years, the aspirations of the nation’s people have
remained surprisingly constant. And the American
people found in the end that the underlying
framework of their public institutions still serves
them rather well, even if the performance of those in­
stitutions can be found wanting from time to time.
It is in this same spirit that we at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago have taken the opportuni­
ty provided by our 1976 Annual Report to reflect
momentarily on the structure of one of our public
institutions—the Federal Reserve System—before
turning to the Chicago Fed’s performance, as one
component of that structure, during the past year.
Our primary aim is not really to describe the rather
unusual structure of the nation’s central banking
system, but rather to place that structure in a
perspective that makes it somewhat more un­
derstandable. And even more importantly, it is
hoped that by putting the Fed’s structure in the con­
text of the past, some focus can be provided for
current discussion of whether that structure can
continue to meet the nation’s needs for the future.

\976 Afy/y,

^ F R A L R E S ***

The Fed in perspective: 1776-1976
The Chicago Fed in review: 1976
Statement of condition
Statement of earnings
Directors
Officers

The Fed in perspective: 1776-1976
The Federal Reserve System—two hun­
dred years old? Obviously not. It was “ born''
in this century; only some sixty-odd years
have passed since President Woodrow Wilson
signed the Federal Reserve Act. Nevertheless,
the Fed of 1914—the year it was established—
and, indeed, the Fed of today is as much a
reflection of the philosophies expressed in
the structuring of the American republic as it
is a creature of early twentieth-century
American experience.
Without viewing the Fed in such a
perspective, one that transcends its own
lifespan, it is almost impossible to make sense
of its many unusual—indeed unique—
characteristics: the fact that although the Fed
is the U.S. central bank, its structure is basical­
ly decentralized; the fact that although it is a
public institution, with a public purpose, the
Federal Reserve Banks which carry out this
purpose are strikingly private in form; the fact
that although all Fed operations are aimed at
serving the public as a whole, direct dealings
with the public at large are limited compared
to interactions with firms within the private
sector; and finally, the fact that although the
Fed is without doubt a governmental agency,
its operations are largely independent from
the government.
These truly unusual features in the
Federal Reserve’s structure cannot be ex­
plained solely by the economic circumstances
at the time of the Fed’s establishment. In fact,
even the whole of U.S. history, including the
rise and fall of the country’s two previous cen­
tral banks, cannot adequately explain the
Fed’s “ split personality.” (See Box.) To truly
make sense out of this unique central bank,
one must look beyond American historical
events—one must look to the uniquely
American ideas and philsophies that shaped
the nation’s history.

The “ key” to the Fed’s structure. . .

In his Farewell Address, George
Washington warned of “ ...that love of power,
and proneness to abuse it, which pre­
dominates in the human heart.” Hewenton,
The necessity of reciprocal checks in the
exercise of political power; by dividing
and distributing it into different
depositories, and constituting each the
Guardian of the Public Weal against in­
vasions by the others, has been evinced
by experiments ancient and modern;—
some of them in our country and under
our own eyes. To preserve them must be
as necessary as to institute them.
These sentiments are fundamental to our
system of government. While the founding
fathers most certainly displayed abundant op­
timism in launching the “ great American ex­
periment” and in creating institutions to fulfill
their hopes for the future, it was their abiding
pessimism that government power could
“ forge the fetters for freedom” that deter­
mined their approach to those institutions.
In the eyes of the founding fathers, only a
fine line separated the exercise of power and
the abuse of power. To avoid creating con­
centrations of power, to assure that this line
would not be crossed, they created a
governmental structure with built-in limits on
power—a system of “ checks and balances.”
Not only was the latitude of each branch of
the federal government to exercise power
sharply restricted by the powers granted to
the others, the power granted to the national
government as a whole was circumscribed. It
was a federal rather than a central govern­
ment that was established, a government that
could exercise only those powers specifically

1

The "split personality” of the Fed
The Federal Reserve is a central bank but it is d ecen tralized:

Instead of a single central bank, there are 12 regional Reserve Banks. The operations of each,
while coordinated through the System's Board of Governors, are to a significant degree
autonomous from those of the others. Moreover, the Fed's relationship to the commercial
banking system is strangely dichotomous for a central monetary authority since it is individual
commercial banks that exercise the option of membership in the Federal Reserve. Perhaps
most interestingly, authority for each of the central bank’s primary policy tools (reserve re­
quirements, discount rates, open market operations) is vested in a different component within
the System.
The Fed is a public institution with a public purpose, but many of its characteristics are m ore
typical of a private organization:

Like any public institution the Fed can be reduced to a singular purpose: promoting the well­
being of the nation’s people. Specifically, the Fed pursues economic stability and growth, high
employment and stable prices, both domestic and international, through its power to in­
fluence the flow of money and credit in the nation's economy. But while its substance is wholly
public, the Fed’s form is strikingly private. Reserve Banks have corporate charters, private
“ stockholders,” and directors representing the "stockholders” who elect them. And while the
Fed operates for the purpose of serving the public at large, many of its operations represent
service to a particular industry (commercial banking) within the private sector and even
parallel services offered by firms within the private sector.

