View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

pd
papers

NUMBER 10

by Charles T. Carlstrom and Timothy S. Fuerst

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER

Oil Prices, Monetary Policy, and the
Macroeconomy

APRIL 2005

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Oil Prices, Monetary Policy, and the
Macroeconomy
by Charles T. Carlstrom and Timothy S. Fuerst

Charles T. Carlstrom is a
senior economic advisor at
the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. Timothy S. Fuerst
is an associate professor
at Bowling Green State
University and a research
associate at the Bank.

Every U.S. recession since 1971 has been preceded by two things: an oil price shock and an increase
in the federal funds rate. Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson (1997,2004) investigated how much oil price
shocks have contributed to output growth by asking the following counterfactual question: Empirically
how much would we expect oil price increases to have contributed to output growth if the Fed had
kept the rate constant instead of letting it increase? They concluded that, at most, half of the observed
output declines can be attributed to oil price increases. Most were actually caused by funds rate
increases. A problem with their empirical analysis, however, is that it implicitly assumes that the Fed
can continually “fool” the public. That is, the funds rate is led constant even though the public actually

Materials may be reprinted,
provided that the source is
credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the
editor.

expects the Fed to follow its historical policy rule of raising the funds rate in conjunction with oil price
increases. We show that if the new policy rule were anticipated oil price increases would have had a
much larger impact on output than suggested by Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson’s analysis.

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

Policy Discussion Papers are published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.To receive copies or to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4dsubscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216-579-3050. Please send your questions
comments, and suggestions to us at editor@clev.frb.org.
Policy Discussion Papers are available on the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World Wide Web:
www.clevelandfed.org/Research.
Views stated in Policy Discussion Papers are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

ISSN 1528-4344

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Introduction
Oil price increases have preceded every recession since 1971. Each of these recessions has also been
preceded by an increase in the federal funds rate (see figure 1).Are recessions caused by the spikes in
oil prices or a sharp tightening of monetary policy? Perhaps they are caused by a confluence of both
factors, a so-called “perfect storm.”
In an influential article, Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson (1997), hereafter BGW, tried to answer this
question. Disentangling the effects of oil and monetary policy on output is extremely difficult, and
BGW’s novel contribution was to quantify the effects of each in a VAR analysis.1
BGW first report a baseline case in which these effects are not disentangled and the funds rate
moves endogenously in response to the oil shock. Output falls sharply in this case. They then disentangle the effects by asking the following counterfactual question: How much would output have

1. There are, of course, numerous
studies that analyze the effect of
monetary shocks and oil shocks
in isolation. See BGW (1997) for
references.

fallen if the Federal Reserve had kept the funds rate constant in the wake of the oil price shock? Their
initial answer was surprising to many. If the Fed had kept the funds rate constant, output would have
fallen only modestly. The endogenous response of monetary policy accounted for virtually all of the
negative impact of oil shocks on the economy. Because their counterfactual experiment was related
to previous work by other authors (Sims and Zha 1996), BGW called it the “Sims-Zha” experiment.
This Policy Discussion Paper examines BGW’s conclusions. We first identify some problems with
their empirical analysis, which have been pointed out previously, in particular, insufficient lag length
and the possibility of spurious correlation. But our main focus is on a more serious problem with the
BGW analysis. In the Sims-Zha experiment, the funds rate is counterfactually held at its pre-oil-shock
level by adding exogenous unanticipated policy shocks to the funds rate. This is equivalent to an assumption that policy can systematically surprise the public, which is, of course, a highly questionable
assumption. If the public becomes aware of a systematic movement in policy, the public’s behavior
FIGURE 1

OIL PRICES AND EFFECTIVE FEDERAL FUNDS RATES

Percent, quarterly average
20

Dollars per barrel
50

18

45

16

40

14

West Texas intermediate
crude oil price

35

12

30

10

25

8

20

6

15

4

10

2

Effective federal funds rate

5

0
0
3/71 3/75 3/79 3/83 3/87 3/91 3/95 3/99 3/03
Note: Shaded bars indicate periods of recession.
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial Services.

