View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

An Incentive-Compatible
Suggestion for Seigniorage Sharing
with Dollarizing Countries

Owen Humpage is an economic
advisor at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. He thanks
Jerry Jordan, Mark Sniderman, and
Edward Stevens for their comments
and suggestions.

by Owen F. Humpage
Sixteen countries now give the U.S. dollar legal-tender status. Although dollarizing can help emergingmarket countries gain monetary credibility and avoid currency crisis, many do not want to give up the
seigniorage revenues associated with issuing their own fiat currency. This article offers a proposal for
seignoirage sharing.

Materials may be reprinted if the
source is credited. Please send
copies of reprinted materials to
the editor.
We invite questions, comments,
and suggestions. E-mail us at
editor@clev.frb.org.

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

Policy Discussion Papers are published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216-579-3050.
Policy Discussion Papers are available electronically through the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World
Wide Web: www.clev.frb.org/Research.

ISSN 1528-4344

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Author’s Note: The past few years have witnessed a growing debate about the merits of dollarization. Although
most of the work has focused on theoretical macroeconomic issues, a few proponents have recommended that
the United States support dollarization by sharing the seigniorage that it acquires from the foreign use of the
dollar. This paper offers a proposal for seigniorage sharing.
The ideas expressed in this paper are presented solely as an academic exercise to foster further discussion of
dollarization. The ideas do not represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Neither institution has taken a position on dollarization. The decision
on whether to share seigniorage does not fall within the purview of the Federal Reserve System. It is, rather, a
decision to be made by elected officials in the U.S. government. The Federal Reserve System operates within
the range of authority given to it by the U.S. Congress as expressed in the Federal Reserve Act. The System
does not currently have authority to engage in seigniorage sharing and would not undertake any form of seigniorage sharing unless directed to do so by Congress.

Introduction
In January 1999, Argentina’s President Carlos Menem recommended that his country officially dollarize—replace the peso with the U.S. dollar. His proposal stirred interest throughout the Americas.
Ecuador officially dollarized in 2000, and El Salvador and Guatemala followed suit early last year. In
all, 16 countries are now officially dollarized.1,2
For many Latin American countries, however, official dollarization amounts to little more than the
legal recognition of a situation that has existed since the 1970s, one that is now quite advanced and,
perhaps, irreversible in several places. The residents of many Latin American countries already denominate a significant share of their assets and liabilities in U.S. dollars and often use dollars to set prices
and to settle current transactions, despite the dollar’s lack of legal-tender status in their countries.
These dollar holders have completed a cost–benefit analysis and have acted in their individual best
interests. Some of their governments, however, resist dollarization—official or unofficial—
primarily because a country that dollarizes loses seigniorage to the United States and because, as Sims

1. The officially dollarized countries
are East Timor, Ecuador,
El Salvador, Guam, Guatemala,
Marshall Island, Micronesia,
Northern Mariana Island, Palau,
Panama, Pitcairn Island (partial),
Puerto Rico, American Samoa,
Turks and Caicos Islands, British
Virgin Islands, and American
Virgin Islands.
2. We use the term dollarization only in
reference to the substitution of U.S.
dollars for the local currency of a
country. Often dollarization refers to
the substitution of any reserve
currency for a local currency. We
also focus on Latin America.

(2001) suggests, the option to generate surprise inflation has value to them.
This Policy Discussion Paper discusses an incentive-compatible proposal for returning seigniorage
to officially dollarizing countries, under which the U.S. Treasury would purchase dollar-denominated,
zero-coupon bonds at face value from the governments of dollarizing countries that undertake sound
budgetary practices and that liberalize their financial markets. Assuming that Congress directs the
Federal Reserve to participate, the U.S. Treasury would then monetize these purchases by selling special certificates to the central bank. The Federal Open Market Committee would set overall limitations
on the amounts of these special certificates that the System holds, and the Open Market Desk would
sterilize any undesired monetary-base changes resulting from their acquisition.
As prelude to the presentation of this proposal, I first explain the factors that have encouraged unofficial dollarization and the problems that partial, unofficial dollarization creates. Next I define official
dollarization, explain seigniorage, and present some rough estimates of seigniorage for a set of Latin
American countries. Then I present a proposal for seigniorage sharing and compare it with plans offered
by the Joint Economic Committee and by Harvard economist Robert Barro. I conclude by briefly
addressing some traditional optimal-currency-area concerns about dollarization. Dollarization may not
be desirable for all emerging-market economies, but the United States stands to benefit in terms of
seigniorage and financial stability from those who do. Seigniorage sharing offers compensation for the
spillover benefits.

