View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Money and Output: Keynes and Friedman
In Historical Perspective
Sharing the Credit: A Quarter Century of
Change
Variable-Rate Mortgages: Boon or Bane?

business review

The Fed In Print

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA




1973

Money and Output:
Keynes and Friedman in Historical
Perspective
. . . The views of Keynes and Friedman re­
garding the effectiveness of monetary as
opposed to fiscal policy can be traced to
differences in approach as well as circum­
stances rather than any basic theoretical dis­
agreements over the role of money in the
economy.
Sharing the Credit?
A Quarter Century of Change
. . . Business and household borrowers now
account for bigger chunks of the total credit
picture while Uncle Sam's share has steadily
declined.
Variable-Rate Mortgages:
Boon or Bane?
. . . New-style home mortgages with fluctu­
ating interest rates may help reduce the
stresses and strains on mortgage-lending in­
stitutions as well as benefit borrowers.

On our cover: At Fifth and Arch streets, just a short walk from Independence Hall, is the United States
Mint. Its modern pink granite structure covers three city blocks and houses the most modern coinage
equipment in the world. The Mint's history dates back to the Presidency of George Washington and to
the time Philadelphia was the nation's capital. The Mint was the first public building erected by the United
States Government. It has grown from a small cluster of brick buildings dating from 1792, located at
Seventh and Market streets, to the present location. The Philadelphia Mint is part of a nationwide Treasury
agency known as the Bureau of the Mint, headquartered in Washington, D. C.

BUSINESS REVIEW is produced in the Department of Research. Ronald B. Williams is Art Director and Manager,
Graphic Services. The authors will be glad to receive comments on their articles.
Requests for additional copies should be addressed to Public Information, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19101.



Money and Output:
Keynes and Friedman
In Historical
Perspective
By ). H. Wood*
The continuing debate among policymakers
and economists on the role of money in the
economy has been confined until a few
years ago to technical journals. Recently,
however, the business press has introduced
the debate to the general public. The arti­
cle presented here is in keeping with this
trend. It provides a fresh look at the his­
torical underpinnings of the current monetarist-fiscalist debate.
Money—its quantity, importance, and ef­
ficacy—is the root of the squabble. Each
camp, armed with logic, statistics, and other
essential academic trappings, has dug in for
a long and running battle—or debate—over
the effectiveness of governmental monetary
and fiscal policies as means of influencing
economic activity.
One clan—the Keynesians, self-styled fol­
lowers (or disciples) of )ohn Maynard
Keynes—argues that money and monetary
policy have little or no impact on income
and employment, particularly during severe
economic downturns; and that government
taxation and spending are the most effective
remedies for inflation and unemployment,
especially the latter.

It's not quite the Montagues and the
Capulets, even the Hatfields and the Mc­
Coys, again, but a long-time feud has been
raging between two prominent “families"
of economists.
* John Wood was the recipient of a fellowship from
the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia in 1968-69
and was a visiting economist at the Bank during the
summer of 1971. He is currently a Professor of In­
vestment at the University of Birmingham (England).
This article is adapted from an inaugural lecture
delivered at the University of Birmingham, March 21,
1972. The author wishes to express his deep appreci­
ation to the Esmee Fairbairn Charitable Trust, whose
generosity made possible the research leading to this
lecture, and to Douglas Vickers for encouragement
and helpful discussions in the early stages of that
research.



3

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

British economists as well. In short—and
this may jolt some economists and non­
economists—there are no fundamental theo­
retical differences between Keynes and
Friedman. As with such controversies, the
differences between Keynes and Friedman
on the employment of fiscal and monetary
policies to achieve economic stability hinge
on differences in economic conditions exist­
ing at the times that each economist wrote
and from dissimilar political philosophies
rather than from any theoretical differences
over money's influence on output. More­
over, the genesis of most of these "differ­
ences” can be found in the positions taken
by many British economists of previous
centuries.

The other group—the Monetarists, largely
rallying around Milton Friedman of the Uni­
versity of Chicago—emphasizes money's
role in the economic process. Spurning the
notion that fiscal policy is paramount, they
argue that a rule which requires the mone­
tary authorities to cause the stock of money
to increase at some constant rate, say 3 per­
cent annually, would effectively reduce
fluctuations in prices, output, and employ­
ment.
It is curious that when the dust settles on
this debate, the problems that have inter­
ested Keynes and Friedman, the policy tools
each has used and the principal results
each has obtained resemble not only each
other but those of eighteenth-century

WHO'S WHO
RICHARD CANTILLON (1697-1734), Irish-born French economist, became a prosper­
ous financier in Paris and London and wrote the authoritative Essai sur la nature du
commerce en general (1755), which in many respects anticipated Adam Smith and
Thomas Malthus.
MILTON FRIEDMAN (1912- ) is Paul S. Russell Distinguished Professor of Economics
at the University of Chicago, where he began his academic career forty years ago. He
has been a member of the research staff of the National Bureau of Economic Research
since 1937. He was recently president of the American Economic Association.
DAVID HUME (1711-1776), Scottish philosopher and historian, is one of the great
British empiricists. His Treatise of Human Nature argued skeptically against the claims
of metaphysicians that there are innate ideals and of theologians that we can know
the ultimate reasons for anything. His arguments challenged the "natural law" and
"social contract" theories of Thomas Hobbes, Richard Hooker, John Locke, and later
Jean-Jacques Rousseau. In 1748 he published a simplified version of the Treatise
entitled Enquiry concerning Human Understanding. His Political Discourses (1752)
gave him a greater reputation as an economist in his lifetime than his contemporary,
Adam Smith.
JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES (1883-1946) pioneered the "New Economics" of employ­
ment and output. During both world wars he was an adviser to the British Treasury,
which he represented at the Versailles Peace Conference but resigned in opposition
to the terms of the draft treaty, inspiring his Economic Consequences of the Peace.
The unemployment crises in England and Europe inspired his two great works, A
Treatise on Money and the General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. In
1943 he played a leading part in formulating the Bretton Woods agreements, thereby
establishing the International Monetary Fund.




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

JOHN LAW (1671-1729) made a study of the credit operations of the bank at Am­
sterdam but his proposals for a paper currency were unfavorably received by the
Scottish Parliament. In Paris he and his brother William established a private bank.
This was so prosperous that in 1718 the Regent Orleans adopted Law's plan of a
national bank. The next year Law originated a joint-stock company for reclaiming and
settling lands in the Mississippi Valley (called the Mississippi scheme) and in 1720 he
became comptroller-general of finances. When the bubble burst he became an object
of popular hatred, left France, lived in England for a while, then died forgotten in
Venice.
JOHN LOCKE (1632-1704) was the principal founder of philosophical Liberalism and,
with Francis Bacon, of British empiricism. His Treatises on Government, considered
his most important work in political philosophy, were a reply to the divine right theory
and political philosophy of Thomas Hobbes. In economic theory Locke adopted many
mercantilist principles.
JOHN STUART MILL (1806-1873) wrote Principles of Political Economy (1848) which
foreshadowed the marginal utility theory. Also his System of Logic with its four cele­
brated canons of induction influenced economists such as Jevons and Keynes. But
Mill is best remembered for his essay “On Liberty" (1859), in which he argued not
only for political freedom but for social freedom, not only against the “tyranny of the
majority" but also against the "social tyranny" of the prevailing conventions and
opinions.
DAVID RICARDO (1772-1823) wrote The High Price of Bullion: a Proof of the De­
preciation of Bank-Notes (1809), in which he argued for a metallic basis to the
money supply. His Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817) set forth his
views on value, wages, and rent.
HENRY THORNTON (1760-1815), banker, economist, and member of Parliament,
became known as an astute financier, this reputation being confirmed by his An
Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain.

money and output. The most celebrated
contributors to these discussions were John
Locke and John Law. The superstructure
supporting their view has the majestic sim­
plicity of a great idea. They began with the
obvious. Total monetary payments must
equal total monetary receipts; or, what
amounts to the same thing, the number of
dollars in circulation multiplied by the
average number of times each dollar is paid
out (total monetary payments) must equal
the number of units of output multiplied by
the average price of each sale (total mone­
tary receipts).