3

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 10, APRIL 2005

will change in response, so that estimated VAR coefficients may not be invariant to systematic changes
in monetary policy.This is an example of the celebrated “Lucas critique” (1976).
Since VAR modeling cannot address the quantitative importance of the Lucas critique, we build a
small-scale, structural, computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. Within this theoretical model,
we explicitly perform BGW’s counterfactual experiment under two different assumptions:The funds
rate behavior is anticipated or it is not. In our “unanticipated” Sims-Zha experiment, the central bank
keeps the funds rate constant by repeatedly fooling the public.This corresponds exactly to BGW’s empirical analysis. In our “anticipated” Sims-Zha experiment, the public anticipates that the central bank
will keep the funds rate constant in the wake of the oil price shock.We also perform BGW’s baseline
case so that we can compare our model’s results more meaningfully with BGW’s.
The results of our model are similar to BGW’s for both the baseline case and the unanticipated SimsZha experiment. However, when we consider the anticipated Sims-Zha experiment, we get a much
different result. If the public correctly anticipates that the central bank will respond systematically
to oil price movements in order to keep the funds rate stable, the economy contracts by roughly the
same amount as in the baseline case.That is, once policy is anticipated, output falls as much as when
the funds rate is allowed to increase endogenously. The sharp difference between the unanticipated
and anticipated Sims-Zha experiments implies that expectations are critical, and the Lucas critique
is quantitatively relevant. Thus, if the Fed had systematically held the funds rate constant after every
oil shock, output would have declined by an amount comparable to the decline actually observed. In
other words, the Fed cannot use systematic policy to avert output declines after oil price shocks.

Oil Price Hikes and Output: Estimation Concerns
Recall that BGW (1997) concluded that the characteristic decline in output after an oil price shock
was almost entirely driven by monetary policy and not oil prices per se. According to BGW, if the
funds rate had been kept constant after the shock, output would not have fallen significantly. In their
comment on BGW (1997), Hamilton and Herrera (2004) suggest that BGW’s conclusion is very sensitive to lag length. BGW estimated the impact of oil using monthly data with seven lags. Practically
speaking, their analysis implicitly assumes that the exogenous impact of an oil price shock on the
economy ends within seven months. But when Hamilton and Herrera (2004) increase the number of
monthly lags from seven to twelve months, oil has a significant impact on the economy—even when
the funds rate is held constant.
There are two possible explanations for why increasing the number of lags affects BGW’s (1997)
results so dramatically. One is that it may simply take a year or longer for oil price hikes to fully appear
in GDP. If this is the case, then extra lag lengths seem warranted.The other explanation is that the effect is spurious. Introducing extra lags multiplies the number of additional parameters that need to be
estimated. Estimating all of the extra lags introduces greater imprecision into the estimates, because
more coefficients are being estimated. Hence, although the longer lag length suggests a larger effect
for oil on the economy, that effect is estimated with greater error, so that one cannot be confident that
it reflects oil’s true effect.
Which lag length to use is an open question. In their response to Hamilton and Herrera, BGW
(2004) run a quarterly version of their model with four lags. (The results of this experiment are reproduced in figure 2.) With the longer lag, the maximum impact of a 10 percent oil price shock with the
endogenous increase in the funds rate is approximately a 0.7 percent decline in GDP. This is similar
to their earlier result with a shorter lag length. But if the funds rate were not allowed to increase

4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

FIGURE 2

RESPONSE TO A HAMILTON OIL SHOCK
SAMPLE: 1965:1–1995:4 (4 LAGS, SZ: FED FUNDS SHUT DOWN FOR 4 QUARTERS)

Response of Oil to Oil

10

Base scenario
SZ scenario

8

6

4

2

0

–2
1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

Response of GDP to Oil

0.2

Base scenario
SZ scenario

–0.0

–0.2

–0.4

–0.6

–0.8
1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

Response of GDP Deflator to Oil

0.2

Base scenario
SZ scenario

–0.0

–0.2

–0.4

–0.6

–0.8
1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

Response of Fed Funds to Oil

1.6

Base scenario
SZ scenario

1.2

0.8

0.4

0.0

–0.4

–0.6
1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

Source: Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Mark Watson, “Oil Shocks and Aggregate
Macroeconomic Behavior: The Role of Monetary Policy A Reply,” Journal of Money
Credit and Banking, vol. 36, no. 2, April 2004, 287–91.

