View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MICHAEL H. MOSKOW
President and Chief Executive Officer

March 15, 2007

SENT VIA EMAIL
Ms. Jennifer J. Johnson
Secretary,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
20th Street and Constitution Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20551
Re: Consultation Paper on Intraday Liquidity Management and Payment System Risk Policy,
Docket No. OP-1257 (71 Fed.Reg. 35,679, June 21, 2006).
Dear Ms. Johnson:
The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago welcomes this opportunity to comment on the
Consultation Paper on Intraday Liquidity Management and Payment System Risk Policy (the
“Consultation Paper”). The Consultation Paper provides new evidence that banks frequently
delay the release of large-value Fedwire payments until late in the settlement day. The Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago shares the Board’s concern that the increasing pattern of delay “. . .
increases the potential magnitude of liquidity dislocation and risk in the financial industry if latein-the-day operational disruptions should occur” (71 Fed.Reg. 35,680-82), possibly with
systemic implications, and that this raises important questions concerning the safety and
efficiency of the U.S. payment system.
The enclosed paper, which was prepared by the staff of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
provides specific comments on the Consultation Paper and the proposals discussed therein. The
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago has been aware of persistent, albeit anecdotal, reports that payments
associated with exchange-traded settlements, which are both systemically important and timesensitive, have been routinely delayed. Until recently, however, it has not been possible to evaluate
such reports empirically.
Based upon our analysis of confidential data, we can now confirm that there is evidence of
late-in-the-day bunching of payments associated with exchange-traded settlements. This evidence
corroborates the aggregate findings of the Consultation Paper and suggests that the Board’s concerns
relating to the timing of Fedwire payments in general is well-founded. More importantly, we believe
that the bunching of systemically important payments, such as financial market settlement payments,
could have adverse consequences during periods of financial turmoil.
_______________________________
230 SOUTH LA SALLE STREET
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS 60604-1413
(312) 322-5001 (312) 322-2141 (Fax)
E-mail: Michael.Moskow@chi.frb.org

Ms. Jennifer J. Johnson
March 15, 2007
Page 2

To address this problem, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago endorses changes to the
Federal Reserve’s Payments System Risk (“PSR”) policy that would result in the reduction or
elimination of daylight overdraft charges for fully collateralized overdrafts. This
recommendation echos the position we articulated in our response to an earlier request for
comment in 2001. We believe that the elimination or reduction of daylight overdraft charges for
overdrafts that are fully collateralized could help mitigate the problem of end-of-day payments
bunching, would have extremely low implementation costs and impose essentially no adaptation
costs on the private sector. Regarding the other measures identified in the Consultation Paper,
we conclude that they deserve further consideration and study.
I hope you will find the Chicago Reserve Bank’s comments on the Consultation Paper
useful. If my staff or I may be of further assistance to you, please do not hesitate to contact one
of us.
Sincerely,

Michael H. Moskow

Enclosure

_______________________________
230 SOUTH LA SALLE STREET
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS 60604-1413
(312) 322-5001 (312) 322-2141 (Fax)
E-mail: Michael.Moskow@chi.frb.org

Consultation Paper on Intraday Liquidity Management
and Payment System Risk Policy
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Docket No. OP-1257
Comments Prepared by the Staff of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago1

1. Introduction and Summary
The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System has requested public
comment concerning intraday liquidity management and the Federal Reserve’s
Payments System Risk (“PSR”) policy.2 As noted in the Board’s Consultation
Paper, there are inherent trade-offs among the Federal Reserve’s various public
policy objectives relating to the management of credit, liquidity and systemic risks
in the U. S. payments, clearing and settlement systems. For example, Federal
Reserve “. . . efforts to reduce systemic risk may be associated with increased
levels of daylight overdrafts in Reserve Bank accounts, and efforts to reduce
daylight overdrafts may be associated with delays in making final payments.”3

In particular, the Consultation Paper notes that many banks developed “. . .
explicit strategies and techniques to manage their intraday liquidity and daylight

1

This commentary was prepared by Carol Clark, David Marshall and Robert Steigerwald,
with the assistance of Nicholas Buchholz and Victor Lubasi. Comments by Douglas Evanoff,
Craig Furfine, John McPartland, and Richard Porter are gratefully acknowledged.
2

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Consultation Paper on Intraday
Liquidity Management and Payment System Risk Policy, 71 Fed.Reg. 35,679 (June 21, 2006)
(the “Consultation Paper”).

