View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release at 7: 30 p. m. ,
Eastern Standard Time,
Monday, December 9, 1963.

Monetary Policy and the Balance of Payments

Remarks of Wm. McC. Martin, J r . ,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,




before Annual Dinner Meeting
of the
United States Council,
International Chamber of Commerce

New York City

December 9, 1963

In a world as dangerous and uncertain as ours, we are
fortunate to live in a country whose people and institutions con¬
sistently rise to their greatest heights in times of greatest strain.
Just as 22 years ago this nation withstood the shock of a
savage bombing attack at Pearl Harbor and then moved forward
with strength of purpose, so two weeks ago it withstood the shock
of an assassin's fire and now--in determination as well as in
anguish—is moving forward once again.
The continuity of this movement, as a new President has
taken over from the old and pledged himself to carry onward the
national course, attests the solidity of our constitutional founda¬
tions and the continuing vitality of the institutions we have built
upon them.
It is a matter of some pride to me that the Federal Reserve
System, which I have the honor to represent here tonight, is one of
those institutions.

And on this date so near the 50th anniversary

of the signing of the Federal Reserve Act on December 23, 1913,
it is also a matter of some pride to all of us in the Federal Reserve
that the System was able to be of some service to its country in this
most recent moment of crisis, as in other crises over half a
century.




-2-

Within minutes after the first news flashes out of Dallas,
the Federal Reserve moved into the foreign exchange markets in
defense of the dollar, and began offering foreign currencies at
prior prevailing exchange rates.

With that offer, and the market's

knowledge of the magnitude of the resources available, the immediate
crisis was safely passed.
That is good, so far as it goes.
go very far.

But it does not, of course,

The problem of out international balance of payments

did not spring into being overnight, and it cannot be resolved over¬
night by any single stroke, however dramatic.

It is a serious, a

complex problem, and it continues.
Four months and four days before his life was tragically
ended, President Kennedy—whose programs President Johnson has
vowed to continue--sent a special message to the Congress on the
international payments problem and the steps to be taken to meet it.
In that message, he declared:




fl

. . . continued confidence at home and coopera¬
tion abroad require further administrative and legis¬
lative inroads into the hard core of our continuing
payments deficit—augmenting our long-range efforts
to improve our economic performance over a period
of years in order to achieve both external balance
and internal expansion--stepping up our shorter-run
efforts to reduce our balance of payments deficits
while the long-range forces are at work--and adding
to our stockpile of arrangements designed to finance
our deficits during our return to equilibrium in a way
that assures the continued smooth functioning of the
world!s monetary and trade systems. "

-3-

In that same message, President Kennedy also said:
"• . . this nation will continue to adhere to its
historic advocacy of freer trade and capital move¬
ments, and . . . will continue to honor its obliga¬
tion to carry a fair share of the defense and
development of the free world. At the same time,
we shall continue policies designed to reduce
unemployment and stimulate growth here at home —
for the well-being of all free peoples is inextricably
entwined with the progress achieved by our own
people. I want to make it equally clear that this
nation will maintain the dollar as good as gold,
freely interchangeable with gold at $35 an ounce,
the foundation stone of the free world's trade and
payments system. "
No one could miss the firmness of that commitment to
"maintain the dollar as good as gold. " Neither could anyone who
heard or read President Johnson's message to the Congress on
November 27 miss the equal firmness of his "rededication of this
Government"' to nthe defense of the strength and stability of the
dollar."
Likewise, no one could miss the emphasis upon such
principles as "freer trade and capital movements, " nor the stress
upon the need to pursue simultaneously the interrelated policy
objectives of internal expansion and external balance without assign¬
ment of priority.
The Federal Reserve, for its part, is deeply engaged in
the simultaneous pursuit of those interrelated policy objectives, and
it is to that engagement I should like to turn now.




-4-

As many of you are aware, basic Federal Reserve policies,
both domestically and internationally, are reviewed and determined
every three weeks in the nation's capital by the Federal Open Market
Committee, a statutory body representing the entire Federal Reserve
System.
At a meeting 12 months ago—on December 18, 1962, to be
exact—the Committee came to the conclusion that it would be
dangerously inappropriate to continue further the extensive degree of
credit ease that had been long prevalent —since at least the beginning
of the 1960's.

Accordingly, it redirected its policy toward lessening

that degree of ease and toward "accommodating moderate further
increases in bank credit and money supply, while aiming at money
market conditions that would minimize capital outflows inter¬
nationally, "
Over the past 12 months, the wording of the Committee's
over-all policy directive has been changed a number of times but
only, and always, to advance policy goals that have, themselves,
remained fundamentally the same.
Some thoughtful people would contend that there is an
incompatibility between monetary and credit conditions that will
help promote sustainable domestic economic expansion and those
that will foster balance in our international payments, and that it
is not possible for monetary policy at one and the same time to aim




-5-

at both successfully.