5

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 10, APRIL 2005

(their Sims-Zha experiment), the decrease in output would have been muted considerably, falling by
approximately half of that amount. Specifically, output would have declined approximately 0.4 percent.This stands in contrast to BGW (1997), where they argued that oil would have little independent
effect on the economy.
It is instructive to put these numbers into context. Oil prices increased more than 50 percent between January 2004 and October 2004 (from $34 to $53 per barrel). If the funds rate were allowed to
increase after this 50 percent oil price shock, we would expect output to decline by 3.5 percent! If
the funds rate were held constant, however, their Sims-Zha experiment suggests that this same shock
would reduce output by only 2 percent.
It is also instructive, however, to examine figure 2 more closely. Specifically, in BGW’s (2004)
baseline experiment, a 10 percent increase in the price of oil increased the funds rate by almost 1.5
percentage points. Given a 50 percent oil price increase, this implies that the funds rate would have
increased by nearly 750 basis points. Put another way, their Sims-Zha experiment (keeping the funds
rate constant) asks what would happen if we were to lower the funds rate by 7.5 percent in conjunction with the oil price hikes of 2004. Even if you take the baseline funds rate to be 4 percent, as is
currently suggested by the Taylor rule, this still amounts to lowering the funds rate to –3.5 percent,
which is clearly nonsensical.
BGW’s counterfactual Sims-Zha experiment implicitly assumes that the large hikes in the funds
rate in the mid-1970s and early 1980s were entirely due to oil or the impact of oil on the economy.
But this assumption is unlikely to be true. The period leading up to the 1975 recession may provide
us with some guidance as to what the VAR estimates are picking up.
From the beginning of 1972 to the middle of 1974, the Fed increased the funds rate nearly 10
percentage points (3.3 percent to 12.9 percent).There was also a huge jump in oil prices during this
same period—oil prices tripled from $3.56 per barrel in the middle of 1973 to $11.20 at the end of
1974. But the huge run-up in interest rates was also preceded and likely caused by years of excessively
easy monetary policy during the late 1960s and early 1970s. This resulted in a nearly 9 percentage
point jump in actual inflation from 1972 to 1974. Inflation expectations, while not observable, can
certainly be expected to have risen as well around this time. These increases, however, were almost
certainly not entirely due to the oil price shock, which began a little later.The funds rate increase was
as likely to be caused by the Fed’s earlier accommodation of rising inflation expectations as it was oil
prices.
When inflation expectations rise, the Fed must increase the funds rate by same amount as the
increase in expected inflation just to keep the real funds rate constant. Moving the funds rate from
1973 to 1975 as inflation expectations were increasing meant keeping monetary policy neutral. But
today, when inflation expectations are steady, keeping the funds rate constant would be neutral policy.
BGW’s VAR estimates cannot shed any light on this hypothesis, as they cannot tease out the contribution oil makes to policy increases from that made by anything else. If there were shocks to expected
inflation unrelated to the oil price shock, then BGW’s VAR results could be interpreted to say that if
the Fed were to run an excessively easy and accommodative monetary policy, then output would not
have declined as much. This suggests that spurious correlation may be driving some of their results
and that the results of their Sims-Zha experiment are likely to be overestimated.

6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Oil Prices and Monetary Policy: A CGE Model
A more serious concern with BGW (1997, 2004) is the potential quantitative relevance of the Lucas
critique. BGW (1997) are clearly cognizant of the critique.They claim, however, that “it seems plausible to us that a purely transitory deviation from the usual policy rule would not significantly affect the
structure of the economy (that is, the quantitative effect of the Lucas critique should be small).” But
this is just a conjecture on their part.To assess the importance of the critique it is necessary to use a
model such as the one we develop in this paper. We construct a calibrated computable general equilibrium model, which can fully account for Lucas critique effects.
To have a point of reference for comparison, we first use our model to replicate the two experiments of BGW’s 2004 analysis, the baseline and the Sims-Zha (the unanticipated Sims-Zha in our
model). For our model’s estimates to be taken seriously, the results of our baseline and unanticipated
Sims-Zha experiments should be roughly similar to those generated from BGW’s (2004) VAR data.We
use BGW’s (2004) quarterly VAR as our empirical benchmark because it is less prone to lag-length
problems and because our theoretical model is quarterly. In what follows, BGW refers to BGW (2004).
The appendix presents a brief description of our model and the calibration of its parameters.
A key issue in the analysis is, of course, the statement of monetary policy. For the baseline simulation, we assume that policy is given by the following Taylor-type rule:
Rt = τπ t + τ y yt + ηt ,
where Rt denotes the net nominal interest rate as a deviation from the steady state, π t denotes the
inflation rate as a deviation from the steady state, and yt denotes output as a log deviation from the
steady state. The variable ηt can be interpreted as “policy errors,” which we assume are i.i.d. across
time. For the baseline experiment ηt = 0. Empirical evidence suggests that, since 1983, the coefficients in such a monetary policy rule are τ = 1.53 and τ y = 0.27 (Kozicki 2002) .
In our unanticipated Sims-Zha experiment interest rates are held constant for four quarters or
equivalently,

