View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions

What's happening to
meat prices?

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Restrictions on world trade
Worldwide concern about the state of the
international economy, including restric­
tions on international trade, has intensified
since August 15, 1971, when the President
announced that the United States would no
longer redeem foreign dollar claims in gold,
and imposed an import surtax affecting
over 50 percent of U. S. imports. Other
events of major importance for the interna­
tional economy that occurred in 1971
included the completion of negotiations ex­
panding the European Economic Communi­
ty (EEC) from six to ten members as of
January 1, 1973 (if candidate countries rati­
fy the treaty), and U. S.-sponsored volun­
tary import quotas on textiles—and at­
tempts to negotiate import quotas on steel
—with major foreign producers. As a finale
to the year, the final set of tariff reductions
agreed upon in 1967 during the Kennedy
Round of tariff negotiations became ef­
fective on January 1, 1972.
Still, the focus of attention during 1971
for foreign trade experts increasingly cen­
tered on the distortions existing in the fi­
nancial and trade markets of the world.
That U. S. producers felt intensified compe­
tition from foreign producers is seen in the
deterioration of the U. S. merchandise
trade balance—a $4.7 billion decline from
the 1970 level to a deficit of $2.0 billion
(census basis), the first U. S. trade deficit
in the twentieth century. Disequilibrium in
financial markets contributed to a record
balance-of-payments deficit of $29.6 billion
(on an official reserve basis). As these dol­
lars streamed into Europe and Japan, pres­
sures on governments to “do something”




finally culminated in December with a com­
bination package of foreign currency re­
valuations, a dollar devaluation, and an
agreement by the United States and its ma­
jor trading partners to at least discuss re­
ductions in nontariff distortions to trade.
The importance of multinational nego­
tiations on nontariff trade distortions have
long been stressed by the United States.
Nontariff distortions in trade have been
influential in reducing U. S. competitive­
ness in world markets. The December cur­
rency realignment and the trade agreements
reached in early February 1972, while not a
replacement for full-scale negotiations, do
constitute a “foot-in-the-door” that hope­
fully will be followed by agreement for
broader negotiations under the sponsorship
of the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade (GATT). In the February agreements,
the European Economic Community and
Japan indicated they would support multi­
national negotiations to begin in 1973. In
addition, the EEC and Japan made several
concessions on imports of U. S. agricultural
products, and Japan reduced several indus­
trial import restrictions, including those on
computers and automobiles.
Since W o rld W a r II

When World War II ended, much of the
world economy lay in ruins. Government
officials in the free world understood that
the success of the rebuilding job would de­
pend in large part on international trade,
and that the job would be difficult, if not
impossible, under the extremely restrictive
trade policies of the prewar period. In an

Business Conditions, February 1972

attempt to formulate
Average tariff levels before (1967)
new rules for internaand after (January 1, 1972)
tional trade, the InterKennedy Round—selected categories
national Trade O r­
EEC
Japan
U. K.
U. S.
ganization (ITO) was
1967 1972
1967 1972
1967 1972
1967 1972
proposed under the
(P e rc e n ta g e o f C .I .F . v a lu e )
auspices of the United
Electrical machinery
14.2
9.1
17.8 10.8
20.1 12.4
13.6
7.1
Nations. The attempt
Nonelectrical machinery
11.9
15.6 10.0
14.2
11.1
6.4
6.0
8.6
failed. But in 1947,
Transportation equipment
9.9
18.4 13.9
20.0 11.0
15.4
7.1
3.5
and springing directly
Base metals & metal
out of the previous
products
11.0
7.1
12.8
9.9
6.3
9.0
7.0
8.5
endeavor, came the
Stone, ceramic, & glass
16.9
16.4 10.3
products
14.1
21.0 15.0
9.5
8.0
G eneral Agreement
20.6 16.9
Textiles
21.4 20.1
23.5 13.6
16.0 12.6
on Tariffs and Trade
6.4
6.7
Pulp and paper
10.7
7.5
10.9
5.5
16.6 13.2
(GATT).1 Over the
12.0
6.2
9.3
4.8
Mineral products
9.4
5.5
9.9
7.5
years, GATT guide­
Manufactured imports
14.3
9.9
17.6 10.7
17.8 10.8
13.5
8.6
lines have provided a
Industrial imports
12.8
8.1
13.5
9.6
15.5
9.5
16.6 10.6
yardstick nations use
SOURCE: Preeg, Ernest H., Traders and Diplomats, The Brookings Institution,
to gauge their own ac­
Washington, D. C., 1970.
tions and those of
others in matters of
progress toward their further reduction will
international trade relationships. Unfortu­
be painfully slow. And all has not been
nately, the agreement has often been abused
progress, for while some artificial trade dis­
when nations felt vital short-term interests
tortions have been eliminated in recent
were at stake. But GATT does supply a
years, there have been new ones added.
platform for continuing trade negotiations
Whether the net effect has been toward
and, in fact, has been a major force in
promoting reductions in tariff barriers.
fewer restrictions is not always clear.
Major world governments have intensified
T ariff b a rrie rs to tra d e
their conscious examination of the artificial
impediments distorting international trade,
A tariff often protects domestically-pro­
and the result is a concerted effort to re­
duced products from the competition of im­
duce, rather than increase, these distortions.
ports by raising the price of the import
While much has been accomplished over
relative to its nontariff price. While a tariff
the years in reducing nontariff distortions,
may be an impediment to trade in that it
and while progress has been made in identi­
interfers with the allocation of resources
among nations, it does retain price as the
fying distortions that remain, it is obvious
allocating factor determining supply and de­
that the distortions are legion and that*
mand.
The quantity imported is not directly
JGATT is adhered to by the United States and
affected—rather, because the price of the
other countries under a “protocol of provisional
application.” Basically, the General Agreement on
import is higher due to the tax, fewer goods
Tariffs and Trade sets down rules of conduct in
are
imported.
international trade and specifies maximum levels
for individual tariff rates.
Under GATT auspices, the “ Dillon