But it would be unavailing for a central bank,

or for government in general, to do less than attempt to accomplish
both.

Monetary and credit conditions that are inconsistent with

long-run payments balance could hardly serve to promote sustain¬
able economic expansion domestically.

And monetary and credit

conditions that are inconsistent with sustainable domestic economic
growth could hardly serve to promote long-run balance in inter¬
national payments.
Policies designed to combine orderly economic growth
with external equilibrium are appropriate for every country, large
or small.

They are vital, however, for a country such as the

United States, the currency of which is extensively used by the
traders, bankers, and investors of many other countries as well as
of its own in settlement of international transactions.
Any country suffering from persistent erosion of its mone¬
tary reserves faces a threat that confidence may decline in the value
of its currency internationally.

But whenever any country's currency

lacks acceptability and circulation in world markets, its residents
can avoid some of the consequences of currency instability by using
a more stable currency as their unit of account.

The dollar, for

instance, is so used in many countries whose currencies are suffer¬
ing loss of purchasing power at home and depreciation in value




-6-

abroad.

In such cases, the currency depreciation will scarcely

affect nonresidents at all because their commercial and financial
transactions with that country will generally be denominated and
settled in one of the two main international currencies, the dollar
or the pound sterling.
In the case of our country, however, neither U. S. nor
even foreign traders, bankers, and investors can easily switch from
their use of the dollar to another currency.

Moreover, the pre¬

dominant position of the dollar in international trade and finance
means that uncertainty about the dollar generates uncertainty about
all other currencies of the free world.

In 1931, the troubles of

sterling led, either immediately or within a few years, to troubles
for every other currency.
Today, the dollar is more widely used in international
economic relations than sterling was 32 years ago, and any trouble
of the dollar would under present conditions generate trouble for
all other currencies--and in turn more trouble for the dollar itself.
Thus, uncertainties about the dollar affect not only the
U. S. economy but the world economy as a whole.

Therefore, the

Federal Reserve cannot look at the dollar solely from the point of
view of its function as a domestic currency.

It must also consider

the role of the dollar as the main international currency of the free
world.




-7-

The basic strength of the dollar, of course, lies in the
health of the U. S. economy, in the stability of the dollar's pur¬
chasing power, in the variety and competitiveness of U. S. goods and
services available in international markets, in the size of U. S. mar¬
kets for foreign short- and long-term capital--and in the fact that,
adhering to a commitment involving the faith and credit of the United
States, we stand ready to sell gold on demand at the fixed rate of
$35 an ounce to foreign monetary authorities for legitimate monetary
purposes.

This gold convertibility permits foreign central banks to

treat dollars as the equivalent of gold and therefore to keep sizable
working balances and reserves in dollars.

These foreign dollar

holdings have become an essential part of our own and of the world's
financial system.
In order to fulfill its commitment to gold convertibility, the
U. S. needs adequate gold reserves.

These reserves need not be so

large as to cover all dollar holdings of foreign monetary authorities;
in this respect, the U. S. position is like that of a bank, and banks do
not--and need not--hold cash balances equal to their liabilities.

But

the gold reserves must be large enough to give full assurance that
even under adverse circumstances the United States would at all
times remain able to fulfill all legitimate requests of foreign monetary
authorities for gold purchases.




That we stand ready to use our gold

-8-

to meet our international obligations —down to the last bar of gold,
if that be necessary—should be crystal clear to all: the Federal
Reserve itself, let me remind you, has ample power under the
Federal Reserve Act, should the necessity arise, to suspend the
statutory reserve requirements against Federal Reserve deposits
and notes, and to make any needed part of our gold stock available
for sale to foreign monetary authorities.
The dollar not only needs protection from any suspicion
that the U. S. might fail to live up to all its monetary commitments
to foreigners, but it must be guarded against exchange market dis¬
turbances stemming from any deficit in our international payments
as well as from deficits experienced by other leading countries.
The most important contribution of the Federal Reserve to the
solution of this second problem has been its decision to engage
again in foreign exchange operations, including the creation of a
network of interchanges of currencies, commonly called "swap
arrangements, " with foreign central banks.
These arrangements by now have added more than $2 billion
to the sums potentially available for the defense of the dollar and of
other leading currencies in case of need.

