View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE 1978 MIDYEAR REVIEW OF THE ECONOMY

HEARINGS
BEFORE THE

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
NINETY-FIFTH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION

PART 1
JUNE 28 AND 29, AND JULY 11, 1978

Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
36-S70 0

WASHINGTON : 1978

For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20402


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. o(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri, Ohairman
LLOYD BENTSEN, Texas, Vice Ohairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
SENATE
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
LEE H. HAMILTON, Indiana
EDWARD M. KENNEDY, Massachusetts
GILLIS W. LONG, Louisiana
PARREN J. MITCHELL, Maryland
GEORGE McGOVERN, South Dakota
CLARENCE J. BROWN, Ohio
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
WILLIAM v. ROTH, JR., Delaware
GARRY BROWN, Michigan
MARGARET M. HECKLER, Massachusetts JAMES A. McCLURE, Idaho
JOHN H. ROUSSELOT, California
ORRIN G. HATCH, Utah
JOHN R. STARE, E111eoutt11e Director


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(II)

CONTENTS
WITNESSES AND STATEMENTS
WEDNES!)AY, JUNE

28, 1978

The Economic Outlook

Bentsen, Hon. Lloyd, vice chairman of the Joint Economic Committee:
Opening statement_______________________________________________
Adams, F. Gerard, professor of economics, University of Pennsylvania
and Wharton EFA, Inc__________________________________________
Heller, Walter W., regents' professor of economics, University of Minnesota___________________________________________________________
Kaufman, Henry, partner and member of the executive committee,
Solomon Bros., New York, N.Y___________________________________
Schmiedeskamp, Jay, research director, Gallup Economic Service,
Princeton, N.J ________________________________________________ -THURSDAY, JUNE

Page

1

2

17
29
38

29, 1978

Monetary Policy

Bolling, Hon. Richard, chairman of the Joint Economic Committee:
Opening statement_______________________________________________
Miller, Hon. G. William, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System_________________________________________________
Laffer, Arthur B., professor, University of Southern California________
TUESDAY, JULY

89
90
128

11, 1978

I nveatment in the Current Recovery

Bentsen, Hon. Lloyd, vice chairman of the Joint Economic Committee:

c11~~

-E-c""o~""o~etri~ -Asso~iates,-i~~~- ifaii
E~~:~iRfi!~!!!mi~ti>~~;ic1;~£,Cynwyd, Pa ___________________________________________________ _
Feldstein, Martin, president, National Bureau of Economic Research, and
professor of economics, Harvard University _______________________ _
Fromm, Gary, director, SRI InternationaL __________________________ _
Kuehner, Charles D., director, security analysis and investor relations,
American Telephone & Telegraph Co _____________________________ _

157
158
170
237
240

SUBMISSIONS FOR THE RECORD
WEDNESDAY, JUNE 28, 1978
Adams, F. Gerard:
Prepared statement ___________________________________________ _
Heller, Walter W.:
Prepared statement ___________________________________________ _
Kaufman, Henry:
Prepared statement ___________________________________________ _

th
Ro Article entitled "Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of Interest" __ - ___ _

6i!~f~g'!!~i::e!t_~~~~----------------------------------------


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(III)

5

22
34
47
61

IV
THURSDAY, JUNE 29, 1978
Laffer,
Arthur statement
B.:
Prepared
___________________________________________ _
Miller, Hon. G. William:
Prepared statement __________________________________________ _
Response to Representative Reuss' query regarding procedures used
by the German Bundesbank to control monetary growth ranges ___ _
Response to Senator Roth's query regarding the projected inflation
rates for 1979 ______________________________________________ _
Roth, Hon. William V., Jr.:
Staff letter to Arthur B. Laffer transmitting additional written questions posed by Senator Roth _________________________________ _
Article entitled "The Breakdown of the Keynesian Model" ________ _
TUESDAY, JULY 11, 1978
Evans, Michael K.:
Prepared statement ___________________________________________ _
Feldstein, Martin:
Prepared statement_ __________________________________________ _
Studies:
"Inflation and the Excess Taxation of Capital Gains on Corporate
Stock"------------------------------------------------"Inflation, Tax Rules, and the Long-Term Interest Rate" _____ _
Fromm, Gary:
Table showing preferred tax code revisions _______________________ _
Kuehner, Charles D.:
Prepared statement ___________________________________________ _
An additional written response to a question posed at the hearing by
Senator Bentsen regarding investment tax credit influencing business
decisions to make investments in new plant and equipment ______ _


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Page

130

95
118

122

141
143

162
175
178
188
239

243
267

THE 1978 MIDYEAR REVIEW OF THE ECONOMY
WEDNESDAY, JUNE 28, 1978

THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,
Washington, D.O.
The committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 :20 a.m., in room 1202,
Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Lloyd Bentsen (vice chairman
of the committee) presiding.
Present: Senators Bentsen, Proxmire, Javits, Roth, and McClure.
Also present: John R. Stark, executive director; Louis C. Krauthoff
II, assistant director; Richard F. Kaufman, assistant director-general
counsel; Lloyd C. Atkinson, Thomas F. Dernburg, Kent H. Hughes, L.
Douglas Lee, Deborah Norelli Matz, and M. Catherine Miller, professional staff members; Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; and
Charles H. Bradford, Stephen J. Entin, and Mark R. Policinski,
minority professional staff members.
OPENING STATEMENT OF SENATOR BENTSEN, VICE CHAIRMAN
Senator BENTSEN. The committee will come to order. Let me apologize for being late.
We have recently done a great service to ourselves. We have cut
down on the number of committee hearings that meet at the same time.
Today I had only three.
I was downstairs at the Finance Committee, where the Secretary of
the Treasury was discussing some of these tax measures. The subject of
our discussion here is exactly what we were discussing down below.
This morning we are convening to begin the JEC's midyear review
of the American economy. Today's hearing will focus on the economic
outlook.
Since this committee reviewed the state of our economy earlier this
year, a number of events occurred which will have a substantial impact
on the outlook for the remainder of 1978 and for 1979.
First : The first quarter GNP statistics were considerably below the
expectations of many economists and forecasters. Even with the data
revisions, we still had a very poor first quarter with zero growth. Despite the disappointing growth performance, the unemployment rate
has fallen more quickly than most forecasters had anticipated.
Second: Interest rates have risen dramatically since the beginning of
this year, and may continue to do so. I will ask you gentlemen for your


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(1)

2
judgments on that subject and your assessment of the impact that the
interest rate increases will have on our economic performance.
Third: It now appears that the tax cut, which many forecasters had
assumed would become effective in late 1978, will not go into effect until
1979. In addition, the size of the tax cut, when it is finally approved
by Congress, may be substantially less than the President requested
and less than forecasters were assuming earlier this year.
Fourth: In January President Carter estimated that the budget
deficit would exceed $60 billion. It now seems likely that the deficit will
be roughly $50 billion for fiscal year 1978 and even smaller in 1979.
All of these factors will have an influence on our economic performance for the remainder of this year and for 1979. This makes it imperative that we reassess the state of our economy and the outlook for
the future.
I trust that you gentlemen will identify other sources of change in
our economy and direct our attention toward the economic policies best
designed to address the problems that you foresee.
Our first witness this morning will be Pro£. Gerard Adams, professor of economics and finance at the w·harton School of Finance, University of Pennsylvania. The second witness will be Prof. Walter
Heller, professor of economics at the University of Minnesota and
former Chairman of the President's Council of Economic Advisers.
The next witness is Mr. Henry Kaufman, a partner in Salomon Bros.
The final witness will be Mr. Jay Schmiedeskamp, research director,
the Gallup Economic Service, and vice president of the Gallup Organization. All of these witnesses are old friends of the committee and
need no further introduction. Mr. Adams, ·would you please proceed.
STATEMENT OF F. GERARD ADAMS, PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS,
UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA AND WHARTON EFA, INC.
Mr. ADAMS. Thank you for the opportunity to express my views and
those of my colleagues on the economic outlook for 1978 and 1979. I
will try to make my remarks brief.
Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Adams, if you could move the microphone
closer to you. There are those in the audience who want to hear you.
Mr. ADAMS. I will try to make my remarks brief and address them
speci~cally to the question of moderate expansion versus the risk of
recession.
The Wharton economic forecast for the U.S. economy continues to
be cautiously optimistic, with moderate economic growth between 3
and 4 percent during the remainder of 1978 and during 1979. This
represents a slowdown from the past 2 years but not a recession. Our
:forecast :for the inflation rate signals some acceleration in the rate of
price increase, to the neighborhood of 7 percent, but still short of
the double digit level. Nevertheless, at this advanced stage of the business recovery, it is appropriate to keep a watchful eye on developments
which could signal a turnaround.
We have compared a most probable forecast scenario, one which
does not indicate a true recession in the next couple of years, to a more
pessimistic alternative. The latter case, wihch we consider less likely,
illustrates the circumstances under which a recession could occur m
1979.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3
In the prepared statement I have distributed there are two sets of
tables.
Table 1 is our most rec.ent . Wharton control situation which is still a
reasonable appraisal of our view of the most likely economic outlook.
Table 2 consists of two panels. Toward the end of the prepared
statement is a recession alternative scenario. I will make a comparison
between these two.
First, what we call the Wharton control forecast: The economic
statistics for the second quarter show an economy advancing with
considerable strength. As the chairman pointed out, this represents a
rebound from the weakness during the winter so that the second
quarter figures give a deceiving picture of the potentials from expansion during the remainder of the year. Indeed, from the point of view
of excessive inflationary pressures, such rapid expansion would not be
desirable. A more likely pattern of developments suggests relatively
more modest expansion during the remainder of 1978, and some further slowing of the rate of expansion during 1979 and 1980.
We cannot expect that consumer spending and residential construction will continue to provide stimulus to the economy the way they
have in the past 2 years. The consumer savings rate may move up
moderately ; corn,umer sentiment threatens to decline in the past few
months as a consequence of fears of inflation and consumer installment credit and mortgage debt is at a high level. Housing starts, particularly for single family dwellings, have peaked and are likely to
drop further as a consequence of tightening money and high pnces.
Between now and the middle of next year we see a decline of about 20
percent in the number of housing starts.
We had anticipated some expansion of State and local government
spending, but the passage of Proposition 13 in California puts much
growth in this sector into question.
On the positive side we see some further expansion of business fixed
investment, particularly if tax incentives are provided. This is a matter of very high priority. While investment anticipations are reported
up around 6 percent in real terms, construction contracts are at a high
level.
Inventories are quite low relative to sales. There is no basis currently
for an inventory swing, and indeed, some inventory rebuilding may
occur. And some improvement in our foreign trade balance, in volume
terms if not in dollars, will provide modest stimulus.
There will be only moderate further reduction in the unemployment
rate _to around 5.5 percent by the end of 1978 and unemployment will
contmu~ near that rate during 1979. We will not yet be at a point of
generalized labor shortage, which might make for significant acceleration of wage increases, though there may well be spot shortages of
skilled workers.
Inflation measured by the gross national product deflator and by
the C~I has expanded sharply in recent months, reflecting the upsurge
of agr1cultur~l prices, the impact of minimum wages and other Government regulat10ns, and the effect of dollar devaluation. If agricultural
prices do not go up still further and that depends on crops here and
abroad, we are hopeful that the inflation rate will ease to the 6 or 7
perce7:t !evel, 4,n important consideration in this regard are the labor
negotiations with post office workers, teamsters, and in the railroads.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

4
Sharply increased wage settlements could trigger price increas.eis
throughout the economy. The labor :maket situation, ?<>th in the
unionized and the nonunionized sectors bears close wa.tching.
We anticipate only moderate improvement in the U.S. trade balan_ce.
In nominal terms, that is in terms of current dollars, the commodity
trade deficit is likely to be in the $30-$40 billion range. The devaluation of the dollar means that imports denominated in foreign prices
become more costly. Even if we import smaller quantities, as we will,
the total import bill in dollar terms remains large. vVe do expect some
improvement in our import-export balance in volume terms.
vVith relatively soft economic expansion, and only moderate growth
of corporate profits, tax revenues will only grow moderately. Even
with a tight lid on spending, Federal deficits will remain betwen $40
and $50 billion.
Turning to the risk of recession: After 3 years of economic expansion, it is only realistic to ask how long the expansion can contmue.
The issue is not, however, the length of the expansion, which began
from a low point and which has been quite slow, but rather whether
the imbalances which signal a business recession are becoming
apparent.
I want to summarize those imbalances in three ways: One, demand
imbalances, two, price wage imbalances, and three, policy imbalances.
On the demand side, there is no evidence of excessive inventories,
indeed inventories are at the lowest level relative to sales in many
years. It is clearly premature to signal an inventory cycle at this point.
There is no imbalance either from the point of the capital stock. There
has not been an excessive expansion of plant capacity. We have not
yet returned to the prerecession utilization levels.
With regard to :foreign trade, the imbalance of our trade account is
a serious problem but not one which will aggravate a cyclical downturn. The improvement in our trade balance as we cut back on the
volume of expensive imports will strengthen economic activity.
On the negative side, however, I already mentioned housing, and
the high level of consumer indebtedness. This does pose a risk of cutbacks in consumer purchasing particularly, if real purchasing power
fails to grow and if consumer expectations turn sharply pessimistic.
This is a real risk, one which must be factored into any economic
forecast.
Price wage imbalances may affect both the consumer and the producer. From the consumer's point of view, the upsurge of food prices
threatens to cut into real purchasing power. Continued rapid rises
of farm prices which are not offset fully by wage increases oould
cut sharply into consumer demand for durables and .-mtomobiles. This
remains a real threat. Price increases resulting from excessive pressure on industrial capacity are not yet in prospect. From the producer's point of view, wage price imbalances involve the upward
movement of unit production costs relative to prices. Our present projection does forecast a moderate squeeze of producer margins-profits
continue to grow, but slowly. If costs aocelerate further, relative to
prioes, a reduction in profits rates could have significant impact on
financial markets and on real investment.
In. terms of policy imbalances, one may focus particularl~r on the
relat10n between fiscal and monetary policy in limiting economic ex
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

5

pansion. Both have a legitimate role to play, but in recent years, the
burden of slowing the expansion has £alien largely on monetary
:eolicy. But tight money is not a neutral tool of economic control.
Quite the contrary, tightening money sharply raises short-term rates
relatively to long-term rates and twists flows of financing, with particular impact on residential construction. Moreover, monetary policy
operates with significant lags, so that the impact is long after the
policy has been enacted. So far, there is not yet serious evidence of
financial strain, but short rates are at high levels, and at higher rates
than we had anticipated. Significant financial imbalances can result
from excessively tight money, even financial crises and business failures, and the use of monetary policy imposes risks on the economy.
In order to appraise the impact of the imbalances considered above,
we have computed an alternative forecast with the Wharton model.
That is shown in table 2 o:f the prepared statement. This forecast was
designed to examine the circumstances under which a recession coulu
occur during 1979. The particular assumptions which distinguish this
forecast from our control solution discussed above are :
First, faster rate of inflation, principally through more rapid increase in agricultural prices. We get an inflation rate of 8.5 percent
in their solution. We assume failure to enact the proposed tax relief
either for consumers or investors. Considerably tighter monetary
policy; we have assumed monetary actions leading to additional increase of short-term rates of another 100 basis points above our con•
trol forecast. Cutbacks in consumer spending as a result of high levels
of indebtedness and less favorable sentiment.
The combination of these steps does indeed lead to a considerably
lower rate of growth even to a real decline in GNP during the second
half o:f 1979.
It is o:f interest to note that the recession forecast would mean a
worsening of the unemployment situation, continued large Government deficits with relatively little gain in the inflation rate.
Our current appraisal of the economy suggests that growth will be
slower in 1979 but a recession is not yet in prospect. Nevertheless, as
the business expansion continues, the risk of a greater slowdown and
recession increases. A recession in 1979 is possible, but it would require
a combination of negative factors. The management of economic
policy must recognize this possibility. Moderation in monetary policy
and a tax cut with emphasis on investment incentives and efforts to
limit inflation represent a first line of defense against the risk of
recession.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Adams follows :]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF

F.