3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

4

Round” of tariff negotiations in 1960, fol­
lowed by the more extensive “Kennedy
Round” (extending from May 1964 to June
1967) resulted in significant reductions in
tariffs on nonagricultural goods for the ma­
jor trading nations of the noncommunist
world. With the final tariff reductions,
which went into effect January 1, 1972, it
is estimated that U. S. tariffs are 36 per­
cent lower, that common external tariffs
of the EEC are 37 percent lower, and tariffs
of both Japan and the United Kingdom are
39 percent lower than they were prior to
the first reduction in 1968. Average tariff
rates for all industrial imports subject to
duties have been estimated at 8.1 percent
for the EEC, 9.5 percent for Japan, 9.6
percent for the United States, and 10.6 per­
cent for the United Kingdom. (See table.)
Averages can be misleading in determin­
ing the degree of protection afforded by
what might appear to be a relatively high
or a relatively low average tariff. A very
high rate, that is to say a rate high enough
to effectively prohibit the importation of a
product, will not show up in the averages
because nothing is imported to which the
prohibitive rate applies. Nevertheless, there
has been a lowering in tariff levels, as well
as a narrowing in the difference between
average tariff rates of major trading coun­
tries. Not only did average tariff levels de­
cline, but the decline was proportionately
greater for high-tariff countries. In terms of
average tariff levels, the differences among
countries are quite small. This does not
mean, however, that the small differential
carries over to specific products or cate­
gories of products. For example, the aver­
age tariff level for transportation equipment
entering Japan is 13.9 percent, while the
comparable level imposed on U. S. imports
is 3.5 percent. The average level for U. S.




imports of textiles is 20.1 percent, while the
comparable average level for EEC textile
imports is 12.6 percent. Tariff rates for spe­
cific items will show far wider variations
than indicated by the averages.
Nominal tariff rates are easy enough to
identify. They are published in a nation’s
tariff schedule. It would be too simple, how­
ever, to say that a 20 percent tariff on im­
ported shirts means the same thing in two
different countries. The tariff might be ap­
plied to the value of the shirt at the port
of export, or the value at the port of import
(including shipping costs), or on the price
of a comparable domestically-produced
shirt. Each of these methods of valuation
results in a different effective tariff on the
import, and consequently different levels of
protection for domestically-produced goods.
Differences among nations in their product
valuation procedures remain a point of fric­
tion in trade liberalization negotiations. It
is worth noting that in a case like this it is
the procedure itself that constitutes the
trade distortion.
The U. S. Government generally applies
its tariff schedule rates to the free on board
(F.O.B.) price of imports at the foreign
port. European countries, Japan, and other
major trading countries (excepting Canada)
apply their tariff schedule rates to the cost
of imports, including insurance and freight
(C.I.F.), at their port of entry.
A politically serious valuation contro­
versy centers on the American Selling Price
(ASP) valuation, used in connection with
benzenoid chemicals, certain rubber-soled
footwear, and canned clams. Under this
procedure, the import tariff is based on the
higher price of comparable domesticallyproduced products rather than the price of
the imported product.
The ASP has long been a rallying point

Business Conditions, February 1972

for European countries in discussions of re­
ducing trade restriction. The ASP is espe­
cially irritating to foreigners because it is
a vestigal remains of an arbitrary valuation
system generally outlawed by GATT in
1947. The U. S. Government, in Kennedy
Round negotiations in 1967, agreed to its
elimination subject to legislative approval
as part of a separate package on tariff and
nontariff distortion concessions. Although
ASP was initiated in 1922 to protect the
then newly-developing chemical industry,
the Congress, so far, has not determined to
terminate it.
N o n ta riff b a rrie rs to tra d e

legislated nontariff barriers represent the
hard core of the problem—barriers such
as the negotiated “voluntary” export quotas
compound the problem. A major impeding
factor is that many nontariff barriers are
not specifically related to trade, or any
other single area.
Broad-scale enabling legislation authoriz­
ing concessions is difficult to draft because
it would have to specify the limits and con­
ditions of concessions permissible on con­
ceivably everything from health and safety
standards, to patent requirements, to quota
restrictions. Groups with vested interests in
such things could not be expected to stand
idle while the barricades are dismantled for
the sake of freer foreign trade.