1

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

NUMBER 4, JUNE 2002

Unofficial Dollarization
Unofficial dollarization became widespread in Latin America as a consequence of the unstable monetary conditions of the 1970s and 1980s. Latin American countries had some of the highest rates of
inflation among emerging-market economies during this time (table 1). In a few cases, notably
Argentina, Brazil, and Peru, this included hyperinflations, that is, inflation rates at 50 percent or
greater per month (see IMF 2001). At the national level, such high rates of inflation hamper growth
and development, largely by interfering with capital accumulation. High rates of inflation make the
real return on savings uncertain and exacerbate distortions that interfere with the allocative efficiency
of the financial sector.3
At the individual level, inflation encourages dollarization. Residents of emerging-market
economies commonly protect the real value of their nominal wealth by relying on U.S. dollars to perform the traditional functions of money.4 Estimates suggest that unofficial dollarization is extensive.
Using the proportion of foreign-currency-denominated deposits in banks to broad money as a proxy
for the extent of overall dollarization, an IMF study found that in 1995, dollar deposits exceeded
30 percent of the broad money stock in Argentina, Bolivia, Costa Rica, Nicaragua, Peru, and Uruguay,
and that dollar deposits were significant but less than 30 percent of the broad money stock in Ecuador,
El Salvador, Honduras, Jamaica, and Mexico.5 This, however, was undoubtedly an underestimate of
the extent of dollarization. For one thing, it does not include dollar-denominated currency. Porter and
Judson (1996) found that as much as 70 percent of all U.S. currency in 1995 was held outside the
United States. In addition, residents of developing countries hold dollar deposits beyond their shores,

3. On the relationship between inflation
and economic growth, see the
papers contained in Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis (1996).
4. Much of the literature differentiates
between asset substitution and
currency substitution. Asset substitution occurs when residents hold
financial wealth in foreign-currencydenominated assets. Portfolio
decisions may motivate asset
substitution, even in highly developed countries. Currency substitution occurs when residents use
foreign-currency-denominated
assets as a means of payment and
set prices in foreign currencies.
Currency substitution is a response
to monetary instability. See Baliño
et al. (1999, p. 5).

and banks in developing countries typically denominate a substantial portion of their loan portfolios
in dollars. Anecdotal evidence suggests that in some countries, such as Uruguay, nearly 80 percent of
all monetary and financial transactions involve dollars.
While this partial, unofficial dollarization protects individuals from an inflation tax leveled on the
local currency and extends investment opportunities to them, it also tends to expose the developing
country as a whole to foreign-exchange risk and to increase its vulnerability to currency crises. Because
foreigners typically refuse long positions in the inflation-prone local currencies of emerging-market
TA B L E 1

I N F L AT I O N I N D E V E LO P I N G C O U N T R I E S ( a n n u a l p e r c e n t c h a n g e )

Average
1982–91 1992–94 1995–97
All developing countries
Western hemisphere
Argentina
Bolivia
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Ecuador
Mexico
Paraguay
Uruguay
Venezuela

45.1
163.0
452.7
220.0
384.7
20.5
23.9
39.7
64.4
22.8
67.3
25.1

49.1
181.7
13.3
9.5
1,675.2
13.2
24.1
42.3
10.8
18.0
55.9
43.4

Note: Inflation measured by consumer prices.
SOURCE: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, October 2001.