GERARD ADAMS

Economic Outlook for 1918 and 1919-Moderate Expansi® Versus Recession

The Wharton economic forecast for the United States' economy continues to
be cautiously optimistic, with moderate economic growth between 3 and 4 percent during the remainder of 1978 and during 1979. Thris represents a slowdown
from the past two years but not a recession. Our forecast for the inflation rate
signals some acceleration in the rate of price increase, to the neighborhood of
7 percent, but still short of the double digit level. Nevertheless, at this advanced
stage of the business recovery, it is appropriate to keep a watchful eye on developments whiich would signal a turnaround. In this paper, we compare a most

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6
probable forecast scenario, one which does not indicate a true recession in the
next couple of years, to a more pessimistic alternative. The latter case, which we
consider less likely, illustrates the circumstances under which a recession could
occur in 1979.
THE WHARTON "CONTROL" FORECAST

The economic statistics for the second quarter .show an economy advancing
with considerable strength. In part, this represents a rebound from the weakness
during the winter so that the second quarter figures give a deceiving piicture of
the potentials for expansion during the remainder of the year. Indeed, from the
point of view of excessive inflationary pressures, such rapid expansion would
not be desirable. A more likely pattern of development suggests, relatively more
modest expansion during the remainder of 1978, and some further slowing of the
rate of expansion during 1979. An essential feature of this scenario is enactment
of a $20 billion tax cut, effective in 1979, with substantial incentives for capital
formation.
The following are the principal features of our current forecast (Table 1) :


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

TABLE 1.-THE WHARTON QUARTERLY MODEL, MARK 5.1-POST-MEETING CONTROL SOWTION: MAY 30, 1978: MSP0782 (CNTLPOS782)
TABLE I.DO-SELECTED MAJOR ECONOMIC INDICATORS
line

Var. label

L_ __

GNP$
GNP$

2 ____
3 ____
4 ____
5 ____
5 ____
7 ____
8 ____
9____
10 ___
IL12 ___
13 ___
}4 ___
15..16 ___
11--.
18 ___
19.-20
___

Item

1978.1

1978. 2

1978. 3

1978. 4

1979.1

1979. 2

1979. 3

1979. 4

1980. 1

1977

1978

1979

1980

Gross national product_ ________
Percent chg gross national p____

1,993.4
6.60

2,082.9
19.20

2,138.3
11.08

2,208.8
13. 84

2,263.5
10. 29

2,319.6
10. 29

2,376.7
10. 21

2,441.7
11.39

2,495.5
9.12

1,889.6
10. 73

2,105.8
11. 44

2,350.4
11. 61

2,591.0
10.24

GNP
GNP

Real gross national pro ________
Percent chg real gross natl. ____

1,358.8
-0.41

l, 388. 9
9.15

1,404.5
4. 57

1,422. 7
5.29

1,435.1
3.52

1,447.0
3. 37

1,459.4
3.46

1,473.5
3.94

1,482.7
2.52

1,337.3
4.92

l, 393. 7
4.22

1,453.7
4.31

1,502.3
3. 34

PDGNP
PDGNP

GNP price deflator (1978) .. ____
Percent chg GNP price dsflaL.

146. 7
7.06

150. 0
9.18

152.2
6.22

m.3
8.12

157. 7
6. 54

160.3
6.69

162.9
6. 52

165. 7
7.18

168. 3
6. 44

141. 3
5. 53

151. 0
6.92

161.6
7.02

172.4
6.68

WRCPV$
PVTOUT

Percent chg pvt compensation ..
Percent chg pvt output per ma _

14. 78
-1.27

10.61
0.41

10. 29
1.27

10.22
2.49

11. 88
1.38

9. 74
0.97

9.80
1. 32

9.83
2.04

10. 56
0.86

8.61
1.74

10.35
0.43

10.49
1. 47

10. 01
1.52

B Unemployment rate (percent) __

6. 20

5. 95

5. 77

5.63

5.56

5.53

5.47

5.43

5.45

7.02

5.89

5. 50

5.44

YPD

I Disp income per capita ... _____

959. 9

973.2

988.3

1,003.8

1,018.4

1,027.3

1,041.6

1,054.4

1,059.9

930.8

981.3

1,035.4

1,075.0

CUNIP
CPUBT$
CPUAT$

B Capacity utilization (percent)___
I Corporate profits before ________
I Corporate profits after. ________

89.3
172. 2
102. 9

90.8
189. 3
112. 8

91. l
176.0
105.2

91. 7
185. 7
110. 9

91.9
184. 7
116.2

92.0
184. 5
116.4

92. l
178. 7
113.1

92.3
182.4
115. 7

92.2
182.6
117.1

89.9
171.7
102. 5

90. 7

180.8
108.0

92. l
182.6
115.3

92. 5
183. 0
118.0

Fed. Govl surplus(+) def.. ___

-55. 7

-35.8

-40.1

-36. 7

-42.4

-38.5

-43.6

-45.6

-35.1

-49.5

-42.1

-42.5

-38.0

Money supply (curr + de) _____
I Percent chg money supply_. ___
E Bank reserves (nonborro) ______
F Discount rate (percent per ye)..
B Commercial paper rate ________
B Avg. Corp bond rate (percent)__

339. 5
5.10
36.6
6.46
6.80
8. 77

347. 4
9. 59
36. 8
6. 75
7.02
8.96

352. 8
6.38
37. 2
7. 25
7.26
8. 99

357.4
5. 30
37.1
7. 25
7.44
9.04

361.1
4. 24
37. 5
7. 50
7. 72
9.06

366.8
6.44
37. 9
7. 75
7. 91
9.14

372.9
6.82
38. 3
8.00
8.18
9.16

381. 7
9. 75
38. 9
8.00
8. 24
9. 25

388.4
7. 25
39.6
8.00
8.25
9.35

326. 0
7.14
34. 7
5.46
5.61
8.43

349. 3
7. 13
36. 9
6.93
7.13
~.94

370.6
6.11
38.2
7.81
8.01
9.15

402. 3

NRUT

2L- GVSURPF$
22 ___
23 ___ FM1$
24 ___ FM!$
25 ... FREN$*
26 ..• FRNDNY
27 .. _ FRMCP4M
28 ... FRMCS


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

8.54

40.6
7.81
8. 21
9.50

"'

TABLE !.-THE WHARTON QUARTERLY MODEL, MARK 5.1-POST-MEETING CONTROL SOLUTION: MAY 30, 1978: MSP0782 (CNTLPOS782)-Continued
TABLE 2.00-GNP DEMAND COMPONENTS (BILLIONS OF CONSTANT DOLLARS)
1978. 2

1978. 3

Line

Var. label

L. ..
2....
3.. ..
4....
5.. ..
6....
7....
8 ....
9 ....
10 ...
IL.
12 ...
13 ...
14 ...
15...

CE

I Personal consumption sp .......

877. 5

892. 9

904. 3

IBFN
IBFR
IBIT

I Plus: Business fixed in ........
B Plus: Residential cons!.·---·-I Plus: Change in busn in .......

130.6
59.1
13. 8

133. 2
60.6
18. 0

136. 4
60. 8
14. 6

GVPF

I Plus: Federal Govt. purc .......
Plus: State and local
government purc ........
B

101. 7

102. 2

103.6

103. 7

104. 2

172.6

174.1

175.6

177.0

178. 5

NETEX
TEB
TMB

Plus: Net exports ............
Total exports ............
Minus: Total imports ....

3. 4
98. 0
94.6

7.8
103. 4
95.6

9. 2
108. 8
99.6

11.1
112. 9
101.8

14. 5
117.0
102.6

GNP

Equals: Gross nationaL ....... I, 358. 8

I, 388. 9

I, 404. 5

I, 422. 7

I, 435. I

GVPS

Item


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1978. I

1978. 4

1979. 1

1979. 2

1979. 3

1979. 4

915. 9

927. 1

936. 2

946. 2

957. 0

139. 7
60.2
15.1

141. 9
58.0
10. 9

143. 8
56.1
11.1

145. 5
55. 2
10.1

104. 5
180. 0
15. 3
118. 5
103. 2
I, 447. 8

1980. I
---~---·-

1977

1978

1979

1980

964. 2

861. 2

897. 7

941. 6

976.4

147.1
54. 4
10. 5

148. 2
53. 4
9. 2

126. 8
56. 9
11. 8

135.0
60. 2
16. 4

144. 6
55. 9
10. 7

150. l
52.4
8.2

104. 5

104. 8

104. 2

101.4

102. 8

104. 5

106.8

181. 6

182. 5

184. 4

169. 7

174. 8

180. 7

186. 9

16.1
120. 2
104. 0

17. 2
121. 8
104.6

19. 0
123. 6
104.6

9. 5
97. 5
88.0

7. 9
105. 8
97. 9

15. 8
119.4
103. 6

21. 5
125. 7
104.2

I, 459. 4

I, 473. 5

I, 482. 7

I, 393. 7

I, 453. 7

I, 337. 3

I, 502. 5

0G

TABLE 3.00-GNP INCOME COMPONENTS (BILLIONS OF CURRENT DOLLARS)
l__ __ GNP$
2 ____ CCAT $
L ..
4 ____ NNP $

5-. .• TXCB$
6____ MISC

7____ SD$

8 ____

9____ YN $
lL.
ll ___ WBC $
IL_ YENT $
113 ___ YRENT $
lL. YINTB $
{~::: CPABT $
17 ___ TXCCT $
18 ___ PROFTVA $
lL. TXCSTT$
20 ___ TPIOP $
2L_ YINTGC $
22___
23 ___ YP $
24 .. _ TXCP $
25 ___
26 ___ YPD $
27 ___ YPDOUT $
28 ___

29 ___ YPDSAV $
3L. YPDSAVR $

I Gross national product__ _______ 1,993.4
8 Less: Capital consumption _____
210.8

2,082.9
218. 4

2,138.3
225. 4

2,208.8
232.3

2,263.5
239. 5

2,319.6
246.9

2,376.7
254. 4

2,441.7
261.8

2,495.5
269. 9

1,889.6
197.0

2,105.8
221. 7

2,350.4
250. 7

2,591.0
282.2

I Equals: Nit n1tion1I pr _________ 1.7a~. 6
I Less: Indirect business ________
173. 3
Miscellaneous ITE_ ________
13. l
Statistical discr__ ________
-6.7
E

1,861.5
176. 2
13. 5
-4.0

l, 912. 9
177.8
13.0
-4.0

1,976.5
181.7
16.9
-4.0

2,024.0
188. 3
14.6
-4.0

2,072.7
191. 9
13.8
-4.0

2,122.3
196. 7
13.2
-4.0

2,179.9
199. 7
17.0

1,692.5
165. 2
11.0
-0.2

1,884.1
178.0
14.1
-4. 7

2,099.7
193. 9
14. 7

2,308.8

-4.0

2,225.6
203. 3
14. 7
-4.0

-4.0

208.9
14. 7
-4.0

I Equals: National income _______ l, 609. S
National income includes:
I
Comp~nsatir~ of empL. _. 1,243.5
Proprietors income ..• ____
103.1
I
Renlaliaeomeof per •. _____
26. 9
8
Net interest. ______________
109. 6
8
Corporate profits __________
126. 8
I

i, 68b.3

i.732. 5

1,793.0

1,834.6

1,879.0

1,924.2

1,981.5

2,021.4

1,520.5

l, 705. 4

1,904.9

2,098.9

1,294.4
107.8

1,334.3
109. 7
30. 4

1,422.1
115.0
31.8
129.1
136.6

1,461.6
117. 2
32. 8
134.0
133. 4

1,501.6
119. 5
33. 7
139. 0

1,545.5

1,156.3
98. 1
25. 3
100.8
139. 8

1,312.6
108. 9
29.2
116. 9
137. 8

1,652.0
130.1
36.8

130.4

124. 8
34. 5
144.0
132. 8

1,587.6
125. 9
35. 5
148. 9
123.5

1,482.7

138. 9

1,378.4
115.0
31.2
124.3
144.2

76.5
40.2
160.1
220.1
52.1

70. 8
43. 5
164. 1
230.0
54.8

74. 7
44. 7
168.4
235.4
57.3

68. 5
43. 2
183. 5
238.2
59. 8

68. l
40. 4
187. 7
242.0
62.0

65. 6
40.0
192. 0
253. 5
64. 1

66. 7
41. 3
196. 5
258. 0
65. 9

65.4
33. 5
205. 8
263.0
67.4

69. 2
46.8
139.0
206. 9
46. 9

72.8
40. 7
161.8
225.4
53.8

67.2
41.2
189. 9
247. 9
62. 9

65.0
34.5
212. 7
274.1
68.5

Equals: Personal income _______ l, 638.8
ws: Personal income tax ______
236. 7

1,702.5
256. 9

1,761.0
27l. 5

1,821.2 1,861.9
285.5
78. 7

1,912.8
288. 5

1,971.7
298. 5

2,030.0
310.0

2,077.9
319. 7

1,536. 7
227. 5

1,730.9
262. 9

1,944. l
293.9

2,162.9
335.2

Equals: Disposable pers ________ 1,402.1
Less: Total personal ou ________ l, 315. 9

1,445.6
1,361.0

1,488.5
l, 397. 8

1,535.7
1,438.1

1,583.2
1,479.3

1,624.3
1,519.4

1,673. l
1,560.1

l, 720.0
1,602.4

1,758.3
1,642.0

1,309.2
1,241.9

l, 468. 0
1,378.2

1,650.2
1,540.3

1,827.7
1,704.0

84.6

90. 7
6.1

97. 7

103. 9
6.6

105.0
6. 5

113.1
6.8

117. 5

116. 3
6.6

67. 3
5.1

89.8

Less: Corp profits tax __________
Undist corp profits _______
Social security ins _______
Plus: Transfer to pers _________
Interest pd by Govt • ____

Equals: Personal savings ______
Personal savines .•••..


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

69.2
34. 3
154. 9
215.9
50. 9

86.2
6. 1

28.4
114. 3
141. 3

5.9

119.3

6.4

6.8

6.1

119.1

33. 2
136. 5
133. 3

109. 9
6. 7 .

156. 4

125. 6

123. 7
6.8

~

TABLE 1.-THE WHARTON QUARTERLY MODEL, MARK 5.1-POST-MEETING CONTROL SOLUTION: MAY 30, 1978: MSP0782 (CNTLPOS782)-Continued
TABLE 4.00-FEDERAL GOVERNMENT RECEIPTS AND EXPENDITURES
line Var. label

Item

1978.1
--~-----·-

L ..
2.•..
3••..
4....
5....
6 ...•
7....
8 ....
9 ....
10•..
IL.
12 ...
13...
14...
15...
16 ..•

1978.2

1978. 3

1978. 4

1979.1

1979.2

1979.3

1979.4

--- - - - - - - - - - - -

1980.1

1977

1978

1979

1980

·-------- - - - --·-------

GVRF $

I Federal Government receipts ____

395.1

422. 7

433. 6

454. 3

453.4

463.8

472. 5

485. 9

500. 2

373. 9

426.4

4€8.9

517. 3

TXCPF
TXCCF $
TSCBF $
TXCSFT $

B Federal personal income _______
B Federal corporate profits .. ___ .
I Fed. indirect busn taxes ..•....
I
Federal social security .......

176.1
59.5
26.0
133. 5

192. 8
66.2
25. 7
138.0

205. 7
60.6
26.0
141. 4

215. 5
64.1
29. 6
145. 2

206.2
57.6
29. 9
159. 7

213. 3
56. 9
30. 2
163.3

220. 6
54.4
30. 5
167.0

229.0
56.2
30. 9
170.9

236.0
53. 7
31.1
179. 5

170. 7
59. 5
24. 8
118. 9

197.5
62.6
26.8
139. 5

217. 2
56.0
30.4
165.2

247.3
53.0
31.6
185.4

Federal Government expenses._

460. 9

458. 5

473.8

491.0

495.8

502. 3

516.1

531.6

535. 3

423.4

464. 5

511.4

555.2

Purchases of goods and svs •.
National defense_. __ . __ ._.
Other ____________________
Transfer payments •... _... __
Grants-1n-a1d to State...•....
Net interest paid_. ______ .. __
Federal GovL subsidies .•. __ .

152. 7
99.5
53. 2
180.1
74. 7
33. 9
9.5

155. 6
100. 6
~5.0
183.2
74. 7
35. 3
9. 7

159. 7
101. 7
58.1
192.1
76.1
36.6
9. 2

166.1
105. 4
60. 7
196.6
77.4
37. 9
13. 1

168. 9
107. 9
61. 9
198. 4
78. 7
39.0
10.8

171. ~
108. 5
62.9
201. 2
79. 7
39.9
10.0

173.6
110.0
65.6
211. 8
80.6
40.7
9.4

180.1
114. 3
65.8
215.2
81.7
41. 3
13.2

181. 1
116.0
65. 1
219.2
82.6
41.6
10.9

146. 4
94. 3
31.1
173. 0
67. 5
29.6
7. 8

158.5
101. 8
56. 7
188.0
75. 7
35. 9
10. 4

173. 5
109.9
65. 5
206. 7
80.2
40.2
10.8

189.9
119.1
70.8
228.4
84. 3
41.6
10.9

BVEF $
GVPF $
GVPFD $
GVPFO $
TRGF $
GVGTA $
YINIGF $
GVSUBTF $

I
E
E
I
E
B

E

NOTE.-A product of Wharton EFA, 4025 Chestnut St., Philadelphia, Pa. 19104. Written permission must be obtained for secondary distribution.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

s

11
The real Gross National Product will grow at annual rates near 4 percent
during the remainder of 1978 and then there will be slower expansion in 1979
and into 1980. We cannot expect that consumer spending and residential construction will continue to provide stimulus to the economy the way they have
in the past two years. The consumer savings rate may move up moderately;
consumer sentiment has declined in the past few months as a consequence of
fears of inflation and consumer installment credit and mortgage debt is at a
high level. Housing starts, particularly for single family dwellings, have peaked
and are likely to drop further as a consequence of tightening money and high
prices. We had anticipated some expansion of state and local government spending, but the passage of Proposition 13 in California puts much growth in this
sector into question. On the positive side we see some further expansion of
business fixed investment, particularly if tax incentives are provided. While
investment anticipations are reported up around 6 percent in real terms, construction contracts are at a high level. Inventories are quite low relative to
sales. There is no basis currently for an inventory swing, and indeed, some
inventory rebuilding may occur. And some improvement in our foreign trade
balance-in volume terms if not in dollars-will provide modest stimulus.
There will be only moderate further reduction in the unemployment rate to
around 5 and one half percent by the end of 1978 and unemployment will continue near that rate during 1979. We will not yet be at a point of generalized
labor shortage, which might make for significant acceleration of wage increases,
though there may well be spot shortages of skilled workers. It would be unrealistic to try to absorb the remaining unemployed with aggregate demand
stimulus. Specific training and apprenticeship programs, will be needed to take
up a large part of our unemployed work force.
Inflation measured by the gross national product deflator and by the CPI has
expanded sharply in recent months, reflecting the upsurge of agricultural prices,
the impact of minimum wages and other government regulations, and the effect
of dollar devaluation. If agricultural prices do not go up still further-and that
depends on crops here and abroad-we are hopeful that the inflation rate will
ease to the 6 to 7 percent level. An important consideration in this regard are
the labor negotiations with post office workers, teamsters, and in the railroads.
Sharply increased wage settlements could trigger price increases throughout the
economy. The labor market situation, both in the unionized and the non unionized
sectors bears close watching.
We anticipate only moderate improvement in the U.S. trade balance. In nominal terms, that is in terms of current dollars, the commodity trade deficit is
likely to be in the $30---40 billion range. The devaluation of the dollar means that
imports denominated in foreign prices become more costly. Even if we import
smaller quantities, as we will, the total import bill in dollar terms remains large.
We do expect some improvement in our import-export balance in volume terms.
A significant development in that direction is the increased production in the
United States of goods previously imported from abroad, the Volkswagen plant
in Pennsylvania is a good example. While the U.S. dollar may now stabilize for
the moment, further gradual devaluation may be anticipated over the next year
particularly against the yen.
Monetary policy is likely to remain restrictive. We expect further increases
of short term rates of some 75-100 basis points between now and mid 1979 and
some moderate upward movement of long term rates as well. As we will note
below, further tightening of monetary policy is possible, but this represents only
a very imperfect tool against the types of inflationary pressures which we have
been observing in the economy.
With relatively soft economic expansion, and only moderate growth of corporate profits, tax revenues will only grow moderately. Even with a tight lid on
spending, federal deficits will remain between $40 and $50 billion. These figures
must however, be seen in perspective, that is in the context of a $2 trillion
economy and one in which state and local government units are running
substantial surpluses.
THE RISK OF RECESSION

