View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

2015
NUMBER 337

Chicag­o Fed Letter
Job switching and wage growth
by R. Jason Faberman, senior economist, and Alejandro Justiniano, senior economist and research advisor

This article shows a remarkably strong relationship between job switching and nominal
wage growth. We also find a fairly strong relationship between job switching and the
cyclical component of inflation. Furthermore, job switching seems to be predictive of
both wage growth and inflation.

The current debate on monetary policy

1. Quit rate and wage growth from the ECI
percent

9

centers around the issue that inflation
has remained weak and below expectations, despite a relatively strong labor
market. It is unclear when policymakers
can expect inflation
to rise, which could
signal a need to raise
percent
interest rates.

Economists often focus
4
on the negative rela8
tionship between the
unemployment rate
7
3
and wage growth as a
gauge of future infla6
tion.1 In this Chicago
Fed Letter, we show that
2
the worker quit rate,
5
a proxy for the pace
of job switching in
1
4
the U.S. labor mar1992 ’94 ’96 ’98 2000 ’02 ’04 ’06 ’08 ’10 ’12 ’14
ket, is also a strong
Quit rate, 4Q moving average (left-hand scale)
predictor of nominal
ECI wages, year-over-year change (right-hand scale)
wage growth. This is
Note: ECI indicates Employment Cost Index.
not surprising, given
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover
that job switching
Survey (JOLTS) and the ECI.
tends to reflect individuals moving up a
“job ladder” to higher-paying jobs. Nevertheless, the strength of the relationship
is striking. The quit rate also helps predict the inflation gap, which is the difference between actual and long-run
expected inflation. Our analysis suggests
that one reason inflation currently

remains below expectations is that the
quit rate is rising but remains relatively
low, despite overall growth in the labor
market and a rapidly declining unemployment rate. As the quit rate nears its
pre-recession pace, it may be predictive
of increased wage growth and, ultimately,
higher inflation.
The cyclicality of quits and wage growth

People generally switch jobs by quitting
(rather than losing) their previous job.
Furthermore, the vast majority of people observed quitting their job tend to
move directly to a new job, rather than
becoming unemployed or exiting the
labor force.2 Therefore, estimates of
worker quits provide a good measure
of job switching in the U.S. economy.
Data from the Job Openings and Labor
Turnover Survey (JOLTS) provide an
estimate of the aggregate quit rate each
month for the U.S. economy since 2000.
Recent research by Steven Davis, R. Jason
Faberman, and John Haltiwanger has
extended the JOLTS data series back to
the early 1990s.3 Their work shows that
quits are highly procyclical. That is, they
rise during expansions and fall during
recessions. This is seen in figure 1, which
shows the quit rate (solid line), measured
as total quits during the quarter divided
by quarterly employment, since the last
quarter of 1991. It varies between a peak
of 8.7% of employment during the boom

2. Quits and wages, production and nonsupervisory workers
percent
9

3. Quit rate, wage growth, and inflation gap correlation

4
8

7

3

6
2
5
4
1992

xt equals:

percent

1
’94

’96

’98 2000

’02

’04

’06

’08

’10

’12

’14

Correlation between
quits (qt) and xt+k,
k quarters ahead

Wage growth,
ECI

Wage growth,
AHE

Inflation
gap

qt, xt

0.88

0.66

0.50

qt, xt+1

0.92

0.71

0.52

qt, xt+2

0.94

0.76

0.53

qt, xt+3

0.93

0.77

0.53

qt, xt+4

0.91

0.78

0.52

qt, xt+8

0.76

0.69

0.25

Quit rate, 4Q moving average (left-hand scale)

Notes: ECI indicates Employment Cost Index; AHE indicates average hourly earnings.

Average hourly earnings, year-over-year change
(right-hand scale)

Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
(JOLTS), the Employment Cost Index (ECI), the Current Employment Statistics (CES), and the
Survey of Professional Forecasters.

Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover
Survey (JOLTS) and the Current Employment Statistics (CES).

of the late 1990s and a trough of 4.3% at
the height of the Great Recession. At the
end of 2014, the quit rate stood at 6.6%,
still below its pre-recession peak of 7.6%.
The fact that quits are procyclical makes
intuitive economic sense. Quits reflect
job switching. People are more likely to
switch jobs during economic expansions.
During these times, there are more jobs
available and labor markets are tighter.
A tighter labor market implies that employers are more willing to offer higher
wages to attract new workers. These
higher wages provide a greater incentive
for workers to leave their current position and move up what is often referred
to as the job ladder. During recessions,
labor markets are more slack. There are
fewer available jobs and unemployment
is higher, so workers have less bargaining power to obtain a better wage offer.
Research by Gadi Barlevy suggests that
this can create a “sullying” effect of recessions, where workers become stuck
in either low-quality jobs or jobs to which
their skills are poorly matched because
of the difficulty in moving up the job
ladder during an economic downturn.4
The economic intuition behind the procyclicality of quits suggests that wages
should be procyclical as well. Since job
switching generally involves individuals
moving to higher-paying jobs, aggregate wages should rise as the quit rate