ηt = −τπ t − τ y yt for t = 1 to 4.
Note the systematic surprises here: The unanticipated Sims-Zha experiment assumes that households
anticipate ηt to be white noise when, in fact, it is a function of inflation and output.
In the anticipated Sims-Zha experiment everyone understands that the central bank is going to
keep the funds rate constant for four quarters by systematically reacting to oil prices.The Taylor rule
is now given by
oil oil
oil oil
Rt = τπ t + τ y yt + τ1oil ptoil + τ 2oil ptoil
−1 + τ 3 pt −2 + τ 4 pt −3 ,

where τ oil
(for j = 1 to 4) are chosen so that the impact of an oil shock on interest rates is zero for
j
four quarters. More details on the analysis are contained in Carlstrom and Fuerst (2004).

7

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 10, APRIL 2005

Oil Prices and Monetary Policy: Some Simulations
Figure 3 shows the effect of a 10 percent oil price shock on real GDP. The baseline experiment allows the funds rate to increase as it responds to the systematic part of monetary policy. In contrast
to BGW’s VAR exercise, where the impact of a 10 percent oil price shock (and the ensuing funds rate
increase) was a fall in output of around 0.7 percent, we estimate the effect to be approximately 0.45
percent. Given a 50 percent oil price hike, this amounts to a decline in output of 2.3 percent.The simple model we build and estimate does not include any of the lags that are obviously important in the
data.Therefore, this number should not necessarily be thought of as a one-time drop in output growth
of 2.3 percent. Instead, it may show up as something that lowers output growth on average by something like 0.6 percent per quarter over the course of a year.Thus, the current oil shock is not likely to
cause a recession but something more akin to the “soft patch” suggested by Chairman Greenspan.
Figure 3 also illustrates our model’s estimates of BGW’s Sims-Zha experiment (our unanticipated
Sims-Zha), where the funds rate is held constant. Like BGW, we estimate that the negative impact of oil
on real GDP is smaller than the baseline case, now 0.2 percent for a 10 percent oil price hike. Figure 3
also shows, however, a more striking difference between our estimates and BGW’s. In BGW’s baseline
experiment, the funds rate increases 1.5 percent, but in ours, it increases only 0.5 percent. Recall that
we argued earlier that BGW’s funds rate responses were probably overestimated.
In BGW’s (2004) Sims-Zha experiment, monetary policy had to respond (negatively) to oil prices
directly to keep interest rates from increasing 1.5 percent. Our model implies instead that a 10 perFIGURE 3

SIMULATED INFLATION, OUTPUT, AND NOMINAL INTEREST RATE
INFLATION

OUTPUT

Percent
0.5

Percent
0.4

0.4
Unanticipated Sims-Zha

0.2

0.3
0

0.2

Unanticipated Sims-Zha

Baseline
0.1

0.2

0

Baseline
Anticipated Sims-Zha

0.4

0.1

Anticipated Sims-Zha
0.6

0.2
0 1

3

5

7

9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23

0

1

3

5

7

9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23
Quarters

NOMINAL INTEREST RATE
Percent
0.6
0.5
Baseline
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1

Unanticipated Sims-Zha

0
0.1

Anticipated Sims-Zha

0.2
0 1

3

5

7

9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23
Quarters

Source: Authors’ calculations.