2

16.2
23.4
1.4
9.1
29.6
7.2
20.1
26.0
30.0
10.1
30.4
69.9

1998

1999

2000

10.5
9.9
0.9
7.7
3.2
5.1
18.7
36.1
15.9
11.6
10.9
35.8

6.8
8.8
–1.2
2.2
4.9
3.3
10.9
52.2
16.6
6.8
5.7
23.6

6.0
8.1
–0.9
4.6
7.0
3.8
9.2
96.2
9.5
9.0
4.8
16.2

5. Baliño et al. (1999), table 1, p. 2.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

countries, local residents must denominate their international transactions in U.S. dollars. Overall,
dollar liabilities within emerging markets tend to exceed dollar assets. Calvo (2001) regards this
balance-sheet mismatch, which he calls liability dollarization, as especially pernicious. He contends
that liability dollarization encourages local governments to manage their exchange rates in such a way
as to avoid timely adjustment. Indeed, evidence suggest that emerging markets allow substantially less
variation in their exchange rates than developed countries even when both supposedly maintain
flexible exchange rate systems, and that emerging-market countries hold substantially larger amounts of
foreign-currency reserves relative to imports and to GDP than industrial countries (Mussa et al., 2000,
p. 29). Presumably, these funds are for exchange rate management. This fear of floating, as Calvo and
Reinhart (2000) call it, sets up the necessary conditions for speculative attacks and currency crises.
Once dollarization becomes fairly widespread, it persists and may even continue to progress despite
successful stabilization programs that lower the rate of inflation, particularly if the past inflation experience was long-lived and extreme.6 Switching currencies involves substantial fixed transactions costs stemming from network economies within the payments system. These switching costs prevent a rapid
de-dollarization when inflation falls. Before a stabilization plan can de-dollarize a developing economy,

6. See, for example, Clements and
Schwartz (1993), who provide a
case study of currency substitution
in Bolivia.

expected inflation and monetary uncertainty must fall far enough to lower the opportunity cost of hold`
ing the local currency vis-a-vis
the dollar, and it also must offset the fixed transactions costs associated
with the switch back from dollars.7 The more widespread dollarization is and the greater the degree of
financial liberalization a country has attained, the larger these transactions costs become, and the more
persistent unofficial dollarization will prove.
Any stabilization program must gain public confidence in its durability, and this has proven to be
a difficult task. Argentina, for example, successfully pegged its peso to the dollar between 1991 and
early this year through a currency-board type of arrangement and maintained an inflation rate similar

7. Guidotti and Rodriguez (1992)
discuss and formalize these ideas.
They show that dollarization in
Bolivia, Mexico, Peru, and Uruguay
was nonstationary while inflation
differentials (with the United States)
were stationary, and that dollarization is not cointegrated with the
inflation differential.

to, and often below, that in the United States. Nevertheless, the ratio of foreign-currency deposits to
broad money in that country actually rose from 35 percent in 1991 to nearly 44 percent in 1995.8

8. Baliño et al. (1999), table 1, p. 2.

Interest rates on peso loans and deposits often exceeded interest rates on comparable dollar loans and
deposits, suggesting that the market imposed an exchange rate risk premium on locally denominated
securities. These factors indicate that even a currency board can lack full credibility. The uncertainty
may have business cycle implications.9
A key factor undermining monetary reforms is fiscal profligacy. Although Argentina also adopted
some structural reform, only recently, and belatedly, did it take steps to rationalize a fiscal process that

9. Mendoza (2001) suggests that the
risk of devaluation affects international investors’ decisions and
induces price distortions that accentuate business cycle fluctuations in
developing countries.

promoted deficit spending and saddled the country with large public debts. Large, persistent budget
deficits increase the likelihood that a government will return to the inflation tax in the future.10 For
example, Buenos Aires and other Argentine provinces made payments for current transactions with
newly issued securities, despite the currency board. In many emerging-market economies, the central

10. The IMF (2001, box 4.2, p. 124)
finds a significant and consistent
long-run relationship between the
size of government budget deficits
and inflation in emerging markets.

government is fiscally weak relative to the state governments or relative to political interests throughout the country. In Argentina, for example, the federal government collects and distributes most of the
taxes, but the provinces undertake most of the expenditures. The disconnect between expenditures and
revenues encourages provincial governments to expand outlays in hopes of garnering more revenues.11

11. See Saiegh and Tommasi (1999)
and Cooper and Kempf (2001).

3

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

NUMBER 4, JUNE 2002

A second factor underlying the credibility problems of many developing countries is weak financial systems—inadequate capital, poor regulation, and risky lending. State and federal governments in
developing countries often share the burden of supporting a distressed banking sector, particularly
when a currency crisis has caused the problem. Often state and local governments have substantial
equity stakes in these banks. Bailouts typically take the form of an expansion of the monetary base that
results in higher inflation and currency devaluation. Consequently, inflation is associated with the weakness of the domestic financial sector. Even independent of inflation, financial market distortions hamper
the investment and growth that ultimately determine a country’s ability to advance and develop.12