Their value has become

particularly clear during the two great crises of recent years: the
very recent one, to which I referred earlier, and the Cuban missile




-9-

crisis of October 1962. Apart from actions of the kind already men¬
tioned, it appears on the basis of experience that the mere existence
of the facilities has prevented any large-scale attack on the dollar
from developing.
1 his network seems to be complete for the time being,
although from time to time the maximum amounts involved in
individual arrangements may be altered to conform to changed condi¬
tions.

For instance, on the day of the Presidents assassination the

maximum amounts of two such arrangements that might have proved
insufficient were raised by 50 per cent within a few hours~-although
in the circumstances it actually proved unnecessary to use those
two agreements at all.
And I should refer here to the supplementary step taken by
our Treasury to offer to foreign official holders of dollars nonmarketable medium-term Treasury obligations denominated, if
desired, in the holder's currency and with maturities flexibly
tailored to the holder's needs.

These bonds provide foreign mone¬

tary authorities an alternative opportunity to invest accumulated
dollars instead of converting them into gold.
conserve our gold resources.




Thus they help to

-10-

The Federal Reserve's arrangements for the interchange
of currencies are designed to protect our reserves against adverse
effects from temporary dollar outflows that are expected to be
reversed in the very short run.

The Treasury's new-type bonds

are designed to prevent repercussions from movements of dollars
that may not be reversed until our payments balance is more
nearly restored to equilibrium, at least in relation to the foreign
country involved.

But valuable and important as these arrangements

are, they cannot deal with the hard core of the payments problem.
This brings us to consideration of monetary actions to
help reduce and eventually eliminate our payments deficit without
hampering sustainable economic growth.

Let us see how this year's

monetary Experience agrees with the contending claims about the
possibility of successfully achieving the combined goals.
During 1963 the Federal Reserve has gradually lessened the
monetary ease that had been prevalent for several years.

The only

dramatic step was that taken in July, when the discount rate of the
Federal Reserve Banks was raised from 3 per cent to 3-1/2 per
cent and the maximum rates payable on time deposits with a
maturity of 3 to 12 months were raised to 4 per cent.

But over the

preceding months, the banking system had been permitted gradually
to absorb its margin of uninvested reserve funds.




-11-

What happened to the money market, to the domestic
economy in general, and to the U. S. payments balance in the past
year ?
The gradual curtailment of reserve availability during 1963
was first reflected in a modest uplift in short-term rates but between
May and November the rise was more pronounced.

All told, rates

on money market paper—Treasury bills, bankers' acceptances,
finance paper, and prime commercial paper—increased by about
five-eighths of 1 percentage point.
In contrast, the movement in long-term rates was smaller
and mixed.

Average yields on Government bonds and high-grade

State and local bonds rose by about one-quarter of 1 percentage point;
those on lower grade State and local bonds and on high-grade cor¬
porate bonds rose much l e s s .

But mortgage rates and rates on lower

grade corporate bonds declined slightly.

And stock prices advanced

enough to reduce the dividend-price ratio for common stocks
significantly, despite the substantial rise in corporate profits and
dividends.
The moderate lessening of credit ease had apparently little
restrictive effect this year on the availability to the economy of money
and bank credit.

The money supply, computed on the basis of

currency outside banks and adjusted demand deposits, rose at an




-12-

annual rate in excess of 3 per cent in the first 10 months.

In only one

out of the past 10 years, 1958, a year of revival from recession, was
there a higher rate of increase.

This year's growth, moreover, has

followed two years of non-inflationary economic expansion.
Because time and savings deposits at commercial
banks are in practice readily convertible without penalty into demand
deposits or currency, many observers believe—and I agree with
them—that for purposes of policy determination these deposits should
be counted as part of the money supply.

Counting the money supply

on this basis, the annual rate of increase this year has been 7-1/2
per cent, a pace of expansion approached only once in the past
decade—and that was last year.
In the field of bank credit, the expansion this year has been
equally striking.

While there has been some slowing in the second

half of the year, total bank loans and investments so far have risen
nearly 7 per cent; bank loans alone, more than 10 per cent.

These

rates of increase have been exceeded in very few of the 10 previous
years.
The data cited suggest that there has been no lack of money
or bank credit to finance the expansion of business activity and the
making of new investments.

Over the past four quarters, both indus¬

trial production and the gross national product rose 6 per cent.




In

-13-

contrast, consumer prices rose only about 1 per cent and wholesale
commodity prices did not rise at all.

Thus, virtually the entire

growth in the national product has reflected real increases in goods
and services available for consumption and investment.
It seems reasonable to conclude that monetary policy,
during the past 12 months, was consistent with a policy goal of sus¬
tainable economic expansion at stable prices.

But what about the

international payments situation?
The lessening of monetary ease was hardly enough to have
a significant effect either on our surplus of exports of goods and
services over imports, or on the volume of direct investment abroad
by U. S. corporations.