enumerated, with any other powers remain­
ing the preserve of the various states.
Striking parallels to the concerns raised
by Washington can be found in thoughts ex­
pressed at the time plans for the nation’s third
central bank, ultimately the Federal Reserve
System, were being discussed:
We must devise a plan, suited to the
democratic genius of our government,
which will save us from a dominating,
powerful, centralized monetary in­
stitution.1

1J. Laurence Laughlin, The Federal Reserve Act, Its
Origins and Problems (New York: Macmillian Co., 1933)
p. 389. Speech delivered in Chicago on May 24,1911 by
j.L. Laughlin, Professor of Political Economy at the
University of Chicago and Chairman of the Executive
Committee of the National Citizens’ League for the
Promotion of a Sound Banking System.
2New York Times, 18 January 1911, p. 5. Statement (in
reference to the Aldrich plan) of Paul M. Warburg,

2

The plan gives to the future central
organ sufficient powers to render it ef­
ficient but at the same time restricts the
functions of the central organ so that no
possible danger of abuse in dealing with
individual concerns or of interfering
with the business of the existing banks,
need be apprehended.2
It seems to me that he has avoided the
prejudice felt against a central bank,
w hile safeguarding the proposed
reserve association from becoming a
political football.3

partner in the New York banking firm of Kuhn, Loeb and
Company. In 1914 Mr. Warburg was appointed to the first
Federal Reserve Board.
3Chicago Daily Tribune, 18 January 1911, p. 6. State­
ment (in reference to the Aldrich plan) of George M.
Reynolds, President, Continental and Commercial
National Bank, Chicago. From 1914 Mr. Reynolds served
almost 20 years on the Board of Directors of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago.

The Fed is a com ponent of the governm ental structure, but in large part it operates in ­
dependently of the governm ent:

Like any other government agency, the Fed is the creation of a legislative act, and just as Con­
gress established it, Congress could modify or even abolish the Fed as it sees fit. Like officials of
other government agencies, the members of the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors are ap­
pointed by the President with the advice and consent of the Senate, and report to Congress
periodically on the performance of the agency they administer. But despite these clear ties to
government, the Fed's degree of independence from government—especially on a day-to-day
basis—is almost unique, not only among American government agencies, but among most
central banks in the world. Underlying the Fed’s independent posture within government are
the facts that:
• The Fed is not subject to Congress's "power of the purse” —it operates on its own earnings
rather than federal budget appropriations, and it need not seek Congress’s prior approval
for its actions and programs (so long, of course, as they are consistent with the Federal
Reserve Act).
• The Fed, in formulating and executing national monetary policy, is institutionally separated
from all other components of the federal government that exercise responsibility in the
economic policy area. In particular, and in sharp contrast to many other central banks, the
Fed is not an agency within the executive branch's finance ministry, i.e., our Treasury
Department.
• The Fed’s governmental^ appointed officials serve 14-year terms, terms longer than those of
the elected officials who choose them. In addition, the power to appoint many other Fed of­
ficials largely resides in the private sector.

The "prejudice felt against a central
bank” was the natural outgrowth of the
American view of man’s propensity to abuse
power. The fear of a “ dominating, powerful,
centralized monetary institution” was
endemic given the American's suspicion of
central authority of any kind.
It was these fears and suspicions that
were expressed by the Jeffersonians—that
creating an institution which concentrated
economic power in the hands of a few would
be tantamount to granting it the power to
d estro y individual liberties, thereby
resurrecting the tyranny the revolution had
overthrown. It was these fears that forestalled
the establishment of a U.S. central bank until
the end of the eighteenth century, and
likewise sealed the demise of two U.S. central
banks during the nineteenth century. And it
was these fears that shaped the unique U.S.
central banking system that was devised in the
twentieth century.

. . . C h e ck s and balances

Just as the concept of a central bank
posed the same paradox the American people
had encountered in creating institutions to
govern them—that the power to promote the
public good could also be used to contravene
it—the same device, a system of checks and
balances, was employed to resolve the
paradox. These checks, or safeguards against
the abusive use of central bank power,
provide the Fed with its own paradoxical but
uniquely American features.
On the one hand, the perceived need to
place checks on the power and influence of
the central bank itself dictated the Fed's
uniquely decentralized design. Reserve Bank
autonomy and the distribution of authority
for monetary policy implementation between
distinct components of the Fed parallel the
distribution of counterbalancing powers
between the various branches of the federal