3

Id. at 35,680.

1

overdrafts” after the Federal Reserve imposed fees for intraday credit.4

One

such strategy is to delay the transmission of large-value payments until late in the
settlement day, a phenomenon that appears to be increasing.5 As discussed in
the Consultation Paper, this phenomenon of late in the day bunching of
payments may raise significant operational, liquidity and systemic concerns.6
Therefore, the Board requests “information from financial institutions and other
interested parties on their experience in managing intraday liquidity, credit, and
operational

risks

related

to

Fedwire

funds

transfers

and

associated

transactions.”7 In addition, the Board of Governors has requested comment on a
variety of possible market, operational and policy changes that might address the
problem of late-in-the day bunching of Fedwire payments.

4

Id.

5

Id. at 35,681 and Appendix, Chart 3..

6

The Consultation Paper identifies a number of operational, liquidity and systemic risks
associated with this end-of-day bunching of large-value Fedwire funds transfers:
“[T]he larger the number and value of Fedwire or other payments that are made
late in the day, the greater the risk to financial markets that payments will not be
settled in a timely manner if significant operational disruptions were to occur late
in the day.”
“A related long-standing concern of the Federal Reserve has been that
depository institutions’ intraday liquidity management strategies may lead them to
delay sending Fedwire payments until they receive payments in order to manage
their use of daylight overdrafts at the Reserve Banks. If this practice became
widespread, it could lead to a form of ‘gridlock’ in the payments system with
multiple depository institutions waiting for each other to send payments in order
to obtain intraday funds and limit their daylight overdrafts.”
Id. at 35,681-82.
7

Id. at 35,679.

2

In responding to the Board’s requests, we focus on a particular manifestation of
the general problem of delayed payments: delays affecting time-sensitive
settlement payments associated with exchange-traded derivatives markets.
Because the Seventh Federal Reserve District is home to some of the largest
clearinghouses for derivatives markets,8 the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
has a special interest in potential changes to market practice, operations or
Federal Reserve policy that might tend to mitigate the delay of such settlement
payments. As we discuss in Part 2 of this comment, these settlement payments
represent a very small fraction of overall Fedwire activity. However, their timesensitivity makes them particularly important for the smooth functioning of and
public confidence in the financial system. In Part 2, we present evidence that
these payments are often made late and the payments associated with the
largest dollar values are those delayed the longest. Based upon this evidence,
we believe that the Board’s concern about the phenomenon of payment bunching
is well-founded. More importantly, we believe that the bunching of systemically
important payments, such as financial market settlement payments, could have
adverse consequences during periods of financial turmoil.

In Part 3, we discuss the incentives that appear to cause persistent payment
delays in Fedwire. In particular, we provide evidence that overnight borrowers in
the federal funds market could reduce their costs of borrowing by repaying their

8

The Clearing House Division of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (“CME”) clears
derivatives traded on the CME and Chicago Board of Trade. The Options Clearing Corporation
(“OCC”) clears all U.S. exchange-traded securities options.

3

overnight loans early in the settlement day. This, by itself, should provide an
incentive for borrowers to repay their federal funds loans early. However, during
the period we studied, there is clear evidence of end-of-day bunching of such
payments.

We conclude that, under current institutional arrangements, the

private costs of delayed payments in the form of higher interest charges on
overnight loans are insufficient to outweigh the private benefits of these delays.

In Part 4, we discuss a number of possible operational, market or policy changes
that may address the problem of persistent payment delays. Based upon this
analysis, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago endorses changes to the PSR
policy that would result in the reduction or elimination of daylight overdraft
charges for fully collateralized overdrafts. In addition, we discuss other potential
policy measures that, in principle, could help mitigate the problem of end-of-day
payments bunching.

2. Delays in Time-Sensitive Financial Markets Payments
Commercial banks and the interbank payment system play a critical role in the
processing of settlements for derivatives clearinghouses. The Committee on
Payment and Settlement Systems, in its March 1997 report on “Clearing
arrangements for exchange-traded derivatives,”9 provides a clear discussion of
the dynamics of these clearinghouse and settlement bank operations.