LOCKE AND LAW
Close examination of the views of eigh­
teenth- and nineteenth-century economists
regarding the circumstances under which
money does or does not influence economic
activity reveals the connections between
Keynes and Friedman.
In the late seventeenth and early eigh­
teenth centuries, years of fluctuating prices
and recurrent unemployment and depressed
trade, there developed a substantial body of
thought concerning the connection between



5

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

the analyses of his predecessors. In his view,
they tended to look at only two periods and
to compare the state of prices and trade
before the change in the money stock or
its velocity with that state existing after the
impact of a monetary disturbance had
worked its way through the system (this type
of analysis is labeled comparative statics).
Cantillon's discussion of the processes by
which variations in the quantity of money
lead to variations in prices and in the direc­
tion and volume of production focused on
dynamic monetary processes. His work
was perhaps the most sophisticated dynamic
analysis until the appearance of Keynes's
Treatise on Money 200 years later.
Toying with the possibilities of how an
increased money supply could result (such
as domestic gold discoveries, a favorable
trade balance, and foreign borrowing), Can­
tillon concluded that in general more money
causes "a corresponding increase of con­
sumption which gradually brings about
increased prices." But in general a doubling
of the money supply does not correspond­
ingly lead to a doubling of prices. So, some
of the increases in monetary payments lead
to increases in output.
Cantillon also recognized what many
economists would later point out. First,
the increased quantity of money is beneficial
to trade only during the period in which
money is actually increasing. Once a new
equilibrium is reached, output would return
to its original or "normal" level, and only
the price level would be higher. Second,
the inflationary process cannot last forever,
even with continued monetary expansion,
because the increase in prices and incomes
leads to an adverse balance of payments
and an outflow of money. The trick is to
keep the inflationary process going so as
to gain the attendant benefits to output and
employment, and yet harness it sufficiently
to maintain a favorable balance of trade.
Next we come to David Hume whose
essay "On Money" (1752) stands as the
watershed between the dynamic analysis of

John Locke
Now anyone knows that an increase in
total monetary payments must be matched
by an increase in total monetary receipts.
As we shall see, however, there can be
great disagreement of far-reaching implica­
tions as to whether total monetary receipts
go up because prices rise or because output
rises. Locke and Law contended that in­
creases in the quantity of money and in the
velocity of circulation (that is, the rapidity
with which money changes hands during a
given period of time) not only raised prices
but expanded output and employment. They
proposed measures for increasing the supply
and velocity of money, including the stan­
dard mercantilist policy of inducing inflows
of money from abroad by means of a favor­
able balance of trade.
CANTILLON, HUME, THORNTON
Richard Cantillon agreed with Locke and
Law that increases in either the money stock
or its velocity caused both prices and output
to rise, but he criticized the static nature of



6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

proportion with the new quantity of
specie which is in the kingdom. In
my opinion, it is only in this interval
or intermediate situation, between the
acquisition of money and rise of prices,
that the increasing quantity of gold and
silver is favorable to industry.1
The implication for monetary policy that
Hume draws from his analysis is identical
to Cantillon's—rising money or velocity af­
fects output only as the economy adjusts
from one equilibrium to another. Like
Cantillon, however, Hume had little con­
fidence that it would be possible to continue
such a policy for long because of balanceof-payments constraints.
Henry Thornton agreed with Hume that
an increased quantity of money at first
induces increases in output and employ­
ment. And, even more than Hume, he
emphasized the transient nature of the
beneficial effects of monetary expansions.
According to Thornton, price increases
which follow an increase in money would
occur very rapidly and greatly exceed any
increases in output.
We see in Cantillon, Hume, and Thornton
a progression toward the view that money
does not matter in the sense that output is
independent of money. Movement toward
this view developed as economists shifted
from a focus by persons like Cantillon on
periods of transition to Hume, who dealt
with both transitions and comparative equi­
libria but emphasized the former, to Thorn­
ton, who emphasized the latter. The next
step is David Ricardo, who dealt almost
exclusively with comparative statics.

David Hume
inflationists such as Cantillon and the em­
phasis on comparative statics of the nine­
teenth-century followers of David Ricardo.
Like Cantillon, Hume tried to follow the
economy's dynamic course during and after
a disturbance. But he also anticipated later
thinkers by comparing in detail the state
of the economy before a disturbance with
its state after the disturbance had completely
run its course. He recognized the different
roles played by money in the two types of
analyses.
To account, then, for this phenom­
enon, we must consider, that though
the high price of commodities be a
necessary consequence of the increase
of gold and silver, yet it follows not
immediately upon that increase; but
some time is required before the money
circulates through the whole state, and
makes its effect be felt on all ranks of
people. At first, no alteration is per­
ceived; by degrees the price rises, first
of one commodity, then of another;
till the whole at last reaches a just



RICARDO AND MILL
The shift in emphasis from transition
periods to comparative statics was probably
the result of events more than changes in
academic fashions or even advances in eco-1
1 David Hume, "O f Money," Eugene Rotwein, ed.,
David Hume: Writings on Economics (Madison: Uni­
versity of Wisconsin Press, 1970), pp. 37-38.
7

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

John Stuart Mill

David Ricardo

inclined to recommend monetary expansion
as a means of curing unemployment.
The most explicit "classical" statements
of money processes are contained in John
Stuart Mill's Principles of Political Economy
(1848). In this work, he was not prepared
to admit that changes in the quantity of
money affected output, employment, and
relative prices even during the transition
from one price level to another. Blasting
as unrealistic the policy of ever-increasing
money and ever-rising prices suggested by
Cantillon and Hume, he pointed out that
people observe increases in money, foresee
the effect on prices and make their plans,
and draw up their contracts accordingly.
A price rise that is expected by all parties
has no impact on employment or output.
In sum:
. . . there cannot, in short, be intrin­
sically a more insignificant thing in the
economy of society than money; except
in the character of a contrivance for
sparing time and labor. It is a machine
for doing quickly and commodiously,

nomic theory. Perhaps because of the
breakdown of medieval price and wage
regulations, advances in transportation and
the communication of information, and the
growth of financial markets, Ricardo's model
—
that is, output is independent of the
quantity of money (see Box)—really was the
one most appropriate to the nineteenth
century; whereas, Cantillon's approach had
been the one most applicable to the pre­
vious century. This view is not too far­
fetched if one really believes that there was
such a thing as the Industrial Revolution—
not only in methods of production but in
the costs and speed with which materials
and people could be transported and in
the development of facilities for moving
money and credit from one part of the
country to another.
Remember, too, that Thornton and
Ricardo lived during a period of rising
prices, especially a wartime inflation from
1797 to 1813 of nearly 4 percent per year.
More acutely aware of the evils of inflation
than Locke and Cantillon, they were less