3

government. And comparable to con­
stitutional provisions which insured that the
federal government's power would be less
than absolute—preserving powers to the
various states—voluntary membership
restricted the central bank’s control over the
commercial banking system—preserving the
dual banking system or the authority of state
governments to charter and regulate banks.
On the other hand, various features of
the Fed’s structure have to be regarded as
designed to limit the ability of those outside
the institution from using the central bank to
promote their own self-interest, i.e., to serve
narrow economic or political purposes.
Similar to the constitution of the federal
government, the device employed to isolate
the Fed from any single interest group was to
subject it to a plurality of interests. Control
over the Fed is diffused between the branches
of the federal government and between the
public and private sectors. The regional struc­
ture, the mechanisms for selection of officials,
and the institutional separation of monetary
and fiscal policy serve to insulate Fed policy
from particular partisan or economic

pressures; these features encourage its
responsiveness to a diversity of influences—
both geographic and sectoral.
With only very few exceptions the Fed’s
distinguishing characteristics are unchanged
from 1914. Indeed, of the few modifications to
the Fed’s original structure, probably the
most notable—the removal of two govern­
ment officials from the Federal Reserve Board
after 1935—further strengthened one of the
Fed’s unique features.
But the absence of major structural
change is hardly sufficient evidence that
Americans have discovered the ideal in­
stitutional framework for a central bank.
Without doubt, Americans today are as firm as
their predecessors in their distaste for con­
centrations of power. But the true test for the
American people of the viability of any public
institution must be whether the structure of
the institution enhances its capacity to
promote the public good as well as lessens its
potential to harm it. If the Fed’s structure is
found at any future time to be inconsistent
with the needs, goals and aspirations of the
American people, it will likely be changed.

The Chicago Fed in review: 1976
In a sense, the major activities of a
Reserve Bank today, like the structural
characteristics of the Federal Reserve System,
generally correspond to those outlined in the
original Federal Reserve Act. Establishing a
nationwide payments system by collecting
checks deposited by banks, providing curren­
cy consistent with the needs of commerce by
issuing Federal Reserve notes, providing li­
quidity to the banking system by discounting
commercial paper, serving as the fiscal agent
of the U.S. Government, supervising various
commercial bank activities, and stabilizing
financial markets through discount rate ad­
justments and the purchase and sale of
securities—all these activities were discussed

4

in the first annual report issued by the
Chicago Fed for 1915.
Obviously, however, much has tran­
spired during the past 60years. The nation has
e xp e rien ced fantastic industrial and
economic growth and has benefited from
continuous technological progress. Financial
institutions have become increasingly
sophisticated, and regional markets have
given way to truly national financial markets.
And demands on public institutions to play a
more active role in promoting the economic
well-being of the American people have in­
tensified. Each and all of these factors had and
will continue to have a significant impact on
Chicago Fed operations.

Payments mechanism operations

N um ber of items

D o llar am ount
1975

1976
C h ecks co llected :
C o m m ercial bank checks
U .S. governm ent checks*
Noncash items collected . .
Transfers o f fu n d s ...................

798.8
42.2
1.4
6.007.7

billion
billion
billion
hillion

714.4
41.9
1.3
4 948 6

billion
billion
billion
hillinn

1976

1975

1.8 billion
1.6 billion
104.2 m illion 120.0 m illion
.5 m illio n **
1.1 m illion
^ A m illin n

9 ft m i l l i o n

‘ Includ es postal m oney orders.
“ Basis for counting items changed from 1975.

"O n November 16, 1914, the date this
bank opened for business, it installed a collec­
tion system...” The Chicago Fed's first annual
report went on to say, "The development of
the check-collecting function has proved the
most difficult problem confronting the
management of the bank.”
A dramatic change has taken place in the
magnitude and scope of Chicago Fed
payments activities since 1915, reflecting the
nation's economic growth and technological
progress through the ensuing years. Perhaps
unchanged, however, despite the fact that a
"less-check” society no longer need be
regarded in futuristic terms, is that check
collection remains the Chicago Fed’s most ex­
pensive function, and in a sense, as it was in
1915, its most difficult function. Since the five
offices of the Chicago Fed—Chicago, Detroit,
Des Moines, Indianapolis, and Milwaukee—
consistently process more checks than in any
other Federal Reserve District, increasing ef­
ficiency is a constant challenge. “ Operations
improvements” and productivity analyses
have become the focal point of Chicago Fed
check collection activities in order to ease and
speed a continuously increasing work load.
One result has been the implementation of
new computer programs at all five offices dur­
ing 1976.
But while the check remains a viable and
much used payments instrument, certainly
most discussed in the payments mechanism
area today are the various developments
which substitute electronic fund transfers for
check payments. The Federal Reserve’s
systemwide communications network has for
a number of years provided a facility for

effecting paperless payments. The Chicago
Fed currently processes more than $6 trillion
in funds transfers annually through this
system, a dollar total which greatly exceeds its
check volume, and during 1976, the Detroit
Branch for the first time passed the $1 trillion
mark in funds transferred. Current efforts to
expand and improve this system are aimed
primarily at linking additional member banks
"on-line” or computer-to-computer with the
network. During 1976 six additional banks
served by the Chicago head office and seven
banks in the Detroit Branch territory were
linked to the network for a total of 27 district
banks, and the Detroit Branch was linked
directly to Chicago. As a result, the volume of
paperless transfers that could be processed
instantaneously was greatly increased.
Chicago Fed participation in other elec­
tronic payments projects was also notable
during 1976. Automated clearing houses
(ACHs), which exchange electronic-based
payment information such as direct deposit
payrolls, have been organized with Chicago
Fed cooperation in all five office cities. All are
operational except the ACH in Milwaukee,
and its implementation is imminent.
Finally, and probably most significant in
terms of the number of current check
payments eliminated by electronic transfers
in the Seventh District, have been devel­
opments in the area of federal government
recurring payments programs. The five
Chicago Fed offices, the Treasury Depart­
ment, and the district’s financial institutions
cooperated to automate Seventh District
Social Security direct deposits during 1976—
removing over half a million payments each