The valuation controversy surrounding
imports, while tied to tariffs, moves one
C a ta lo g of n o n tariff b a rrie rs to trad e
into the realm of nontariff barriers to trade.
It is within the area of nontariff barriers
Import quotas
that the most serious, present day disloca­
tions occur. Since the conclusion of the
Import quotas, one of the most obvious
Kennedy Round, the U. S. Government
nontariff barriers to trade, are a tool fa­
has repeatedly proposed consideration of a
vored by governments desiring to protect
possible new round of GATT-sponsored
selected domestic industries from the com­
trade negotiations to deal with nontariff
petition of imports, or desiring to regulate
barriers and their undesirable consequences.
the amount of expenditures on certain prod­
GATT is developing a detailed inventory of
ucts in their domestic market. An example
existing nontariff barriers to trade, a neces­
of the latter is the tendency prevalent
sary basis for negotia­
tion when formal dis­
cussions eventually
Quantitative restrictions on imports
take place.
Value of imports subject to
Even if negotiations
Proportion of imports subject
quantitative restrictions
to quantitative restrictions
aimed toward the re­
Industrial
Agricultural
Industrial
Agricultural
duction of nontariff
(b illio n d o lla r s )
(p e rc e n t)
barriers were to begin
EEC
0.9
2.6
4.3
33.7
tomorrow, the pros­
United Kingdom
0.7
1.1
4.7
21.9
pect for any signifi­
Japan
1.4
0.8
11.4
27.9
can t re d u c tio n in
United States
5.1
1.2
16.5
21.6
their magnitude or
Compiled from: John C. Renner, "National Restrictions on International Trade," in
number lies well in
United States International Economic Policy in a Interdependent World, Commission
the future. Existing
on International Trade and Investment, Vol, 1. July 1971, Washington, D. C.



Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

among the less developed countries to im­
pose tight import quotas on luxury goods.
Quantitative restrictions imposed by in­
dustrial countries most often are applied to
agricultural products, plus a few categories
of industrial goods. In 1970, quantitative
restrictions were applied to about 22 per­
cent of the value of U. S. and U. K. agri­
cultural imports. Comparable percentages
for Japan and the European Economic
Community were 28 and 34 percent, re­
spectively. (See table.) The EEC’s high
degree of quantitative restriction on the
value of agricultural imports is reflected in
the fact that nearly 60 percent of their ma­
jor agricultural import categories are cov­
ered, at least in part, by quantitative restric­
tions. The United States, on the other
hand, imposes import quotas on only 7 per­
cent of its agricultural import categories.
The United Kingdom employs quantita­
tive restrictions relatively sparingly as com­
pared with the numbers used by the EEC,
Japan, and the United States.
Import licenses

6

Import licensing is a highly flexible form
of restriction commonly used by Japan, by
European countries, and by the less devel­
oped countries. Import licenses constitute
a potentially serious deterrent to trade be­
cause of the low degree of visibility associ­
ated with licensing arrangements in most
countries, and because of the uncertainty
surrounding the issuing of licenses. A prime
example of how licenses can rigidly control
imports is the U. K.’s requirement that coal
and solid fuels be imported under license.
But the licensing authority does not issue
licenses for coal, thereby barring all imports
of coal. This fact causes considerable frus­
tration in the U. S. coal industry which
would be competitive, pricewise, if per­




mitted entry into the U. K. market.
Export subsidies

Export subsidies are commonly used in
international trade to expand exports, to
gain a market advantage, or to dispose of
excess production in a foreign market so as
not to cause a disruption in prices in the
home market. Subsidized exports tend to
disrupt the markets to which the products
are shipped, as well as the markets of thirdcountry competitors. Countries of the EEC
are among the most prominent users of ex­
port subsidies.
Direct export subsidies for the EEC’s
agricultural exports are a particular sore
point with the United States. The Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP) of the EEC sup­
ports high internal prices for many grains,
and for dairy and poultry products. These
high domestic prices are buffered from the
competition of lower world prices by a tariff
called a variable levy which raises the prices
of specific imported commodities to the
level of the supported domestic prices. In
this way, imports are effectively restricted;
furthermore, high domestic prices encour­
age expanded domestic production. When
this situation leads to surplus production,
the surplus is placed on the world market
at subsidized prices, thereby cutting into the
third-country markets of other leading ag­
ricultural exporters. The United States has
countered EEC subsidies in some instances
by instituting export subsidies of its own.
Another case of export subsidies, one be­
coming increasingly prevalent, is where a
government actively subsidizes the financing
of exports. The willingness and ability of
a government to grant tax deferrals on
goods exported, as in the case of the new
U. S. Domestic International Sales Corpo­
ration Program (DISC), to provide loan

Business Conditions, February 1972

guarantees, and to provide funds directly to
exporters at low interest rates, oftentimes
are key factors in whether an export sale
will be made. The Japanese government, for
example, is especially aggressive in promot­
ing low-cost financing for exports. In 1971,
the Export-Import Bank of the United
States received authority to participate
more actively in export financing.
Dumping