8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

WHY MONEY DOESN'T MATTER . . . A LOOK AT RICARDO'S MODEL
In the model developed by Ricardo and his successors, an increase in the quantity
of money is associated with a fall in interest rates. This induces an increase in the
demand for investment goods on the one hand and a decline in saving on the other;
thus, the increased supply of money is matched by an increased demand for com­
modities. Upward pressures are exerted on prices, with the increased demand for
commodities being financed by the increased quantity of money. As prices rise,
people need more money for their transactions and the initial decline in interest rates
is reversed. The rise in prices and interest rates continues until both the commodity
and money markets are in balance at the original rate of interest. The inflation also
will have disturbed the labor market since commodity prices will have risen relative
to wage rates. Since labor is now cheap relative to the price of commodities, firms
compete for labor, bidding wages up until the original wage-price ratio is reestablished.
In this way, a doubling of the money supply leads to a doubling of both wages and
prices with no long-run effect on interest rates or any other part of the system—except
for an unfair redistribution of wealth from creditors to debtors. Such was the nine­
teenth-century quantity theory of "the classical economists."
Even changes in productive techniques or the public's thriftiness, while influencing
the direction of production and the rate of growth of the economy, will not cause
unemployment. For example, if people decide to save more of their incomes, more
money is made available at lower rates to firms that will use those funds to increase
their productive capacity and benefit society in the long run. Abstinence and thrift
directly increase the wealth of society no less than that of individuals. Relative prices,
output, employment, interest rates, saving, investment, and consumption are deter­
mined by the state of knowledge of productive techniques, by institutional arrange­
ments and by the attitudes of the population toward work and leisure, consumption,
and thrift. Money, although useful in carrying out transactions, changes none of these
underlying forces.
w hat w o u ld be done, though less
quickly and commodiously, without it;
and like many other kinds of machinery,
it only exerts a distinct and independent
influence of its own when it gets out
of order.2
But, argued the nineteenth-century critics
of Ricardo and Mill, this is no mean excep­
tion and it begs the whole question of trade
cycles and other periods of monetary dis­
turbance. Rapid changes in the quantity of
money are impossible without the "ma­
chinery getting out of order." And it is this

argument that Keynes and Friedman stressed
in the twentieth century.
ENTER KEYNES
In his Tract on Monetary Reform (1923),
Keynes was highly critical of the pre-1914
theory of Ricardo, Mill, and others.
Now "in the long run" this theory is
probably true. If, after the American
Civil War, the dollar had been stabilized
and defined by law at 10 percent below
its present value, it would be safe to
assume that M [money] and P [prices]
would now be just 10 percent greater
than they actually are and that the
present values of V [velocity] and T
[volume of transactions] would be en-

“John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy,
ed. W. J. Ashley (London: Longmans, Green and Com­
pany, 1909), p. 488.



9

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1972

prices tripled, then dropped by nearly onehalf by 1922. He pointed out that the ar­
rangements of the nineteenth century could
not work properly if money, the assumed
standard, is not dependable.
Unemployment, the precarious life of
the worker, the disappointment of ex­
pectation, the sudden loss of savings,
the excessive windfalls to individuals,
the speculator, the profiteer—all pro­
ceed, in large measure, from the insta­
bility of the standard of value.5
If businessmen are to develop their pro­
ductive capacity and if the savings of house­
holds are to be converted into investment
projects, then businessmen must be able to
foresee with a reasonable degree of assur­
ance the prices of the products coming out
of their new plants and the costs of the
inputs from which those products will be
made.
To Keynes, the overriding determinant
of investment is price expectations. Ex­
pectations of price increases encourage in­
vestment; expected deflation discourages
investment. Uncertainty is the worst of­
fender. If rapid monetary changes have
occurred in the past and are expected to
be repeated in the future—in which direction
no one knows—businessmen will refuse to
bear the risk of investment.
The problems that Keynes considered as
well as the remedies proposed in his Treatise
on Money (1930) were the same as those
analyzed and advanced in the Tract. Only
his methodology had changed; it had be­
come more sophisticated. He traced in
detail the effects of changes in the quantity
of money on the level and composition of
output. Some passages in the Treatise echo
Cantillon. Like the latter, Keynes always

John Maynard Keynes
tirely unaffected. But this long run is
a misleading guide to current affairs.
In the long run we are all dead. Econ­
omists set themselves too easy, too use­
less a task if in tempestuous seasons
they can only tell us that when the
storm is long past the ocean is flat
again.3
But things were different after 1914.
Keynes began his Tract in the same way
that he had begun the Economic Conse­
quences of the Peace (1919), discussing what
he believed had been the extremely delicate,
short-lived, and essentially unstable eco­
nomic system existing before 1914:
For a hu ndred years the system
worked throughout Europe with an
extraordinary success and facilitated the
growth of wealth on an unprecedented
scale. To save and to invest became at
once the duty and the delight of a large
class.4

3John Maynard Keynes, The Collected Writings of
Keynes (London: Macmillan Ltd., 1971), p. 6.
4 Ibid., p. xiv.
s Ibid.

Keynes wrote during a time of extraordi­
nary upheaval. Between 1914 and 1920



10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

carefully specified the source of an assumed
monetary disturbance before discussing its
effects. For him, most increases in money
resulted from increases in bank loans to
businessmen. He stressed that the failure of
different prices to move together is the
essence of short-period fluctuations and that
an easier monetary policy that leads to low
interest rates and rising prices results in
higher profits and increases investment.
The processes through which monetary
disturbances lead to variations in output in
the first instance are the same in the General
Theory of Employment, Interest and Money
as in the Tract and the Treatise: namely,
through price changes and their influence
on expectations of future prices. He argued
that the relation between current and future
prices influences investment decisions most.
Keynes came to the conclusion that in a
world of rapidly fluctuating prices uncer­
tainty on the part of businessmen would be
so great that the state would have to under­
take the investment necessary for growth and
economic stability. Since 1924 he had ad­
vocated public works in a supporting role
to monetary policy as an antideflationary
device. But, from the behavior of the Bank
of England—from its determination to accept
and enforce whatever price fluctuations
were consistent, first with the return to gold
at the prewar par and then with the main­
tenance of the gold standard at a fixed rate—
Keynes became convinced that the nation
would have to rely on means other than
monetary policy to stabilize prices and
output.

