View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery




Z-4869

Statement of
William McChesney Martin, Jr.,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Ways and Means Committee
House of Representatives

June 10, 1959

Mr. Chairman:
At the outset, I should like to state that the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System agrees that the debt manage¬
ment proposals transmitted to you by the President are necessary and
desirable and we urge their favorable consideration.
There are only a few points that I would like to make, but
before turning to them, I think it is important that you should
understand that I come before you in connection with these proposals
not as spokesman for the Administration, but as Chairman of the Board
of Governors.
We are living today in a country of unprecedented wealth.
It is wealthy, in part, because of abundant natural resources; and,
in part, because of the energy and initiative of our people.

An even

more important distinction between the United States and most other
countries is the size and quality of the accumulated stock of capital
goods in the hands of producers and consumers.

Due to past saving,

we enjoy the benefits which flow from a reservoir of housing and
durable goods in the hands of consumers, of public facilities, such
as

highways, school buildings, and waterways, and of industrial

plant and equipment.

The society in which we live has been popularly

characterized as affluent, and despite our proper concern for certain
depressed areas--both economic and geographic, I am sure that we can
all agree with this characterization.




One cosequence of affluence is exposure to instability in the
pace of general activity and also in interest rates which rise in periods
of boom and decline in periods of recession.

In a very poor economy,

where everyone must work as hard as he can to eke out a bare living, ad¬
ditions to stock of capital are largely made by diverting effort directly
to production of capita] goods.

Such borrowing and lending as does take

place, is effected at interest rates which we would regard as fantasti¬
cally high.

In this type of economy, there is little threat of instability

except from natural causes. A drought or an unusually good season may
produce relative poverty or plenty.

But everyone is always fully employed

and the range of economic fluctuation will tend to be fairly small.
The greater the accumulation of wealth the greater are the pos¬
sibilities for economic fluctuation.

These may stem from shifts in the

peoples' preferences among the wide range of expenditure opportunities
open to them, from changing attitudes toward saving and investment, from
over-speculation which undermines the solvency of financial institutions,
or, perhaps on some occasions, simply from the arrival at a point where
even a high rate of technical innovation fails tc induce investment de¬
cisions adequate to sustain capital expansion1.
It is not surprising that, in a free and wealthy economy, we
are unable to counterbalance perfectly, through changes in public policy,
the wide shifts that can take place. We always have had, and, I think,
always will have, changes in the pace of our economic progress. We can
and should work to reduce these fluctuations and strive for the goal of
stable growth.

At the same time, however, we must recognize that it is

highly unlikely that we shall ever achieve perfection.




-3Fluctuations in our economy express themselves in various
ways, and we attempt to gauge them by various statistical measures.
If we lock at the movements in any of the broad measures of economic
activity and compare them with fluctuations in interest rates, the
conclusion is inescapable that interest rates tend generally to move
upward in periods of prosperity and downward in times of recession
or arrested growth.

Hence, concerned as we may be about the impact

of rising interest rates on the burden of the public debt or on
necessitous borrowers, we must recognize that rising interest rates
are, in fact, a symptom of broad prosperity and rapid economic growth.
Since the stabilization of monetary systems in key countries
after World War II, interest rates have shown a rising trend throughout
the industrial nations of the free world.

This has been a period of

great economic growth, very active demands for credit, further monetary
expansion, and continuing, though perhaps abating, inflationary pressures.
Throughout the period, interest rate levels in other industrial countries
have been higher than in the United States. This past year's rise in
interest rate levels here, accompanying economic recovery, has been in
contrast to some decline in-interest rate levels in Western European
countries, where a modest recession came somewhat later than in the
United States and Canada.
In the United States, the rise in interest rates has affected
all types and maturities of debt instruments. Yields on long-term
securities have generally risen by about 2 percentage points since the
low point reached shortly after the end of the war.




Yields now range

4from 4 to 4-1/2 per cent on U. S. Government securities of long- and
medium-term, over 4-1/2 per cent on many outstanding Aaa corporate
bonds, and average over 5 per cent on outstanding Baa corporate "bonds.
New issues necessarily have to be offered to investors at higher rates.
Despite their recent upward movement, interest rates in the
United States are still at levels comparable with those prevailing
during much of our history.

Long-term rate movements since last summer

have been within the range of the period from the early part of this
century through 1930. The level is still substantially lower than
during most of the nineteenth century.