5

Statement of condition
(In thousands of dollars)
As of December 31
1975

1976

Assets
C o ld certificate a c c o u n t ..................................................
Interdistrict settlem ent a c c o u n t..................................
Special draw ing rights certificate acco unt . . . .
Federal R eserve notes o f other b a n k s ...................
O th e r c a s h ..................................................................................
Loans:
Secured by U .S. G o vern m en t s e c u r it ie s ...........
O t h e r ............................................................................................

$ 1,704,081
570,496
190,000
76,709
36,278

Total lo an s...............................................................................
Federal agency obligations, bought o u trig h t. .
U .S. G o ve rn m en t s e c u r it ie s ..........................................

$

Total loans and s e c u r it ie s .............................................
Cash items in process o f c o lle c t io n ........................
Bank p re m is e s ..........................................................................
O th e r a s s e ts ...............................................................................

$16,030,574
1,182,956
15,715
238,751

$14,022,937
1,460,522
15,651
206,022

Total assets ...............................................................................

$20,045,560

$17,977,159

$ 1,767,736
324,257
79,000
71,867
29,167

7,020
—
7,020
1,087,925
14,935,629

46,000
—
$

46,000
914,637
1 3,062,300

Liabilities
Federal R eserve n o t e s ........................................................
Deposits:
M em b er bank r e s e rv e s ..................................................
U .S. Treasury— general a cco u n t................................
Fo re ig n ..........................................................................................
O t h e r ............................................................................................

$13,972,631

$12,464,478

3,713,914
824,742
36,062
222,489

3,744,954
493,323
40,440
58,306

Total d e p o sits.......................................................................
D eferred availability cash ite m s...................................
O th e r lia b ilit ie s .......................................................................

$ 4,797,207
837,098
142,708

$ 4,337,023
739,575
152,375

Total liabilities .......................................................................

$19,749,644

$17,693,451

Capital accounts
Capital paid i n ..........................................................................
S u rp lu s ............................................................................................

Total liabilities and capital accounts .....................

6

$

147,958
147,958

$20,045,560

$

141,854
141,854

$17,977,159

The financial
enterprises—balance s
income—are statistical
future capacity to g
provide a basis for evt
contrast, Federal Resei
under an earningsobje
earnings are incident;
formed. Changes in tl
and income items refl
economy and actions t
System monetary obj
mainly of interest on
System’s portfolio of Tr
this is returned to the
and statutory dividenc
paid.
Through purchase
member banks, the Re
base for expansion in
accord with the econc
ditions to member ba
result from this proces
currency or used to sup
at commercial banks.
Last year almost £
Reserve Bank credit wa
of currency (Federal R<
in response to public <
mercial bank deposit
member bank reserves
of lower reserve req
deposits between bant
differing reserve requi
System monetary p
ed at providing reserv
sufficient to finance <
pansion, resulted in a
bank’s share of secur
Open Market Accoun
earned on this larger pi
tor accounting for the
over 1975. It more than
market interest rates,
banks, reductions in t
creased expenses. Re:
less this bank’s share o
actions losses entailed
operations, produced
Treasury.

tements of private
ets and statements of
ficators of current and
grate earnings. They
iting performance. By
Banks do not operate
^although substantial
to the functions perr major asset, liability
developments in the
fertaken in support of
ives. Income consists
s bank’s share of the
;ury securities. Most of
easury after expenses
o member banks are
securities and loans to
rve Banks increase the
rency and deposits in
y’s growth needs. Adreserve deposits that
re either withdrawn as
rt the public's deposits
of the net increase in
bsorbed by the payout
rve notes outstanding)
nands. Although comose slightly last year,
dined, mainly because
ements and shifts of
nd d e p o s it cla sse s w ith

nents.
cy actions in 1976, aimto the banking system
itinued economic ex­
billion increase in this
?s held in the System
he increase in interest
folio was the major facrrease in 1976 earnings
fset the effects of lower
wer loans to member
discount rate, and inting current earnings,
>reign exchange trans­
currency stabilization
ecord payment to the

Statement of earnings
(In thousands o f dollars)
Year ending December 31
1975

1976
C u rre n t earnings:
Advances and d is c o u n ts ..................................................................
U .S. G o vern m en t s e c u r it ie s .................................................
Foreign c u r r e n c ie s ...............................................................................
A ll o t h e r .......................................................................................................
Total curren t e a rn in g s ....................................................................