After three years of economic expansion, it is only realistic to ask how long
the expansion can continue. The issue is not, however, the length of the expansion, which began from a low point and which has been quite slow, but rather
whether the imbalances which signal a business recession are becoming apparent.
These imbalances which are all closely interrelated in the cyclical process can
be seen from a number of perspectives :

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

12
1. Demand imbalances

On the demand side, there is no evidence or' 'excessive inventories, indeed
inventories are at the lowest level relative to sales in many years. It is clearly
premature to signal an inventory cycle at this point. There is no imbalance ei~her
from the point of the capital stock. There has not been an excessive expansion
of plant capacity. We have not yet returned to the pre-recession utilization levels.
With regard to foreign trade, the imbalance of our trade account is a serious
problem but not one which will aggravate a cyclical downturn. The improvement in our trade balance as we cut back on the volume of expensive imports
will strengthen economic activity. On the negative side, however, is the high level
of consumer indebtedness. This does pose a risk of cutbacks in consumer purchasing particularly, if real purchasing power fails to grow and if consumer
expectations turn sharply pessimistic. This is a real risk, one which must be
factored into any economic forecast.
2. Price wage imbalances

Price wage imbalances may affect both the consumer and the producer. From
the consumer's point of view, the upsurge of food prices threatens to cut into
real purchasing power. Continued rapid rises of farm prices which are not offset
fully by wage increases could cut sharply into consumer demand for durables
and automobiles. This remains a real threat. Price increases resulting from
excessive pressure on industrial capacity are not yet in prospect. From the producer's point of view, wage price imbalances involve the upward movement of
unit production costs relative to prices. Our present projection does forecast a
moderate squeeze of producer margins-profits continue to grow, but slowly. If
costs accelerate .further relative to prices, a reduction in profits rates could have
significant impact on financial markets and on real investment. This poses some
difficult challenges to price stabilization policy which must emphasize the cost
side though not to the neglect of prices.
3. Policy imbalances

In terms of policy imbalances, one may focus particularly on the lation
between fiscal and monetary policy in limiting economic exipansion. B,,; havP
a legitimate role to play, but in recent years, the burden of slowing the expansion has fallen largely on monetary policy. But tight money is not a neutral tool
of economic control. Quite the contrary, tightening money sharply raises short
term rates relative to long term rates and twists flows of financing, \\ith particular impact on residential construction. Moreover, monetary policy operates
with significant lags, so that the impact is long after the policy has been enacted.
But so far, there is not yet serious evidence of financial strain, but short rates
are at high levels, and beginning to catch up to long rates. Significant financial
imbalances can result from excessively tight money, even financial crises and
business failures, and the use of monetary policy imposes risks on the economy.
As we have noted, there are potential problems with respect to inflation, and
its impact on consumers and businesses, with respect to a high level of consumer
credit extensions, and with respect to monetary policy. These forces are not likely
to lead to a cyclical turnaround during 1978, but as we turn toward 1979 and
1980, they must be watched closely.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

~
~

'

~
~

0

0
~

TABLE 2.-THE WHARTON QUARTERLY MODEL, MARK 5.1-RECESSION SCENARIO ALTERNATIVE-Continued

w

TABLE 1.00-SELECTED MAJOR ECONOMIC INDICATORS
1978.l

197R. 2

1978. 3

1978. 4

1979.1

1979.2

1979. 3

1979. 4

1980.1

1977

1978

1979

1980

!__ __ GNP$
2____ GNP$
3____
4 ____ GNP
5-. __ GNP

Gross national product_ ________ I, 993. 4
Percent ch2 gross national p____
6.60

2,082.4
19. 09

2,141. I
11.76

2,214.5
14.44

2,263.8
9. 21

2,313.2
9.01

2,363.9
9. 07

2,423.2
10. 42

2,468.8
7. 73

I, 889. 6
10. 73

2,107.8
II. 55

2,341.0
11. 06

2,547.7
8.83

Real Gross national pro. _______ I, 358. 8
Percent chg real gross natl. ____ -0.41

I, 388. 5
9.03

I, 401.2
3. 70

I, 415. 6
4.19

I, 418. 2
0. 74

I, 420. 2
0.55

I, 423.0
0.80

I, 427. 5
1.25

I, 426. I
-0.37

1,337.3
4. 92

I, 391.0
4.02

1,422.5
2.24

1,428.6
0. 44

7____ PDGNP
3 ____ PDGNP

GNP price deflator (1978) ______
Percent chg GNP price deflat. __

146. 7
7.06

150.0
9.20

152.8
7. 77

156.4
9.83

159.6
8.41

162.9
8.40

166.1
8. 20

169.8
9.06

173. l
8.13

141.3
5. 53

151. 5
7.23

164.6
8. 66

178.3
8.35

JO ___
IL12 ___
13 ___
14 ___
15 ___
16 ___
IL18___
Jg ___
20 ___
2L2L23 •..
24 ___
25 ___
26___
27 ___
28 ___

10. 75
0. 15

10.85
1.02

11.62
-0.20

8. 61
1.74

10. 41
0.28

11. 15
0.22

11.02
0.44

Line Var. label

Item

5____
9 ____

WRCPV $
PVTOUT
NRUT

Percent ch2 pvt compensation ___
Percent chg pvt output per ma_

14. 78
-1.27

10.61
0.30

10.53
0. 57

10. 70
1.76

12. 61
-0.65

10. 62
-0.65

B Unemployment rate (percent)._

6.20

5.95

58.2

5. 75

5.90

60.6

6. 24

6.45

E. 74

7.02

5. 93

6.16

7.19

GPO

I Disp income per capita. _______

959. 9

973.3

98E.O

998.9

998. 7

1,002.3

I, 010.8

I, 017.3

1,016.2

930.8

979. 5

1,007.3

1,020.1

CUNIP
CPUBT $
CPUAT $

B Capacity Utilization (percent)___
I Corporate profits before ________
I Corporate profits after _________

89.3
172.2
102.9

90.8
188.9
112.6

90.9
182.3
108.8

91.3
191. 3
114.2

90.8
184.2
110.3

90.4
176.2
106.0

98.8
164.9
99.3

89.4
165.3
99. 7

88. 7
160. 7
97. 3

89.9
171. 7
102.5

90.6
153. 7
109.6

90. l
172. 7
103.8

87. 9
152. 3
9.28

Fed. Govt. surplus (+)def______

-55.7

-36.0

-37 2

-33.9

-19.5

-17.9

-24.8

-27. 7

-18.5

-49.5

-40.7

-22.5

-26.1

Money supply (curr + de) _____
Perc6nt chg money supply __ • __
Bank reserves (nonborro)______
Discount rate (percent per ye)_.
Commercial paper rate ________
Av2. corp bond rate (percent) •.

339. 5
5.10
36.6
6.46
6.80
8. 77

345.9
7. 76
36.4
7.00
7.40
8. 99

349.3
3.92
36. 4
7. 50
7. 70
9.11

352. 4
3. 59
36. 2
7.50
8.03
9.25

354.9
2.91
36.5
8.00
8.43
9.38

358.0
3.49
36.6
8.0Q
8. 77
8.55

361. 7
4.28
3f.5
8.00
8.88
9. 65

366.4
51. 9
36. 5
7. 75
9.17
9.82

368.2
2. 38
36. 7
7.50
9.32
10.00

326.0
7.14
34. 7
5.46
5.61
8.43

346.8
6.36
36.4
7.11
7.48
9.03

360.2
3.88
36.5
7.88
8.81
9.60

374.5
3.96
36.9
7.00
9. 52
10.28

GVSURPF $
FMI $
FM!$
RFEN $•
FRMDNY
FRMCP4M
FRMCS

I
I
E
F
B
B


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1-6
0,)

TABLE 2.-THE WHARTON QUARTERLY MODEL, MARK 5.1-RECESSION SCENARIO ALTERNATIVE-Continued
TABLE 2.00--GNP DEMAND COMPONENTS (BILLIONS OF CONSTANT DOLLARS)
Line Var. label
!__ __ CE
2 ____
3____ IBFN
4c..• IBFR
5____ IBIT
6____
7-___ GVPF
8____
9____ GYPS
10•. _
lL_ NElEX
12..- TEB
13••• TMB
14•••
15••• GNP

Item

1978.1

1978.2

1978.3

1978.4

1979. 1

1979. 2

1979. 3

1979. 4

1980. 1

1977

1978

1979

1980

I Personal consumption sp _______

877. 5

892.6

902.3

911. 5

915.8

918.9

923.7

929.0

930.6

861.2

896.0

921. 9

933. 5

I Plus: Business fixed in ________
B Plus: Residential consL •••.••
I Plus: Change in busn in _______

130.6
59.1
13. 8

136.0
60.6
18.0

136.0
50.6
14. 4

149.6
59. 7
14.5

139.6
56.9
9.4

139. 8
54.3
8.0

139. 3
52.5
6.3

138.4
50. 9
6.8

137.1
49.3
5.2

126.8
56.9
ll.8

134.6
60.0
15. 2

139. 3
53.6
7.6

135.1
47. 5
3.6

I Plus: Federal Govt. rurc _______
Plus: State and loca __________
Government pure ________
B

101. 7

102.2

103.5

103.5

103.9

104.0

103.9

104.0

103.3

101.4

102. 7

103.9

105. 6

172.6

174.1

175.6

176 9

178.3

179. 7

181. 2

182.0

183. 7

169. 7

174.8

180.3

186.1

Plus: Net exports _____________
Total exports ___________
Minus: Total imports ____

3.4
98.0
94.6

7.8
103.4
95.6

8.8
108.4
99.6

10.8
112. 5
101. 7

14. 5
ll6.4
102.0

15.6
117. 7
102.1

16. 2
118. 7
102.6

16. 3
119.1
102. 8

17. 0
119. 5
102. 5

9.5
97. 5
88.0

7. 7
105.6
97.9

15.6
118.0
102.4

17.2
ll8.8
101. 7

Equals: Gross national__ _______ 1,358.8

1,388.5

1,401.2

1,415.6

1,418.2

1,420.2

1,423.0

1,427.5

1,426.1

1,337.3

1,391.0

1,422.2

1, 428- 6


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

~

TABLE 3.00-GNP INCOME COMPONENTS (BILLIONS OF CURRENT DOLLARS)
---- ·----~-L__ GNP$

2 ___ CCAT$
3

4 ___
5___
6 ___
7___
8
9___
JO ___
IL12___
IL14 ___
15...
16
17 ___
18. __
19.-.
20 ___
2L.
22
23...
24 ___
25
26 ___
27 ___
28
29 •..
30 ...

NNP$
IXCB$
MISC
SD$

-

-----------

----

--------

I Gross national product_ ________ 1,993.4
B Less: Capital consumption _____
210. 8

2,082.4
218. 4

2, 141. 1
225. 7

2,214. 5
233. 2

2,263.8
240. 9

2, 313. 2
249. 0

2,363.9
256. 9

2,423.2
264. 9

2,468.8
273. 4

1,889.6
197. 0

2, 107. 8
222. 0

2,341.0
252. 9

2,547. 7
285. 9

Equals: Net national pr_ _______ 1,782.6
Less: lndirrct business ________
173. 3
Miscellaneous ITE ________
13. I
__________
discr
Statistical
7
-6.
E

1,864.0
176.2
13. 5
-4.0

1,915.4
178.1
13. 0
-4.0

1,981.3
185. 2
16. 9
-4.0

2,022.9
188. 5
14. 6
-4.0

2, 064_"2
191. 8
13. 8
-4.0

2,107.0
195. 5
13. 2
-4.0

2, 158. 4
199. 4
17. 0
-4.0

2,195.4
202. 9
14. 7
-4.0

1,692.5
165. 2
II. 0
-0.2

1,885.8
178. 2
14. I
-4. 7

2, 088. 1
193. 8
14. 7
-4.0

2,261.8
208. 2
14. 7
-4.0

Equals: National income _______ 1,609.9
National income includes:
Compensation of empL ___ 1,243.5
Proprietors' income ________
103. 1
Rental income of per_ _____
26. 9
Net interest__ _____________
109. 6
Corporate profits __________
126. 8

1,685. 7

1, 734. 7

I, 797.4

I, 833. 4

1,870.6

1,909.1

1, 960. 3

1, 991.6

l, 520. 5

1, 706. 9

l, 893. 3

2,052.7

1,294.3
107.7
28.4
114. 4
140. 9

1, 334. 1
113. 0
30. 4
119. 3
137. 9

1,378.1
121. 1
31. 0
124. 4
142. 8

1, 420. 7
123. 5
32. 1
129. 3
127. 8

l, 458. 2
127. 0
33. 1
134. 2
118. 1

1, 495. 5
130. 3
34. 0
139. 0
110. 2

l, 536. 1
137. 1
35. 0
143. 7
108. 4

1,574.2
138.8
36. 2
148. 3
94. 1

1, 156. 3
98. 1
25. 3
100. 8
139. 8

1,312.5
Ill. 2
29. 2
116. 9
137. 1

1,477.6
129. 5
33.6
136. 5
116.1

1,630.2
143. 2
37. 9
154. 9
86. 4

73. 9
29.1
183. 5
239. 2
59. 9

70. 3
23. 1
187. 5
243. 7
61. 9

65.6
20. 2
191. 4
255. 9
63. 5

65. 5
18. 7
195. 5
261. 2
64. 8

63. 4
7. 1
204. 2
267. 0
65. 7

69.2
46.8
139. 0
206. 9
46. 9

740. 0
38.6
161. 9
225. 5
53. 9

68. 8
22. 8
189. 5
250. 0
62. 5

59. 5
4.2
210. 1
279. 7
65. 9

YN$
I
I
B
B
I

WBC$
VENT$
YRENT$
YINTB$
CPABTS

------

TXCCT$
PROFIVA$
TXCSTT$
TRTOP$
YINTGC$

Less: Corp profits tax __________
Undist corp profits _______
Social security tax. ______
Plus:Transfers to pers ________
Interest pd by Govt_ _____

69. 2
34. 3
154. 9
215. 9
50. 9

76.3
39. 9
160. l
220. I
52. 2

73. ~
39.6
164. 1
230. 2
55. 0

77. 1
40. 8
168. 4
235. 9
57. 6

VP$
TXCP$

Equals: Personal income _______ 1,638. 8
Less: Personal income tax ______
236. 7

1,702.6
256. 9

1,764.6
273. 3

l, 827. 8
287. 0

I, 870. 7
297. 7

I, 921. 3
308. 6

1, 978. 7
319. 3

2,035.6
331.6

2,080.4
341. 1

1, 536. 7
227. 5

1,733.4
263. 5

1,951.6
314. 3

2, 158. 0
356.4

YPD$
YPDOUT$

Equals: Disposable rers_ ••• - -Less: Total persona ou ________

1, 402. 1
l, 315. 9

1,445. 7
I, 3€0. 6

1,491.3
l, 400. 4

1,540.8
I, 442. 9

1,573.0
1,480. 3

1,612. 7
1,517.5

1,659.4
1,556.4

1,704.0
I, 597. 2

1,739.3
l, 634. 6

1,309.2
1,241. 9

1,470.0
I, 379. 9

1,637.3
I, 537. 8

1,801.6
I, 691. 6

YPDSAV$
YPDSAVR$

Equals: Personal saving ________
Personal savings _______

86.2
6.1

85. 1
5. 9

90. 9
6. 1

97. 9
6.4

92. 7
5. 9

95. 2
5. 9

103. 0
6.2

106. 9
6. 3

104.6
6.0

67. 3
5.1

90.0

99. 4
6.1

109. 9
6. l

·----··------··


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

-~------ ----~-

------------

6.1

.....