When products are exported to a foreign
market and sold at a price that is lower
than that on the domestic market, it is
called “dumping”—economists call this
practice price discrimination. This practice
may be a disrupter of markets and if it leads
to injury is not sanctioned by GATT. As a
defense against dumping, injured countries
are permitted by GATT to impose offset­
ting import taxes called antidumping duties
to negate the price advantage the foreign
producer obtains by pricing abroad at less
than in the home market.
Domestic component requirements

Minimum domestic component require­
ments are a form of nontariff barrier often
used by less developed countries, as well as
by some developed countries, in the attempt
to nurture their infant industries. These re­
quirements typically stipulate that a certain
proportion of the value of the final product
must be composed of components that origi­
nate in the importing country. Countries
attempting to develop an automotive in­
dustry, for example, often require that key
subassemblies be manufactured internally,
or that a minimum proportion of foreign
cars sold internally be assembled domesti­
cally. These regulations have the effect of
forcing foreign car producers to assist in
the industrial development of the country




if they wish to sell cars in that market.
A more subtle form of the domestic com­
ponent requirement is tied to tariff sched­
ules. Developed as well as developing coun­
tries regularly apply higher tariff rates to
manufactured or processed forms of pri­
mary products than to the primary product
itself. There is a higher tariff on refined
sugar and ground coffee than on raw sugar
and coffee beans. Thus, imports incorporat­
ing foreign processing are discouraged to a
greater extent than are raw products. The
less developed countries find the imposi­
tion of this trade barrier by the industrial
countries especially galling because it re­
tards their industrial development by in­
hibiting their ability to compete in foreign
markets with higher-value processed goods.
Financial controls

Some of the least visible nontariff trade
restrictions are those involving financial
and currency controls. The characteristic
that makes this type of control of unusual
significance is that currency restrictions on
international commercial transactions—
such as foreign exchange rates, monetary
flows, interest rates on government obliga­
tions, and a nation’s balance-of-payments
position—are tied in with governmental
image-making and national prestige. Were
the roots of prestige not so deep, nontariff
barriers involving financial and currency
controls would be among the easiest of all
barriers to overcome.
Arbitrary controls over foreign exchange
introduce widespread uncertainty in inter­
national commercial transactions. Typically,
exchange controls are used by governments
to attack the symptoms rather than the
politically difficult causes of an undesirable
balance-of-payments situation. The onagain, off-again international monetary

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

turmoil of recent years has caused coun­
tries to establish exchange controls to pro­
tect their currencies against speculation,
hindering trade in the process. The mone­
tary realignment agreed upon in December
1971 has permitted elimination of many of
the exchange control barriers that were in
the process of being erected.
While it is true that exchange controls
can be implemented in such a way as to be
an effective deterrent to speculative capital
flows and no more than a nuisance to trade,
they also can be applied in a manner that
makes trade a very expensive proposition.
A common example is regulations requir­
ing that a currency deposit cover all or part
of the value of an import shipment.
"Buy-at-home" policies

Among the most conspicuous nontariff
barriers to trade are “buy-at-home” policies.
The United States is probably the most ob­
vious practitioner of this form of restric­
tion in that she is open and above board
about it. For years, the “Buy American”
Act has imposed, in addition to the tariff,
a special restraint on federal procurement
of foreign goods. A recent example of this
practice of promoting domestic goods over
foreign goods is a section in the U. S. Reve­
nue Act of 1971 which provides for the ex­
clusion of foreign-made investment goods
from the investment tax credit allowed on
similar U. S.-made goods. The provision
was so odious to our major trading partners
that the United States agreed that it would
not be implemented as a condition of the
international monetary accord reached in
December 1971.
Western European countries typically do
not employ “buy-at-home” laws per se.
They do, however, follow the practice of
“closed bidding.” Closed bidding, poten­




tially more restrictive than buy-domestic
policies, effectively bars foreign firms from
even submitting bids. Thus, whether the
price is competitive with that of domestic
producers makes little difference. Closed
bidding is particularly prevalent in the realm
of government procurement.
A related practice, based on the buydomestic concept, is that of requiring that
a minimum proportion of funds provided
for foreign aid be used to purchase goods
and services from the donor country. “TiedAid” may reduce the real value of aid to a
country by forcing it, if it accepts the aid,
to buy at a higher cost than necessary.
Nontariff barriers like these are difficult
to dismantle because they are usually ad­
ministratively and arbitrarily imposed. Of­
ten legal statutes do not identify their ex­
istence and, therefore, cannot be repealed.
Administrative convention would have to
be changed either by general agreement or
by legal imposition of an “open tender”
requirement.
Health and safety restrictions

Nontariff barriers related to health and
safety include a broad and growing group­
ing of regulations, some of which promote
the general well-being of the population
while incidentally restricting trade, and
some of which promise to serve the general
well-being of the population but actually do
little more than restrict trade. To a greater
or lesser degree, such regulations are neces­
sary, but they do make international trade
more expensive than it would otherwise be.
When an importing country requires safety
tests on a product that has been adequately
tested in the exporting country, it amounts
to one more barrier to hurdle. If destructive
testing is required, the direct cost of the
import is consequently increased.