12. See Levine and Carkovic (2001).

Official Dollarization and Seigniorage Losses
Despite the damage that inflation can do to growth and development, few developing-country governments seem eager to dollarize. Official dollarization gives the U.S. dollar full legal-tender
status for all transactions (and contracts) in a country. This may involve withdrawing the regional
currency or allowing the dollar to circulate with the same legal status as the domestic currency.
Dollarization might also involve providing parallel legal status to more than one reserve currency—for
example, U.S. dollars and euros—and allowing individuals to freely choose among them and the local
currency for use in any type of contract or transaction (see Bogetic´ 2000).
Emerging-market governments have not embraced dollarization because they can gain real revenue
both through the inflation tax and through the interaction of inflation and progressive income taxes.
They often can reduce the real value of their outstanding government debts through inflation. Hence,
in times of fiscal crisis, inflation and depreciation offer an alternative to higher taxes or spending cuts.13
Sometimes, governments can temporarily induce favorable changes in real economic variables through
inflation and improve their election prospects. An IMF study found that inflation in Latin America
often exceeded the rate for optimal seigniorage (IMF 2001, p. 119), so while I will discuss only
seigniorage revenue below, one should keep the other incentives to inflate in mind.
Seigniorage is the revenue that governments earn from issuing fiat money instead of interestbearing debt. Economists typically measure the annual flow of seigniorage as the change in the
TA B L E 2

S E I G N I O R A G E I N T E N L AT I N A M E R I C A N C O U N T R I E S
a
b

Seigniorage
1990–2000
(Percent of GDP)
Argentina
Bolivia
Brazil
Chile
Columbia
Ecuador
Mexico
Paraguay
Uruguay
Venezuela

1.0
1.0
4.2
5.6
1.4
0.1
0.9
1.7
4.2
2.4

Monetary base
2000
($ equivalent)

Futurec
seigniorage
($ equivalent)

$15.1 billion
$0.8 bilion
$36.6 billion
$27.5 million
$5.2 million
<$0.1 million
$27.2 million
$0.9 million
$3.0 billion
$8.6 million

$19.8 billion
$1.8 billion
$36.0 billion
$0.4 billion
$5.6 million
<$0.1million
$80.6 million
$0.5 million
$0.9 billion
$3.9 million

a. The average value between 1990 and 2000 of change in the monetary base from year t–1 to year t divided by GDP in year t.
b. Level in local currency converted to dollars using average exchange rate in 2000.
c. Present discounted value of future seigniorage based on formula in Velde and Veracierto (2000). Assumes that base on currency grows at the
same rate as real GDP grew between 1994 and 2000 and that the interest rate is equal to the average U.S. Treasury bill rate between 1994 and
2000. Data converted to dollars using average exchange rate in 2000.
SOURCES: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; and author’s calculations.

4

13. See Sims (2001).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

monetary base. This amount represents revenue available to the government for the purchase of interestearning assets, such as foreign currency reserves, government securities, loans to the banking
system, or for consumption. Following Fischer (1982), the second column of table 2 presents
estimates of seigniorage revenue for a set of Latin American countries. On average, the countries in this
sample earned seigniorage revenue equal to slightly more than 2 percent of nominal GDP between 1990
and 2000. This was substantially greater than the seigniorage earned by the G-7 industrialized countries,
which equaled approximately 0.2 percent to 0.3 percent of nominal GDP over the same period.
A country that officially dollarizes will lose seigniorage to the United States.14,15 As Berg and
Borensztein (2000) explain, this loss consists of two components. First, the dollarizing country will
convert its outstanding monetary base to dollars.16 Column 3 of table 2 shows the dollar equivalent (estimated at current exchange rates) of the monetary base in my set of Latin American countries for 2000.
At that time, for example, Argentina had an outstanding peso monetary base equal to approximately
$15 billion.17 Second, a dollarizing country loses the future flow of seigniorage associated with the
issuance of currency.18 Velde and Veracierto (2000) show that the present discounted value of future
RC0
seigniorage is equal to (1 + α)
, where C0 is the currency component of the monetary base; R is
R–α
the average rate of return on government debt, and α is a (constant) growth rate of currency. Because I
have no reliable method of predicting R and α in a country that does not dollarize, estimates of the future
flow of lost seigniorage are very crude. If, for example, a country generated a high inflation rate, C0 might
be high, R might also be high, but α could actually become negative, as in Ecuador. The values presented in the fourth column of table 2 assume that in the absence of dollarization, currency would have grown
at the same rate as each country’s real GDP did between 1994 and 2000 and that the interest rate earned
there would have equaled the U.S. Treasury bill rate over these same years. For some countries, such as
Brazil, the seigniorage costs of dollarization seem to be quite high. For other countries, such as Ecuador,
the seigniorage costs are low because the local currency monetary base is relatively small.