$

639
1,006,357
4,320
252

$

1,588
927,614
842
255

$1,011,567

$930,299

$

78,053
6,009
6,365

$ 71,844
4,112
6,168

T o t a l..............................................................................................................
Less reim bursem ent for certain
fiscal agency and o ther e x p e n s e s ..........................................

$

90,427

$ 81,124

7,291

6,919

C u rre n t net e xp e n se s.........................................................................

$

83,136

74,205

C u rre n t net e a r n in g s ..........................................................................

$

928,431

$856,094

Additions to cu rren t net earnings:
Profit on sales of U .S. G o vern m en t securities (net) . .
All o t h e r ......................................................................................................

$

5,111
214

$

5,828
317

Total a d d itio n s.......................................................................................

$

5,325

$

6,145

D eductions from cu rren t net earnings:
Loss on foreign exchange transactions ( n e t ) ..................
A ll o t h e r ......................................................................................................

$

3,836
§2

$

3,897

C u rre n t expenses:
O perating e x p e n s e s ............................................................................
Federal Reserve c u r r e n c y ...............................................................
Assessm ent for expenses of Board o f G o vern o rs . . . .

Total d e d u c tio n s ..................................................................................
Net deductions from (-) or additions
to current net e a rn in g s ..................................................................
Net earnings before paym ents
to U.S. T re a s u ry ....................................................................................

1/429
$

929,860

D ividends p a id .........................................................................................
Payments to U .S. Treasury
(interest on Federal Reserve n o t e s )....................................

$

8,661

Transferred to s u r p lu s .......................................................................

$

$ 37,236
33
$

- 31,124
$824,970
$

915,095
6,104

37,269

8,453
812,186

$

4,331

Surplus account
Surplus, January 1 ..................................................................................
Transferred to surplus— as a b o v e .............................................

$ 141,854
6,104

$137,523
4,331

Surplus, D ecem b er 3 1 .......................................................................

$ 147,958

$141,854

7

month from check-processing channels.
Railroad and Civil Service retirement
payments were also automated at year-end.

and the automation of additional payments—
such as veterans, revenue sharing, govern­
ment salaries—can be anticipated.

Currency operations
D o llar am ount
1976
C u rre n c y received and c o u n te d ...........
U nfit cu rren cy w ith d ra w n ...........................
C o in received and c o u n te d .....................
Food stamps received and processed.

1975

6.8 billion
1.2 billion
229.5 m illion
938.5 m illion

About $4.4 million in Federal Reserve
notes, the new currency created by the
Federal Reserve Act, had been issued by the
Chicago Fed at the end of 1915. Today, the
Chicago Fed’s balance sheet indicates that
almost $14 billion of its notes are outstanding,
reflecting current needs for currency to ac­
commodate total spending in today’s
economy. But the significance of the Fed’s
currency activities is not the growth in the
magnitude of these figures. Its real sig­
nificance is how easily currency and coin
flows to and from the Reserve Banks—into
and out of the hands of the public—as the
needs of commerce dictate.The nation today
has the truly “ elastic” currency that the
Federal Reserve Act sought.
The Fed of Chicago satisfies the currency
needs in its district by supplying currency and
coin in whatever volumes and denominations
its member banks request—which in turn cor­

N um ber of items

6.5
1.2
230.0
870.3

billion
billion
m illion
m illion

1976
890.8 m illion
271.7 m illion
1.8 billion
244.7 m illion

1975
874.9 m illion
278.7 m illion
1.7 billion
282.7 m illion

respond to the demands of bank customers—
and charging member banks’ reserve ac­
counts. Conversely, when the public’s stock
of currency or coin held exceeds its needs,
the excess flows back into commercial banks
and ultimately to the Reserve Bank, where it is
stored for reissue or withdrawn if unfit for
further circulation. Currency operations at
the Fed today also include the receipt—and
destruction—of food stamps.
On April 13,1976—Jefferson’s birthday—
the $2 bill was reintroduced by the Chicago
Fed and other Reserve Banks. Substantial
savings in Treasury printing costs and Federal
Reserve handling costs could result from
broad acceptance of the bill, i.e., where twos
replaced ones. But despite promotional ef­
forts, actual circulation of the $2 bill has not
approached what had been desired. By yearend the Chicago Fed head office had issued
about $61 million in $2 bills.

“ Discount window” operations

D o llar am ount
1976
Loans to m em ber banks

2.6

When the Chicago Fed opened, its dis­
count operation—providing short-term li­
quidity to member banks—was regarded as its
paramount tool for influencing general

8

1975

billion

5.0 billion

N um ber of banks
accom m odated
1976

1975

114

166

money and credit conditions. Given the
development of national money markets,
which serve to efficiently channel funds to
regions where they are most needed, other

located in areas where economic activity
tends to follow pronounced seasonal pat­
terns. Such banks—typically smaller in­
stitutions in rural areas—lack ready access to
national credit markets. The original re­
quirements for qualifying for seasonal credit,
however, effectively precluded participation
by many of the banks meant to be served by
the program. A study by the Chicago Fed of
143 “ seasonal” district banks found that cer­
tain restrictions excluded all but nine from
qualifying for seasonal credit. As a result,
seasonal borrowing program requirements
were significantly liberalized during 1976.