°'

TABLE 2.-THE WHARTON QUARTERLY MODEL, MARK 5.1-RECESSION SCENARIO ALTERNATIVE-Continued
TABLE 4.00-FEDERAL GOVERNMENT RECEIPTS AND EXPENDITURES
Line Var. label

1978.1

Item

1978. 2

1978.3

----- - - - - - - - · - - - - ~ - - - - - l___

2
3___
4___
5___
6___
7
8___
9
10 ___
11 ___
12 ___
13 ___
14 ___
15 ___
16 ___

1978.4
~

1979.1

-~-- - - - - "

1979. 2

1979.3

1979.4

1980. l

1977

1978

1979

1980

GVRF$

I Federal Government receipts ___

395. l

422. 5

436. 9

457.8

477. 3

485.6

492. 7

505. 5

518. 7

373. 9

428. l

490.3

531.6

TXCPF$
TXCCF$
TXCRF$
TXCSFT$

B Federal personal income _______
B Federal corporate profits ______
I Fed. indirect busn taxes _______
I Federal social security _________

176. 1
59. 5
26.0
133. 5

192. 8
66. 0
25. 7
138.0

206. 3
63. l
26.0
141. 5

216. 6
66. 3
29.6
145.2

224. 7
63. 0
29.9
159. 7

233.0
59.4
30.1
163.1

241.1
54. 7
30. 4
166. 4

250.4
54. 4
30.8
169. 9

257.6
52.2
30. 9
178. 0

170. 7
59. 4
24. 8
118.9

198.0
63. 7
26. 8
139. 6

237. 3
57. 9
30. 3
164.8

269. l
48. 3
31.3
182. 9

Federal Government expenses __

450. 9

458.6

474. 1

491. 6

496.8

503.5

517. 5

533. 2

537. 2

423.4

468.8

512.8

557. 7

Purchases of goods and svc __
National defense ____________
Other ____ • ________________
Transfer payments __________
Grants-in-aid to State ________
Net interest paid ____________
Federal Govt. subsidies. _____

152. 7
99. 5
53.2
180.1
74. 7
33. 9
9.5

155. 6
100.6
55.0
183. 2
74. 7
35.4
9. 7

159. 7
101. 7
58. l
192.2
76.1
36. 8
9.2

166.1
105. 4
60. 7
196.8
77. 4
38. 2
13. l

168. 9
107.0
~1.9
199.1
78. 7
39.2
10.8

171. 4
108. 5
62.9
202.5
79. 7
40.0
10.0

173. 6
110.0
63.6
213.6
80.6
40. 4
9.4

180.1
114. 3
65.8
217.6
81.7
40.6
13. 2

181.1
116.0
65. l
222.2
82.6
40.4
10. 9

145.4
94. 3
51. l
173.0
67. 5
29.6
7.8

158. 5
101.8
56. 7
188. l
75.0

173. 5
109. 9
63. 5
208. 2
80.2
40. l
10.8

189.9
119.1
70.8
232.9
84.4
39.5
10. 9

GVEF$
GVPF$
GVPFD$
GVPFO$
TRGF$
GVGTA$
YINTGF$
GVSUBIF$

I
E
E
I
E

B

E

NOTE.--A product of Wharton EFA, 4025 Chestnut St., Philadelphia, Pa. 19104. Written permission must be obtained for secondary distribution.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

36. l

10.4

....

c,)

17
AN ALTERNATIVE PESSIMISTIC FORECAST

In order to appraise the impact of the imbalances considered above, we have
computed an alternative forecast with the Wharton model, (Table 2). This forecast was designed to examJne the circumstances under which a recession could
occur during 1979. The particular assumptions which distinguish this forecast
from our control solution discussed above are:
1. Faster rate of inflation, principally through more rapid increase in agricultural prices.
2. Fail~re to enact the proposed tax relief either for consumers or investors.
3. Considerably tighter monetary policy.
We have assumed momitary actions leading to additional increase of short
term rates of another 100 basis points above our control forecast.
4. Cutbacks in consumer spending as a result of high levels of indebtedness
and less favorable sentiment.
The combination of these steps does indeed lead to a considerably lower rate of
growth even to a real decline in GNP during the second half of 1979. Our computations suggest that recession would not be provoked by any one of these steps
alone, though each one will contribute to a slower growth rate. The process which
provokes this slowdown anu recession has three main elements:
1. 'l'he cutback in corisrimer spending, pa,rticularly on durables.
An important contributing factor in this regard is the rapid increase in food
prices which erodes consumer purchasng power and tends to depress consumer
expectations.
2. The failure to enact the tax cut will affect consumer spending as well, but
its longer term impact on business fh:ed investment is of more serious concern.
The investment stimulus stretches out over a longer period. Its absence would
hold down investment which is needed for expansion and modernization of our
plant capacity.
3. Impact of tight money, particularly on housing, but also on business fixed
investment. The impact of monetary policy is difficult to direct and is likely to
impact on housing markets and business fixed investment for a long period.
It is of interest to note that the recession for~ast would mean a worsening of
the unemployment situation, continued large government deficits with relatively
little gain in the inflation rate.
·
·
CONCLUSION

Our current appraisal of the economy suggests that growth will be slower in
1979 but a recession is not yet in prospect. Nevertheless, as the business expansion continues the risk of a greater sl_owdown and recession increase. A recession
in 1979 is possible, but it would require ·a combination of negative factors. The
management of economic policy must recognize this possibility. Moderation in
monetary policy and a tax _cut with emphasis on investment incentives and
efforts to limit inflation represent a first line of defense against the risk of
recession.

Senator BENTSEX. Thank you, Professor Adams. Your statement
brings to mind a number of questions that I would like to ask but I
think that we will proceed with all of the witnesses before we go to
questioning.
Our second witness is ,valter Heller, professor of economics at the
University of Minnesota and former chairman of the President's
Council of Economic Advisers.
We are pleased to have you back with us.

STATEMENT OF WALTER W. HELLER, REGENTS' PROFESSOR OF
ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF MINNESOTA
Mr. HELLER. Thank you, Senator Bentsen. Plowing new R"round in
an appearance before this sagacious and well-staffed committee is not
always easy. But on tax reduction, one of the subjects on which your
chairman solicited our views, the Kemp-Roth biil offers a target of
opportunity.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

18
Senator BENTSEN. That is very interesting and will be very helpful
to us. I just came up from listening to a discourse on it by Senator
Roth and Congressman Kemp.
·
Senator PROXMIRE. It is especially appreciated because there is no
one that knows tax cuts better than Kemp· and Roth than w· alter
Heller. You were right at the economic helm during the Kennedy tax
cuts of 1963-proposed then and actually passed in 1964. It is often
cited as the whole basis for it.
So you are probably the best person in the country to speak on the
validity of their proposals now.
Mr. HELLER. I had dinner with Congressman Kemp last night. I
understand that Senator Roth will be :here today so I expect a one-two
punch.
As you are well aware, their bill represents a bold Republican
alternative to the now-muted Carter tax proposal. Instead of a single
$15 to $20 billion tax cut, it proposes an $80 billion slash-in 1978
dollars-via successive 10 percent across-the-board income tax cuts in
each of the next 3 years. Citing the 1964 Kennedy-Johnson tax cut, in
which I have a certain paternal interest, as Senator Proxmire just
mentioned, and a variety of other tax reductions as precedents, the
Kemp-Roth supporters claim that their program could unleash such
productive energies and generate so much GNP and revenue feedback
that it would quickly pay for itself.
It is high time to examine their claims, the evidence cited to support them, and the assertions and estimates that underlie them. In
this brief statement, I will plow no deep furrows, but I can at least
scratch the surface and join a few issues.
I would like to comment first on the "verdict of history" on the
1964 tax cut. As a general observation, it is true that the 1964 tax cut,
$12-billion-plus, or roughly equivalent to $35 to $40 billion today,
succeeded. almost exactly as projected, in stimulating the economy. It
is also true that the expansion associated with the tax cut and other
sources of growth eventually raised income tax revenues above the
pre-tax-cut level. But in citing the 1964-65 experience as support for
their proposal to cut income taxes, the Kemp-Roth advocates are misreading the "verdict of history" in two important respects:
First, contrary to their assertion that the Kennedy-Johnson tax
cut achieved its economic stimulus and consequent revenue flows "by
increasing aggregate supply, by increasing the reward to work and investment," the record is crystal clear that the great bulk of the success of the "great tax cut" that was phased in during 1964-65 came,
as expected, from its stimulus to demand, its release of some $10 billion of consumer purchasing power and another $3 billion or so of
corporate funds.
Second, the economic setting for the Kennedy tax cut was sharply
different from our setting today. The 1964 tax cut was injected into
an economy characterized by plenty of slack in both labor and product
markets. We have a good deal of slack today but in 1964, slack was
coupled with virtual price stability, inflation averaging about 1.2
percent per year, and stable-to-falling unit labor costs.
In other words, the "aggregate supply" capacity already existed
in the form of high unemployment and low industrial operating rates,
and inflation was not a problem. So the tax cut was able to activate

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

19
idle physical and human resources without more than minimal impact
on the price level.
Then, in my prepared statement, I address myself to two specific
counts on which the Kemp-Roth view of the Kennedy tax-cut world
is simply wrong. The first has to do with our alleged failure to recognize the stimulus to incentive and productivity that our 1962-64 tax
cuts would provide. I cite chapter and verse to refute this and append
the relevant excerpts from President Kennedy's January 1963 economic
message. The second and more serious twisting of the facts relates to
alleged Treasury mistakes in estimating the 1964 tax-cut's rev~nue
effects. My prepared statement corrects the record on this score.
Let me return to the first two points. The core of the 1964 tax cut
was a $12-billion-plus boost in after-tax income and profits injected
into a slack, noninflationary economy. At the time, we calculated (a)
that actual output was running about $30 to $35 billion below potential output, and (b) that the $12-billion-plus cut, as it was spent and
respent and as it energized new investment, would boost consumer
spending and business investment by a combined amount of $25 to $30
billion a year without significantly stepping up inflation.
The true verdict of history is that the tax cut, predominantly operating through the release of purchasing power, worked almost precisely as planned: The unemployment rate fell from 5.6 percent in
January 1964 to 4.5 percent in July 1965, when escalation in Vietnam
began.
Inflation, which had been running at 1.4 percent a year just before
the tax cut, crept up to 1.6 percent by the summer of 1965, mainly because of food price increases. In other words, the purchasing power
punch of the tax cut was converted into higher sales of goods and services, higher output, more jobs, more income, and more tax revenues, but
not into higher prices.
As a careful quantitative appraisal by Arthur Okun showed, the
multiplied impact of the tax cut did indeed raise aggregate demand
and GNP by about $30 billion, at annual rates, above what they would
have been without the tax cut.
But what about the alternative explanation offered by the KempRoth forces that the 1964 tax cut accomplished all this by quickly expanding supply through its benign effect on incentives 1
A great leap forward on the supply side would have to show up in
a big jump in trend productivity increases and in the growth of GNP
potential. The Kennedy tax program, including both the 1964 tax
cuts and the 1962 investment tax stimulants in the form of the investment tax credit and liberalized depreciation guidelines, did in fact
improve investment and work incentives and contribute to good, sustained growth in productivity. But no sudden bulge in productivity
and potential has been found by any close student of the subject.
Yet it would take precisely such a bulge, many times as big a supply response as the 1964 tax cut produced, to get the kind of results
that Senator Roth and Congressman Kemp claim on the basis of estimates by Norman B. Ture. There is no basis in either the 1964 tax
cut or any other modern tax cut for Ture's prediction that a KempRoth tax cut would, in a year or two, boost GNP by $150 to $170
billion, capital investment by over $100 billion and jobs by 2 to 4 million, thus boosting revenues above pre-tax-cut levels.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

20
Such findings stretch both credulity and :facts. As Rudolph Penner
of the American Enterprise Institute puts it, "There can't be two or
three or four times more bang in a Kemp-Roth tax cut than we've
had with any other."
Given no validated evidence that huge tax cuts would generate huge
increases in supply, that is, in productive potential, what would the
3-year $80 billion Kemp-Roth tax cut do to budget deficits and inflation? My answer won't surprise you: The huge surge in demand would
overwhelm our supply capacity and soon generate soaring deficits
and roaring inflation.
Let me turn to the Laffer curve. Increasingly, supporters of KempRoth are drawing aid and comfort from the Laffer curve, a diagram
purporting to show how tax changes can suppress or unleash incentives to work and invest and hence affect tax revenues. Some of my
views on the subject are implicit in what I have already commented on.
But let me add some thoughts that go beyond the 1964 tax experience:
The Andrew Mellon tax cuts of the 1920's are cited as evidence to
support the Laffer thesis. As Jude Wanniski flatly put it, "As a result [of the Mellon cuts], the period 1921-29 was one of phenomenal
economic expansion."
At a time when a relative handful of Americans paid income taxes
and Federal spending was less than 5 percent of GNP, we are asked
to believe that Federal income tax reduction powered the growth of
GNP from $70 billion in 1921 to $103 billion in 1929. It just isn't
possible.
Or take the 1948 tax cuts in \Vest Germany, also advanced as "evidence" to support the Laffer thesis. As chief of internal finance in
our military government in Germany in 1947 to 1948, and as tax
adviser to General Clay, I can say, I was there. What actually touched
off the great expansion ? One, a tough and successful currency reform;
two, removal of wage and price controls; three, the Marshall Plan;
four, bountiful harvests; and five, tax reduction and reform. Yet
the whole German "economic miracle" is attributed to tax cuts. Among
other factors, the 2 million expellees and refugees from Eastern Europe, the major source of increased German labor supply in the post1948 period, are conveniently ignored.
In short, the whole Laffer thesis and Kemp-Roth initiative rely excessively on post hoc, ergo propter hoc reasoning and on a onedimensional view of the world. There is more to life than economics,
and there is more to economics than taxes.
Apart from the weakness of such shaky evidence, the alleged miracle effect of tax cuts in generating great surges of work, savings, investment, and productive potential has to face such questions as the
following:
\Vhy, in the face of Laffer's assertions, has Denison's law held true
throuci:h thick and thin for the past 100 years or so? Edward F. Denison of Brookings has found that U.S. gross private domestic savings
at high employment has held at just about 16 percent of the gross
national product through high taxes, low taxes, and periods of virtually no taxes. There are some studies that show some savings elasticity in response to changing rates of return, but the basic law has not
been refuted.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

21
Also, there is the question of whether we are in a high enough tax
zone to produce these dire effects of higher rates and the delightful
effects of lower rates than Laffer postulates.
Let me just quote a respected authority, William Fellner, of the
American Enter_prise Institute, on this. He says, "The United States
is not yet at high enough tax rates to produce anything like the
revenue explosion Laffer is predicting. Where the U.S. economy is
along such a curve is completely undocumented, unexplored, and unknown."
And how is it that the Kemp-Roth tax cuts could, by increasing
take-home pay sharply, lead to such an upsurge in the work ethic
when a considerably larger average increase in real take-home pay
in the decade of the 1960's, mostly as a result of sustained economic
growth, produced no similar upsurge? People worked less in res_ponse
to longer real pay per hour, they took longer vacations, more holidays,
and worked shorter workweeks; that is, they took out part of the
proceeds of growth in more leisure. Why wouldn't they do the same
with the proceeds of big tax cuts, that 1s, respond as much or more
to the increase in income, by working less hard to gain a given target
income, as they would to the increase in incentives, by working harder
as lower taxes made leisure more expensive. Or, to put it in an economic frame, all the explorations of labor supply, of worke,rs reactions
to changes in aftertax income that I know of, cannot even tell us
for sure whether the net will to work is increased or decreased by a
rise in aftertax income.
Having said a few things about excessive tax cuts in 1978-80, let
me turn for a moment, lest I be misunderstood, to tax cuts in 1978.
I do not want to tarnish my reputation as a tax-cut advocate.
Nothing I have said above about the dangers of gigantic tax cuts
in 1978-80 applies to a moderate 1978 tax cut of $15 or $20 billion,
or even $25 billion, if monetary policy tightens a lot. With unemplo1,ment still at 6.1 percent and operatmg rates in manufacturing still
hovering arout 84 percent of capacity, there is still a sizable margin
of unused supply potential to accommodate a $15 to $20 billion tax
cut. Expecially in a year when payroll tax boosts and the inflation tax
are increasing taxpayer liabilities by some $15 billion, it is economically safe and sound to enact a tax cut to neutralize this increase and
provide some modest stimulus to an economy that would otherwise
slow down to an annual growth rate below 4 percent. It would work
to the benefit of output, jobs, and incomes, and pay a good dividend
in tax revenues without shoving the economy into an excess-demand
inflation. Just two supporting observations:
First, a careful comparison of key unemployment rates today with
those of 1971, when we were clearly operating well below our potential, shows that they are just about identical. Rates of unemployment
of adult males were 4.1,:,percent then and 4.3 percent now-I took the
last 3 months' average-the rate for adult females was 5.7 then and
6.0 percent now; teenagers, 16.9 percent then and 16.9 percent now;
all persons, 5.9 percent then and 6.1 percent now. And one should recall that it took a 6.2 percent real GNP growth rate from mid-1971
to the fourth quarter of 1972, to start stretching our supply capacity
and falling prey to excess demand.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

22
Second, apurt from the need to overcome continued slack in the
economy, we need added stimulus to private investment to serve our
major economic goals. To forgo the boost to incentives and markets
that a $15 billion to $20 billion tax cut could provide might shrink the
deficit in fiscal 1979, but it would result in higher unemployment, lower
investment, a less· vigorous economy; and the risk of higher deficits in
fiscal 1980. That would be a poor trade-off indeed.
The economic slowdown that will confront the Congress and the
country at the end of 1978, will leave a lot of red faces around here if
Congress simply scuttles the Carter tux cut and does nothing. But if
instead Congress adopts the Roth-Kemp super cut, and thereby guarantees dizzying deficits and sizzling inflation, faces will be even redder.
It isn't always easy to make a distinction of this kind; that is, to
oppose this kind of gigantic cut and yet to say that a moderate tax
cut is good economic policy. That distinction is what I have tried
to make in my statement today.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Heller follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF WALTER

W.