From an historical viewpoint,

the present level of rates can hardly be regarded as "out of line" for
a period of wide prosperity and growrth.
In comparing present rate levels with those of past periods,
one of the important things sometimes overlooked is the effect of our
necessarily high tax structure on the effective rate of interest.

For

example, if both the borrower and lender are subject to the 52 per cent
tax on corporate profits the borrowers' net cost and the lenders' net
return is a little less than half of the expressed rate.

Thus, a

market rate of say, 4 per cent, implies for both parties a net rate
of a little loss than 2 per cent.

On its own taxable bonds, the Federal

Government, through the income tax, recaptures a substantial share of
the interest it pays.

When we look at interest rates in long-term

perspective, we must bear in mind that net yields after taxes are
lower today than a comparison of market rates would suggest, because
of the fact that taxes are higher.




-5-

Aggressive demands for financing which, as I have said, are
characteristic of prosperous times, represent efforts to attract
resources away from current consumption in return for the payment of
interest.

In a free economy, no matter how affluent, it follows that,

when borrowers attempt to attract a larger share of the total product
for their purposes, they will have to pay for doing it.
The presence of strong demands on the credit markets from
borrowers of all kinds does create a difficult financial problem.
Recently credit defends have been pressing on the banking system, and
the banks have been accommodating a growing volume of loans. As
borrowers have sought accommodation, banks have raised their prime rate
from 4 to 4-l/2 per cent.

This is the interest rate that banks charge

top-quality customers on short-term loans.
More recently, the discount rate of the Federal Reserve Banks
has been raised from 3 to 3-1/2 per cent.

The discount rate is the

interest rate that is charged by a Federal Reserve Bank when a member
bank borrows money from it. This money is often called high-powered
money.

It is high-powered because it is credited directly to the

reserve account of a member bank, and, unless used to finance a pay¬
ment of currency into public circulation or an outflow of gold or some
other development which drains the member bank reserve base, it forms
the basis for a multiple expansion of bank credit and money.
For some months, we have been having rapid expansion of
bank credit and money, based largely on borrowed reserve funds. The
seasonally adjusted money supply--demand deposits at banks plus




-6—
currency in circulation—has increased by more than $2 billion in the
last four months, an annual rate of growth of about 5 per cent.

In the

face of developing high-level prosperity and the potential threat of
inflationary boom, the Federal Reserve should not be in the position of
encouraging an undue expansion of bank credit and money.

Hence, the

appropriate discount- rate under present circumstances is one that does
not encourage member bank borrowing and is generally above current rates
on short-term market obligations. such as bills.
It is sometimes asserted that the Federal Reserve System should
step in and halt the upward trend of interest rates resulting from active
demands for loans by supplying sufficient Federal Reserve credit in one
form or another to keep interest rates from rising.

This cannot be

done without promoting inflation—indeed without converting the Federal
Reserve System into an engine of inflation.
When such a program was adopted during and following the war,
it did succeed for a time in actually pegging interest rates on
Government obligations.

But, at the same tine it promoted and facilitated

the dangerous bank credit and monetary expansion that developed under the
harness of direct price, wage, and material controls.

The suppressed

inflation that resulted, we are now well aware, burst forth eventually
in a very rapid depreciation of the dollar and even threatened to destroy
our free economy.
This experience is very recent and the effects are widely and
well remembered.

It is now very doubtful whether the Federal Reserve

System could, in fact, peg interest rates on Government obligations
under today's conditions even if we accepted the inflationary costs, which




would be high and would eventually lead to severe collapse.

It is

certain that the Federal Reserve could not extend interest rate stability
to all markets.
The trouble is that the world has learned from wartime infla¬
tionary experience.

It now knows that inflation follows any effort to

keep interest rates low through money creation as the night follows the
day.

Any attempt on the part of the Federal Reserve to peg rates today

would be shortly followed by an acceleration of the outflow of gold in
response to demands from abroad, by further diversion of savings from
investment in bonds and other fixed interest obligations into stocks
and other equities, and by a mounting of demands for borrowed funds in
order to speculate in equities and to beat the higher prices and costs
anticipated in the future.
Those familiar with the investment markets will confirm to you
that such developments would inevitably follow a Federal Reserve attempt
to peg interest rates. A simply tremendous volume of bank reserves
would have to be thrown into the market through Federal Reserve open
market purchases in the attempt to stem the upward pressure on interest
rates.

As these reserves enhanced inflationary pressures even further,

the rush from money and fixed obligations into gold and physical property
as well as the mounting demands for credit to reap speculative profits
and to hedge against future inflation would overwhelm even the most
heroic efforts to hold interest rates down.