Federal Reserve activities—especially open
market operations—have become more
effective devices for influencing the flow of
money and credit in the national economy.
Nonetheless, the availability and exten­
sion of credit through the Reserve Bank
“ discount window” still serve an important
economic stabilization function, and through
time Fed credit programs have been modified
and expanded. Provisions for longer-term
emergency credit were added in the 1930s.
More recently, in 1973, the seasonal borrow­
ing program was implemented to aid banks,
and thereby the communities they serve,

“ Bank service” operations
D o llar am ount
1976
Safekeeping of securities
D efinitive s e c u r it ie s .....................................
Book entry s e c u ritie s ..................................
Purchases and sales of securities
for m em ber banks ........................................

1975

N um ber of items
1976

1975

7.7 billion
31.6 billion

7.2 billion
21.3 billion

1.6 m illion

1.6 m illion

1.1 billion

852.7 m illion

11.6 thous.

12.7 thous.

The payments, currency and lending ac­
tivities of the Chicago Fed emanate from
specific provisions of the Federal Reserve Act.
Through time, the Fed has taken the oppor­
tunity to expand the range of its activities
which interface with member bank opera­
tions for the purpose of enhancing commer­
cial bank operating efficiency and/or System
membership. Generally, these activities
utilize Fed facilities and expertise developed
in conjunction with statutory responsibilities

or serve to encourage more efficient utiliza­
tion of its facilities.
Examples of services provided by the
Chicago Fed in this regard are: the purchase,
sale and safekeeping of securities for member
banks; the functional cost analysis and bank
visitation programs; and various seminars and
meetings with banks where Fed operations
are discussed. During 1976 a new publication,
the FED WIRE, was introduced to improve
communication with district banks.

Supervision and regulation
Perhaps no single area of Federal Reserve
operations has expanded so dramatically as its
supervision and regulation responsibilities.
Americans have increasingly demanded that
the public sector take a more active role in
assuring that the private sector’s performance
be consistent with the public interest, and the
Federal Reserve has been significantly

affected by this trend.
From its original activities, such as ex­
amining bank operations for safety and
soundness and passing on applications for
trust powers and membership, the Fed is to­
day involved in the regulation of almost every
phase of commercial bank operations: from
mergers, branches, holding companies, and

9

bank operations abroad to the imposition of
deposit interest rate ceilings, reserve re­
quirements, and margin requirements for
securities purchases. Particularly significant
has been the recent development of Fed
regulatory responsibilities in the area of con­
sumer credit, where Congress has generally
charged the System with formulating
regulations applicable to all credit vendors,
not solely commercial banks: Truth-in­
Lending since 1969, Equal Credit Opportunity
in 1975, and Home Mortgage Disclosure dur­
ing 1976. And these newer regulations are
themselves expanding as a result of subse­
quent Congressional legislation, e.g., the ad­
dition of Fair Credit Billing (in 1975) and con­
sumer leasing (to take effect in 1977) toTruthin-Lending, and the expansion of Equal Credit
to prohibit racial, religious and other types of

discrim ination in addition to original
provisions covering sex and marital status.
During 1976 the Federal Reserve’s Board
of Governors adopted a new regulation, AA—
“ Unfair or Deceptive Acts or Practices by
Banks’’—specifying formal procedures for
handling consumer complaints. Complaints
concerning district financial institutions are
handled by the Chicago Fed’s Consumer Af­
fairs Division, established in 1975. The unit im­
plemented in May of 1976 a pilot program of
separate examinations of state member
banks, focusing exclusively on regulation
com pliance. The unique Chicago Fed
program, which is aimed at educating banks
in new regulatory requirements as well as
checking for institutional comformity, has
drawn the interest of other federal bank
regulators.

Fiscal agency operations
D o llar am ount
1976
M arketable go vernm ent securities
issued, se rviced , red ee m ed :*
D efinitive s e c u r it ie s .............................
Book entry s e c u r it ie s ..........................
U .S. savings bonds issued,
serviced , r e d e e m e d .............................
Fed tax receipts p ro c e s s e d ................

19.7
589.0

N um ber of items

1975

billion
billion

3.6
billion
41.4 billion

1976

43.9 billion
379.3 billion
3.6
35.7

billion
billion

701.2
221.4

thous.
thous.

55.6
4.4

m illion
m illion

1975

1.3 m illion
204.8 thous.
53.0
6.6

m illion
m illion

’ Includ es transfers of securities.