Milton Friedman
plicit statement of the processes through
which, in their view, money affects eco­
nomic activity), they descend into a quag­
mire of algebraic manipulations. But, if we
carefully examine the way in which Friedman
handles the data in this and other historical
discussions, we can get an inkling of how,
in his view, money matters.
In comparing the two periods 1865-1879
and 1879-1897 as well as other lengthy in­
tervals, Friedman and Schwartz conclude
that over long periods “generally declining
or generally rising prices had little impact
on the rate of growth [of output], but the
period of great monetary uncertainty in the
early nineties produced sharp deviations
from the long-term trend."
They make this point again and again,
concluding:

. . . THEN FRIEDMAN
Reading Milton Friedman and Anna Jacob­
son Schwartz's A Monetary History of the
United States is a frustrating experience. On
the one hand, the authors present a wealth
of highly suggestive and expertly handled
historical data. But, on the other hand, just
as they seem to be on the verge of explaining
causal relationships (that is, of giving an ex


Apparently, the forces determining
the long-run rate of growth of real
income are largely independent of the
long-run rate of growth of the stock of
money, so long as both proceed fairly
smoothly. But marked instability of
11

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

money is accompanied by instability of
economic growth.6
Surprise is the key word in all this. To the
extent that changes in money and prices
proceed smoothly and are foreseen, money
does not influence economic activity. But
sudden and unforeseen monetary disturb­
ances produce fluctuations in output.
There is a close connection here and else­
where between Friedman's descriptions of
historical periods and Mill's argument that
changes in the money supply that people
expect and upon which they can plan allow
employment, output, and other economic
variables to be determined by nonmonetary
forces.

output, and employment. But they part ways
in approach and emphasis on how to achieve
the benefits of monetary stability.
Keynes, on the one hand, was pragmatic.
He was a man of a thousand plans. If one
was impractical, he would try another. To
him monetary policy was important but not
the "be-all and end-all." And so he moved
from a reliance on monetary to fiscal policy
when he thought it unrealistic on political
or other grounds to expect a stable growth
in the money supply.
Friedman, on the other hand, has less con­
fidence than Keynes in the willingness or
ability of the authorities—monetary or fiscal—
to make the economy work smoothly. That
is why Friedman wants to tie both the mone­
tary and fiscal authorities to certain specific
rules—not because the people who would
make the rules are more intelligent than
those who formulate and implement dis­
cretionary policies, but because, whatever
the rule, it will be known. People can for­
mulate plans on the basis of what they can
expect the future money supply and price
level to be. In such a way, Friedman hopes,
as Keynes did with fiscal policy, that money
CAN BE MADE not to matter.

PARALLEL IN THEORY BUT PARTING
IN PRESCRIPTION
Both Keynes and Friedman, therefore, fear
monetary instability. They both desire a
stable growth rate in the money supply as a
way of minimizing fluctuations in prices,
"Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobson Schwartz, A
Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963), p. 678.




12




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

13

BUSINESS REVIEW

CHART 1
BU SIN ESS AND HOUSEHOLD BOR­
ROWERS PICKED UP THE SLACK AS
GOVERNMENT’S PORTION OF TOTAL
CREDIT HAS SHRUNK SIN CE WORLD
WAR II

AND WITHIN THE GOVERNMENT S E C ­
TOR, UNCLE SAM’S SHARE HAS
TRENDED DOWNWARD

Percent

100 ---------90

Share of total credit

—

Share of Government credit
STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT

70 —
60
50

j

30

—

—

40

|—

40

50

FEDERAL GOVERNMENT

—

—

20

10
’45

’50

'55

’60

’65

—

—

0 l---

70

Source: Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System




“

’45

14

’50

’55

’60

’65

70

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

CHART 3
AND B U SIN ESS BORROWERS HAVE
RELIED SOMEWHAT LE S S ON CORPO­
RATE BONDS AS THEY UPPED THEIR
USE OF OTHER CREDIT MARKET
INSTRUMENTS

ALTHOUGH HOUSEHOLDS HAVE AC­
COUNTED FOR A BIGGER PIECE OF
TOTAL CREDIT, THE S LIC E S GOING
TO CONSUMER DEBT AND MORT­
GAGES HAVE CHANGED LITTLE

80 —

40 —
30 ~

20

10

—

TOTAL MORTGAGES
—

’45

’50

’55




’60

’65

’70

’45

15

’50

’55

’60

’65

70

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1972

Variable-Rate
Mortgages:
Boon or Bane?
By Alan ). Krupnick
from their earnings on mortgages, most of
which carry a fixed rate and which were con­
tracted in the past. As rising market rates
push savers' demands upward, earnings on
most S&L mortgages lag behind. And this is
exactly when thrift institutions get pinched.
Suppose Sunnyside Savings and Loan As­
sociation offers 4 percent interest on its
savings deposits at a time when market rates
are generally low. Savers attracted to this
investment supply the S&L with plenty of
funds for lending. Market-determined rates
on fix e d -ra te m ortgages (FRM s) hover
around 6 percent. The 2-percent difference
goes toward covering Sunnyside's cost of
doing business and return to its investors.
This situation remains fairly stable unless
market rates drift upward. In order to keep
old savers and draw new ones, Sunnyside
must offer higher rates. But, here the prob­
lem begins. Although Sunnyside can get a
full 8 percent on its new mortgages, it still
has all the old ones, contracted at 6 percent
or lower, to worry about. Since most of
Sunnyside's portfolio is made up of "old"
mortgages its earnings limp while the rates

A prospective homebuyer applies for a
mortgage and gets only excuses. An account
holder in a thrift institution occasionally
finds his return well below that of the going
market rate. An officer of a savings and loan
association (S&L) or mutual savings bank
sometimes has difficulty turning a profit.
Troubling these three is the mortgage scene.
Earlier this year the Hunt Commission (the
President's Commission on Financial Struc­
ture and Regulation) suggested many re­
forms which might aid all parties. One
suggestion favored by the Federal Home
Loan Bank Board—widespread use of vari­
able-rate mortgages (VRMs)—may help alle­
viate the stresses and strains on the mortgage
market every time that credit tightens.
THRIFT INSTITUTIONS IN A BIND
The problem starts when, quite reason­
ably, sophisticated savers expect their thrift
institutions (such as S&Ls) to match rises in
market interest rates. If S&Ls can't do it,
savers may withdraw their deposits. The
S&Ls' ability to meet savers' demands comes



16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

off lenders by providing a source of funds
during tight periods. But, by dipping into
the capital markets for their funds, they have
helped perpetuate the credit squeezes caus­
ing the trouble.
In 1966, ceilings on savings deposit rates
at thrift institutions were imposed to help
assume the heavy load. The ceilings were
intended to end competition among these
institutions for savers' funds which could
send deposit rates soaring and profits plum­
meting every time market rates rose. Up­
ward pressure on rates could be relieved and
the squeeze on profits could be reduced—
or so the argument went.
Of course, savers weren't too happy about
this turn of events. In effect, policymakers
forced them to accept a low return on their
savings deposits so that S&Ls could maintain

paid on its savings deposits climb. If Sunnyside were permitted to raise deposit rates
heedless of its poor earnings picture, it could
eventually fold. Yet, if it doesn't raise rates,
savers may withdraw their funds. Without
funds, Sunnyside can't make loans and may
face insolvency.
WAYS OUT
Policymakers have long been aware of
the mortgage lender's "plight." Initially, the
Federal Home Loan Bank Board and the Fed­
eral National Mortgage Association (Fannie
Mae) stepped in with cash for thrift insti­
tutions wanting it in a hurry, thereby es­
tablishing a secondary market for home
mortgages (see Box). Most critics agree that
these agencies have taken some pressure