HELLER 1

T= Cuts, the Kemp-Roth Bill, ana the Laffer Curve

Ploughing new ground in an appearance before this sagacious and well-staffed
Committee is not always easy. But on tax reduction, one of the subjects on which
your chairman solicited our views, the Kemp-Roth Bill offers a target of
opportunity.
As you are well aware, their bill represents a bold Republican alternative to
the now-muted Carter tax proposal. Instead of a single $15 to $20 billion tax
cut, it proposes a $98 billion slash via a 33 percent cut in individual income taxes
plus a $15.5 billion cut in corporate taxes, both to be phased in over the next
three years. CHing the 1964 Kennedy-Johnson tax cut (in which I have a certain paternal interest) and a variety of other tax reductions as precedents, the
Kemp-Roth supporters claim that their program would unleash such productive
energies and generate so much GXP and revenue feedback that it would quickly
pay for itself.
It is high time to examine their claims, the evidence cited to surpport them, and
the assertions and estimates that underlie them. In this brief statement, I will
plough no deep furrows, but I can at least scratch the surface and join a few
issues.
THE "VERDICT OF HISTORY" ON THE 1964 TAX CUT

As a general observation, it is true that the 1964 tax cut ($12 billion plus, or
roughly equivalent to $35 to $40 billion today) succeeded, almost exactly as
projected, in stimulating the economy. It is also true that the expansion associated with the tax cut anc\ other sources of growth eventually raised income
tax revenues above the pre-tax cut level. But in citing the 1964.-1965 experience
as support for their proposal to cut income taxes by a huge total of $113.5 billion,
the Kemp-Roth advocates are misreading the "verdict of history" in two important respects:
Contrary to their assertion that the Kennedy-Johnson tax cut achieved its
economic stimulus and consequent rewnue flows "by increasing aggregate supply,
by increasing the reward to work and investment," the record is crystal clear
that 'the great bulk of the success of the "great tax cut" that was phased in
during 1964-1965 came, as expected, from its stimulus to demand, its release of
some $10 billion of consumer purchasing power and another $3 billion or so of
corporate funds.
Second, the economic setting for the Kennedy tax cut was sh'a·rply different from
our setting today. The 1964 cut was injected into an economy characterized by (a)
plenty of slack in !both labor and product markets, coupled with (b) virtual price
1 This is a somewhat revised version of the original statement Incorporating several
editorial changes and corrections and adding five footnotes documenting or supplementing
statements In the text.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

28
st.ability-inflation averaging &!bout 1.2 percent per year--'and stable-to-falling
unit 'labor costs. In other words, the "aggregate supply" capacity already existed
in the form of high unemployment and low industrial operating rates, and
inflation was not a problem. So ,the tax cut was able to activate idle physical
and human resources without more than minimal impaC't on the price level.
As to misrepresentation, I regret to say that on two important counts, the
retrospective Kemp-Roth view of the Kennedy-Johnson tax cut is simply wrong:
First, it is said that the Kennedy tax program succeeded for the wrong reasons,
that is, virtually ignored the incentive and supply side of the tax equation. On
the contrary. President Kennedy's 1963 economic program was a careful blend
of measures designed to stimulate -both markets and incentives. As he put it in
his January 1963 Economic Message: "Only when we have removed the heavy
drag our fiscal gystem now exerts on personal and !business purchasing power
and on ,the financial incentives for greater 1isk taking and personal effort can
we expect to restore the high levels of employment and .growth we took for
granted in the fi·rst decade after the war." Appended to his statement is a
lengthier excerpt from his 1963 Economic Report providing a further perspective
on his tax cut proposal.
Second, it is asserted that the revenue-generating effect of the 1964 tax cut
were not foreseen. Exactly the opposite was true. As President Kennedy said:
"The impact of my tax proposals on the budget deficit wil·l be cushioned • • •
most powerfully, in time, •by the accelerated growth of tamble income ana tlLX
receipts as the economy expands in response to the stimulus of the tax program."•
Let me return to the first two points. The core of the 1004 tax cut was a $12
billion-plus •boost in after.Jtax income and profits injected into a slack, noninflationary economy. At the time, we calculated (a) that actual output was
running about $80 to $85 tbHlion below potential output, and (b) that the $12
billion-plus cut-as it was spent and respent and as it energized new investment~would :boost consumer spending and business investment by a combined
amount of $25 to $80 billion a year without significantly stepping up inflation.
·The true verdict of 'history is that the tax cut, predominantly operating
through the release of purchasing power, worked alm'OSt precisely as planned :
·The unemployment rate fell from 5.6 percent in January 1964 to 4.5 percent
in July 1965 (when escalation in Vietnam began).
Inflation, which had been running at 1.4 percent a year just before the tax
cut., crept up to only 1.6 percent by the summer of 1965 (mainly because of food
price increases). In olJher words, the purchasing power punch of the tax cut was
converted into higher sales of goods and services, higher output, more jobs, more
income, and more tax revenues but not into higher prices.
As •a careful quantitative appraisal by Arthur M. Okun (in late 1965) showed,
the multiplied impact of the 'tax cut did indeed raise aggregate demand and
GNP iby a•bout $80 billion (at annual rates) above what they would have been
without the tax cut.•
KEMP-BOTH: SUPPLY RESPONSES AND INFLATION

But what about the alternative explanation offered by the Kemp-Roth fOTces
that the 1964 tax cut accomplished all this by quickly expanding supply through
its 'benign effect on incentives?
A great leap forward on the supply side would have to show up in a big jump
in trend productivity increases and in the growth of GNP potential. The Kennedy
• A careful appraisal of the official Treasury Tax estimates for the period In question shows
that they too foresaw the revenue-stlmulat'lng potential of the Income tax cut, expenditure
Increases, and associated measures. To be specific. the assertion that Treasury tax were off
by $143 billion "because Treasury Ignored the feedback effects of tax rate changes on production behavior" (as Congressman Kemp puts It) represem's a complete misreading or twisting
of the facts: (1) close Inspection of tbe Treasury's actual year-by-year revenue estimates
shows ( a) that the tax-cut's feedback eft'ects were Indeed taken into account, (b) t'hat apart
from tax cut,!!. the Vlet'nam war played a major role In stimulating the economy and boosting
revenues, and (cl that t'he "net miss" or revenue gains between 1963 and 1968 was about
$2 billion, not $143 billion; (2) the Treasury tahle cited by Roth-Kemp advocates was In
no sense a summary of Treasury revenue estimates but a 1968 submission to the House
Banking Committee to show what revenues would have been in fiscal years 1963 to 1968
if (a) taxes had not heen cut In 1962-64 but (b) the economy hnd nonethPless exnanded
as much as it did with the tax cut; (3) on!y the minus Items In the Treasury's 1967 submission to the Banking Committee were used, anfl. even those were not added up .correctly.
Those who did the staff work for Congressman Kemp and Senator Roth have clearly done
them-and the cause of rational tax llehat~a serious disservice.
8 See "Measuring the Impact of the 1964 Tax Reduction" in Perspectives of Economic
Growth, Random House, New York, Walter W. Heller. Editor, 1968.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

24
tax program-including both the 1964 tax cuts and the 1962 investment tax stimulants in ·the form of the investment tax credit and liberalized depreciation guidelines--did in fact improve investment and work incentives and contributes to
good, sustained growth in productivity. But no mdden bulge in productivity and
potential has been found by any close student of the subject.
Yet it would take precisely such a bulge-many times •as big a supply response
as the 1964 tax cut produced-to get the kind of results ,that Senator Roth and
Congressman Kemp claim on •the basis of estimates by Norman B. Ture. There
is no basis in either the 1964 tax cut or any other modern tax cut for Ture's
prediction that a Kemp-Roth tax cut would in little more than a year, generate
4 miHion jobs and boost GNP by $157 billion, and soon boost -tax revenues a·bove
pre-tax cut levels!
Such findings stretch both credulity and facts. As Rudolph Penner of the
American Enterprise Institute puts it, "There can·t be two or three or four times
more bang in a Kemp-Roth tax cut than we've had with any other."
Given no validated evidence that huge tax cuts would generate huge increases
in supply-that is, in productive potential-what would the three-year $98 billion Kemp-Roth tax cut do to 'budget deficits and inflation? l\Iy answer won't
surprise you: 'the huge surge in demand would overwhelm our supply capacity
and soon generate soaring deficits and roaring inflation.
THE "LAFFEB CUBVE"

Increasingly, supporters of Kemp-Roth are drawing aid and comfort from the
"Laffer Curve", a diagram purporting to show how tax changes can suppress or
unleash incen'tives to work and invest and hence affect tax revenues. Some of my
views on the sUJbject are implicit in the foregoing comments. But let me add some
thoughts that go beyond the 1964 tax experience:
The Andrew Mellon tax cuts of the 1920s are cited as evidence to support the
Laffer 'thesis. As. Jude Wanniski flatly put it (in the "Public Interest," Winter
1978) : "As a result [of the :Mellon cuts], the period 1921-1929 was one of phenomenal economic expansion ..." At a time when a relative handful of Americans
paid income taxes and Federal spending .was less than 5 percent of GNP (in
1929, it was 3 percent), we are asked to believe that Federal income tax reduction powered the growth of GNP from $70 billion in 1921 to $103 ·billion in 1929 !
Or take the 1948 tax cuts in West German, also advanced as "evidence" to
support the Laffer thesis. As Chief of Internal Finance and Tax Adviser to General Lucius Clay in our Military Government in Germany in 1947-1948, "I was
there." What actually touched off the great expansion? (1) A tough and successful currency reform; (2) Removal of.wage ,and price con'trols; (3) The Marshall
Plan; (4) Bountiful harvests; (5) Tax reduction and reform. Yet the whole
German "economic miracle" is attributed to tax cuts. (Among other factors, the
2 million expellees and refugees from Eastern Europe, the major source of increased German labor supply in the post-1948 period, are conveniently ignored.)"
In short, the whole Laffer thesis and Kemp-Roth initiative rely excessively
on post hoc, ergo propter hoc reasoning and on a one-dimensional view of the
world. There's more to life than economics, and there's more to economics than
taxes.
Apart from such shaky evidence, the alleged miracle effect of tax cuts in generating great surges of work, savings, investment, and productive potential has
to face such questions as the following:
Why, in the face of Laffer's assertions, has "Denison's Law" held true through
thick and thin for the past 100 years or so? Edward F. Denison of Brookings has
found that U.S. gross private domestic saving has been virtually invariant year-in
• As to the revenue impact of the 1964 tax cuts, the Congressional Budget Office in its
April 1978 Background Paper, "Understanding Fiscal Policy", page 25, concludes that
the economic stimulus of the near-$12 billion tax-cut "recaptures $3 to $9 billion of this
revenue at the end of 2 years." Total revenues, of course. rose much more as GNP rose
$155 billion in the 3 years following the tax-cut but. "there is no model or economist who
would attribute all, or anything approaching all, of this increase to a $12 billion cut in
personal taxes." (One should note that the references to the size of the ,1964-1965 tax-cut
difl'er somewhat depending In part on whether those cuts are looked at on a 1964 or a
1965 economic base and on whether corporate cuts are Included.)
5 The same statistical sin Is committed in (a) attributing to the 1962-64 tax-cut all the
expansion that occurred in 1963-1968. simply Ignoring the huge (over-) stimulus of Vietnam expenditures and (b) attributing to the 1962-64 tax-cut all the revenue increase
that occurred in 1963-68. ignoring Social Security payroll rate and base increases in
1965, 1966, 1967, and 1968 as well as the Tax Adjustment Act of 1966, wliich added $1.2
bUlion to revenues in fiscal year 1966 and $4.6 billion in fiscal year 1967.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

25
and year-out in the face of high taxes, low taxes, or virtually no taxes. Adjusted
to a high-employment level, it has held stubbornly at roughly 16 percent of GNP
for about a century. And investment has necessarily been stuck right there with
it. This simply does not square with the assertion that changes in tax rates
touch off big changes in the will to work, save, and invest.•
And even if there were something to the Laffer thesis, who is to say that we
are in a high enough tax zone to produce those dire effects of higher rates and
delightful effects of lower rates that Laffer postulates? Not Dr. William Fellner
of A.EI: "The U.S. is not yet at high enough tax rates to produce anything like
the revenue explosion Laffer is predicting• * * where the U.S. economy is along
such a curve is completely undocumented, unexplored, and unknown."
And how is it that the Kemp-Roth tax cuts could, by increasing take-home pay
sharply, lead to such an upsurge in the work ethic when a considerably larger
average increase in real take-home pay in the decade of the 1960s (mostly as a
result of sustained economic growth) produced no similar upsurge? People
worked less in response to longer real pay per hour-they took longer vacations
and more holidays, and worked shorter work weeks, i.e., they took out part of the
proceeds of growth in more leisure. Why wouldn't they do the same with the
proceeds of big tax cuts, i.e., respond as much or more to the increase in income
(by working less hard to gain a given target income) as they would to the increase in incentives (by working harder as lower taxes made leisure more "expensive") ? Or to put it in an economic frame, all the explorations of labor
supply, of worker reactions to changes in after-tax income that I know of, cannot
even tell us for sure whether the net will to work is increased or decreased by
a rise in after-tax income.
A 1978 TAX CUT

Lest I be misunderstood, I want to add a few comments, on the wisdom of
a tax cut in 1978 that will, I hope, maintain my credentials as a tax cutter.
Nothing I have said above about the dangers of gigantic tax cuts in 1978-1980
applies to a moderate 1978 tax cut of $15 or $20 billion ( or even $25 billion if
monetary policy tightens a lot): with unemployment still at 6.1 percent and
operating rates in manufacturing still hovering around 84 percent of capacity,
there is still a sizable margin of unused supply potential to accommodate a $15
to $20 billion tax cut. l!:lxpecially in a year when payroll tax boosts and the "inflation tax" are increasing taxpayer liabilities by some $15 biHion, it is economically safe and sound to enact a tax cut to help neutralize this increase and provide some modest stimulus to an economy that would otherwise slow down to
an annual growth rate below 4 percent. It would work to the benefit of output,
jobs, and incomes and pay a good dividend in tax revenues without shoving the
economy into an excess-demand-inflation. Just two supporting comments:
A. careful comparison of key unemployment rates today with those of 1971,
when we were clearly operating well below our potential, shows that they are
just about identical. Rates of unemployment of adult males were 4.4 percent
then and 4.3 percent now (March, April, May average) ; adult females, 5.7 perC'ent then and 6.0 percent now; teenagers, 16.9 percent then and 16.9 percent now;
all persons, 5.9 percent then and 6.1 percent now. And one should recall that it
took a 6.2 percent real GNP growth rate from mid-1971 to 19721V to start
stretching our supply capacity and falling prey to excess demand.
A.part from the need to overcome continued slack in the economy, we need
added stimulus to private investment to serve our major economic goals. To
forego the boost to incentives and markets that a $15 to $20 billion tax cut could
provide might shrink the deficit in fiscal 1979, but it would result in higher unem•
ployment, lower investment, a less vigorous economy, and the risk of higher deficits in fiscal 1980. That would be a poor trade-off indeed.
The econ<;>mic slowdown that will confront the Congress and the country at
the end of 1978 ,vill leave a lot of red faces around here if Congress simply scuttles the Carter tax cut and does nothing. But if instead Congress adopts the
Roth-Kemp super-cut, and thereby guarantees dizzying deficits and sizzling inflation, faces will be even redder.
• The surprising finding by Michael Boskin (reported in the April 1978 "Journal of
Political Economy") of a .3 to .4 Interest elasticity of the saving rate--even thouerh it
runs connter not only to Denlson's Law hnt to vlrtuallv all previous research reR••lts on
this subject-deserves close and critical follow-up by other Investigators. Even if Boskin's
far-out estimate were to be corroborated bv other research. one shonlfl note that a savings
elasticity of .3 to .4 still falls far short of the taxpayer response required t'o support the
sensational jumns in savinirs that und1>rlle the Ture predictions of huge increases In investment, GNP and jobs under the Impact of the Kemp-Roth bill.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

26
APPENDIX

Ea:cerpt8 From Pr~Bident Kennedy'8 January 1963 Economic Report
TAX REDUCTION AND REFORM IN 1963

We approach the issue of tax revision, not in an atmosphere of haste and panic
brought on by recession or depression, but in a period of comparative calm. Yet
if we are to restore the healthy glow of dynamic prosperity to the U.S. economy
and avoid a lengthening of the 5-year period of unrealized promise, we have no
time to lose. Early action on the tax program outlined in my State of the Union
Message-and shortly to be presented in detail in my tax message---will be our
best investment in a prosperous future and our best insurance against recession.
The ReBponBible Citizen and Ta:r Reduction