8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

cent oil price shock would push up the nominal rate only 0.5 percent.The impact of such a difference
on the funds rate that would result after the recent 50 percent oil price increase is especially dramatic.
BGW’s estimates imply that the nominal rate would rise 750 basis points, so that the Sims-Zha experiment would require an aggressive loosening of policy that is not possible given the recent level of
the funds rate. In contrast, our model implies a funds rate movement of only 2.5 percent.To put these
numbers in context, note that the current Taylor rule estimate for the funds rate is around 4 percent,
so that a 750 basis point decline is nonsensical.
Our unanticipated Sims-Zha experiment might suggest that a pause in the Fed’s attempt to gradually increase the funds rate to something that roughly resembles the Taylor rule might be in order.
Figure 3 suggests that the impact on inflation would be small. But before accepting this conclusion,
we will investigate how sensitive it is to assumptions about expectations and ask whether its validity
is affected by alternative assumptions.

The Relevance of the Lucas Critique
While the unanticipated Sims-Zha experiment may help us determine the impact of a one-time deviation from a Taylor-type rule, where the Fed responds to oil prices to keep the funds rate constant,
it is not at all clear that it tells us what would happen if this endogenous response to oil were anticipated. Another way to think of this problem is: What would happen to output if the Fed were to respond systematically to oil price increases in such a way as to keep the funds rate constant after an
oil price shock?
Our anticipated Sims-Zha experiment addresses this issue by incorporating a systematic monetary
response to oil into the monetary policy rule, namely, that if oil prices rise, the funds rate should stay
constant. Because the monetary policy response to oil is systematic, the public would anticipate the
constant funds rate, and inflation expectations would adjust accordingly.
In sharp contrast to BGW’s assertion that expectations are likely to have a small and insignificant
effect on their results, figure 3 indicates otherwise. The Lucas critique is quite relevant and quantitatively significant.The unanticipated Sims-Zha experiment had output declining by a small 0.2 percent.
Once this effect becomes anticipated, however, the effect increases dramatically to –0.48 percent. In
fact, the response of output to a 10 percent oil price shock is essentially the same as it was in our
baseline experiment, where interest rates are allowed to increase endogenously in response to the
increase in oil prices.
The impact of expectations is clear. In the unanticipated Sims-Zha experiment, when oil prices
rise, the monetary authority keeps the funds rate constant even though the monetary policy rule calls
for an increase. The only way to do this in the real world is to take the public by surprise. Keeping
the funds rate contant when everyone expects it to rise amounts to an unexpected decline in the
funds rate and is thus expansionary relative to the baseline case. Hence, output falls less than it would
have otherwise. But once this constant funds rate is anticipated, matters are much different. Output
responds in the anticipated Sims-Zha experiment in essentially the same way as in the benchmark
case, where the funds rate increases in response to oil price hikes. These results demonstrate that if
expectations are not modeled explicitly, it is not possible to disentangle the quantitative effects of oil
shocks and monetary policy on the economy.

9

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 10, APRIL 2005

Conclusion and Policy Advice
This paper presents evidence that indicates the likely effect of an oil price shock on output and inflation. We do this by modeling two hypothetical relationships between oil and the funds rate—one in
which the funds rate increases endogenously because of oil’s impact on inflation and output, and one
in which the Fed actively offsets this rate increase by holding the funds rate constant. Furthermore,
we show the effect of this latter experiment under two different scenarios—one in which the Fed
engineers the constant fed funds rate by systematically fooling the public (replicating BGW’s SimsZha experiment), and another in which the Fed’s new reaction function is anticipated. By “fooling” the
public we mean that the public expects the Fed to follow its policy rule, which calls for it to raise the
funds rate, but instead the Fed keeps the rate constant. Contrary to BGW’s hunch, we show that when
the new policy rule is anticipated, it makes a large and important difference on output.
The policy implication of this difference is clear. Our simulation of the Sims-Zha experiment suggests that delaying further increases in the funds rate could help the economy through the “soft
patch” caused by the recent oil price hikes—without increasing the chance of inflation. But our anticipated Sims-Zha experiment demonstrates the downside of such a choice.The only reason a constant
fed funds rate would keep output from declining as much as it should after a big spike in oil prices
is because people don’t expect the Fed to do it. It might work this time, but responding to oil price
increases in the same way every time will eventually be anticipated by the public and lead to even
larger output losses.