Seigniorage Sharing
As already noted, the United States benefits from dollarization because a country that dollarizes loses
seigniorage to the United States. Initially, this seigniorage accrues to the Federal Reserve System, but
because the Federal Reserve remits its profits to the U.S. Treasury, the seigniorage revenue ends up with
the federal government. In addition, however, the United States may benefit from dollarization in

14. A country that is unofficially dollarized also loses seigniorage to the
United States.
15. As the Joint Economic Committee
(1999) notes, U.S. possessions that
dollarize, for example, Guam or
Puerto Rico, indirectly receive a
share of seigniorage through federal
spending.
16. In the discussion that follows, we
assume that the dollarizing country
intends to completely replace the
local currency with dollars. If the
dollarizing country allowed the
dollar to circulate along with the
local currency, the pace of conversion would change along with the
demand for U.S. dollars.
17. Under Argentina’s currency board,
U.S. dollars backed the peso monetary base. Because Argentina could
invest the dollar backing in interestearning dollar assets, Argentina did
not lose seigniorage to the United
States under the currency board.
18. The second seigniorage component
considers only currency because
once the dollarizing country converts its monetary base to dollars, the
reserve component of the base
would be invested in interestearning dollar assets and, therefore,
would not incur a seigniorage loss.

developing countries because it reduces the prospects for currency crises, which can create losses and
payments system disruptions for U.S. banks, and which, in extreme cases (such as the 1998 Russian
default), result in monetary policy responses that complicate the task of maintaining price stability.
By sharing seigniorage revenues, the United States enables dollarizing countries to internalize, at
least in part, the positive externalities that their actions create and that the United States enjoys.
Seigniorage sharing was common among British colonies, and it is not unheard of today (see Bogetic´
2000). Members of the European Monetary Union, for example, share the seigniorage associated with
the issue of euros.19
Previous Seigniorage-Sharing Proposals
At least two proposals for sharing seigniorage with dollarizing countries have already been made. The
U.S. Joint Economic Committee (JEC 1999), for example, recommends sharing seigniorage associated

19. Stevens (1999) explains that the
participating national central banks
pool and distribute the earnings of
their monetary operations among
themselves in proportion to their
holdings of capital in the European
Central Bank.

5

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

NUMBER 4, JUNE 2002

with the initial conversion of the domestic currency into dollars and with any subsequent increase in the
dollars circulating there. The JEC would not share seigniorage on any U.S. currency held abroad before
a country officially dollarized. Under the JEC proposal, the Federal Reserve would make quarterly
seigniorage-sharing payments, consistent with a formula. Accordingly, the Federal Reserve would calculate the total net seigniorage that accrues to the United States from issuing base money and would allocate a portion of this amount to specific dollarizing countries in proportion to the amount by which U.S.
currency in that country increases because of dollarization.20 The JEC also recommends that the United

20. The JEC formula is
$

States withhold from newly dollarizing countries 15 percent of their estimated seigniorage payments and
that the United States use this amount to partially reimburse countries that are already dollarized, such
as Panama, for their past seigniorage losses.
To qualify for seigniorage sharing under the JEC proposal, a dollarizing country must withdraw from
circulation the entire domestic monetary base (with the possible exception of domestic coins). To facilitate this substitution, a dollarizing country could sell to the Federal Reserve System certain preapproved,
liquid dollar assets, such as U.S. Treasury securities, deposits at the Federal Reserve, or funds in U.S.
commercial banks. These securities would act as collateral against the prospects that the emergingmarket economy might re-issue its own currency after receiving U.S. seigniorage-sharing payments.
Harvard economist Robert Barro (1999) offers a different recommendation for seigniorage shar-