Business Conditions, February 1972

Measurement standards

In the near future, measurement stan­
dards will become a problem peculiar to the
United States. The Canadian government is
committed to adopting the metric system of
weights and measures, and the British gov­
ernment is in the process of converting.
Once these nations go metric, the United
States will be the only major trading nation
still using a nonmetric system. In 1971, the
National Bureau of Standards published a
report recommending that the United States
convert to the metric system. U. S. trade
now lost due to nonmetric measures is due
largely to higher product costs primarily
because of higher development costs associ­
ated with using the nonmetric system.
P re fe re n tia l trad in g arran g em en ts

Preferential trading arrangements, dis­
couraged by the international community
until recent years, represent a method of
distorting trade flows that cuts across tariff
and nontariff barriers alike. One of the
most rapidly growing forms of trade distor­
tions, they involve a major shift away from
the Most Favored Nation principle that has
been an acceptable practice in international
trade since the 1930s. The Most Favored
Nation principle holds that a trade conces­
sion granted to one nation will be granted
to all other trading partners.
When the European Economic Com­
munity was formed, a number of African
nations associated with individual members
of the EEC (usually through former colonial
status), but not members of the EEC, were
granted special access to the markets of all
EEC members. Since then, the EEC has
also granted some Mediterranean nations
preferential trading rights, and late in 1971
the EEC announced plans to extend pref­
erential arrangements to those members of




the European Free Trade Association
(EFTA) that did not apply for membership
in the EEC (Austria, Finland, Iceland, Por­
tugal, Sweden, and Switzerland). At no
point has the EEC extended similar conces­
sions to all trading nations, thus putting
these actions in direct violation of the Most
Favored Nation principle, and putting non­
participating nations at a disadvantage.
The United States also is a party to limit­
ed preferential trade agreements, such as
the Canada-U. S. auto agreement. (See Busi­
ness Conditions, November 1968). More­
over, the United States has proposed pref­
erential agreements with the less developed
countries to help further their economic
developments. The EEC and Japan already
have adopted preferential measures with
many of the less developed countries.
The increasing prevalence of preferential
trade agreements is a major point of con­
tention between the United States and the
EEC. While the U. S. concern is naturally
in its own self-interest, there is a basic
economic problem in agreements which dis­
regard the Most Favored Nation principle.
An economically undesirable redirection of
the world’s resources occurs if selective
trade concessions direct trade away from
efficient low-cost producing nations—na­
tions that may not be party to the prefer­
ential trade agreements—and direct trade
toward high-cost producing nations included
in such agreements.
Sum m ing up

Trade-distorting policies of nations result
from an intricate combination of political
and economic reasoning. They may come
out of actions specifically intended to dis­
criminate against foreign-produced goods
in order to protect domestic jobs and in­
dustry. Or, at the other extreme, they may

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

occur as a secondary effect to a regulation
whose intended purpose is guarding the
safety and well-being of the population.
Trade barriers that are formal, with strict
legal standing—such as tariffs, import quo­
tas, legislated buy-domestic policies—are
based on law; and laws can be changed,
given an appropriate political climate. In­
formal barriers, especially those subject to
administrative whim, are sometimes diffi­
cult just to identify, compounding the prob­
lem of their elimination. Informal barriers
must be first recognized, and accepted as
significant. This is not an easy task in itself.
If they are to be removed, the removal
must be through an administrative change
of heart, or through legislation that restricts

the imposition of the barriers themselves.
The current flurry of activity centering
on bilateral trade negotiations is aimed at
lessening the number of nontariff barriers
and at shoring up the international commit­
ment to the Most Favored Nation principle.
The United States already has served notice
that she will make a strong push to open a
new multilateral “round” of trade negotia­
tions directed especially at the elimination
of nontariff barriers. The EEC and Japan
now appear receptive to participating in
such negotiations in 1973. More open trade
among nations would be well served by a
concerted multinational effort to reduce
existing nontariff barriers, and to guard
against erecting new ones.

Glossary of trade terms
1. Trade distortion: A situation in which

higher value than the raw product, the
absolute tariff is higher on the finished
good. If the differential is large enough,
only raw material will be imported, and
all of the finished product will be pro­
duced domestically. In such a case, the
effective tariff on the finished good is
“prohibitive,” providing a high degree of
protection for the domestic processing in­
dustry, while the nominal rate may be, in
fact, relatively low.
7. Dumping: The practice of selling a prod­
uct in a foreign market at a price below
the price in the domestic market—price
discrimination.
8. Export subsidy: The practice by a govern­
ment of subsidizing the exportation of
goods. This may be accomplished through
direct cash assistance, tax deferrals on
profits gained through exporting, tax
credits for indirect taxes applied to ex­
ports, subsidized interest rates to assist
export financing, and so on.
9. Most Favored Nation principle (MFN):
Any trade concession agreed to with a
single nation will be extended to all other
nations.