10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

References
Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Mark Watson. 1997.“Systematic Monetary Policy and the Effects of
Oil price Shocks,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 91–142.
Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Mark Watson. 2004. “Oil Shocks and Aggregate Macroeconomic
Behavior: The Role of Monetary Policy, A Reply,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 36, no.
2 (April), 287–91.
Calvo, Guillermo. 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 12, 383–98.
Carlstrom, Charles T., and Timothy S. Fuerst. 2004. “Oil Prices, Monetary Policy, and Expectations,”
unpublished manuscript.
Erceg, Christopher J., Dale W. Henderson, and Andrew T. Levin. 2000. “Optimal Monetary Policy with
Staggered Wage and Price Contracts,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 46, 281–313.
Hamilton, James D., and Ana Maria Herrera. 2004. “Oil Shocks and Aggregate Macroeconomic
Behavior:The Role of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 36, no. 2 (April),
265–86.
Kozicki, Sharon. 1999. “How Useful Are Taylor Rules for Monetary Policy?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Economic Review, vol. 84, no. 2, 5–33.
Kim, In-Moo, and Prakesh Loungani. 1992.“The Role of Energy in Real Business Cycle Models,” Journal
of Monetary Economics, vol. 29, no. 2, 173–90.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1976. “Econometric Policy Evaluation:A Critique,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy 1, 19–46.
Sims, Christopher A., and Tao Zha. 1996. “Does Monetary Policy Generate Recessions?” unpublished
manuscript, Princeton University.
Walsh, Carl. 2003. Monetary Theory and Policy, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Woodford, Michael. 2003. Interest and Prices, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Yun,Tack. 1996.“Nominal Price Rigidity, Money Supply Endogeneity, and Business Cycles,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, vol. 37, no. 2,April, 345–70.

11

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 10, APRIL 2005

The Model
Other than the addition of oil to the production technology, the underlying model is fairly standard.
See Woodford (2003) and Walsh (2003) for details. In this appendix, we will sketch the framework.
The theoretical model consists of households and firms. We present the decision problems of each
in turn.

Households
Households are infinitely lived, discounting the future at rate β . Their period-by-period utility function is given by

M  C1−σ L1+γ
M
U  Ct , Lt , t +1  ≡ t − t + V t +1 ,
P
Pt
1
σ
1
γ
−
+
t 

Mt +1
Pt
denotes real cash balances, which can facilitate time-t transactions. The household begins period t

where σ > 0, γ > 0, V is increasing and concave, Ct denotes consumption, Lt denotes labor, and

with Mt cash balances and Bt-1 one-period nominal bonds that pay Rt-1 gross interest.With wt denoting
the real wage, Pt the price level, and Xt the time-t monetary injection, the household’s intertemporal
budget constraint is given by
Pt Ct + Bt + Mt +1 ≤ mt + Rt −1Bt −1 + Pt wt Lt + Xt .
The household’s portfolio choice is given by
M
V ′  t +1 
Pt  Rt − 1

=
Rt
Ct−σ
Ct−σ = Rt β Ct−+σ1 π t +1.
Following Erceg, Henderson, and Levin (2000), we assume that households are monopolistic
suppliers of labor and that nominal wages are adjusted as in Calvo (1983). In this case labor supply
behavior is given by
Ctσ Lγt = Zht Wt .
It is easy to see that the wage elasticity of labor demand in this model is 1 γ . The variable Zht
in this labor demand equation is the monopoly distortion as it measures how far the household’s
marginal rate of substitution is from the real wage. In the case of perfectly flexible but monopolistic
wages, Zht = Zh is constant and less than unity.The smaller is Zh, the greater is the monopoly power.
In the case of sticky nominal wages, Zht is variable and moves in response to the real and nominal
shocks hitting the economy. Erceg et al. (2000) demonstrate that in log deviations nominal wage adjustment is given by

π tW = λ W zht + βπ tW+1,
W
where π t is time-t net nominal wage growth, and zht denotes the log deviation from steady-state.

12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Firms
The firms in the model utilize labor services, Lt, from households, and energy, Et, from external sources
to produce the final good using the CES technology:
1

Y = f ( L, E ) ≡ (1 − a ) L1− ρ + aE1− ρ  (1− ρ ) .