Si = [(MBTotal • RTBill) – EFed]
∆Ci$
•
$
MBTotal

• p,

where Si is the net seigniorage
$
payment to country i ; MBTotal is the
total monetary base measured over
a specified period; RTBill is the
3-month Treasury bill rate; EFed is
the net cost of operating the Federal
Reserve System; ∆Ci$ is the
increase in the dollar currency in
country i as a result of official dollarization in country i ; and p is an
arbitrary proportion determined by
Congress.

ing. He suggests a one-time transfer to an emerging-market economy equal to the circulation of its
local currency at the current exchange rate. Unlike the JEC, he would not compensate dollarizing
countries for future seigniorage losses. The dollarizing country would exchange its currency with the
Federal Reserve, which would hold the currency as collateral against the prospects that the dollarizing
country might re-issue its own currency after receiving U.S. seigniorage-sharing payments.
An Incentive-Compatible Proposal
While both of these proposals are feasible, I offer an alternative that would allow a dollarizing country to continue to issue its own currency and would encourage the country’s leadership to make institutional adjustments compatible with maintaining monetary stability.21 I propose that the U.S. Treasury
buy relatively short-term, dollar-denominated, zero-coupon bonds at their face value from countries
that grant the dollar full legal-tender status, and that, at the explicit direction of Congress, the Federal
Reserve monetize these bonds as it would special drawing rights or gold held by the U.S. Treasury.22
Purchasing the zero-coupon bonds at face value would immediately return the potential interest costs

21. Economists George Selgin (2001)
and Steve Hanke (2001) have
suggested dollarizing Argentina by
allowing private banks to issue their
own dollar-denominated bank notes.
Banks would back these notes with
dollar assets and would convert
them to U.S. dollar notes on
demand. This process for dollarization would enable these Argentine
banks to retain seigniorage.

of the securities to the issuing country as seigniorage. The Treasury would assume no exchange risk,
since the securities are dollar-denominated, but the Treasury would incur any sovereign risk associated
with the emerging-market securities. To minimize this sovereign risk, the Treasury would impose two
general conditions on these transactions: First, the emerging-market economy would agree to redeem
the securities at maturity should the U.S. Treasury request that they do so. Redemption would ensure
that the emerging-market economy conformed to other conditions (discussed below). Second, the
Treasury would agree routinely to roll over these securities, providing that the emerging-market
government continually met certain criteria that enhanced their creditworthiness.23
Chief among these criteria, the dollarizing country must grant, and maintain, legal-tender status
for the U.S. dollar equal to that of the local currency and any other circulating reserve currencies.
Unlike the JEC’s and Barro’s proposals, I would not preclude a dollarizing country from issuing its own
6

22. Instead of a zero coupon, the bonds
might pay a small amount of interest
to cover U.S. Treasury costs of
administering the program or to
cover any sovereign risk associated
with the securities.

23. Alternatively, the securities might be
a type of consul, instead of a shortterm obligation. The Treasury,
however, must be able to sell the
securities back to the issuer on fairly
short notice, if this seignioragesharing proposal is to provide
incentives for more basic structural
reforms.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

currency. Allowing the local currency to coexist with the U.S. dollar would encourage a competition
between the circulating currencies that would help secure their stable purchasing power. The ability to
switch among the local currency, U.S. dollars, and any other reserve currency imposes discipline on
the emerging-market economy and, to some extent, on monetary policy in the United States.
In addition, before holding or rolling over the dollar-denominated securities, the U.S. Treasury
also would impose limitations on fiscal deficits and on the overall governmental debt—federal, state,
and local—of the dollarizing country. Moreover, the Treasury would guarantee that the financial
system was privatized, regulated to conform with standard capital adequacy requirements and sound
lending practices, and open to foreign competition. By imposing these institutional requirements, the
seigniorage-sharing arrangement would provide an incentive for the dollarizing country to adopt institutional changes compatible with dollarization, growth, and development.
Initially, the U.S. Treasury would buy these securities to enable the foreign country to dollarize
its monetary base. After that, the Treasury would accommodate future increases in the demand for
currency.24 As noted, the Federal Reserve would monetize these securities, subject to some overall
limitation established by the Federal Open Market Committee. Because the transactions would merely
satisfy foreign demand for U.S. currency, they would not be inflationary to the United States. The

24. Because dollar-denominated bank
reserves would be invested in
interest-earning assets, they would
earn seigniorage.

seigniorage-sharing proposal, however, could permit the emerging-market economy some further latitude
for selling additional amounts of dollar-denominated securities to the U.S. Treasury. The System would
monetize these securities for the U.S. Treasury, but would also sterilize any transaction that threatened to
generate inflation by exceeding the demand for currency in the dollarized country. This sterilization
would occur automatically as long as the System operated with a federal funds rate target.