2.

3.
4.

5.
6.

10

trade between or among nations is affect­
ed by actions of government or business
in such a way as to disrupt the allocation
of world resources and decrease the net
welfare of the nations involved, or of
third-party nations.
Tariff: A tax on imports applied as a
percentage of the value of the product
(ad valorum tariff), as an unvarying level
(specific tariff), or as some combination
of the two.
Quota: A quantitative limitation on the
physical amount of an import.
Nontariff barrier (NTB): A broad cate­
gory referring to trade restrictions other
than tariffs.
Nominal tariff: Tariff rate reported in
a nation’s tariff schedule.
Effective tariff: The effective tariff is
determined by the degree of protection it
affords the domestic industry. For ex­
ample, the same ad valorum nominal
tariff rate may be applied to a raw prod­
uct and a finished good made of the raw
product. Because the finished good is of




Business Conditions, February 1972

W hat’s happening to meat prices?
Rapidly rising meat prices amidst national
wage and price controls have dismayed con­
sumers and are viewed by some as a threat
to public confidence in Phase II of the Ad­
ministration’s anti-inflation program. Retail
prices of beef during the last two months
of 1971 rose 3 percent, and pork went up 2
percent. Compared to a year earlier, beef
and pork prices were up 12 percent and 7
percent, respectively. Meat prices continued
their upward spiral in the new year, with
January beef prices up 3 percent from a
month earlier and pork prices up 5 percent.
The sharp price advances stem largely from
a strong rise in consumer demand at a time
when farm production of livestock was on
the decline.
Food p rices—pre- and post-freeze

During the past several years, accelerat­
ing costs of processing and distribution
rather than the cost of food commodities
per se have been the major factor behind
rising food prices. About three-fifths of
every consumer dollar spent for food goes
to pay for direct labor, transportation, utili­
ties, and all the other services associated
with moving food from farmer to consumer.
The sum total of these costs associated with
a typical supermarket basket of farm foods
advanced over 11 percent from 1969 through
1971. In contrast to the unbroken upward
spiral of “nonfood” costs, the cost attrib­
utable to raw food commodities fluctuated,
with the average for 1971 falling below the
1969 level.
The price and wage freeze and Phase II
apparently broke the upward momentum of




food processing and distribution costs, at
least temporarily. During the last four
months of 1971, the proportion of food
costs attributable to processing and distri­
bution actually declined, while that attribut­
able to raw commodities increased 5 per­
cent. Raw agricultural commodities—in­
cluding livestock—were exempted from
controls both during the freeze and in Phase
II. Probably the exemption was allowed be­
cause of the mammoth job of policing the
prices of an industry with so many small
and geographically-dispersed producers.
Government officials also may have been
persuaded that “market forces” alone were
adequate to restrain agricultural prices,
especially since farm prices were declining

Sharply rising livestock prices . . .
dollars per cwt.

1971

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

generally at the time controls were initiated.
Under Phase II guidelines, meat processors
and retailers are allowed to “pass through”
higher costs that are directly associated
with higher prices paid for livestock. Thus,
as market forces shifted in the fourth quar­
ter of 1971 and livestock prices began to
rise, so did prices at the retail meat counter.
W o rk in g s of " th e m a rk e t"

Agricultural production and prices are
often subject to disruptive fluctuations be­
cause of the many small producers, the lack
of an industrywide discipline on produc­
tion, and because agricultural production is
a biological process subject to the effects
of weather, disease, and animal physiology.
Although government programs have stabi­
lized the crop sector, at least partially, the
1970 corn blight demonstrated once again
the uncontrollable nature of the agricultural
production process.
The livestock-meat sector of agriculture
is especially characterized by cyclic produc-

. . . led to rising retail
meat prices in 1971

Supplies lag d em an d

cents per pound

12

J

F

M




tion and prices. Moreover, demand for live­
stock, as well as other farm products, is
such that a small change in supplies results
in a much larger change in prices in the
opposite direction. Thus, a small drop in
livestock supplies in a given period will re­
sult in sharply higher prices only to be fol­
lowed a year or so later (depending on the
species involved) by increased production
and sharply lower prices. Recent experience
provides such an example.
At the beginning of 1971, farmers were
receiving $15 per hundredweight for hogs—
the lowest price in seven years. Beef steers
and heifers were averaging only $28 per
hundredweight. In January 1972, only a year
later, hogs were selling at $22.70 per hun­
dredweight—49 percent higher—and beef
steers and heifers, at over $34 per hundred­
weight, reached a 20-year high.
The low prices during the latter part of
1970 and through much of 1971, coupled
with short corn supplies because of a blightreduced 1970 crop, caused farmers to cur­
tail livestock feeding, especially hog feed­
ing. But early in 1971, the general economy
began to rebound from a recessionary low,
and consumer meat demand strengthened.