9

Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems of the central banks of the Group of Ten
countries, “Clearing arrangements for exchange-traded derivatives” (Basel: Bank for International
Settlements, March 1997) at 12-16, et seq. (defining the term “settlement bank”); see also,

4

We focus on the balancing payments among the various settlement banks that
are necessary to complete the settlement process associated with margin calls.
Many settlements are internally processed at the settlement banks as so-called
“on us” debits and credits. After charging the accounts of clearing members and
crediting the account of the clearinghouse (for amounts owed by clearing
members) and then charging the account of the clearinghouse and crediting the
accounts of clearing members (for amounts owed by the clearinghouse), there
usually is a surplus or a deficit that remains in the clearinghouse’s account at
each of the settlement banks. These surpluses and deficits must be eliminated
by interbank funds transfers. These balancing payments are the focus of our
analysis.

For several years the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago has received anecdotal
reports that these interbank transfers and other settlement-related payments are
often made late. To ascertain whether these reports are valid, staff from our
Financial Markets Group reviewed confidential data related to derivatives
clearing activities during a period when then there were no major financial market
disruptions.

Analysis of these confidential data confirms that the interbank

balancing payments made through Fedwire display patterns of late-in-the-day
bunching, even though these balancing payments are considered time-critical. In
particular, a substantial percentage of these interbank balancing payments were
made late, as determined by the relevant agreements between the clearing

McPartland, J., “Clearing and settlement demystified,” Chicago Fed Letter (Chicago: Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, January 2005).

5

members and the clearinghouse.10 A nontrivial percentage was made
exceptionally late (3 to 9½ hours). Furthermore, we find that the payments
associated with the biggest delays tend to have the largest dollar value.

These delays mirror the late-in-the-day bunching patterns described in the
Consultation Paper.

While settlement payments for the exchange-traded

derivatives markets represent a small fraction of total Fedwire payments, they
are properly regarded as time-critical. Public confidence in derivatives markets
depends in part, on the timely completion of those payments. If these Fedwire
transfers are not made on a timely basis, settlement banks may not give clearing
members full or immediate access to funds due from the clearinghouse. If this
occurs, absent any information to the contrary, clearing members and other
market participants might assume that the clearinghouse has failed to completely
collect losses from other clearing members, resulting in a loss of public
confidence in the settlement process.

Indeed, late settlement payments

associated with derivatives markets were one of the root causes of near
payments gridlock during the 1987 market break.11 We believe that these

10

These agreements concerning the obligation of clearing members and settlement banks
to discharge their payment obligations promptly are discussed in the CPSS’s 1997 report on
Clearing arrangements for exchange-traded derivatives. Id. at 27-28, et seq.
11

Kidder Peabody and Goldman Sachs experienced delays in receiving $1.5 billion in
settlements after advancing margin funds for customers. See Bernanke, B. (1990), “Clearing and
Settlement during the Crash,” The Review of Financial Studies, v. 3, n. 1. Eichenwald finds that
the firms’ accounts were not credited for more than three hours. It is well known in the industry
that the inability of clearing members to have full access to their settlement funds during the 1987
market break was related to delays in settlement payments between settlement banks. “Indeed,
Government and market studies of the crash and interviews with Wall Street professionals show
that the flow of money through the nation’s markets came perilously close to gridlock on Oct. 20
because of chaos in the clearing system.” See Eichenwald, Kurt (1988), “The Day the Nation’s
Cash Pipeline Almost Ran Dry,” The New York Times, October 2.

6

considerations support the Board’s concern about pervasive payments delays,
and provide additional motivation for policy changes aimed at reducing these
delays.

3. Private Costs and Benefits of Payments Delays
As noted in the CPSS report on New developments in large-value payment
systems,12 there are three primary funding sources in contemporary real-time
gross settlement (or “RTGS”) systems:
ƒ

Reserve balances;

ƒ

Intraday credit facilities provided by the operator of the payment
system or private money markets; 13 and

ƒ

Incoming payments received from other participants in the payment
system.

The first two of these liquidity sources have explicit costs. Users of the payment
system incur opportunity costs by holding reserves or precautionary account
balances to fund outgoing payments.

They also incur opportunity costs by

pledging collateral used to secure intraday extensions of credit. Furthermore, in
some payment systems, such as Fedwire, there is an explicit charge for intraday

12

Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems of the central banks of the Group of Ten
countries, New Developments in large-value payment systems (Basel: Bank for International
Settlements, May 2005) (the “New Developments Report”) at 15.

13

See also D. Evanoff, “Daylight overdrafts: Rationale and risks,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago Economic Perspectives (May 1988) at 21.

7

credit. To the extent that payment system participants rely upon private credit
markets,14 there are positive costs of borrowing, as we discuss later.