In this situation, the citizen serves his country's interest by supporting income tax reductions. Jfor through the normal processes of the market economy,
tax reduction can be the constructive instrument for harmonizing public and
private interests:
The taxpayer as consumer, pursuing his own best interest and that of his
family, can turn his tax savings into a higher standard of living, and simultaneously into stronger markets for the producer.
The taxpayer as producer-businessman or farmer--responding to the profit
opportunities he finds in fuller markets and lower tax rates, can simultaneously
create new jobs for workers and larger markets for the products of other factories, farms, and mines.
Tax reduction thus sets off a process that can bring gains for everyone, gains
won by marshalling resources that would otherwise stand idle-workers without
jobs and farm and factory capacity without markets. Yet many taxpayers seem
prepared to deny the nation the fruits of tax reduction because they question the
financial soundness of reducing taxes when the Federal budget is already in deficit. Let me make clear why, in today's economy, fiscal prudence and responsibility
call for tax reduction even if it temporarily enlarges the Federal deficit-why
reducing taxes is the best way open to us to increase revenues.
Our choice is not the oversimplified one sometimes posed, between tax reduction
and a deficit on one hand and a budget easily balanced by prudent management on
the other. If the projected 1964 Federal cash deficit of $10.3 billion did not allow
for a $2. 7 billion loss in receipts owing to the new tax program, the projected
deficit would be $7.6 billion. We have been sliding into one deficit after another
through repeated recessions and persistent slack in our economy. A planned cash
surplus of $0.6 billion for the fiscal year 1959 became a record cash deficit of $13.1
billion, largely as the result of economic recession. A planned cash surplus of $1.8
billion for the current fiscal year is turning into a cash deficit of $8.3 billion,
largely as the result of economic slack. If we were to slide- in to recession- through
failure to act on taxes, the cash deficit for next year would be larger without the
tax redction than the estimated deficit with tax reduction. Indeed, a new recession
could break all peace-time reficit records. And if we were to try to force budget
balance by drastic cuts in expenditures-necE"Ssarily at the expense of defense
and other vital programs-we would not only endanger the security of the country, we would so depress demand, production, and employment that tax revenues
would fall and leave the government budget still in deficit. The attempt would
thus be self-defeating.
So until we restore full prosperity and the budget-balancing revenues it generates, our practical choice is not between deficit and surplus but between two
kinds of deficits: between deficits born of waste and weakness and deficits incurred
as we build our future strength. If an individual spends frivolously beyond his
means today and borrows beyond his prospects for earning tomorrow, this is a
sign of weakness. But if he borrows prudently to invest in a machine that boosts
his business profits, or to pay for education and training that boost his earning
power, this can be a source of strength, a deficit through which he builds a better
future for himself and his family, a defiicit justified by his increased potential.
As long as we have large numbers of workers without jobs, and producers without markets, we will as a Nation fall into repeated deficits of inertia and weakness. But, by comparison, if we enlarge the deficit temporarily as the by-product
of our positive tax policy to expand our economy this will serve as a source of
strength, not a sign of weakness. It will yield rich private dividends in higher
output, faster growth, more jobs, higher profits and incomes; and, by the same

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

27
token, a large pubZio gain in expanded budget revenues. As the economy returns
to full employment, the budget will return to constructive balance.
This would not be true, of course, if we were currently straining the limits
of our productive capacity, when the dollars released by tax reduction would
push against unyielding bottlenecks in industrial plant and skilled manpower.
Then, tax reduction would be an open invitation to inflation, to a renewed pricewage spiral, and would threaten our hard-won balance of payments improvement.
Today, however, we not only have unused manpower and idle plant capacity; new
additions to the labor force and to plant capacity are constantly enlarging our
productive potential. We have an economy fully able and ready to respond to the
stimulus of tax reduction.
Our need today, then, is
To provide markets to bring back into production underutilized plant and
equipment;
To provide inoentives to invest, in the form both of wider markets and larger
profits-investment that will expand and modernize, innovate, cut costs;
Most important, by means of stronger markets and enlarged investment, to
provide jobs for the unemployed and for the new workers streaming into the
labor· force during the sixties-and, closing the circle, the new jobholders will
generate still larger markets and further investment.
It was in direct response to these needs that I pledged last summer to submit
proposals for top-to-bottom reduction in personal and corporate income taxes in
1963-for reducing the tax burden on private income and the tax deterrents to
private initiative that have for too long held economic activity in check. Only
when we have removed the heavy drag our fiscal system now exerts on personal
and business purchasing power and on the financial incentives for greater risktaking and personal effort can we expect to restore the high levels of employment
and high rate of growth that we took for granted in the first decade after the war.
Tar.ces and Consumer Demand

In order to enlarge markets for consumer goods and services and translate these
into new jobs, fuller work schedules, higher profits, and rising farm incomes, I
am proposing a major reduction in individual income tax rates. Rates should be
cut in three stages, from their present range of 20 to 91 percent to the more reasonable range of 14 to 65 percent. In the first stage, beginning July 1, these rate reductions will cut individual liabilities at an annual rate of $6 billion. Most of this
would translate immediately into greater take-home pay through a reduction in
the basic withholding rate. Further rate reductions would apply to 1964 and 1965
incomes, with resutling revenue losses to be partially offset by tax reforms, thus
applying a substantial additional boost to consumer markets.
These revisions would directly increase the annual rate of disposable after-tax
incomes of American households by about $6 billion in the second half of 1963,
and some $8 billion when the program is in full effect, with account taken of both
tax reductions and tax reform. Taxpayers in all brackets would benefit, with
those in the lower brackets getting the largest proportional reductions.
American households as a whole regularly spend between 92 and 94 percent of
the total after-tax (disposable) incomes they receive. And they generally hold to
this range even when income rises and falls; so it follows that they generally
spend about the same percentage of dollars of income added or subtracted. If we
cut about $8 billion from the consumer tax load, we can reasonably expect a direct
addition to consumer goods markets of well over $7 billion.
A reduction of corporate taxes would provide a further increment to the flow of
household incomes as dividends are enlarged; and this, too, would directly swell
the consumer spending stream.
The direct effects, large as they are, would be only the beginning. Rising output
and employment to meet the new demands for consumer goods will generate new
income-wages, salaries, and profits. Spending from this extra income flow would
create more jobs, more production, and more incomes. The ultimate increases in
the continuing flow of incomes, production, and consumption will greatly exceed
the initial amount of tax reduction.
Even if the tax program had no influence on investment spending-either directly or indirectly-the $8-9 billion added directly to the flow of consumer income
would call forth a flow of at least $16 billion of added consumer goods and
services.
But the program will also generate direct and indirect increases in investment
spending. The production of new machines, and the building of new factories,

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

28
stores, offices, and apartments add to incomes in the same way as does production
of consumer goods. 'l'his too sets off a derived chain reaction of consumer spending, adding at least another $1 billion of output of consumer goods for every $1
billion of added investment.
Taa;es and, Investment
To raise the Nation's capacity to produce-to expand the quantity, quality, and
variety of our output-we must not merely replace but continually expand, improve, modernize and rebuild our productive capital. That is, we must invest, and
we must grow.
'l'he past half decade of unemployment and excess capacity has led to inadequate
business investment. In 1962, the rate of investment was almost unchanged from
1957 though gross national product had risen by almost 16 percent, after allowance
for price changes. Clearly it is essential to our employment and growth objectives
as well as to our international competitive stance that we stimulate more rapid
expansion and modernization of America's productive facilities.
As a first step, we have already provided important new tax incentives for
productive investment. Last year the Congress enacted a 7-percent tax credit for
business expenditures on major kinds of equipment. And the Treasury, at my
direction, revised its depreciation rules to reflect today's conditions. Together,
these measures are saving business o,er $2 billion a year-in taxes and significantly
increasing the net rate. of return on capital investments.
The second step in my program to lift investment incentives is to reduce the
corporate tax rate from 52 percent to 47. percent, thus restoring the pre-Korean
rate. Particularly to aid small businesses, I am recommending that effective January 1, 1963, the rate on the first $25,000 of corporate income be dropped from 30
to 22 percent while the 52 percent rate on corporate income over $25,000 is retained. In later stages, the 52 percent rate would drop to 47 percent. These changes
will cut corporate liabilities by over $2.5 billion before structural changes.
The resulting increase in profitability will encourage risk-taking and enlarge
the flow of internal funds which typically finance a major share of corporate investment. In recent periods, business as a whole has not been starved for financial
accommodation. But global totals mask the fact that thousands of small or rapidly
growing businesses are handicapped by shortage of investible funds. As the total
impact of the tax program takes hold and generates pressures on existing capacity, more and more companies will find the lower taxes a welcome source of
finance for plant expansion.
The third step toward higher levels of capital spending is a combination of
structural changes to remove barriers to the full flow of investment funds, to
sharpen the incentives for creative investment, and to move tax-induced distortions in resource flow. Reduction of the top individual income tax rate from 91
to 65 percent is a central part of this balanced program.
Fourth, apart from direct measures to encourage investment, the tax program
wil got to the heart of the main deterrent to investment today, namely, inadequate
markets. Once the. sovereign incentive of high and rising sales is restored, and
the businessman is convinced that today's new plant and equipment will find
profitable use tomorrow, the effects of the directly stimulative measures will be
doubled and redoubled. Thus-and it is no contradiction-the most important
single thing we can do to stimulate investment in today's economy is to raise
consumption by major reduction of individual income tax rates.
Fifth, side-by-side "ith tax measures, I am confident that the Federal Reserve
and the Treasury will continue to maintain, consistent with their responsibilities
for the external defense of the dollar, monetary and credit conditions favorable
to the flow of savings into long-term investment in the productive strength of the
country.
Given a series of large and timely tax reductions and reforms, as I have proposed, we can surely achieve the balanced expansion of consumption and investment so urgently needed to overcome a half decade of slack and to capitalize on
the great and growing economic opportunities of the decade ahead.
The impact of my tax proposals on the budget deficit will be cushioned by the
scheduling of reductions in several stages rather than a single large cut; the
careful pruning of civilian expenditures for fiscal 1964-those other than for
defense, space, and debt service-to levels below fiscal 1963 ; the adoption of a
more current time schedule for tax payments of large corporations, which will at
the outset add about $1½ billion a year to budget receipts; the net offset of $3½
billion of revenue loss by selected structural changes in the income tax; most

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

29
powerfully, in time, by the accelerated growth of taxable income and tax receipts
as the economy expands in response to the stimulus of the tax proi:ram.

Senator BENTSEN. Thank you, Mr. Heller. Our next witness will be
Mr. Henry Kaufman.

STATEMENT OF HENRY KAUFMAN, :PARTNER AND MEMBER OF
THE EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE, SALOMON BROS., NEW YORX, N.Y.
Mr. KAUFMAN. I will try to shorten my prepared statement that I
have submitted.
I am pleased to respond to your request for my vieiws on the outlook
for the American economy and financial markets. But, I must say, that
I am saddened by the conclusions which I have reached from an analysis of the situation. I have concluded that our economy and financial
markets are on a treacherous course. We are in the midst of a volatile
economic recovery and a dangerously high rate of inflation. Cost-push
inflation, to which our Government has contributed importantly
through well-known legislative and administrative decisions, is now
being reinforced by demand-pull inflation as employment continues
to increase and more plant capacity is utilized.
The pressure on the economy this year is due partioularly to the
shrinking availability of skilled help which our aggregate statistics
fail to reveal. Because of a variety of structural problems, full employment today must be considered at a higher rate than the post-World
War II norm of a 4 percent unemployment rate. Indeed, Michael
Wachter of the University of Pennsylvania, in analyzing these structural changes, has concluded that defining full employment as a 4
percent unemployment rate in 1957 is equivalent to defining it at 5.5
percent in 1977.
Similar conclusions have been reached in studies conducted by the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Unfortunately, there are no policies now in place that will readily
curb the growing economic and financial excesses. Indeed, official pronouncements by our Government that inflation is not the No. 1 national problem, is hardly reassuring. They can only be regarded as a
failure in the recent past to perceive correctly the chaUenge.s that confronted us. If the inflation problem had been perceived correctly and
countered with preventive measures, no such admission of failure
would be necessary today, of course, recognizing correctly, the current
problem is a step in the right direction. However, considering the complexity of the current economic and financial situation, I know of no
easy or simple solution. Whatever direction policies will take from here
on will be painful to some sectors, and most likely for the economy as
a whole.
When the present business recovery is viewed in the broadest sense,
two aspects stand out. One is the high degree of volatility in eoonomic
activity. On average, the economy has achieved an annual rate of real
growth of 5.2 percent during the first 3 years of this expansion. This is
not too different from the growth rates attained during the same years
of the business expansion that began in 1961 and 1971. But the quarterly fluctuations in these growth rates have been exceptionally large
since 1915.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
35-570 0 - 79 - 3
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

30
For the 12 quarters involved, the difference between the high and
low re,al growth Tates equals 12 percentage points compared with 8.7
percentage points for the comparable period in 1971 through 1973, and
only 6.3 percentage points for the 1961-63 periods. This economic
volatility is continuing. In this quarter, real growth may be around 10
percent as compared with about zero growth in the first quarter. For
the balance of the year, I would expect real growth in the range of 4
percent to 4.5 percent.
The other distinguishing feature of the present business expansion,
the escalation in the rate of inflation, is ominous. It clearly validates
the expectations of many who doubted the promise of Government to
keep the inflation trendline moving downward.
The tJrend is quite the o_pposite, and the record now shows that the
trend toward irregularly higher inflation rates is intact. This alarming
pattern is clearly demonstrated in table 1 of my prepared statement,
which shows the post-World War II cyclical lows and highs for the inflation rate as measured by the GNP deflator.
For the five cyclical periods, the lows in the inflation rate have moved
progressively higher-from an actual reduction in the price level in
the third quarter of 1949, to an increase of 4.7 pe.rcent in late 1976.
The cyclical peaks ·of inflation have also moved progressively higher
throughout the post-World War II years if one excludes the 1951 high
when we were involved in the Korean war. The inflation peak for this
cycle will probably be established during the next 12 months. "\Ve may
well come close to testing the previous cyclical high of 11.6 percent
which was reached in the early part of 1975.
In evaluating the inflation problem, there is a tendency to explain
much of it away by focusing on food and fuel. While these two sectors
are substantial cost-imbedding factors, they are not alone by any means.
Even excluding food and fuel, the rate of inflation is alarmingly high
today by any historical standard. I demonstrat t'his in ta;ble 2 of my
prepared statement.
Neither fiscal nor monetary policies have functioned effectively to
blunt the inflationary thrust. The most inappropriate actions so far
have come from the fiscal side. By a wide array of yardsticks, the fiscal
posture of the Federal Government this year is ex00$ive, and virtually
without historical precedent.
For example, this year's unified budget deficit is estimated at around
$52 billion. During the comparable years of the two previous economic
recoveries, the deficits totaled only $15 billion and $6 billion, respectively. Federal expenditures in this fiscal year will increase by 12 percent. This annual percentage increase has been exceeded only seven
times during the past 25 years and only once in a nonwar year of economic expansion.
While much has been said during the current economic recovery
about the extent to which the expansionary Fede,ral fiscal policy has
been offset by the surplus that is being generated bv State and local
governments, the net stimulus is still extraordinary. When the data for
the first 3 years of the current economic recovery is examined, we ~nd
that the combined total oomulative public sector budget-Federal,
State, and local~was in significantly greater deficit than in the previous comparable periods of economic recovery. I demonstrated that
in table 3 of my prepared statement.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

31
Monetary policy, however, has been far :from faultless1 althoug?monetary policy operations have been hampered by the outs1zed deficit
of the Federal Government. From a technical viewpoint, the Federal
Reserve has had only mixed results in containing the growth. of the
money supply within the official long-run targets. For example, m each
of the quarters starting mid-1977, the growth of the narrowly defined
money supply-(M-1 )-=-has exceeded the long-run range of tolerances
targeted by the Fed.
More importantly, monetary policy has not been able to confine the
massive debt creation to reasonable limits in this business recovery.
The growth of debt in the United States is proceeding at even a more
reckless pace this year than I had estimated in February, when I reported on this matter to the House Budget Committee.
Think of it in these terms. Outstanding credit market debt of all
sorts rose at annual rates of 7.4 percent :from 1962 to 1971. It accelerated to an annual average of 11 percent from 1972 to 1974. Thus far in
this business recovery, it has increased by 8 percent in 197,5, 11 percent
in 1976, 14 percent in 1977, and in the first half of this year at an
annual rate that probably is even higher.
The cutting edge of monetary restraint, at least so far, is not clearly
visible in the credit markets, even though interest rates have increased
sharply since early 1977 and are high by historical standards.
Today, new issues of AAA-rated utilities are around 9 percent,
mortgage borrowing costs to finance private homes are at 10 percent
in some sections of the country, and long-term Government bonds at
around. 8.5 percent. In the entire post-World War II periods, the
average annual yields in long Government bonds and mortgages have
never been higher than current levels and during only 2 years did
AAA utility yields average higher than they are at the present time.
There are several reasons for the lack of bite from the current high
levels of interest rates. Inflation, as a way of life and policy, is
imbedded in tJhe expectations of both users and suppliers of credit.
Indeed, I know of no creditworthy borrowers that are shocked by the
prevailing structure of interest rates, which not too many years ago
would have been viewed with a lot of consternation.
Probably, inflationary expectations are most deeply imbedded in
the household sector. This is reflected in the record-shattering volume
of consumer credit financing and of mortgage borrowings. Consumer
debt rose at an annual rate of $39 billion during the first 5 months of
this year, as compared with $31 billion for all of 1977 and $21 billion
for 1976.
The inflationary bias of individuals, which is reflected in their
decision to refinance existing homes and to acquire new (?nes, is even
more startling. Many individuals are convinced that not only will
inflation persist, but that homes will increase in value at a rate exceeding the pace of inflation generally. As a consequence, the cost of money
is not as key a determinant in the mortgage financing decision that it
used to be. In turn, new residential mortgage financihg will rise to
record levels this year, perhaps as much as $110 billion net, compared
with $103 billion in 1977, $70 billion in 1976, and an annual average of
$47 billion :from 1971 throu~h 1975.
Another factor that has dulled the restraining influence of interest
rates is the liquidity situation which, in some key sectors, is still quite