17

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

OPERATORS IN THE SECONDARY MARKET
The Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae), a government-created
"private" company, is the world's largest mortgage bank.* Fannie Mae's purpose is
providing lenders and builders with mortgage money for housing when such funds
are hard to get from S&Ls, banks, and insurance companies— conventional loans not
backed by the Federal Housing Administration or the Veterans Administration.
The Federal Fiome Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac), a branch of the
Federal Home Loan Bank Board— which supervises and lends S&Ls money that is raised
in much the way Fannie Mae raises hers— is a competitor.
Ending Fannie Mae's virtual monopoly in the secondary market is a newcomer from
Milwaukee— the MC/C Mortgage Corporation (Maggie Mae), a wholly private enter­
prise. A subsidiary of the MGIC Investment Corporation, Maggie Mae can deal with
privately insured, conventional 95 percent home mortgages that S&Ls make. Fannie
Mae is refrained by law to 90 percent conventional loans. But Fannie Mae has an edge
over Maggie Mae in that, as a government operation, she enjoys a privileged borrowing
status, while her rival must pay a higher rate for borrowed funds.
Another operator is the Government National Mortgage Association (Ginny Mae),
a new agency created by Congress, which took over Fannie Mae's job of making
mortgage loans with Treasury money for HUD's array of subsidized housing programs.
These operators and others vie to reshape the residential-mortgage business by
creating a market in conventional loans.
* For a lively account of the activities of Fannie Mae and others in the secondary market, see
George Breckenfeld, "Nobody Pours It Like Fannie Mae," Fortune 85 (June 1972): 86-89, 136,
140, 145-147.

the flow of mortgage funds to borrowers at
more favorable rates than would have other­
wise been possible. Many savers didn't like
the one-sided deal. During the next tight
money period, many withdrew their funds
for more profitable uses. The squeeze left
many S&Ls with depleted savings deposits
and unable to make many loans to bor­
rowers. Now, it was the borrowers' turn to
be unhappy. With thrift institutions short on
funds to lend, many potential borrowers
were frozen out of the mortgage market.

tying the mortgage interest rate to some
market "reference rate" (see Box).1 The
mortgage interest rate would move up or
down periodically to reflect changes in credit
conditions. A borrower, rather than signing
up to pay, say, 6 percent for 25 years, would

1 Last August the Federal Home Loan Bank Board
endorsed just this proposal. Under its proposal the
VRM would be tied to some nationally used interest
rates. Good candidates for this are: the yield on
three- to five-year Treasury securities, the average of
the yield on these securities and the yield on long­
term utility bonds or high-grade corporate bonds, or
the weighted-average cost of savings, borrowing and
FHLBB advances for S&Ls in the system.
Also, for examples of other types of VRMs, see New
England Economic Review, March/April 1970.

VRMs TO THE RESCUE
Variable-rate mortgages (VRMs) may help
to thaw the mortgage market. The VRM
plan receiving the most attention is that



18

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

SETTING IT UP
We can go a long way toward insuring the VRM plan's smooth operation if we weigh
the diverse interests of borrowers, S&Ls, and savers with an eye toward compromise
and equity. Such issues as the choice of “ reference rate,” the proper number of rate
changes per year, the means to adjust the borrowers' payments schedule to changing
mortgage costs, figure crucially in a workable formula.
Reference Rate. The choice of “ reference rate" lies at the heart of the plan. The
rate must be well known, easily understood, and reported in the press so that the
public can keep informed of its movements. To protect the lender from charges of
collusion or conflict of interest that might arise after a sharp boost in rates, the indi­
cator should fall clearly outside the banking community's influence.
It should be a stable indicator of credit and monetary trends, pliable enough to
give the S&Ls' mortgage rate adequate flexibility while averaging out extraneous factors.
Some experts feel the three-to-five-year Treasury-security rate best meets these
qualifications. Others, fearful that any reference rate may suddenly send borrowers'
mortgage costs soaring, favor legislation limiting the number of times per year the
mortgage rate could be raised. California already has such a law. Another approach,
though limited in scope, suggests ceilings on variable-rate movements to prevent a
runaway market from crippling borrowers.
Compromise may be difficult on how and when to adjust the borrower's payments
to the change in his interest rate. Current literature suggests two basic options— a
variable-payment plan where a borrower's monthly payments would vary with interest
rates but his number of payments would remain the same, or a variable-maturity
plan where the length of his mortgage obligation would vary but his monthly pay­
ments would be constant. Although some borrowers would view either variable-rate
plan indifferently, most would probably prefer the variable-maturity plan. The typical
borrower probably attaches relatively little value to a dollar that won't come due
for 10 or 20 years— the prospect of a few monthly payments far into the future does
not seem so terrible.* In contrast, he dislikes frequent changes in his monthly pay­
ments, because they make short-term financial planning difficult and can have a
devastating impact on a family with a tight budget.
* However, if interest rates rise quickly enough while monthly payments remain constant, all
of the monthly payment may be needed to cover the interest cost, leaving none for the
principal. The borrower, at this point, could never make enough payments. To guard
against this occurrence, provision would have to be made to increase monthly payments
temporarily until rates fall.

agree to pay the going rate, whatever it may
be. For the borrower, a rise in the reference
rate would mean higher monthly payments,
longer maturities with less equity buildup,
or a combination of both (see Box). The
lender would realize higher earnings and,
possibly, large cash flows. If interest rates
fall, the reverse would occur.
With their earnings flexible and moving



with market rates, S&Ls could meet market
demand for higher, competitive rates on
savings deposits without fear of financial
strain or need of regulatory intervention.
With savers content to leave their funds
alone, "tight" credit conditions would be
less likely to compel S&Ls to curtail their
mortgage lending. So, savers would receive
more competitive returns on their funds,
19

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

DEPENDING ON TH E COURSE OF THE REFEREN CE RATE FRMs AND VRMs EFFECT
BORROWERS IN RADICALLY DIFFEREN T WAYS
Monthly Payment, Dollars
AMOUNT OF MONTHLY PAYMENT

FRM*

£

.................. ....

I960 61 62

63 64 65 66 67

i i i

68 69 70

71

Months to Maturity
400
NUMBER OF MONThLY PAYMENTS TO MATURITY

FRM**
100

60

61 62

63 64

65

66 67

68

69

70 71 72

Based on contract rate of 61/4 percent, which was the average rate of FHA mortgages in the
fourth quarter of 1959, and an original maturity of 25 years.
Based on a rate of 200 basis points above the 3- to 5-year Treasury securities yield two
quarters before and an original maturity of 25 years.
Based on a rate of 200 basis points above the 3- to 5-year Treasury securities yield two
quarters before and a fixed monthly payment of $6.60.
Principal and months to maturity refer to the beginning of each quarter.