Optimal Currency Area Concerns
Whereas the fiscal authorities in emerging markets that are contemplating dollarization might focus
on the loss of seigniorage revenues, their economic advisors will surely raise two traditional concerns:
Dollarization prevents the nominal exchange rate from fostering needed terms-of-trade adjustments,
and dollarization hinders the government’s ability to act as lender of last resort. These are important
costs against which to compare the benefits of dollarization, but they are not necessarily domineering
concerns.
Terms-of-Trade Adjustment
Changes in a country’s terms of trade maintain the efficient (and full) use of resources following
`
asymmetric economic shocks.25 Dollarizing forces any terms-of-trade adjustments vis-a-vis
the United
States or third countries entirely through domestic prices and wages. Because these are generally slow
to change, unemployment will typically accompany the adjustment process. Although such
factors as resource mobility, financial market integration, and fiscal transfers can lessen the adjustment

25. The terms of trade are the price of a
country’s exports relative to the price
of its imports, expressed in a
common currency. Hence, the terms
of trade include two prices and a
nominal exchange rate.

costs, they probably cannot prevent some unemployment when wages and prices are sticky.
This argument, however, is static. Dollarization could initiate long-term structural changes that
can eventually mitigate the need for terms-of-trade adjustments, particularly if dollarization is widespread throughout Latin America. Rose (2000), for example, finds that sharing a common currency
reduces transactions costs and tends to increase trade between the participating countries roughly by a
factor of three. In addition, Frankel and Rose (1998) find a strong positive correlation between the
degree of bilateral trade and the bilateral correlation of business cycle activity. Similar business cycle
7

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

NUMBER 4, JUNE 2002

patterns among countries using the U.S. dollar should reduce the need for terms-of-trade changes.
Together these studies suggest that dollarized countries will eventually find their business cycles more
closely synchronized with each other and with the United States. The importance of eliminating the
nominal exchange rate as a source of terms-of-trade adjustment will depend on the share of total trade
that dollarized countries conduct within the common currency area. Seigniorage sharing could
increase the number of countries in a dollar area and, therefore, their total dollar-denominated trade.
Lender of Last Resort
In periods of economic or financial crises, uncertainty about banks’ solvency often causes individuals to shift their monetary wealth from bank liabilities to currency. As the public increases its cash-todeposit ratio, the money supply contracts, leading to a general deflation. A traditional lender of last resort
can avoid a contraction in the money supply and prevent a collapse of temporarily illiquid, but solvent,
commercial banks by accommodating the increased demand for high-powered money. Usually, the
lender of last resort fulfills this function through discount-window operations, but a central bank can also
undertake open-market operations.
Although dollarized emerging-market countries can do neither of these, they have other options.
For one thing, global branches of U.S. banks may locate in the dollarized country once currency risk
is eliminated. These banks are likely to be more diversified than local banks and hence better able to
weather domestic shocks. Their ability to borrow from their parent bank can afford them an elastic
supply of reserves. Emerging-market economies may also establish a limited, but sufficient, lender-of
last-resort function by establishing credit lines with foreign banks or by maintaining reserves.
Moreover, under the proposal for seigniorage sharing presented here, the dollarizing country could
issue additional dollar-denominated debt to the United States during an emergency situation. Because
this would accommodate a local demand for reserves, it would not result in a higher inflation rate in
the United States.

Conclusion
Unofficial dollarization is well advanced in many Latin American countries, and it is not likely to ebb.
Official dollarization would afford many of these countries a credible commitment to monetary stability,
one that promotes growth by eliminating the possibility of currency crises. The resulting stability
and growth would have positive spillover benefits for the United States, which seigniorage sharing helps
internalize to the dollarizing country. I hope that this proposal spurs further debate on this issue.