The Federal Reserve Act provided that
the Federal Reserve Banks could be ap­
pointed as the depositories and fiscal agents
of the U.S. Government at the discretion of
the Secretary of the Treasury. The assignment
of these functions was announced on
November 23,1915. Since that time Chicago
Fed fiscal agent operations have grown con­
tinuously, reflecting the constant growth in
the financial needs and requirements of its
“ customer."
During 1976 a number of developments
significantly affected the Chicago Fed’s fiscal
agency operations. The Federal ReserveTreasury Department cooperative effort to

10

encourage conversion of Treasury debt
securities to “ book-entry” form took a major
step forward during the year. In August the
Treasury announced plans to phase out the
issuance of all definitive Treasury bills.(Efforts
since 1968 had already resulted in the sub­
stitution of computerized accounting entries
for paper or definitive certificates for over 80
percent of marketable public debt). Infor­
mational materials on book-entry were made
available in the district by the Chicago Fed,
and during December all 52-week bills were
for practical purposes issued in book-entry
ft.rm only. Issues of definitive securities for
26-week and 13-week bills are to be

eliminated in June and September 1977,
respectively, and the program will un­
doubtedly be expanded to other marketable
Treasury securities in the future.
The Chicago Fed, in cooperation with the
Internal Revenue Service and Seventh District
banks, also implemented a major change in its
procedures for processing federal tax de­
posits during 1976. Early in the third quarter
district banks serving as fed tax depositories
began sending those deposits directly to IRS
service centers rather than to the Chicago Fed

for intermediate processing. Because of the
change, tax payments are credited to taxpayer
accounts far more expeditiously, and the
number of unwarranted late notices should
be drastically reduced.
Finally, during 1976 steps were taken to
improve the public’s understanding of
Treasury securities. The Chicago Fed head of­
fice implemented a new 24-hour telephone
service providing information on current
Treasury offerings and produced a new
general information fact sheet.

Monetary policy
When the Federal Reserve System was es­
tablished, the discount function was regarded
as its primary tool for influencing the flow of
money and credit in the economy. The Act
authorized the 12 regional Reserve Banks
(subject to approval by the Federal Reserve
Board) to change their individual discount
rates. Largely to complement and support the
discount function, the banks were also
authorized to engage in open market
operations— i.e., to purchase and sell
securities for their own accounts. Later, Con­
gress empowered the Federal Reserve Board
to change reserve requirements within
specified limits.
Because open market operations can be
adapted continuously to changing economic
and financial conditions, they have become
the principal tool of monetary policy. And
with financial markets now national in scope,
such operations have had to be centralized:
Reserve Banks no longer buy and sell
securities independently. Instead, Reserve
Bank presidents serve jointly with the Board
of Governors on the Federal Open Market
Com m ittee (FO M C), which formulates
policies and guidelines for transactions in the
System Open Market Account.
Since 1975 annual monetary growth
“ target” ranges have been made public on a
quarterly basis by the FOMC. The ranges set
each quarter for the year ahead reflect the
FOM C’s judgment of the rate of monetary ex­

pansion consistent with the desired perfor­
mance of the economy, taking account of fac­
tors affecting money demand. At the end of
1975 the range projected for growth of the
basic money supply (currency and demand
deposits) for the year ahead was 5-71/2 per­
cent. During the first quarter of 1976 the lower
endpoint was reduced to 41/2 percent and dur­
ing the second and fourth quarters the upper
endpoint was reduced to 7 and 6V2 percent,
respectively. The upper ends of growth
ranges specified for broader measures of the
money supply were also lower at the close of
the year than at the start, consistent with the
FOMC’s goal of allowing for sufficient
monetary expansion to finance continued
economic growth while resisting inflationary
pressures.
The System’s other monetary policy tools
were also employed in the direction of easier
credit during 1976. Two “ discount rate”
reductions by the Chicago Fed’s board of
directors were approved by the Federal
Reserve Board. Effective January 19 the (basic)
“ discount rate” was lowered from 6 to 5V2
percent, and effective November 22, to 5Va
percent. (Reacting to the same needs, direc­
tors of other Reserve Banks instituted similar
changes at roughly the same times.) In addi­
tion, actions by the Board of Governors
reduced reserve requirements twice during
1976—on longer-term time deposits in Jan­
uary, and on demand deposits in December.

77

Directors

as of December 31, 1976

Board o f Directors, Federal Reserve Bank o f Chicago, from left to right: (seated) Messrs. Strotz, Clark,
Schoen hofen ; (standing) Messrs. Farver, Hackett, Spies, M ayer, DeLay, Abboud.