20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

S&Ls would become full partners in the
credit market, and borrowers would face
less severe cutbacks in available mortgages
when money tightens. In the process, the
complicated, sometimes clumsy, set of ceil­
ings meant to protect S&Ls from competition
could be removed along with the plugs to
stop savers from seeking higher returns else­
where.

cent, $20,000 mortgage in 1960 to be repaid
in 1985. By 1971 our FRM borrower's
monthly payments are far less than those of
the variable-payment plan borrower and the
variable-maturity plan borrower (at the mo­
ment) makes twice the number of payments
as the FRM borrower (see Chart).
Yet, the drastic effect on borrowers when
interest rates rise would become a bonanza
should rates fall. Falling mortgage rates
would either push down monthly payments
or hasten the mortgage's maturity. Notice
the first five years on the chart. Because in­
terest rates generally remained low through
the first half of the '60s, VRM holders were
actually in a better position than their FRM
counterparts.
Borrowers expecting falling market rates
might not take, say, a 9 percent FRM, but
a 9 percent VRM might look attractive.
However, other borrowers, believing inter­
est rates might rise, would select a VRM.
If VRMs and FRMs were offered side by side,
borrowers could choose their mortgage
based on their preferences and their expec­
tations of the future course of market rates.3
But, there's opposition to this idea.

OPPOSITION TO VRMs
Yet such a sweeping proposal for change
in the way S&Ls and borrowers do business
was bound to generate much opposition.2
Many question its feasibility, fairness to bor­
rowers, and impact on lenders.
Little Protection for Borrowers. Since the
1960s, fixed-rate mortgages (FRMs) have
cushioned most mortgage borrowers against
the shocks of rising market rates. And, even
if rates had fallen, borrowers would have
been relatively safe. In most cases, these
borrowers could take out a new mortgage
at the lower market rate and use it to pay
off the old, higher-rate mortgage. Prepaying
a mortgage may be relatively expensive, but
it provides the borrower with a way out of
a high-rate mortgage when market rates
drop significantly.
Compulsory VRMs would deprive bor­
rowers of any protection against sudden rate
rises. Compare, for example, the two types
of VRM plans with the FRM plan held by
most homeowners through the 1960s (see
Chart). Our mythical VRM borrowers and
their FRM counterparts take out a 61 perA

Destabilizing Clashes. Some lenders be­
lieve that a "mixed system" could eventually
stymie mortgage activity as borrowers would
never want what the lenders have to sell
and vice versa. They argue that during low
interest periods borrowers might be under­
standably wary of entering into VRM con­
tracts if they believe interest rates appear to
be rising. But, this is the time when lenders
would most favor VRM contracts. If interest
rates are high and on their way down, bor­
rowers will look more favorably on the VRM
2
Roadblocks abound on the path toward VRMs. while lenders might prefer to "lock-in" to a
fixed-rate mortgage to bolster their earnings.
Some states outlaw VRMs. Tied to this obstacle are
those regulations establishing ceilings on mortgage
rates— such as the 9 percent ceiling in Pennsylvania.
For the mixed plan to work, VRMs should be legal in
every state and both types of mortgages should be free
of restrictions on their movements. Furthermore, regu­
lations limiting rates paid on savings deposits likewise
deserve attention.



3 Many countries such as France, Germany, Italy, and
Switzerland have VRMs and FRMs coexisting, but the
use of VRMs is described as “ limited.'' Unfortunately,
limited information makes judging their performance
difficult.
21

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

rates fluctuate according to the preferences
and expectations of sellers and buyers.
We can even say something about the
direction of this differential. A "typical"
borrower probably would rather protect
himself against financial misfortune than
gamble on riches or ruin. The fixed-rate
mortgage commitment allows him this pro­
tection, regardless of interest rate move­
ments. "Typical" S&Ls have experienced
the bind inherent in fixed-rate mortgage
commitments financed through short-term
savings deposits. The flexibility which VRMs
can offer them should be welcome. There­
fore, if most borrowers favor FRMs and most
lenders prefer VRMs, then the latter should
go for a lower basic rate than the compa-

Nothing is wrong with this reasoning ex­
cept that it does not go far enough. The
"clashing" forces would hardly bring the
market to a halt. Rather, they would work
to establish a rate differential between FRMs
and VRMs. If lenders favor the VRM and
borrowers the FRM, the rate on the VRM
will fall below that of the FRM to lure re­
luctant borrowers. At widening rate differ­
entials, more and more borrowers will be
drawn to the VRM. During falling interest
rate periods, when VRMs become attractive
to borrowers, the rate differential may turn
in favor of the FRM. There's really nothing
mysterious about these movements. They
occur daily in the nation's credit markets as
the difference between long- and short-term

mlllllP
"Allowing VRMs and FRMs to coexist provides borrowers and lenders with another
means of dealing with the uncertain course of interest rates."



22

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

rable FRM, although other factors may widen
or narrow the difference.
In fact, at times either type of mortgage
may be temporarily driven off the market
because the differential gets too large. For
instance, if borrowers are very nervous about
taking a VRM, only a very low starting rate
may quiet their fears. But, a mortgage lender
may be unwilling to make a VRM contract
at such a low rate. In this case, very little
trading would take place in VRMs and the
market resulting would be much like today's
—
with one important exception. At least
an option would be present. Changes in
conditions, preferences, or expectations
could easily reverse the S&L's decision, and
trading in both FRMs and VRMs could
resume.

vides borrowers and lenders with another
means of dealing with the uncertain course
of interest rates. But it may promise more
than that. By allowing S&Ls' long-term earn­
ings to adjust to quick changes in their ex­
penses, VRMs can enable them to compete
aggressively for savers' funds. Savers natu­
rally benefit by this courtship through higher
rates on their savings deposits (assuming
there are no ceilings). And, the faithful
stream of savings into these institutions
means mortgage money for the borrower
even during tightest credit periods.
While we can't be sure that long-term
mortgage borrowers and lenders will accept
VRMs, there appears to be little cost in trying
them. Should the VRM become an integral
part of the mortgage market, it could go a
long way toward reducing the stresses and
strains on mortgage-lending institutions that
depend on short-term liabilities for making
long-term loans.

W HICH WAY?
Allowing VRMs and FRMs to coexist pro­




23

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1972

NOW AVAILABLE
BRO CHU RE AND FILM STRIP ON
TRUTH IN LENDING

Truth in Lending became the law of the land in 1969. Since
then the law, requiring uniform and meaningful disclosure of the
cost of consumer credit, has been hailed as a major breakthrough
in consumer protection. But despite considerable publicity, the
general public is not very familiar with the law.
A brochure, "What Truth in Lending Means to You," cogently
spells out the essentials of the law. Copies in both English and
Spanish are available upon request from the Department of Bank
and Public Relations, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Phila­
delphia, Pennsylvania 19101.
Available in English is a film strip on Regulation Z, Truth in
Lending, for showing to consumer groups. This 20-minute presen­
tation, developed by the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, is designed for use with a Dukane project that
uses 35mm film and plays a 33 RPM record synchronized with
the film. Copies of the film strip can be purchased from the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington,
D. C. 20551, for $10. It is available to groups in the Third Federal
Reserve District without charge except for return postage.
Persons in the Third District may direct requests for loan of
the film to Truth in Lending, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19101. Such requests should provide
for several alternate presentation dates.