The real energy price is equal to pte so that a firm’s nominal profits are given by

(

)

profits = Pt Yt − wt Lt − pte Et .
The firm is a monopolistic producer of these goods, implying that labor will be paid below its
marginal product. Let Zt denote marginal cost so that we have
wt = Zt f L ( t )
pte = Zt FE ( t ).
The variable Zt is the monopoly distortion as it measures how far the firm’s marginal products
differ from the real factor prices. In the case of perfectly flexible but monopolistic prices, Zt = Z is
constant and less than unity.The smaller is Z, the greater is the monopoly power. In the case of sticky
prices, Zt is variable and moves in response to the real and nominal shocks hitting the economy.Yun
(1996) demonstrates that in log deviations nominal price adjustment is given by

π t = λ zt + βπ t +1,
where π t is time-t nominal price growth (as a deviation from steady-state nominal price growth) and
lower case zt denotes the log deviation from steady-state.

Equilibrium and Policy
There are four markets in this theoretical model: the labor market, the goods market, the bond market,
and the money market. The respective market-clearing conditions include: Ct = Yt − pte Et

and Bt.

The money market clears with the household holding the per capita money supply intertemporally.

Unanticipated Sims-Zha Experiment
BGW’s Sims-Zha experiment corresponds to the following monetary policy rule. In log deviations the
monetary policy rule is given by a Taylor-type interest rate rule
Rt = τπ t + τ y yt + ηt ,
where yt denotes log deviations in real output. In addition, ηt can be interpreted as “policy errors,” and
we assume it is i.i.d. across time.2 For the baseline experiment, ηt = 0. In the Sims-Zha experiment interest rates are held constant for 4 quarters or equivalently,

ηt = −τπ t − τ y yt for t = 1 to 4.

2. The implied money supply
behavior, the Xt (process), is
passive and can be backed out of
the first-order condition for money
holdings.

Note the systematic surprises here:The Sims-Zha experiment assumes that households anticipate ηt
to be white noise when, in fact, it is a function of inflation and output.

13

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 10, APRIL 2005

Anticipated Sims-Zha
In the anticipated Sims-Zha experiment everyone understands that the central bank is going to keep
the funds rate constant for 4 quarters by systematically reacting to oil prices. The Taylor rule is now
given by
oil oil
oil oil
Rt = τπ t + τ y yt + τ1oil ptoil + τ 2oil ptoil
−1 + τ 3 pt −2 + τ 4 pt −3 ,

where τ oil
j (for j = 1 to 4) are chosen so that the impact of an oil shock on interest rates is zero for
4 quarters.

Calibration
Before proceeding with the analysis, we need to set parameter values at levels consistent with empirical estimates for a quarterly model. Preference parameters are given by β = 0.99 (implying a 4
percent annual steady-state real rate of return), σ = 2, and γ = 3.The latter values are consistent with
micro evidence of fairly inelastic savings and labor supply behavior. Since monetary policy is given by
an interest-rate-targeting procedure, the nature of the utility of money is irrelevant. Finally, we assume
that prices and nominal wage levels can be adjusted on average every 2.9 quarters. Given the other
preference parameters, this implies λ = 0.19 and λ w = 0.0146.
As for firms, the elasticity of substitution between oil and labor is equal to 1 / ρ . Consistent with
empirical estimates, we set this elasticity to 0.59, or ρ = 1.7 (Kim and Loungani (1992). The share
parameter a is set to 0.02.This implies a share of energy in total output of 6 percent (consistent with
its share in 1989).
The (logged) real price of oil is given by an exogenous AR(2) process
pte = a1 pte−1 + a2 pte−2 + ε t .
Estimating this process yields a1 = 1.12 and a2 = –0.15.
Finally, recall that monetary policy in the baseline experiment is given by
Rt = τπ t + τ y yt .
Empirical evidence presented in Kozicki (2002) suggests that since 1983 the coefficients in this
monetary policy rule are τ = 1.53 and τ y = 0.27.

14

pd
papers
Presorted Standard
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND
RESEARCH DEPARTMENT
P.O. BOX 6387

U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit no. 385

CLEVELAND, OHIO 44101

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing
label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research
Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101.