8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

References
Baliño, Tomás J.T., Adam Bennett, and Eduardo Borensztein. “Monetary Policy in Dollarized
Economies,” International Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper no. 171, 1999.
Barro, Robert J. “Let the Dollar Reign from Seattle to Santiago,” Wall Street Journal Europe,
March 9, 1999.
Berg, Andrew, and Eduardo Borensztein. “The Pros and Cons of Full Dollarization,” International
Monetary Fund, Working Paper WP/00/50, 2000.
^

Bogetic,´ Zeljko. “Official Dollarization: Current Experiences and Issues,” Cato Journal, vol. 20, no. 2
(Fall 2000), pp. 179–213.
Calvo, Guillermo. “Capital Markets and the Exchange Rate, with Special Reference to the
Dollarization Debate in Latin America,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 33, no. 2
(May 2001, Part 2), pp. 312–34.
Calvo, Guillermo, and Carmen M. Reinhart. “Fear of Floating,” National Bureau of Economic
Research, Working Paper No. 7993, 2000.
Clements, Benedict, and Gerd Schwartz. “Currency Substitution: The Recent Experience of Bolivia,”
World Development, vol. 21, no. 11 (1993), pp. 1883–93.
Cooper, Russell W., and Huber Kempf. “Dollarization and the Conquest of Hyperinflation in Divided
Societies,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review (Summer 2001), pp. 3–12.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. “Price Stability and Economic Growth.” Proceedings of the Twentieth
Annual Economic Policy Conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, October 26–27, 1995,
in Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, (May/June 1996) vol. 78, no. 3.
Fischer, Stanley. “Seigniorage and the Case for a National Money,” Journal of Political Economy, vol.
90, no. 2 (April 1982), pp. 295–313.
Frankel, J.A., and A.K. Rose. “The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria,”
The Economic Journal, vol. 108, no. 449 (July 1998), pp. 1009–25.
Guidotti, Pablo E., and Carlos A. Rodriguez. “Dollarization in Latin America, Gresham’s Law in
Reverse?” International Monetary Fund, Staff Papers, vol. 39, no. 3 (September 1992), pp. 518–44.
Hanke, Steve H. “Argentine Endgame: Couple Dollarization with Free Banking,” Cato Institute,
Foreign Policy Briefing, no. 67, December 4, 2001.
International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook, Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Stability, May
2001, Chapter IV, “The Decline of Inflation in Emerging Markets: Can It Be Maintained?”
pp. 116–44.
Joint Economic Committee. “Encouraging Official Dollarization in Emerging Markets,” Joint
Economic Committee Staff Report, April 1999.
Levine, Ross, and Maria Carkovic. “How Much Bang for the Buck? Mexico and Dollarization,”
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 33, no. 2 (May 2001, Part 2), pp. 339–63.

9

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

NUMBER 4, JUNE 2002

Mendoza, Enrique G. “The Benefits of Dollarization When Stabilization Policy Lacks Credibility and
Financial Markets Are Imperfect,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 33, no. 2 (May 2001,
Part 2) pp. 440–74.
Mussa, Michael, Paul Masson, Alexander Swoboda, Esteban Jadresic, Paolo Mauro, and Andrew Berg.
“Exchange Rate Regimes in an Increasingly Integrated World Economy,” International Monetary
Fund, Occasional Paper no. 193, 2000.
Porter, Richard, and Ruth Judson. “The Location of U.S. Currency: How Much Is Abroad?” Federal
Reserve Bulletin, vol. 82 (October 1996), pp. 883–903.
Rose, Andrew K. “Does a Currency Union Boost International Trade?” Paper presented at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas conference, “Dollarization, A Common Currency for the Americas?” March
6–7, 2000.
Saiegh, Sebastián, and Mariano Tommasi. “Why Is Argentina’s Fiscal Federalism So Inefficient?
Entering the Labyrinth,” Journal of Applied Economics, vol. 11, no. 1 (May 1999), pp. 169–209.
Elgin, George. “Let Private Money Spark a Recovery in Argentina,” Wall Street Journal,
August 17, 2001, p. A9.
Sims, Christopher A. “Fiscal Consequences for Mexico of Adopting the Dollar,” Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, vol. 33, no. 2 (May 2001, Part 2) pp. 597–616.
Stevens, Edward J. “The Euro,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary (January
1, 1999).
Velde, François R., and Marcelo Veracierto. “Dollarization in Argentina,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Economic Perspectives, (First Quarter 2000), pp. 24–37.

10