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

32
good for the start of the fourth year of economic expansion. For
example, commercial banks still hold most of the $50 billion of U.S.
Government's which they acquired in 1975 and 1976. Their reasonable
liquidity position is also evidenced by their ready willingness to make
loans for a variety of transactions including the financing of mergers
and acquisitions, which is hardly a hallmark of tight money.
Business corporations still have large unused lines of credit at banks,
substantial capacity to issue commercial paper and quite a few leading
corporations have very large reserves of liquid assets. Even our thrift
institutions are somewhat better situated to withstand the initial onslaught of higher interest rates because of longer dated deposits,
enlarged borrowing capacity at the Federal Home Loan Banks and
the innovation of new liquidity instruments such as the issuance of
mortgage-backed. bonds and passthrough certificates.
I must warn -you, however, that the use of liquidity to finance the
operational activities of individual endeavors has two consequences. It
shelters for a while the sector trying to finance its activities through
its own liquidity facility from the restraint usually associated. with
higher interest rates. In this sense, liquidity usage drives the economy
further ahead, but it also pushes interest rates higher unless others
seek less funds or create financial surpluses. But this is not happening
because the credit demands from the private sector are rising this _year,
while tJhe Federal Government is not moving to a surplus position.
The cutting edge of interest rates has also been dulled by important
structural changes in our fina.ncial system. Financial institutions have
been partly liberated from the pressures of rising interest rates
through, among other things, the liberalization of regulation Q ceilings on time and savings deposits, floating interest rates on lending
arra.ngements and access to foreign funds. As a result, they do not
experience the full brunt of restraint themselves, as they had in the
past. Instead, it is the final demander of credit, be it business, households, or governments, who is ultimately restrained by a much higher
level of interest rates.
For the Federal Reserve, the liberation of the financial system from
frictional impediments, which incidentally the Fed has supported,
puts the central bank in a difficult position operationally. In attempting to curb excessive monetary growth, the Fed is forced to ra.ise
interest rates higher than heretofore when frictional devices helped to
restrain monetary creation.
The recent regulation allowing deposit institutions to issue 6-month
consumer certificates of deposit pegged to the Treasury bill rate is
an.other of those changes that will push interest rates higher and complicate the task of monetary restraint. To be sure, this regulation is
well intended. It permits thrift institutions to retain deposits and, at
le~t _to some extent, to attract new funds in support of new housing
activity.
But, if housing is to be cushioned, then who is to be denied credit
when credit formation is excessive? Is it to be the Federal Government, municipalities, or business or some consumer sectors?
Obviously, interest rates will have to move high enough to eliminate
some demanders. The Federal Government will not be denied. Perhaps the inflationary bias among households will persist long enough

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

33.
for them to outbid business, thereby terminating the revival iln business capital spending or, as in the past, business and government. will
outbid the household sector.
·
In any event, the restraining influence of interest rates should be
clearly visible duriing the second half of 1978. Interest rates will be
driven higher by demands for credit which will exceed both genuine
savings generation and the new funds supplied- through the monetary
creation process. Credit demands will be excessive even if money supply grows faster than the officially targeted growth rates.
I have illustrated the problem of net new credit demands of key
sectors for the secO!Ild half of calendar 1978 as compared with the second half of calendar 1977 when these demands were very large.
Against the backdrop of continued high rates of inflation and in the
absence of fiscal restraint, the Federal Reserve has few, if any, palatable monetary options. At first glance, the advice might be to ease up
a little on the credit reins because ec01I1omic growth may be slowing.
This would risk even higher rates of inflation in the future and would
fail to take into account the capacity constraints in the economy. In
addition, it is likely the Fed policy will be limited by the frail position of the dollar in the foreign exchange markets.
I said at the start of this testimO!Ily that there are no simple or painless solutions for the current excesses in the economy and the emerging
credit stringencies. Once again, the timing has been missed in national
stabilization policies in order to facilitate orderly economic growth.
The best we can :now do is to limit the excesses and to ward off severe
damage. What should be done?
Let us lower the official targets for real national product growth to
around 3 percent annually for the near term and use only selective
measures to reduce the number of people who are structurally unemployed.
Let us belatedly reduce the fiscal stimulus by reducing Federal expenditure to the range of $460 or $470 billion for fiscal 1979
and by implemelllting mainly those tax reductions that will encourage
in vestments.
In any event, the credit demands of the Federal Government at this
stage of the economic recovery are much too large. When credit ma,rkets tightened sharply in 1973 and 1974, the net new financiing of the
U.S. Government and its agencies accounted for 13 percent of all
credit demands as compared with an estimated 22 percent this year.
I would also recommend the adoption, or at least further consideration, of the Wallich-Weintraub proposals for reducing inflation
through tax incentives. It is a cumbersome program, but in view of the
precariousness of the current situation it is worth trying.
In the final analysis, however, the key problem which immediately
faces the economic and financial markets is how to constrain large demands for wages in light of the inflation during the past year and the
effective bargaining position of labor due to the shrinking supply of
skilled help. It is quite clear how we got into this dilemma. Unfortunately, history shows that we return to a viable economy only after
an onslaught of financial and ecO!Ilomic shocks.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Kaufman follows:]


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

34
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HENBY KAUFMAN

My name is Henry Kaufman. I am a general partner and member of the Executive Committee of Salomon Brothers, an investment banking and market making firm headquartered in New York City. I also serve as the Firm's chief economist and head of its Bond Ma:rket Researcl} Department.
I am pleased to respond to your reque1;1t for my views on the outlook for the
American economy and financial markets. But, I must say that I am saddened by
the conclusions which I have reached from an analysis of the situation. I have
concluded that our economy and financial markets are on a treacherous course.
We are in the midst of a volatile economic recovery and a dangerously high rate
of inflation. Cost-push inflation, to which our Government has contributed importantly through well-known legislative and administrative decisions, is now
being reinforced by demand-pull inflation as employment continues to increase
and more plant capacity is utilized.
The pressure on the economy this year is due particularly to the shrinking
availability of skilled help which our aggregate statistics fail to reveal. Because of a variety of structural problems, full employment today must be considered at a higher rate than the post World War II norm of a 4 percent unemployment rate. Indeed, Michael Wachter of the University of Pennsylvania, in
analyzing these structural changes, has concluded that defining full employment
as a 4 percent unemployment rate in 1957 is equivalent to defining it at 5½ percent in 1977. Similar conclusions have been reached in studies conducted by the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. If so, full employment is nearly at hand.
Of course, our endeavors sh,ould continue in bringing the structurally unemployed into the work force :but not by using broad stimulative measures which
have been contributing to the rise of inflation.
Unfortunately, there are no policies now in place that will readily curb the
growing economic and financial excesses. Indeed, official pronouncements that inflation is now the number one national- problem is hardly reassuring. They can
only be regarded as a failure in the recent past to perceive correctly the challenges that confronted us. If the inflation problem had been perceived correctly
and countered with preventive measures, no such admission of failure would be
necessary today. Of course, recognizing correctly the current problem is a step in
the right direction. However, considering the complexity of the current economic
and financial situation, I know of no easy or simple solution. Whatever direction
policies will take from hereon will be painful to some sectors and most likely for
the economy as a whole. It is dismaying to me to find that we have learned so
little from the trying economic and financial experiences which began in the mid1960's. As a consequence, we again are confronted with serious imbalances.
•When the present business recovery is viewed in the broadest sense, two aspects stand out. One is the high degree of volatility in economic activity. On average, the economy has achieved an annual rate of real growth of 5.2 percent during the first three years of this expansion. This is not too different from the
growth rates attained during the same years of the business expansion that
began in 1961 and 1971. But, the quarterly fluctuations in these growth rates have
been exceptionally large since 1975. For the twelve quarters involved, the difference between the high and low real growth rates equals 12 percentage points compared with 8.7 percentage points for the comparable period in 1971 through 1973
and only 6.3 percentage points for the 1961-63 period. This economic volatility is
continuing. In this quarter, real growth may be around 10% as compared with
about zero growth in the first quarter. For the balance of the year, I would expect
real growth in the range of 4% to 4½ percent.
The other distinguishing feature of the present business expansion, the escalation in the rate of inflation, is ominous. It clearly validates the expectations of
many who doubted the promise of Government to keep the inflation trendline
moving downward. The trend is quite the opposite and the record now shows
that the trend towards irregularly higher inflation rates is intact. This alarming pattern is clearly demonstrated in Table 1, which shows the post World War
II cyclical lows and highs for the inflation rate, as measured by the GNP deflator. For the five cyclical periods, the lows in the inflation rate have moved progressively higher-from an actual reduction in the price level in the third quarter
of 1949 to an increase of 4.7 percent in late 1976. The cyclical peaks of inflation
have also moved progressively higher throughout the post World War II years if
one excludes the 1951 high when we were involved in the Korean War. The inflation peak for this cycle will probably be established during the next twelve

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

35
months. We may well come close to testing the previous cyclical high of 11.6
percent which was reached in the first quarter of 1975.
In evaluating the inflation problem, there is a· tendency to explain much of it
away by focusing on food and fuel. While these two sectors are substantial costimbedding factors, they are not alone by any means. IDven excluding food and
fuel, the rate of inflation is alarmingly high today by any historical stanard. As
shown in Table 2, the wholesale price index, excluding these two sectors of food
and fuel, has increased at a seasonally adjusted rate of 9.2 percent during the
first five months of 1978. This equals the 1973 high rate and was exceeded only
two times in the past thirty years--in 1950, a Korean War year, and in 1974.
!Neither fiscal nor monetary policy have functioned effectively to blunt the inflationary thrust. The most inappropriate actions so far have come from the fiscal
side. By a wide array of yardsticks, the fiscal posture of the Federal Government
this year is excessive and virtually without historical precedent. For example,
thi-s year's unified budget deficit is estimated at around $52 billion. During the
comparable years of the two previous economic recoveries, the deficits totalled
only $15 billion and $6 billion, respectively. Federal expenditures in this fiscal
year will increase by 12 percent. This annual percentage increase has been exceeded only seven times during the past 25 years and only once in a non-war
year of economic expansion. While much has been said during the current economic recovery about the extent to which the expansionary Federal fiscal policy
ha•s been offset by the surplus that is being generated by state and local governments, the net stimulus is still extraordinary. When the data for the first three
years of the current economic recovery is examined, we find that the combined
total cumulative public sector budget (Federal, state and local) was in significantly greater deficit than in the previous comparable periods of economic recovery. As shown in Table 3, the ratio of the cumulative public sector deficit to
gross national product in the first three years of the present business expansion
was 27.5 percent, at least four times greater than in any prior comparable period.
Monetary policy, however, has been far from faultless, although monetary
policy operations have been hampered by the outsized deficit of the Federal Government. 1''rom a technical viewpoint, the Federal Reserve has had only mixed
results in containing the growth of the money supply within the official long-run
targets. For example, in each of the quarters starting mid-1977, the growth of
the narrowly defined money supply (Ml) has exceeded the long-run range of
tolerances targeted by the Fed. More importantly, monetary policy has not been
able to confine the massive debt creation to reasonable limits in this business
recovery. The growth of debt in the U.S. is proceeding at even a more reckless
pace this year than I had estimated in February when I reported on this matter
to the House Budget Committee. Think of it in these terms. Outstanding credit
market debt rose at annual rates of 7.4 percent from 1962 to 1971. It accelerated
to an annual average of 11 percent from 1972 to 1974. Thus far in this business
recovery, it has increased by 8 percent in 1975, 11 percent in 1976, 14 percent in
1977, and in the first half of this year at an annual rate that probably is even
higher.
The cutting edge of monetary restraint, at least so far, is not clearly visible in
the credit markets, even though interest rates have increased sharply since early
1977 and are high by historical standards. Today, new is-sues of AAA-rated utilities are around 9 percent, mortgage borrowing costs to finance private homes are
at 10 percent in some sections of the country, and long-term Government bonds at
8½ percent. In the entire post World War II periods, the average annual yields
in long Government bonds and mortgages have never been higher than current
levels and during only two years did AAA utility yields average higher than they
are presently. There are several reasons for the lack of bite from the current high
levels of interest rates. Inflation as a way of life and policy is imbedded in the
expectations of both users and suppliers of credit. Indeed, I know of no creditworthy borrowers that are shocked by the prevailing structure of interest rates,
which not too many years ago, would have been viewed with consternation.
Probably, inflationary expectations are most deeply imbedded in the household sector. This is reflected in the record-shattering volume of consumer credit
credit financing and of mortgage borrowings. Consumer debt rose at an annual
rate of $39 billion during the first five months of this year, as compared with
$31 billion for all of 1977 and $21 billion for 1976. The inflationary bias of individuals, which is reflected in their decision to refinance existing homes and to
acquire new ones, is even more startling. Many individuals are convinced that
not only will inflation persist but that homes will increase in value at a rate

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

36
exceeding the pace of inflation generally. As a consequence, the cost of money
is not as key a determinant in the mortgage financing decision that it used to
be. In turn, new residential mortgage financing will rise to record levels this
year, perhaps as much as $110 billion net compared with $103 billion in 1977,
$70 billion in 1976 and an annual average of $47 billion from 1971 through
1975.
These aggressive financing demands of the household sectors pose risks which
cannot be adequately measured by existing data. While the number of wage
earners and the income of households is increasing, it is also true that debt
service burdens are mounting. Repayments on mortgage and consumer debt
combined as a percent of disposable income are about to reach new highs. As
debt service requirements will preempt a larger share of earnings, the risks
increase for a slowing in economic activity. In turn, when economic activity
slows or contracts, these debt service burdens impact discretionary spending.
Another factor that has dulled the restraining influences of interest rates is
the liquidity situation which, in some key sectors, is still quite good for the
start of the fourth year of economic expansion. For example, commercial banks
still hold most of the $50 billion of U.S. Governments which they acquired in
1975 and 1976. Their reasonable liquidity position is also evidenced by their
ready willingness to make loans for a variety of transactions including the financing of mergers and acquisitions which is hardly a hallmark of tight credit.
Business corporations still have large unused lines of credit at banks, substantial capacity to issue commercial paper and quite a few leading corporations
have very large reserves of liquid assets. Even our thrift institutions are somewhat better situated to withstand the initial onslaught of higher interest rates
because of longer-dated deposits, enlarged borrowing capacity at the Federal
Home Loan Banks and the innovation of new liquidity instruments such as the
issuance of mortgage-backed bonds and pass-through certificates. I must warn
you, however, that the use of liquidity to finance the operational activities of
individual endeavors has two consequences. It shelters for a while the sector
trying to finance its activities through its own liquidity facility from the restraint usually associated with higher interest rates. In this sense, liquidity
usage drives the economy further ahead, but it also pushes interest rates higher
unless others seek less funds or create financial surpluses. But this is not happening because the credit demands from the private sector are rising this year,
while the Federal Government is not moving to a surplus position.
The cutting edge of interest rates has also been dulled by important structural
changes in our financial system. Financial institutions have been partly liberated
from the pressures of rising interest rates through, among other things, the
liberalization of Regulation Q ceilings on time and savings deposits, floating interest rates on lending arrangements and access to foreign funds. As a result,
they do not experience the full brunt of restraint themselves, as they had in the
past. Instead, it is the final demander of credit, be it business, households or
governments, who is ultimately restrained by a much higher level of interest
rates.
For the Federal Reserve, the liberation of the financial system from frictional
impediments, which incidentally the Fed has supported, puts the central bank
in a different position operationally. In attempting to curb excess monetary
growth, the Fed is forced to raise interest rates higher than heretofore when
frictional devices helped to restrain monetary creation. The recent regulation
allowing deposit institutions to issue 6-month consumer certificates of deposit
pegged to the Treasury bill rate is another of those changes that will push interest rates higher and complicate the task of monetary restraint. To be sure, this
regulation is well intended. It permits thrift institutions to retain deposits and,
at least to some extent, to attract new funds in support of new housing activity.
But, if housing is to be cushioned, then who is to be denied credit when credit
formation is excessive? Is it to be the Federal Government, municipalities or
business? Obviously, interest rates will have to move high enough to eliminate
some demanders. The Federal Government will not be denied. Perhaps the inflationary bias among households will persist long enough for them to outbid
business, thereby terminating the revival in business capital spending or, as in
the past, business and Government will outbid the household sector.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

37
In any event, the restraining influence of interest rates should be clearly
visible during the second half of 1978. Interest rates will be driven higher by
demands for credit which will exceed both genuine savings generation and the
new funds supplied through the monetary creation process. Credit demands will
be excessive even if money supply grows fas,ter than the officially targeted growth
rates. To illustrate the problem, here are estimates of net new credit demands of
key sectors for the second half of calendar 1978 as compared with the second
half of calendar 1977 when these demands were very large.
[In billions of dollars)
1978

1977

57
55
Mortgages (privately financed) _____________________________________________ ------42
External financing of business corporations'---------------------------------------24
Consumer credit________________________________________________________________
37
33
U.S. Government (privately financed)______________________________________________
16
Federal credit agencies (privately financed)________________________________________
State and local governments __________________________________________________________1_0_ _ _ __
174
180
TotaL_ ____ __ ________________________ ________ __ ______________ ________ ___

~i

g

1

Excluding mortgages.