Ultimately, if the gold

reserve requirements to which the Federal Reserve is now subject were




-8eliminated, the System might acquire a large proportion of publiclyheld Government debt of over $200 billion in this way.

True,, the

interest rate on Government obligations might be said in some distorted
sense to have been stabilized by such an operation.

Interest rates

generally, however, would spiral upward as they always have in every
major inflation.
People who save will be unwilling to lend their money at
low interest rates even when they expect the depreciation in the value
of their dollars to be limited.

This is understandable.

Take, for

example, a corporate financial institution subject to a 52 per cent
tax.

The after tax income from a bond yielding 4-1/4 per cent interest

would amount to just a little over 2 per cent with the dollar stable in
vaule. If this potential investor had reason to fear that the value of
the dollar would depreciate even 1 per cent a year, his real return
would be very low.

If the investor had reason to expect a price rise

of just over 2 per cent a year, his real return would become negative.
Investors are alert today to this way of figuring interest returns.
It might be added that to suggest that holding interest rates
down by supplying the banking system with reserves through Federal
Reserve open market purchases of Government securities, on the one
hand, and taking them away with higher reserve requirement increases,
on the other, represents a fundamental misunderstanding of how the
credit system functions.

Obviously, if the net effects on the credit

base are, in fact, offsetting, they make no not addition to the total
supply of bank credit, nor do they reduce the demands of borrowers.




-9If they are not fully offsetting, the net result would be inflationary.
We are all acutely aware of the gigantic size of the publicly-held debt
that is outstanding and available to provide a basis for such monetary
inflation.

There is no magic formula by which we can eat our cake and

have it too.
If the Federal Government should substitute artificially
created money for savings in an effort to prevent interest rates from
rising, it would have a reverse effect.

It would worsen the very

situation that the action was intended to relieve.

If you really want

to encourage rising interest rates, you have only to follow the pre¬
scription of those who argue that interest rates on Government or any
other obligations can be pegged by inflating the money supply.
In connection with this discussion, it should be re-emphasised
that the Federal Reserve System does not "like" high rates of interest.
We are anxious ; always, that interest levels be as low as is consistent
with sustained high levels of economic activity, with a steady rise in
our national well being, and with reasonable stability for value for the
dollar,

We cannot, moreover, put interest rates where we would whatever

cur "likes."

Federal Reserve policies can, of course, influence interest

rates to some extent through their influence on the rate at which the
banking system can add to the credit and money supply.

The effective¬

ness of Federal Reserve policies is always subject to the reaction of
borrowers and savers as expressed through the market.




-10

In an economy in which people are alert and' sensitive to price
changes, the only way to bring about a lower level of interest rates is
to increase the flow of real savings or to decrease the amount of borrowing.
One important way to do this is to reduce substantially the deficit at
which the Government is operating.

This will not only relieve immediately

some of the demand pressures that are pushing interest rates up in credit
markets, it will also reassure savers as to the future value of the money
they put in bonds and savings institutions and thus increase the flow of
savings into interest-bearing obligations.
The proposals before you do rot relate to the levels of rates
which will prevail in the market, but rather to whether or not the
Government shall be able to use savings bonds and marketable bonds effec¬
tively as parts of its program of debt management.

The forthright

management of the public debt is an essential part of any program to
encourage savings and lower interest rates. We should not force the
Treasury to resort to undesirable expedients in order to comply with
arbitrary ceilings on either the size of the debt or the rate of interest
it pays.
International levels of interest rates among industrial countries
are now more closely aligned than in earlier postwar years.

This re¬

alignment, together with removal of most restrictions on the movement of
capital, reflects progress towards a closer relationship among inter¬
national money markets, which is the financial counterpart of progress
toward sustained growth in output and trade in the free world generally.
It also signifies a state of affairs in which capital demands are becoming




-11international in scope and in which they Will converge rapidly on the
market that is cheapest and most readily prepared to accommodate them.
Under these circumstances, interest rates in this, country must increas¬
ingly reflect world-wide as well as domestic conditions,
We need to remember that today the dollar is the anchor of
international financial stability.

That anchor must be solid.

Realistic

financial policies of Government are essential to that end as well as to
the end of a wealthy and strong domestic economy.

At this juncture of

world development, the least evidence of an irresponsible attitude on
the part of the United States toward its financial obligations or of its
unwillingness to face squarely the issues which confront it in meeting
greater demand pressures on resources and prices, would have very serious
repercussions throughout the free world.