increases. Since job switching is more
prevalent during expansions, wage growth
is higher during these periods and lower
during recessions, when the quit rate
declines. A similar logic suggests that a
low unemployment rate will have a similar effect on wages. Unemployment is
low when labor markets are tight. Fewer
unemployed means that job seekers will
be less likely to accept whatever wage employers offer, which drives the aggregate
wage upward. In contrast, unemployment
is high during recessions. There are more
job seekers competing for relatively fewer
job openings. As a result, workers have
less bargaining power, leading to reduced wage pressures. Some recent research has shown that there is a strong
link between the unemployment rate
and wage growth, though these studies
differ in their emphasis on the importance of the long-term unemployed
(those seeking work for least six months)
in affecting aggregate wage growth.5
While the evidence thus far suggests a
strong link between worker quits and
wages, how can these affect inflation?
Wage growth and inflation are the outcome of the interaction between workers,
who seek to maintain the purchasing
power of their wages, and firms, which
aim to stabilize their profits through
changes in production costs. As a result,
inflation and (nominal) wage growth

move in tandem and can reinforce each
other. Specifically, since the cost of producing an additional unit of output
(known as marginal cost) is a key determinant of a firm’s profits, current (and
future) marginal costs are a crucial determinant of inflation.6 In turn, workers
consume goods using income from their
wages. Increases in their current (and
expected) wages will allow them to demand more goods, increasing their prices.
As wages feed into marginal costs and
prices determine how many goods workers will demand, the growth rates of the
two are tightly linked. Thus, if the worker
quit rate influences wage growth, then it
should also affect production costs and,
hence, inflation.
Evidence on the quit rate, wage growth,
and inflation

Figure 1 plots the year-over-year percentage change in the wage component of
the Employment Compensation Index
(ECI, dashed line), together with the
quit rate (solid line). Both the quit rate
and this measure of wage growth are
quite procyclical and exhibit strong comovement. Moreover, fluctuations in the
quit rate seem to precede fluctuations
in wage growth by roughly one to two
quarters, suggesting that quits may be a
useful predictor of future wage growth.
Figure 2 plots the quit rate against an alternative measure of wage growth using

4. Ten-year-ahead expected inflation and actual core CPI inflation

5. The quit rate and the CPI inflation gap

percent
4

percent

percentage points

9

0.5

8

3

0

7
−0.5

2
6

−1.0

1
5

0
1992 ’94

’96

’98

2000 ’02

’04

’06

’08

’10

’12

’14

4
1992 ’94

−1.5
’96

’98 2000 ’02

Core CPI (year-over-year change)

Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the CPI and the Survey of Professional
Forecasters.

the average hourly earnings of production and nonsupervisory workers (dashed
line). Wage growth and the quit rate
continue to co-move over time, albeit
less strongly than in figure 1, and both
series exhibit strong procyclical patterns.
Figure 3 shows that the co-movement of
the quit rate and wage growth is in fact
quite strong. It measures the correlation
between them not only contemporaneously but up to eight quarters into the
future. The first column reports the
correlations between the quit rate and
wage growth from the ECI, while the
second column reports the correlations
between the quit rate and average hourly
earnings growth. All correlations are
large, but particularly so with the ECI.
Moreover, the largest correlations occur
between the quit rate and wage growth
two quarters ahead using the ECI and
four quarters ahead using average hourly
earnings. This suggests that changes in
the quit rate lead changes in wage growth
by six months to a year. More formal
evidence is provided by a statistical test
that indicates past quit rates help forecast the current behavior of wage growth,
beyond using the history of wages alone.7
In contrast, we find no evidence that
past wage growth helps forecast the
current quit rate.

’06

’08

’10

’12

’14

Quit rate (4Q moving average)

Ten-year inflation expectation
Note: Core CPI refers to the Consumer Price Index, excluding food and energy.

’04

Inflation gap
Note: The inflation gap is the difference between core Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation
and ten-year-ahead expected inflation.
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover
Survey (JOLTS), the CPI, and the Survey of Professional Forecasters.