PETER B. CLARK, Chairman
Chairman o f the Board and President
Evening News Association
Detroit, Michigan

JAY J. DeLAY
President
Huron Valley National Bank
Ann Arbor, Michigan

OSCAR G. MAYER
Chairman, Executive Committee
Oscar Mayer & Co.
Madison, Wisconsin

ROBERT H. STROTZ, Deputy Chairman
President
Northwestern University
Evanston, Illinois

PAUL V. FARVER
Vice Chairman
Rolscreen Company
Pella, Iowa

LEO H. SCHOENHOFEN
Retired Chairman
Marcor Inc.
Chicago, Illinois

A. ROBERT ABBOUD
Chairman o f the Board
The First National Bank
Chicago, Illinois

JOHN T. HACKETT
Executive Vice President
Cummins Engine Company, Inc.
Columbus, Indiana

JOHN F. SPIES
President
Iowa Trust and Savings Bank
Emmetsburg, Iowa

Federal Advisory C o u n cil M em b er

A uditors (re p o rtin g to B o a rd o f D ire c to rs )

WILLIAM F. MURRAY
Chairman of the Board
Harris Trust and Savings Bank
Chicago, Illinois

FRED A. DONS, General Auditor
RICHARD P. BUSH, Assistant General Auditor
ROBERT A. LUDWIG, Assistant General Auditor

Detroit branch
JORDAN B. TATTER, Chairman
President and Chief Executive Officer
Southern Michigan Cold Storage Company
Benton Harbor, Michigan
HERBERT H. DOW
Secretary
The Dow Chemical Company
Midland, Michigan
HAROLD A. ELGAS
President
Gaylord State Bank
Gaylord, Michigan

12

JOSEPH B. FOSTER
President
Ann Arbor Bank & Trust Company
Ann Arbor, Michigan

JOHN SAGAN
Vice President-Treasurer
Ford M otor Company
Dearborn, Michigan

CHARLES R. MONTGOMERY
President
Michigan Consolidated Gas Company
Detroit, Michigan

ROBERT M. SURDAM
Chairman of the Board
National Bank o f Detroit
Detroit, Michigan

Officers

as o f D e c e m b e r 31, 1976

ROBERT P. MAYO, President
DANIEL M. DOYLE, First Vice President
CARL E. BIERBAUER, Senior Vice President

ERICH K. KROLL, Assistant Vice President

WARD J. LARSON, Senior Vice President,
General Counsel, and Secretary

LARRY R. MOTE, Senior Economist and
Assistant Vice President

JAMES R. MORRISON, Senior Vice President

JAMES H. NASH, JR., Assistant Counsel

KARL A. SCHELD, Senior Vice President and
Director o f Research

RICHARD H. RAMSDELL, Assistant Vice President

HARRY S. SCHULTZ, Senior Vice President

HARVEY ROSENBLUM, Senior Economist and
Assistant Vice President

BRUCE L. SMYTH, Senior Vice President

DAVID R. STARIN, Assistant Vice President

PAUL J. BETTINI, Vice President

ARTHUR G. STONE, Assistant Vice President

GEORGE W. CLOOS, Economic Adviser and
Vice President
ROBERT P. CORNELISEN, Vice President
FREDERICK S. DOMINICK, Vice President
FRANKLIN D. DREYER, Vice President
RODERICK L. HOUSENGA, Chief Examiner

HILBERT G. SWANSON, Assistant Vice President
WARREN J. TAUBMAN, Assistant Vice President
PATRICK J. TRACY, Assistant Chief Examiner
THOMAS C. TUCKER, Assistant Vice President
RUTH F. VILONA, Assistant Vice President
CARL C. WELKE, Assistant Vice President

JOSEPH G. KVASNICKA, Economic Adviser and
Vice President

ROBERT W. WELLHAUSEN, Assistant Vice President

RICHARD A. MOFFATT, Vice President

PATRICIA W. WISHART, Assistant Vice President and
Assistant Director o f Research

WILLIAM T. NEWPORT, Vice President
DOROTHY M. NICHOLS, Economic Adviser and
Vice President
WILLIAM ROONEY, Vice President
RAYMOND M. SCHEIDER, Vice President
ROBY L. SLOAN, Vice President and
Associate Director o f Research

THOMAS L. WOLFE, Examining Officer

Detroit branch
WILLIAM C. CONRAD, Vice President and Manager
RONALD L. ZILE, Vice President
WAYNE R. BAXTER, Assistant Vice President

ADOLPH J. STOJETZ, Vice President

ROBERT W. COOK, Assistant Vice President

EUGENE J. WAGNER, Vice President

ROBERT M. FITZGERALD, Assistant Vice President

ALLEN G. WOLKEY, Vice President
RICHARD D. ABRAHAMSON, Assistant Vice President

D es M oines office

BUDDIE J. BELFORD, Assistant Vice President

RUDOLPH W. DYBECK, Vice President

ALAN E. BOUGHNER, Assistant Vice President

THOMAS P. KILLEEN, Assistant Vice President

HARRIS C. BUELL, JR., Assistant Vice President

Indianapolis office

WILLIAM H. GRAM, Assistant General Counsel and
Assistant Secretary

LOUIS J. PUROL, Vice President
RICHARD L. SIMMS, JR., Assistant Vice President

ROBERT JOHNSON, Assistant Vice President and
Control Officer

M ilw au kee office

CAROL P. KASPAR, Assistant Vice President

CARL E. VANDER WILT, Vice President

DANIEL P. KINSELLA, Assistant Vice President

RUSSELL O. LANGAN, Assistant Vice President

13