A

M

J

J

A

S

O

N

D

Beef supplies in 1971 were only about
1 percent larger than in 1970. From Jan­
uary through September, supplies averaged
2 to 3 percent above year-ago levels, but
then dropped below a year ago in the fourth
quarter due to 5 percent smaller supplies
in December.
Pork output in 1971 averaged 10 percent
higher than a year earlier, but nearly all
the increase occurred in the first half. In
October, hog slaughter dipped below a year
earlier, and by December pork production
slipped 5 percent below a year earlier.

Business Conditions, February 1972

Meat supplies smaller
at the end of 1971
pounds per person *

‘ Commercial slaughter supplies.

Long dock strikes reduced the flow of
meat imports in 1971 also. Imports, which
typically account for 5 percent of the total
meat supply, declined nearly 3 percent in
1971. Imported meat generally finds its way
into such processed items as luncheon meat,
hot dogs, and canned meats.
Meat supplies in the latter part of 1971
were only slightly smaller than in late 1970
—a year of unusually large supplies, espe­
cially of pork. But relative to demand,
meat was in much shorter supply than a
year earlier.
Although changes in demand are not as
readily measured as changes in supplies, the
primary indicators suggest that consumer
demand for meat was very strong in the
latter part of 1971. The U. S. population
grew by 2.2 million by the end of 1971.
More importantly, as in other recent years,
the greatest proportional increase occurred
among teenagers and young adults, the big­
gest meat-eaters in the population.



A strengthening of the general economy
was probably the most important factor
fueling demand for meat in 1971. Although
the economy still had weak spots, it was
certainly more robust than it had been in
1970. Per capita disposable personal income
for 1971 measured in terms of 1958 dollars
gained 3 percent, compared to an increase
of 2 percent the year before. And despite
much unemployment, the total number of
persons employed grew steadily throughout
1971. By December, there were 2.8 million
more employed persons in the nation than
there had been a year earlier. As more peo­
ple found jobs or went back to work, meat
likely appeared more often on the weekly
menu.
With demand outstripping supplies, prices
at all levels of the livestock-meat market­
ing channel moved higher in late 1971.
Farm prices increased most rapidly. This is

evidenced by the sharp increases in the
“farm value” component (often called the
farmer’s share) of the retail meat dollar.

Rising meat consumption
is influenced by more people
and more money
percent 1967=100

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The Department of Agriculture computes
the proportion of the retail cost of meat per
pound attributable to the farmer’s share,
the charges of processors and distributors,
and the retail markup. The farm value of
choice beef in December 1971 was nearly
28 percent higher than a year earlier. For
pork, the increase was almost 36 percent.
The retail prices of beef and pork in­
creased less in percentage terms. Choice
beef averaged over $1.08 per pound in De­
cember—12 percent higher than a year ear­
lier. Retail pork prices in December aver­
aged 73 cents per pound—less than 7
percent above the year before.
Not much re lie f in sigh t

14

Cattle and hog prices in 1972 continued
to increase from their December 1971
levels and were 7 percent and 30 percent,
respectively, above December levels during
February. Retail meat prices, which lagged
the earlier farm price increases, have ac­
celerated, and in January alone beef prices
were 3 percent higher than a month earlier
and pork prices jumped nearly 5 percent.
Even though farm prices may continue to
work somewhat lower in the months ahead,
retail prices are likely to hold firm or possi­
bly increase, reflecting a rebuilding of mar­
gins and increases in processing and distri­
bution costs associated with food marketing.
Livestock supplies are expected to remain
relatively tight throughout most of 1972.
Hog marketings are expected to remain
well below year-earlier levels, and cattle
marketings may be only moderately larger.
Last fall’s pig crop (June-November) was
about 8 percent smaller than a year earlier
according to Department of Agriculture
estimates. The smaller pig crop has already
been reflected in smaller marketings last
December and January. In fact, hog sup­




plies were down by 14 percent in January
from a year earlier, a greater decline than
the December estimates of the Department
of Agriculture had indicated. Through midFebruary, hog marketings were averaging
12 percent less than a year earlier. Either
the estimates contained sizable error or
marketings will be “bunched” in the latter
part of the quarter. Pigs on farms that will
be marketed mostly in the second quarter
numbered about 7 percent less than a year
ago. Farmers indicated they intended to re­
duce winter farrowings (December-May) by
10 percent, which should keep hog market­
ings down by a similar amount through
early fall of this year.
Low corn prices relative to hog prices
have caused and will continue to cause
farmers to feed hogs to heavier market
weights—a factor which swells supplies
more than numbers alone indicate. In Jan­
uary, hogs were averaging two pounds per
head heavier than a year earlier. Never­
theless, the reduced marketings will hold
hog prices well above the depressed levels
that prevailed through most of last year,
perhaps by as much as 50 percent this sum­
mer, although prices will decline seasonally
in the fall.
Cattle marketings are likely to be moder­
ately larger in 1972. A January 1 Cattle on
Feed report estimated that first-quarter
marketings would be 7 percent larger than
a year ago. But preliminary information
for January indicates marketings were
down 2 percent from a year ago. And more
tentative data for mid-February show mar­
ketings averaging about 1 percent below a
year earlier. Either the January estimates
were incorrect, or the increase in market­
ings in the remainder of February and in
March will have to be substantially greater
than 7 percent. Marketings in the second