24

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The Fed in Print
Business Review Topics
Second Quarter 1972,
Selected by Doris Zimmermann
Articles appearing in the Federal Reserve
Bulletin and in the business reviews of the
Federal Reserve banks during the second
quarter of 1972 are included in this compila­
tion. A cumulation of these entries covering
the years 7969 to date is available upon
request. If you wish to be put on the mailing
list for the cumulation, write to the Publica­
tions Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia.
To receive copies of the Federal Reserve
Bulletin, mail sixty cents for each to the
Federal Reserve Board at the Washington
address on page 30. You may send for
business reviews of the Federal Reserve
banks, free of charge, by writing directly to
the issuing banks whose addresses also
appear on page 30.
BANK DEPOSITS
Bank debits, deposits, and deposit turn­
over — revised series — F R Bull July
72 p 631

AGRIBUSINESS
Brighter farm picture — San Fran April 72
P 3
Revolutions in American
agriculture — Kansas City June 72 p 3
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
Closing Uncle Sam's trade gap — Phila
April 72 p 13
U.S. balance-of-payments problems in
1971 — St. Louis April 72 p 8

BANK EARNINGS
Member bank income, 1971 — F R Bull
May 72 p 446
OPERATING RATIOS available - Phila
May 72 p 23
Profit rate at District member banks de­
clines in 1971 — Atlanta June 72 p 105

BANK CREDIT CARDS
What's in store for bank credit cards in
the Southeast? — Atlanta June 72 p 99

BANK HOLDING COMPANIES
Boom in multibank holding companies —
Phila May 72 p 8




25

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

BUCHER, JEFFREY M.
Appointment to Board of Governors June
5, 1972 - F R Bull June 72 p 601

Registered in the District number 115 —
Dallas June 72 p 7
BANK LOANS — BUSINESS
Monthly series for commercial and indus­
trial loans — F R Bull July 72 p 683

BUDGET
The full employment budget — its uses and
limitations — Kansas City April 72 p 3
M eeting p u b lic need s: An a p p ra isa l
(Mayo) — Chic May 72 p 2
The full-employment budget: A guide for
fiscal policy — Rich May 72 p 2

BANK LOANS — CONSTRUCTION
Construction loans at commercial banks —
F R Bull June 72 p 533
BANK LOANS — CONSUMER
Continue to grow — Atlanta May 72 p 89

BURNS, ARTHUR F.
Some essentials of international monetary
reform (Montreal) — F R Bull June 72
p 545
Some essentials of international monetary
reform — N.Y. June 72 p 131

BANK LOANS — FARM
Rural bank needs for external funds —
Chic May 72 p 12
BANK MARKETS
Defining the product market in commer­
cial banking — Cleve June 72 p 17

BUSINESS CYCLES
Recovery accelerates — St. Louis June 72
P 2

BANK PORTFOLIOS
Securities: A major outlet for District
member banks — Atlanta April 72 p 69

BUSINESS FORECASTS & REVIEWS
The trend of business — Chic April 72 p 2
Financial developments in the first quarter
of 1972 - F R Bull May 72 p 435
Spring upsurge? — San Fran May 72 p 3

BANK SUPERVISION
The Hunt Commission Report — an eco­
nomic review —St. Louis June 72 p 8
BANKING STRUCTURE
District banking: Ten years of growth and
change — Atlanta April 72 p 54
A newcomer's view of the U.S. banking
industry (Winn) — Cleve April 72 p 3
Banking's widening limits (Eastburn) —
Phila May 72 p 3
Changes in the '60s: A new financial cli­
mate — Phila May 72 p 11
The changing banking scene (Treiber) —
N.Y. June 72 p 135

CALL REPORTS
Banking data on magnetic tape — F R Bull
July 72 p 683
CHECK COLLECTIONS
Regional check processing centers — Rich
April 72 p 10
Recent regulatory changes in reserve re­
quirements and check collection —
F R Bull July 72 p 626

BRIMMER, ANDREW F.
Characteristics of Federal Reserve bank
directors — F R Bull June 72 p 550

COMMERCIAL POLICY
International trade policies — the problem
of nontariff barriers — Kansas City
May 72 p 11

BROKERS
Stock market commission fees: Competi­
tion or bust . . . or be busted — Phila
April 72 p 3



CONTAINERIZATION
Houston and Galveston bid for container
trade — Dallas June 72 p 1
26

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

CORPORATE FINANCE
Financing corporate investment — F R Bull
May 72 p 523

FARM INCOME
Outlook for farm income and food prices
— St. Louis April 72 p 16

CREDIT RATIONING
A review — F R Bull June 72 p 531

FARM O UTLO O K
What's ahead for agriculture in '72? — Rich
April 72 p 14

CRIME
Compensating victims of crime: Blunting
the blow — Phila June 72 p 14

FARM REAL ESTATE
Seventh District farmland values — Chic
June 72 p 19

DISCOUNT RATES
Problems and remedies — Atlanta June 72
p 94

FEDERAL FUNDS MARKET
A market comes of age in the Eleventh
District Part II — Dallas April 72 p 1
A market comes of age in the Eleventh
District Part III — Dallas May 72 p 1

ECONOM IC DEVELOPMENT
Social costs — the due bill for progress —
Kansas City April 72 p 13
Financial analysts and the nongrowth cult
— Phila May 72 p 3

FEDERAL RESERVE ACT
Revised edition — F R Bull July 72 p 684
FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD
Membership of the Board of Governors
1913-1972 - F R Bull June 72 p 560

ECONOM IC STABILIZATION
Federal economic policies in perspective
— Atlanta April 72 p 62
A look at ten months of price-wage con­
trols (Andersen) — St. Louis June 72
p 13

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM —
PUBLICATIONS
The Fed in print — Phila June 72 p 21
FOREIGN EXCHANGE
Devaluation of the dollar — San Fran June
72 p 3

EMPLOYMENT, FULL
The path to full employment — Bost May
72 p 11

FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATES
Exchange-rate flexibility and the forwardexchange markets: . . . The German
mark — Bost May 72 p 2

EXPECTATIONS
Curbing price expectations — St. Louis
May 72 p 2

FORWARD EXCHANGE
Nature and use of — Cleve April 72 p 7

EXPORTS
Domestic international sales corporations
— Rich June 72 p 2
The world trade matrix — Rich June 72 p 7
FARM EXPORTS
Japan: U.S. agriculture's number one cus­
tomer — Kansas City May 72 p 3



27

SEPTEMBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

GOVERNMENT EMPLOYEES
Government employment in the United
States: 1952-1970 — Rich April 72 p 2

MUNICIPAL FINANCE
Fiscal alternatives for Philadelphia — Phila
April 72 p 17

GRANTS-IN-AID
Federal aid to Fifth District states — Rich
May 72 p 9

NEGROES
Economic situation of blacks . . . — Phila
June 72 p 9

INTEREST RATES
On loans, monthly, in G.10 release — F R
Bull May 72 p 510

ONE-BANK HOLDING COMPANIES
In the Southeast — Atlanta May 72 p 82
OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS
And the monetary and credit aggregates —
1971 - N.Y. April 72 p 79
Record of policy actions, Feb 15, 1972 —
F R Bull May 72 p 455
Record of policy actions, March 21, 1972
- F R Bull June 72 p 562
Record of policy actions, April 17 and 18,
1972 - F R Bull July 72 p 640