As mentioned, because changes in prices
and wages are so intertwined, the strong
predictive relationship between quits
and wage growth should, in theory, translate to inflation. Figure 4 plots the yearly
core CPI inflation rate—that is, inflation
excluding food and energy—together
with expected (yearly) inflation ten years
from now from the Survey of Professional
Forecasters. Both realized and expected
inflation exhibited a significant downward trend during most of the 1990s,
which is widely attributed to the emergence of an implicit inflation target by
the Federal Reserve during this time.
Following this period, long-run expected
inflation remains remarkably stable.
Economists and policymakers often
focus on the inflation gap, which is the
difference between actual and long-run
expected inflation, because it better captures movements in inflation that are
cyclical rather than part of a longer-run
trend. Figure 4 shows that inflation has
been running below expectations since
the start of the Great Recession, resulting
in a persistently negative inflation gap.
Figure 5 shows the relationship between
the quit rate and the inflation gap. The
quit rate exhibits substantial co-movement
with the inflation gap, albeit less so than
was the case for wage growth. Most importantly, fluctuations in the quit rate

appear also to lead the inflation gap.
The last column in figure 3 reinforces
this point: Correlations of the quit rate
with future values of the inflation gap
are fairly large and peak two to three
quarters ahead. As was the case with
wage growth, a statistical test showed
that past quit rates help forecast the
Charles L. Evans, President ; Daniel G. Sullivan,
Executive Vice President and Director of Research;
Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic
Advisor ; David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial
markets group ; Daniel Aaronson, Vice President,
microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Richard
Heckinger,Vice President, markets team; Anna L.
Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A. Testa,
Vice President, regional programs, and Economics Editor ;
Helen O’D. Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors  ;
Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors;
Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2015 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed Letter
and other Bank publications are available at
https://www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

inflation gap, but not vice versa. The
evidence suggests that the quit rate can
help predict future inflation pressures
as well as future wage growth.
Conclusion

Economic theory provides intuitive
reasons why the worker quit rate should
be highly procyclical and a determinant
of wage growth: Job switchers drive up
wages as they move up the job ladder,
1

For example, see recent research by
Mary C. Daly, Bart Hobijn, and Timothy Ni,
2013, “The path of wage growth and
unemployment,” FRBSF Economic Letter,
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
No. 2013-20, July 15, available at http://
www.frbsf.org/economic-research/
publications/economic-letter/2013/july/
wages-unemployment-rate/.

2

For example, Michael W. L. Elsby, Bart
Hobijn, and Ayşegül Şahin find that only
16% of quits, on average, enter unemployment; the remainder move to new
jobs. See Elsby, Hobijn, and Şahin, 2010,
“The labor market in the Great Recession,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Spring, pp. 1–48.

3

See Steven J. Davis, R. Jason Faberman,
and John C. Haltiwanger, 2012, “Labor
market flows in the cross section and over
time,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 59,
No. 1, January, pp. 1–18.

4

See Gadi Barlevy, 2002, “The sullying effect
of recessions,” Review of Economic Studies,
Vol. 69, No. 1, January, pp. 65–96.

and opportunities for these moves are
more plentiful during booms. Furthermore, theory suggests that since the quit
rate helps predict current and future
costs of production (through wages),
then it should also be important for
predicting inflation. We find that these
predictions hold true in the data. The
quit rate is strongly procyclical and highly
correlated with different measures of

wage growth, particularly, and quite
remarkably, with the Employment
Compensation Index. Moreover, the
quit rate also co-moves with the inflation
gap. Variations in the quit rate also lead
changes in both wage growth and the
inflation gap by two to four quarters.
This suggests that the pace of job switching is a useful indicator for forecasting
the behavior of wages and inflation.

Examples include Michael T. Kiley, 2014,
“An evaluation of the inflationary pressure
associated with short- and long-term
unemployment,” Finance and Economics
Discussion Series, Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, No. 2014-28;
Alan B. Krueger, Judd Cramer, and David
Cho, 2014, “Are the long-term unemployed
on the margins of the labor market?,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring,
pp. 229–280; and Daniel Aaronson and
Andrew Jordan, 2014, “Understanding the
relationship between real wage growth
and labor market conditions,” Chicago Fed
Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
No. 327, October, available at https://
www.chicagofed.org/publications/
chicago-fed-letter/2014/october-327.

stance, Argia M. Sbordone, 2006, “U.S. wage
and price dynamics: A limited-information
approach,” International Journal of Central
Banking, Vol. 2, No. 3, September,
pp. 155–191, for a model that formalizes
these ideas and empirical evidence that
describes reasonably well the evolution of
both inflation and nominal wage growth.

5

6

The dependence on both current and future conditions is because not all prices
and wages can be adjusted every period in
response to economic conditions. The
equations describing the determination
of wages and prices are known as the goods
price and wage Phillips curve. See, for in-

7

This is known as a Granger causality test,
a statistical concept that need not imply
causality as usually understood. Formally,
a variable (say, quits) is said to Grangercause another (say, wage growth) if the
former’s lagged values help forecast the
latter’s beyond the information contained
in the latter’s own lags. We implement the
test using four lags of the quit rate and wage
growth and reject the hypothesis that lagged
quits do not contain information for future
wage growth at the 5% significance level,
but do not find evidence in the other direction. See C. W. J. Granger, 1980, “Testing
for causality: A personal viewpoint,” Journal
of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 2,
pp. 329–352, for more information.