By comparison, incoming payments are essentially costless as a source of
liquidity. As pointed out in the CPSS New Developments Report, such payments
“. . . simply redistribute the funds among the participants and leave the sum of all
funds in the system unchanged. . . :”15
By doing so, the incoming payments received by other participants
can be used to fund their outgoing payments, and funding can be
recirculated. Thus, the value of payments exchanged is many
times in excess of the underlying sources of funding.16
For these reasons, incoming payments are generally considered to be among the
most important liquidity funding sources.17

For an individual institution to make efficient use of this liquidity source requires
coordinating outgoing and incoming payments. In the absence of an explicit
mechanism to synchronize these payments, such coordination attempts will tend
to induce banks to delay payments until the end of the day. This is effective
because banks know that any payment to be received during a particular
14

Private markets for intraday credit do not appear to exist under current conditions in most
market centers; therefore, the operators of RTGS systems generally provide intraday credit
facilities of one sort or another to their users.
15

Supra, n. 11 at 17.

16

Id. at 38.

17

See, e.g., Payments Risk Committee, Managing Payment Liquidity in Global Markets:
Risk Issues and Solutions (New York: March 2003) (“Incoming payments are the most important
source of a bank’s intraday liquidity. However the use of incoming transfers depends upon the
patterns and predictability of payment inflows and outflows.”).

8

settlement day must be received no later than the end of the day.18 In addition,
this strategy minimizes the term of any intraday credit extended to support
liquidity because the credit can be repaid promptly with the proceeds from
incoming payments.

While these considerations provide clear incentives towards delaying payments,
there may be countervailing incentives for banks to make certain payments
earlier in the day. In particular, the Consultation Paper considers how a market
for early return of federal funds might provide such a countervailing incentive.19
To evaluate this possibility, we studied the timing of federal funds repayments
using data compiled by Craig Furfine.20 Our data consist of nearly 200,000
observations of overnight federal funds transactions from the first quarter of

18

See, e.g., J. McAndrews & S. Rajan, “The Timing and Funding of Fedwire Funds
Transfers,” Economic Policy Review, Vol. 6, No. 2 (July 2000)(“. . . the difficulty of achieving . . . a
synchronized pattern is considerable because the timing of payments in some respects
resembles a coordination game. Banks can benefit by entering payments simultaneously . . . ,
but they typically do not know when their counterparties might send offsetting payments. Hence,
there is the potential for miscoordination.”)

19

As noted in the Consultation Paper:
“Lenders may find an early return option beneficial during periods in which they
anticipate making large or time-critical payments. Terms acceptable to both
parties could be negotiated to compensate for the early return. Currently,
transactions supporting the early return of funds appear to be relatively rare. A
more active market could effectively amount to an implicit market for intraday
funds.”

Supra, n. 2 at 35, 683.
20

Furfine identifies the transactions associated with overnight federal funds loans from the
records of all Fedwire payments during this time period. See Furfine, C., “Banks as Monitors of
Other Banks: Evidence from the Overnight Federal Funds Market,” Journal of Business 74:33:55
(2001).

9

1998.21

Our two key findings are, first, that repayments of overnight federal

funds loans are bunched near the end of the day, and second, higher interest
rates are charged for holding on to loans later in the day.

Chart 1 shows the bunching phenomenon. In particular, the value of overnight
loan repayment steadily increases throughout the day, peaking between 4:00
and 5:00 PM ET before sharply dropping off. (A similar pattern emerges when
examining the volume of repayments, rather than the value.) This finding mirrors
the end-of-day payments bunching discussed in the Consultation Paper.

However, delayed repayment is not without cost. Chart 2 shows that, on average,
the interest rate charged on an overnight loan increases with loan duration. Each
bar in this chart reflects the duration22 interval containing ten percent of daily
repayment value. Thus, ten percent of the value in the sample involve loans less
than or equal to 13.1 hours in duration. The average (annualized) interest rate23
associated with those loans is 4.9 basis points below the target federal funds rate
(which was 5.5% per annum at that time). Ten percent involve loans between

21

Due to unresolved issues of data access, our analysis is limited to data from 1998. It is
therefore noteworthy that a study of recent Euro-area money market data finds similar results to
those we present herein. See Baglioni, A., and A. Monticini, “The Intraday Price of Money:
Evidence from the e-MID Market,” working paper no. 63, Quaderni dell’ Istituto di Economia e
Finanza, Universita’ Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Milano (2005).
22

Duration is the time elapsed between outgoing and return payments, not counting time
when Fedwire is closed.
23

As described in Furfine, the interest rate is inferred from the difference between the
amount of the outgoing payment on the initial date and the amount of the return payment on the
subsequent date. Thus, the computed interest rate includes any fixed charges, negotiated costs,
or penalties for late payment. The interest rate is then annualized using the duration of the loan.
See Furfine, supra note 20.