JACOBSSON, PER
FOUNDATION LECTURE
available — N.Y. April 72 p 105
LOANS, DISASTER
Assistance to banks in flooded areas — F R
Bull July 72 p 682
MAISEL, SHERMAN J.
Resignation May 31, 1972, from Board of
Governors — F R Bull June 72 p 601

OVER-THE-COUNTER MARKET
List of O TC margin stocks — F R Bull May
72 p 511
Changes in O TC margin stocks — F R Bull
July 72 p 682

MANUFACTURING
In West Virginia — Rich May 72 p 12
Virginia — Rich June 72 p 11
METROPOLITAN AREAS
Eighth Federal Reserve District — St. Louis
June 72 p 6

PRODUCTIVITY
Productivity, labor costs, and prices — Rich
April 72 p 6

MITCHELL, GEORGE W.
Statement to Congress, June 19, 1972
(bank tax) — F R Bull July 72 p 636

RECREATION INDUSTRY
Skiers: Their local economic impact —
Kansas City June 72 p 10

MONETARY STABILIZATION
Problems of the international monetary
system and proposals for reform —
1944-1970 — St. Louis May 72 p 24

REGULATION D
Amendment September 21, 1972 — F R
Bull July 72 p 649

MONEY SUPPLY
Recent monetary growth — St. Louis April
72 p 3
Measurement of the domestic monetary
stock — St. Louis May 72 p 10

REGULATION G
Amendment May 15, 1972 — F R Bull May
72 p 464

MORTGAGES, VARIABLE
Variable rates on mortgages? — San Fran
April 72 p 11

REGULATION J
Amendment September 21, 1972 — F R
Bull July 72 p 649




28

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

REGULATION Q
And the commercial loan market in the
1960's - F R Bull June 72 p 532

SAVINGS AND LOAN ASSOCIATIONS
. . . In a changing economy — Atlanta May
72 p 74

REGULATION T
Amendment May 15, 1972 — F R Bull May
72 p 464

SHIPBUILDING
Boom in offshore drilling keeps rig build­
ers busy — Dallas April 72 p 7

REGULATION U
Amendment May 15, 1972 — F R Bull May
72 p 464

TIME DEPOSITS
Growing time deposits — at what cost to
the small bank? —Chic April 72 p 8
Changes in time and savings deposits at
commercial banks — F R Bull July 72
p 615

REGULATION Y
Amendment June 6, 1972 — F R Bull June
72 p 571

UNEMPLOYMENT
What happens when unemployment rate
changes — Cleve June 72 p 3

REGULATION Z
Brochure and film strip on TRUTH IN
LENDING available — Phila June 72
P 8

VOLUNTARY FOREIGN LOAN CREDIT
RESTRAINT 1965
Recent interpretations — F R Bull May 72
p 509
Interpretations — F R Bull June 72 p 602

RESERVE REQUIREMENTS
Member bank reserve requirements — her­
itage from history — Chic June 72 p 2

NOW AVAILABLE
The Fed in Print, a cumulative index to Federal Reserve Bank reviews, is avail­
able on a quarterly basis. It brings Selected Subjects up-to-date. To be placed
on the mailing list, send your request to the Department of Public Services,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19101.




29

FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS AND BOARD OF GOVERNORS
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Federal Reserve Station
Kansas City, Missouri 64198

Publications Services
Division of Administrative Services
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System
Washington, D. C. 20551

Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Minneapolis, Minnesota 55440

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Federal Reserve Station
Atlanta, Georgia 30303

Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Federal Reserve P.O. Station
New York, New York 10045

Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
30 Pearl Street
Boston, Massachusetts 02106

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
925 Chestnut Street
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19101

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
P.O. Box 27622
Richmond, Virginia 23261

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, Ohio 44101

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
P.O. Box 442
St. Louis, Missouri 63166

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Station K
Dallas, Texas 75222




Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
San Francisco, California 94120

30

FOR THE RECORD...

2 YEARS AGO

YEAR AGO

JULY 1972

Third Federal
Reserve District

July 1972
fr om
mo.
ago

year
ago

YEAR AGO

United States

Percent change
SU M M A R Y

2 YEARS AGO

Manufacturing

year
ago

July 1972
frc>m
mo.
ago

year
ago

7
mos.
1972
from
year
ago

Payrolls

Percent
change
July 1972
from

LO CA L
CHANGES
Standard
Metropolitan
Statistical Areas'

Percent
change
July 1972
from

Electric power consumed ... - 6
- 3
Employment, total................... - 2
Wage income*.......................... - 3
CONSTRUCTIO N"..................... + 12
COAL PRODUCTION................... -1 6

- 2
- 2
- 3
+ 4
+15
-2 1

+ 2
—2
- 3
+ 4
-2 4
- 6

7 + 6 + 6

Bridgeton..................

-

-1 0

0 + 2 + lb

-

3 + 3

N/A

- 5 + 6 +13
-1 7 + 4 - 5

+12
+ 13
+ 15
+ 13
+ 10
+ 14
- 2
0
+16
+22
+12f +13t

+ 3t

N/A

N/A

Altoona......................

5 - 3 -

1

N/A

+ 1 N/A

-

4 + 1 + 7 + 8 + 6 + 2 + 8

+ 1 +10
+ 1 + 15
o + 7
- 1
0
0 +11
- 2 +11

+10
+12
+ 10
+ 1
+15
+ 14

1 -

- 2 -

+ 31

+ 1 + 4 + 4
0 + 3 + 3

f 15 SMSA’s
JPhiladelphia

4 + 12 -

-

6 + 16 + 4 +21

1 -

7 + 11 + 1 +10

2 + 9 + 9 - 4 +12

+ 3 +17

2 - 2 -

1 + 11

0 + 12

0 + 7

0 + 2 -

2 + 12 - 5 + 34

+ 2 + 15

3 + 10 + 4 + 18 + 2 + 14

Lehigh Valley............

-

6 - 2 -

Philadelphia..............

-

1 -

2 -

2 + 5 + 1 + 16

1 +13

4 + 5

3 + 1 + 6 + 4 + 1 +12

Scranton....................

- 3 + 1 -

Williamsport..............

N/A

York...........................

-

8 -

4 -

N/A

8 + 1 + 15

7 + 5 + 4 +22

N/A

1 + 1 -

9

-

_ 3 - 2

Wilkes-Barre.............

ot

Percent
change
July 1972
from

- 2 -

Lancaster..................

0
0
0
U.S. Govt, securities............ - 1
Other..................................... + 1
Check paym ents'"................. - It

0 + 1 +20

0

Atlantic City..............

Johnstown.................

BANKING
(All member banks)
Deposits....................................
Loans........................................




Percent
change
July 1972
from

0
-

'Production workers only
'Value of contracts
'Adjusted tor seasonal variation

Check
Total
Payments" Deposits'"

month year montf year month year montf year
ago ago ago ago ago ago ago ago

MANUFACTURING

PRICES
Wholesale...............................
Consumer.................................

Banking

Employ­
ment

Percent change

7
mos.
1972
from

JULY 1972

N/A

+ 6 +29

+ 12 - 4 + 2 N/A

2 + 8 + 10 + 35

0 + 11

'Not restricted to corporate limits of cities but covers areas of one or more
counties.
" A ll commercial banks. Adjusted for seasonal variation.
'"Member banks only. Last Wednesday of the month.