Business Conditions, February 1972

quarter, based on weight groupings of cattle
on feed in January, may be only 2 percent
above a year ago. Somewhat larger increases
over a year ago are likely for the second
half of 1972.
Like hog producers, cattle feeders have
an incentive to feed their animals to heavier
slaughter weights because of abundant and
relatively cheap feed supplies this year. Thus
far in 1972, however, slaughter weights
have not shown any significant increase. A
possible explanation for this may be that in
the past few months cattle have been placed
on feed at younger ages, and these animals
reach the desired market grade at lighter
weights.
The moderate increase in cattle market­
ings and substantially lower hog marketings
suggest total meat supplies in 1972 will re­
main relatively tight. Greater than usual
retention of young animals to increase the
breeding herds of both cattle and hogs
could moderate supplies even more.
M e at im ports

The possibility of raising meat import
quotas in 1972 to augment domestic pro­
duction has been suggested as a means of
easing the upward pressure on retail prices.
Normally, imports make up about 5 percent
of total meat supplies, and about threefourths of these imports are beef. An in­
crease in meat quotas of perhaps 6 to 7 per­
cent has been suggested for this year. This
would translate into a less than 0.5 percent
increase in total supplies.
The bulk of imported meat is used in
such processed items as frankfurters, lunch­
eon meats, and canned or frozen products.
Some imported meat also is used in lowerpriced meats, such as hamburger. Thus, an
increase in imported supplies could have a
dampening effect on prices of these items



which, in turn, could work to moderate
further increases in higher-priced cuts. The
timing of an increase in imported supplies
could strengthen its impact. Since the first
quarter will have passed by the time any in­
crease is implemented, an increase in imports
would come sometime in the remaining three
quarters of the year. But with or without an
increase in imports, total meat supplies are
likely to remain tight relative to demand
through most of 1972.
Larger consumer after-tax incomes, a
slowdown in the rate of inflation with a
resulting increase in real purchasing power,
and a probable lower rate of unemployment
all will contribute to increased demand for
meat in 1972. Total consumer outlays on
all food likely will accelerate from last year’s
increase of 5.5 percent, with outlays for
meat pacing the increase.

Retail meat margins averaged
lower in 1971

cents per pound

II

III
1970

IV

I

II

III
1971

IV

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

At this juncture, the prospective demand
and supply situation suggests livestock prices
probably reached their peak this winter but
probably will remain high throughout most
of 1972 when compared to recent years.
R e ta ile rs m a y recoup m arg in

Although retailers are allowed to “pass
through” their additional costs due to higher
livestock prices, these increases apparently
have not yet been fully reflected in retail
prices, as evidenced by the decline in re­
tailers’ meat margins. Margin, as used here,
is the difference between the price the re­
tailer pays processors for the meat and the
price the retailer sells it for. All costs such
as labor, utilities, etc., plus profits are in­
cluded. During the fourth quarter of 1971,
the retail margin for beef declined nearly
7 percent, and shrank 9 percent for pork.

Falling retail margins are typical in pe­
riods of rapidly rising farm commodity
prices, but margins are usually rebuilt
when farm prices decline. This year is not
likely to be an exception. Margins can in­
crease by virtue of retail prices declining
more slowly than farm prices, but the small
decline anticipated for livestock prices in
1972 is not likely to cause retail prices to
decline. Moreover, other costs will continue
to creep upward, contributing to higher
prices. Therefore, margins are likely to in­
crease as retailers maintain or raise their
prices even though livestock prices decline.
The Department of Agriculture recently
estimated that food prices at the supermar­
ket will increase by 4 percent in 1972, com­
pared to a 2.5 percent increase last year.
Meat prices are likely to be a main con­
tributing factor behind the increase.

“WHAT TRUTH IN LENDING MEANS TO YOU”
A Spanish version of this Federal Reserve System
leaflet has been issued by the Board of Governors
as part of its responsibilities under the Truth in
Lending Act. What Truth in Lending Means to
You, in Spanish, is now available, and you may ob­
tain copies by sending requests directly to: Circulars
and Publications Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago, Box 834, Chicago, Illinois 60690.

BU SIN ESS C O N D IT IO N S is p u b lish ed m o n th ly b y the F e d e ra l R ese rve B a n k of C h ic a g o .
Ja c k L. H e rv e y w a s p r im a rily resp o n sib le fo r the a rtic le "R e strictio n s on w o rld tr a d e ," an d
D ennis B. S h a rp e fo r "W h a t's h a p p e n in g to m eat p ric e s?"
Su b scrip tio n s to Business Conditions a re a v a ila b le to the p u b lic w ith o u t c h a rg e . For in fo r­
m atio n co ncern ing b u lk m a ilin g s , a d d re ss in q u irie s to the Research D e p a rtm e n t, F e d e ra l

16

Reserve B a n k of C h ic a g o , B o x 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , Illin o is 6 0 6 9 0 .