10

13.1 and 14.8 hours, with an average rate of 2.1 basis points below the target
rate, and so on. Chart 2 shows that a higher rate of interest is incurred for loans
with longer duration. Specifically, regression analysis implies a duration premium
of 1.3 percent (annualized) for each additional hour of loan duration, as well as
an additional premium of 5.7 percent (annualized) for repayment received after
5:00 PM ET.

These premia imply that an overnight borrower can cut its funding costs through
early repayment. In that sense, a market for early repayment clearly exists in the
period covered by our data.

However, as shown in Chart 1, the vast

preponderance of repayments are still made late in the day. It appears that
borrowers avoid early repayment because the indirect liquidity costs incurred by
early repayment outweigh the reduced rates of interest documented in this
section.

This evidence leads us to be skeptical that a market for early

repayment of overnight loans, in and of itself, provides a significant incentive for
banks to avoid payment delays.

4. Suggested Changes to PSR Policy
To address concerns about end-of-day bunching of Fedwire payments, the
Consultation Paper identifies several potential changes to payments system
operations, market structure and/or public policy. The Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago considered these changes according to the following criteria:
•

Likely impact on end-of-day payments bunching

11

•

Direct implementation costs to the Federal Reserve System

•

Likely transition and disruption costs to the private sector

•

Effects on the financial system beyond impact on payments
timing.

Based on these criteria, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago endorses changes
to the PSR policy that reduce or eliminate daylight overdraft charges for fully
collateralized overdrafts. In addition, we discuss the certain other operational,
market and policy changes, which are deserving of further analysis.

4.1. Reduced charges for collateralized daylight credit
The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago recommends adoption of a pricing
structure for daylight overdrafts which would either eliminate or substantially
reduce fees for overdrafts that are fully collateralized. Before 2001, the PSR
policy embraced the use of collateral strictly for purposes of securing overnight
discount window lending, as opposed to intraday credit. Once the collateral is
pledged, however, it supports any credit extended to the bank, whether overnight
or intraday. Either way, a security interest in this collateral is created in favor of
the Reserve Bank.24

As noted by President Jeffrey Lacker of the Federal

Reserve Bank of Richmond, “[Reserve Banks have] a lien on any bank collateral
that happens to be pledged for use in overnight borrowing, so perhaps it is best
24

As noted in the Board’s 2001 request for public comment on the future longer-term
direction of the PSR policy: “. . . the majority of Federal Reserve daylight credit extensions are . . .
implicitly collateralized because depository institutions that have pledged collateral must sign
Operating Circular 10, which provides the Reserve Banks with a secured interest in any collateral
recorded on the Reserve Bank’s books.” Policy Statement on Payments System Risk, Docket No.
R-1111, 66 Fed.Reg. 30,208, 30,211 (June 5, 2001).

12

to describe Fed daylight credit as partially secured.”25 From the context of
President Lacker’s comments, it is clear that daylight credit is only “partially
secured” if the amount of this credit exceeds the amount of collateral pledged.
Daylight credit up to the amount of collateral in place is indeed fully secured.

Changes to the PSR policy in 2001 permit banks to use collateral to obtain
daylight overdrafts in excess of their net debit,26 but the cost to banks of such
collateralized overdrafts has not been reduced. The Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago favors modifying this policy so that fully collateralized daylight overdrafts
are subject to fees that are substantially reduced or fully waved. The Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago supported this proposal in its November 2001
comment letter. As discussed in that comment,
The Bank’s policy position
premise . . . that daylight
interest.
To the extent
collateralized, there is little or
a risk premium. 27

on pricing is predicated upon the
overdraft facilities serve the public
that daylight overdrafts are fully
no justification for the price to include

To be clear, this proposal does not mandate full collateralization of all intraday
credit.

25

Lacker, J., “Central Bank Credit in the Theory of Money and Payments,” Remarks,
Economics of Payments Conference II, Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta and New York (New
York, March 29, 2006); see also, Lacker, J., “Payment System Disruptions and the Federal
Reserve Following September 11, 2001,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy (Nov. 21, 2003).
26

Policy Statement on Payments System Risk, Docket No. R-1107, 66 Fed.Reg. 30,199,
(June 5, 2001).