And obviously it could not affect our Govern¬

ment expenditures abroad.

The only practical impact on our pay¬

ments balance in the short run could occur through changes in bank
credit to foreigners, in money market investment abroad, and per¬
haps in some other types of short-term capital movements.
But such an impact could be quite important.

A rise in the

outflow of short-term capital was largely responsible for the serious
increase in the U, S. payments deficit during the second quarter of
1963,

In that quarter, the net outflow of short-term capital from the

U. S. exceeded $500 million.

In contrast, the third quarter outflow,

after allowing for a reflux of the so-called window dressing funds in




-14-

July, was apparently less than $200 million.

The improvement was

partly due to a shift in U. S. money market investments abroad,
mainly in flows of U. S. funds in the so-called Euro-dollar market.
A substantial outflow in the second quarter was replaced in the third
quarter by a modest reflow.
This change in flows of short-term funds was instrumental
in cutting the payments deficit in half between the second and the
third quarter.

While the remaining deficit is still too large, it is

lower than in any other quarter during recent years.
I have not reviewed these data to claim sole credit for
Federal Reserve policy as the cause either of the rise in our national
production or of the decline in our payments deficit.

My purpose has

been merely to affirm that monetary policies and credit market con¬
ditions consistent with sustainable growth in our domestic economy
were also consistent with a significant improvement in the capital
account of our payments balance.
All of us recognize, of course, that monetary policy, while
indispensable, is only one of many influences affecting attainment
of national goals.

Many market factors and many other Government

policies were at work that had a more decisive impact, both on our
domestic economic growth and on our balance of payments, than the
modest change in monetary policy could possibly have had.




In

-45-

addition, labor and management have cooperated in keeping costs
from rising, thus helping to maintain the stability of average prices
and consequently the U. S. competitiveness in international markets
that is so essential to the steady improvement of our export balance.
Nevertheless, this year's experience indicates that monetary
measures favorable to the restoration of payments equilibrium can
be formulated and carried out in a way that precludes harm to
orderly domestic economic growth; and that monetary measures
favorable to orderly domestic economic growth can be formulated
and carried out in a way that precludes harm to the attainment of
payments equilibrium.
The experience of the past year also points to another lesson,
familiar to students of monetary policy but perhaps worth repeating.
The great advantage of monetary policy action lies in its flexibility:
it is capable of gradual application through a succession of steps,
each of which may be as small as deemed prudent at the time.
And if there had been reason to conclude that the gradual
reduction in the availability of bank reserves was having an adverse
effect on domestic economic activity, it would have been possible
to halt or reverse the process.

Such action would be difficult in

the case of other tools of national financial policy.




-16-

It is this gradualness and flexibility which permits the
Federal Reserve to be at the same time cautious and experimental.
In recent years, the Federal Reserve has amply demonstrated that
it is not bound by preconceived ideas and precedents, and that it
is prepared to embark on new and uncharted courses in adapting
its activities to meet changing needs.

In its domestic open market

operations, it extended its operations throughout the maturity range
of Government securities, despite the many advantages of the "bills
only" or "bills preferably" practice, when the extension seemed to
offer somewhat greater advantages in dealing with new economic
developments.

And internationally, it re-entered the foreign

exchange market after an absence of 30 years when it became con¬
vinced that open market operations in foreign exchange were needed
to deal with new problems.
The battle against our international payments deficit pro¬
duced relatively satisfactory results during the third quarter.
we cannot be sure that this progress will prove lasting.

But

Some factors

that explain the relatively small size of the deficit in recent months
have been clearly temporary.

And even if we succeed in maintaining

the deficit at the third-quarter rate, we will still have a long way to
go before achieving equilibrium.

We have become prematurely

optimistic before, as in early 1961 and again in early 1962, when it




-47-

looked for a while as if we had been successful in reducing the pay¬
ments deficit to tolerable levels.
mistake again.

We should not make the same

This is not the time to relax our efforts.

As there are others far more able to speak for the Govern¬
ment itself, I have sought deliberately tonight to confine myself to
monetary policy and operations--and principally, in recognition of
the interest you have in international matters, to the impact of
monetary policy and operations upon the balance of payments.
In so doing, I have been mindful, as I am sure you have,
that even the best efforts and wisest decisions of the Federal Reserve
System could not alone insure the integrity of the dollar.

In this, as

in other matters, help is needed.
President Johnson's message has given us the assurance
that we shall continue to get that help from the Government.

Eut

we must also get help from the economy, from both labor and
management.

And we must get it not only when our actions are

popular, but also, and more urgently, when they are not.