27

See Moskow, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Response to Board of Governors Policy
Statement on Payments System Risk—Potential Longer-Term Policy Direction (Docket No. R1111, November 16, 2001).

13

By reducing the cost of collateralized intraday borrowings, this proposal would
reduce the current incentives to engage in tactical behavior to avoiding daylight
overdraft charges by delaying most large value Fedwire payments until very late
in the day. Furthermore, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago believes that this
policy change would have little impact on current bank behavior concerning
collateralization, at least for the largest banks. Such banks typically have large
amounts of collateral pledged to the Federal Reserve. Coleman (2002)28 reports
that for banks that had collateral pledged, 94% of their average daylight
overdrafts and 70% of their peak overdrafts were collateralized. The Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago obtained similar results when we analyze 2006 data on
the eleven largest Seventh District banks. Specifically, nine of those eleven
banks had collateral pledged to the Federal Reserve at some time during that
year. For these nine, an average of 92% of peak daylight overdrafts were fully
collateralized.

Moreover, as noted in the Consultation Paper, “the level of

collateral pledged to reserve banks [since 2002] for discount window and PSR
purposes has increased steadily.”29

The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago believes that the elimination or reduction
of daylight overdraft charges for overdrafts that are fully collateralized would have
extremely low implementation costs and would impose essentially no adaptation
costs on the private sector. Furthermore, there would be little ancillary impact on

28

Coleman, S., "The Evolution of the Federal Reserve's Intraday Credit Policies." Federal
Reserve Bulletin 88 (February 2002) at 83.
29

Supra n. 2 at 35,683.

14

the financial system beyond the timing of payment instructions.

For these

reasons, this proposal would be relatively easy to institute. However, the overall
impact on payments timing is unknown, and may be modest, taken in isolation.
Thus, additional modifications to the PSR policy may be needed to offset fully the
current financial incentives that seem to encourage end-of-day payments
bunching.

4.2. Discussion of other alternatives
Additional possible changes in payments operation and policy include the
following:
•

Time of day pricing of overdrafts and/or payment transactions;

•

Payment throughput requirements;

•

Development of a liquidity savings mechanism for the Fedwire
funds transfer system;

•

Multiple settlement cycles in private sector settlement systems;
and

•

Payment of interest on reserve balances.

Of these, time-dependent pricing of intraday credit and/or payments transactions
strikes us as the most promising. Both the Consultation Paper and this comment
provide evidence that banks are extremely price sensitive in deciding on the
timing of their payments.

Thus, we believe that time-dependent pricing

represents a promising direction for mitigating end-of-day payments bunching.
Possible ways to implement time-dependent pricing include reduced fees earlier

15

in the day; penalty rates after a certain point (e.g., 1600h ET); and waiving
overdraft fees at certain times in the day in order to encourage payments
synchronization. Time-of-day transaction pricing is currently implemented in the
Swiss Interbank Clearing (“SIC”) funds transfer system.

The other alternatives have less clear cost-benefit tradeoffs. A throughput rule
accomplishes the same objective as a well-designed time-of-day pricing
structure, but with less flexibility. Liquidity savings mechanisms, such as those
incorporated into RTGS+, TARGET2, and the proposed BOJ-NET, would likely
have high implementation costs but potentially high benefit to the financial
system. These proposals merit further study.

Multiple settlement cycles in private settlement systems such as DTCC and
CHIPS could reduce end-of-day payment concentration.

However, we are

concerned about the high costs of private sector adjustment and the possibility of
adverse unintended consequences. For example, moving DTCC settlements to
an earlier time of day may force broker/dealer treasury operations to make
overnight funding decisions with far less information than they have under the
current practice of waiting until later in the day.

Finally, paying interest on reserve balances would, all things being equal,
increase average daily reserve balances and thus reduce the use of daylight
overdraft credit. If the costs of daylight overdrafts are the main factor driving

16

payments towards the end of the day, increasing overall reserve balances by
paying interest on reserves would tend to reduce end-of-day payment bunching.
Of course, there are other financial market distortions that would be mitigated by
reducing the wedge between the rate of return on central bank funds and returns
of other short-term investment alternatives. The proposal to pay interest on
reserves also has implications for liquidity management, monetary policy, and
implementation that go well beyond the focus of this comment letter.

17

Chart 1: Total Value of Overnight Loan Repayments by Time of Day

Chart 2: Average Interest Rates by Duration of Loan

18