Against the backdrop of continued high rates of inflation and in the absence
of fiscal restraint, the Federal Reserve has few, if any, palatable monetary
options. At first glance, the advice might be to ease up a little on the credit reins
because economic growth may be slowing. This would risk even higher rates of
inflation in the future, and would fail to take into account the capacity constraints in the economy. In addition, it is likely the Fed policy will be limited
by the frail position of the dollar in the foreign exchange markets.
I said at the start of this testimony that there are no simple or painless solutions for the current excesses in the economy and the emerging credit stringencies. Once again, the timing has been missed in national stabilization policies
in order to facilitate orderly economic growth. The best we can now do is to
limit the excesses and to ward off severe damage. ,vhat should oe done?
Let us lower the official targets for real national product growth to around
3% annually for the near term and use only selective measures to reduce the
number of people who are structurally unemployed.
Let us belatedly reduce the fiscal stimulus by reducing Federal expenditures
to the range of $460 billion to $470 billion for fiscal 1979 and by implementing
mainly those tax reductions that will encourage investments. Even if these fiscal
measures are adopted, it would be unwise to expect that the return to stability
would be reached quickly. The reduced fiscal stimulus might be offset by enlarged
demands from the private sector which, after all, would still be operating at
high capacity. The effort would nevertheless be worthwhile in improving the
mix of economic expansion. A slower rate of Federal spending, which is primarily consumer-oriented, might slow the excesses in the household sectors and
reductions in the capital gains tax and higher investment tax credits would
probrubly encourage capital outlays. In any event, the credit demands of the
l<'ederal Government at this stage of the economic recovery are much too large.
When credit markets tighten sharply in 1973 and 1974, the net new financing
of the U.S. Government and its agencies accounted for 13% of all credit demands
as compared with an estimated 22% this year.
I would also recommend the adoption of the Wallich-Weintraub proposals for
reducing inflation through tax incentives. It is a cumbersome program, but in
view of the precariousness of the current situation, it is worth trying.
In the final analysis, however, the key problem which immediately faces the
economic and financial markets is how to constrain large demands for wages in
light of the inflation during the past year and the effective bargaining position
of labor due to the shrinking supply of skilled help. It is quite clear how we got
into this dilemma. Unfortunately, history shows that we return to a viable
economy only after an onslaught of financial and economic shocks.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

38
TABLE 1.-POSTWAR INFLATION CYCLES
(GNP deftator)
Percent
change 1

Trough quarter
1949·3••••••.••••••••••••••••••.•....
1953·4•••••••••.•..•.•.•.•....•••..••
1961 ·1. ••••••••••••••••••...••...•.••
1972 ·2••.•.•...••.•••••••.••......•..
1976 ·4•••••••••.....••••.•••••••.••..

Percent
change 1

Peak quarter

-2.5

1951 ·1 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••
1957 ·1 ••••••••••.••••.••••.•••.••••
1970 ·l •••.•••.•••••..•••••. ••·•·•· •
1975 ·1 ••.....••...•••..•...•••.••••
1978·1 ••••••••.•.•.•.•..•••••.•.•.•

.3
•6

3.9
4. 7

I

8. 8
4.0

5. 7
11.6
• 8-10. 0

1 Annual rate of change from same period in preceding year.
1 Korean war.
a Estimated.

TABLE 2.-WHOLESALE PRICES LESS FARM PRODUCTS AND PROCESSED FOODS AND FUEL AND RELATED PRODUCTS
(Percentage change: December to December)
Years

Change

Years

1948•••••..•••.•.
1949•••••••••••••
1950••••••••••.•.
1951. •••••.••••.•
1952•••••••••••.•
1953•••••••••••••
19li_4•••.•.••.•.••
1955•••.•.•.••.••
1956•••.•••.•• .-•.
1957••••••••••••.
1958•••••...••.•.

4. 84
-4.84
15.23
• 07
-1.56

1959 •.••••.•.••••
1960 .•.•...••••••
1961. •.•...••••.•
1962 •••••••••••.•
1963•••••••••••••
1964 ••••••••••.•.
1965 ••....•••.•••
1966•..••••.••...
1967•••·••••••••••
1968- ·••·••••·••·
1969••.••••••••.•

1

1.16

• 67
4.66
4.15
.96
1.30

Change
1. 44
-1.21
. 03
-.26
.78
. 85
1.22
2.21
2.13
2.86
3.84

Years

Change

1970 •••••••••••••
1971. ...•.•••.•.•
1972 •••••·••.•.•.•
1973•••••••••••••
1974 •••••••••.•••
1975••.••.••.•.•.
1976.·•.•·..•.••.•.
1977 •..•••••...•.
1978 1••••••••••••

2.86
3. 50
3.30
9.24
22.37
5.03
6.16
5.86
9.21

5 months, annual rate.
TABLE 3.-CYCLICAL PROFILE OF PUBLIC SECTOR NET BUDGET POSITIONS IN THE POSTWAR PERIOD

First 3 years of business cycle expansions

Cumulative net budget, surplus(+) or deficit(-) Relative im•
- - - - - - - - - - - - - pacttoGNP
Federal State and local
Total
(percent)

1954-57...•.•..•....•.•......•....•.....••.•..•....
1958-60 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••
1961-69 .•.•.•••..•..•••.••••......•.....••........•
1970-73.•.•.•••..•.••.•.•..•.••...•.•....•....•.•.•
1975-78..•••••••••.••••.•••..•....•...•....•....•.•

+10.6
-3.7
-7.6
-46.0
-175.5

-3.3
-1.4
+1.0
+30.4
+61.1

+1.2
-5.2
-6.6
-15.6
-114.5

-6.7
4. 7
4.8
6. 2
27.5

• Expansion lasted only 2 years.

Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much, Mr. Kau:fnian. We have
some panelists here with some very strong views, and men who are
very learned in their profession. In :fact, we were commenting up here
that we don't think we could have put together a more distinguished
panel to discuss the subject.
Our next witness is Mr. Jay Schmiedeskamp. It is my understanding
that you have a transportation problem, and we appreciate having
your testimony. \Ve will direct such questions as we have, and then we
will excuse you to make your plane conned-ion.

STATEMENT OF lAY SCHMIEDESKAMP, RESEARCH DIRECTOR,
GALLUP ECONOMIC SERVICE, PRINCETON, N.1.
Mr. ScHMIEDESKAMP. Thank you very much. I appreciate that. I
have to make a 1 o'clock plane.
As background, let me stress that I am an economist. Although my
special field of expertise-for nearly 20 years-has been conducting

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

39
nationwide surveys of consumer attitudes and expectations, nevertheless I regard these surveys as providing only one import~nt input 1-:<>
forecasts of changes in consumer spendmg. Therefore, while my testimony today will make reference to a number of specific recent survey
findings, my conclusions are necessarily based not just on those findings, but rather on careful study over many years of a wide variety
of economic data.
At present, Gallup is the only organization in the country conducting monthly indepth nationwide representative surveys of consumer
attitudes and expectations with personal interviews.
In addition, Ga.llup has recently begun to conduct, in collaboration
with the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, indepth quarterly surveys of
top business executive attitudes and expectations. To my knowledge,
this is the first time that has been done anywhere in the world.
As the only witness in these hearings whose job it is to study consumers, as opposed to just studying statistics about consumer behavior,
I feel a special responsibility. Consumers have amply demonstrated
their great power to influence the course of economic events.
I believe that a strong case can be made that a downward shift in
consumer spending has been the primary cause of each recession since
Wold War II. Certainly that was the case in 1973-74, at which time
consumer surveys provided practically the only leading indicator of
that downturn.
The recent success of Proposition 13 in California reminds us that
consumers have not only great power in the marketplace, but also at
the polling place. The vote on Pvoposition 13 reflects the great intensity of consumer concern with the financial pressure on their pocketbooks at present.
In my opinion, the economy has substantial upward momentum at
present. Over the past year, there has been an enormous increase in
the number of people with jobs, up bv about 4 million. The economy
has recovered well from the adverse effects of winter weather and the
coal strike. Led by fast-paced auto sales and a near-boom in housing,
consumer credit has been expanding at a record rate in recent months.
Contrary to the expectations of some expert observers who foresaw
greater volatility, the current economic recovery from recession has
proven to be quite durable. As we are already well into the fourth
year, this ranks as one of the longer periods of economic expansion
since World "\Var II.
In many respects, this recovery remains rather well balanced. Because of an unsatisfactory level of business investment in new plant
during- this recovery period, there is little sign of the problem of overcapacity which has characterized most previous downturns. Inventories remain under good control. Consumers are not overextended,
although it must be noted that both sides of their balance sheets have
shown unusual growth in the last several years. Both the incurrence
of instal1ment debt and flows into savings institutions have been quite
strong.
However, there are some very important and significant indications
of imbalance in our economy :
First, inflation is certainly the No. 1 concern of consumers at present, and inflationary expectations have become increasingly pessimistic. The percent of consumers expecting the rate of inflation to become

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

40
worse during the next 12 months increased from 22 percent in January
1977, to 36 percent in January 1978, to 50 percent in May 1978.
To say that consumers resent inflation would be the understatement
of the year. In May 1978, 48 percent expected that their income would
go up less than prices during the next 12 months, while only 11 percent
expected inoome to go up more than prices. Those are pessimistic
expectations.
In _passing, it should be noted that consumers' great concern about
inflation goes far toward explaining the intensity of consumer feeling
about property taxes, as reflected in the Proposition 13 vote. From
the consumers' standpoint, a rise in the taxes they pay is inflation, in
exactly the same way as is a rise in the price they pay for meat or for
cars. However, there is one important difference: While consumers
feel helpless to do anything about rises in general inflation, they mwy
feel that they can do something about ta.xes. There is a great focus
of concern on property taxes in particular because the ballot box provides a means to roll them back.
A second imbalance is interest rates, whiich have risen very rapidly
in recent months, and credit conditions, as very well outlined by the
previous witness. The Gallup surveys show that many consumers and
businessmen expect interest rates to continue to rise in the months
ahead. For this reason, demand is not very responsive to interest rate
increases. Consumers reason that they should buy ,a house before the
rising cost of the house and of the mortgage mooey needed to buy the
house exceeds their ability to pay. Businessmen increasingly worry
about the prospect of further credit tightening, and so do what they
can to increase further their liquidity and extend their lines of credit.
Not so incidentally, business efforts to increase liquidity and to
extend lines of credit result in an increase in both commercial loans
and compensating balances at banks, which in turn lead to a higher
rate of growth in the money supply. Particularly in these circumstances, in my opinion, the rate of growth in the money supply provides an especially inappropriate guide to what the proper monetary
policy should be. I have long been of the opinion that monetary policy
should be judged primarily on the basis of its practical effect on the
behavior of consumers and businessmen, and that the rate of growth
in the money supply is an overly simplistic, and very often misleading
approach to the problem.
A third imbalance is that to an extraordinary extent, the American
people lack confidence in the ability of the Government to achieve its
economic objectives. In May 1978, only 12 percent of consumers believed that their government would go a good job in its economic
policy during the next year or two, down from 32 percent j_n March of
1977, which in turn was substantially below the level of a, decade ago.
This lack of confidence, because it contributes directly to pessimistic
expectations about inflation, in fact makes it more difficult to solve
the problem of inflation. Increasing confidence in government should
be a top priority in this country today.
Because of these imbalances, and a few other more minor considerations, the recovery is increasingly vulnerable at present:
(a) The housing industry is always particularly vulnerable to
lessened credit availability. Under present circumstances, while housing demand may not be very responsive to rising interest rates, there

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

41
are reasons to believe that it may be especially sensitive to tightened
credit availability. For one thing, many consumers have had a tendency to buy a larger house than they normally would, simply because
they view a house as a good investment. As credit becomes less available, banks step up their requirements for downpayments and mortga,ge applicant balance sheets, thereby making 1t more difficult for
consumers to make this kind of investment.
Refinancing of older housing, and second mortgages, hav~ been an
important source of funds for oonsumers in the last several years.
Thls kind of credit is among the first to be cut ·back as mortgage
funds become less available.
In my judgment, under these circumstances, the Federal Reserve
Board should have its eyes fixed firmly on credit availability, and the
impact of credit availability on our economy, rather than on interest
rates which have a relatively small effect on business and consumer
behavior under present conditions, or on the money supply which is
an especially poor guide at present for reasons already explained.
The survey provides strong evidence that the average consumer has
continued to channel substantial savings flows into savmgs institutions
until quite recently. In other words, the shortfall of these savings flows
since the first of the year may be a result of disintermediation to a
greater degree than is generally recognized.
( b) A second source of vulnerability in our economy is that during
1977 and 1978 consumers have become increasingly pessim,istic about
the economic outlook. In May 1978, fully 51 percent expected bad
times druring the next 5 years, while only 23 percent expected good
times to prevail. However, all through 1977 and so far in 1978 the
Gallup surveys have shown that not many people have been thinking
about the economy. Most people have managed to make it through the
day quite nicely without thmking about the economy once, unlike
several years ago when the economy was much on people's minds. And
so the growing pessimism about the economic outlook has had relatively little ad.verse effoot on consumer spending.
However, this increased pessimism meant that consumer attitudes
have become increasingly vulnerable to any bad news which would
focus attention on the economy, and translate the pessimism about the
economy into concern about the economy.
Thus fur in 1978, the increase in inflationary concern has not focused increased consumer attention on economic concerns or on the
danger of a recession. To an increasing extent, consumers have come
to view inflation and recession as two separate problems. Therefore,
thus far in 1978 greatly increased inflationary concerns have not had
much adverse effect on consumer spending.
Many people believe tha,t since prices are going up, now is a good
time to buy. With respect to cars in particular, the survey provides
evidence that, at least in March, April, and May, the expectation of
a high rate of price increase may have even stimulated auto sales,
although the May survey data suggest that this "buy-in-advance"
psychology may now be on the wane.
However, the combination of enoJ.1Illous concern about inflation and
great pessimism iabout the economy has the potential for ca;using a
sharp falloff in consumer spending, if consumers should get the idea


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

42
that their Gover:nment is trying to slow down the economy in order
to fight inflation.
While many people may doubt the Government's ability to achieve
its economic objectives in general, people do not doubt the Government's ability to slow the economy. The past record is that when the
Government tries to do this, they succeed all too well.
In 1969, the buzz word was "gradualism." Instead, a recession
resulted. ,In 1974, the target seems to have been a "growth recession."
Instead, a severe recession was the result.
In my opinion, the main reason the Government tends to overshoot
its objective is that it does not allow for declines in consumer and
business confidence. As the economy slows, businessmen reduce their
investment by more than their sales go down, and consumers reduce
their spending by more than their income goes down.
In passing, I think it is important to note that econometric models
tend to do best in years when there are not significant changes in the
economy; 1977 was a very dull year, and that is a survey finding:
There was very little economic news which influenced consumers'
attitudes and expectations. Presumably, the same was true with respect to businessmen's attitudes and expectations.
My belief is that !l,t present the odds are greatly increased for a
recession later this year, or more likely, early next. The short-term
outlook is good because of (1) the current momentum in the economy, (~) increased State and local spending, and (3) the increases
in the labor force and incomes that we have had.
However, in my judgment, particularly if the Federal Reserve sticks
with its present policy of high interest rates, and most particularly
with its policy which I believe is leading very quickly to severe credit
availability problems, then I believe we may be on a collision course
with recession.
I believe, and Chairman Miller has expressed this view, that the
best economic policy is one of moderation, one that avoids extremes.
In that connection, I think a policy of the Federal Reserve Board
which would result in a recession would be an extreme polic_y.
Unless the economy is overheated, which I believe it 1s not now,
Govemment economic policies which risk recession are inappropriate.
At present, I believe that the risk of recession far outweighs the risk
that the economy may become overheated.
A recession acts to reduce real growth, productivity, and business
investment. In my opinion, a shortfiall in these thing-s in recent years
is the main reason why we have a high rate of inflation today.
Therefore, taking the long view, one should not advocate making
the economy sick in order to make it well.
One of the most important problems which we have in this country
today is the lack of training of our work force. I think we have •a
serious productivity problem, in large part simply because we have
had a rotten economy for most of the last 8 or 9 years. It is an unfortunate truth that most of the useful vocational training takes place
"on the job." When you have a labor force underutilized for long
periods of time, the training, the human capital formation, does not
take place.
In terms of hUlillan capital formation, the cost of the two recent
recessions has been extraordinary, particularly because they occurred

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

43
at a time when so many of the underutilized workers were under age
25 and potential labor force entrants.
In conclusion, I would just simply like to make the point that in
my opinion anything which reduces productivity per capita makes
worse the longrun problem of inflation. I believe that another recession would do that an an.. extreme degree, and therefore we should be
very conservative in our policies in terms of avoiding the risk of recession. That risk is now substantial.
Senator PROXMIRE [presiding]. Thank you.
Senator Bentsen had to leave. As he indicated, we will give you
some questions first, Mr. Schmiedeskamp, and then dismiss you, and
concentrate on your fellow colleagues.
Mr. Schmiedeskamp, one of the theses I have seen proposed in
Business Week and Fortune magazine, and a number of other fine
publications, is the quality of consUJlller expenditures that ha~e
changed. They ,argue that the consumer-and you are an expert m
this area-in the past, in inflationary periods, has pulled in his horns,
has gotten into a more liquid position, preparing for a catastrophe.
But today, that consumer is taking advantage of the prices he thinks
may be much higher than they will be later on, and buying much
more than he would ordinarily buy.
•
The concern is that· he might be making purchases now that he
would otherwise make in the future, and therefore, if he buys an automobile in 1978, he will not buy that car in 1979. If he buys a house
now, he will not buy a house later.
Did you find in your surveys that the positive, objective indication
is that there has been this kind of change in the quality of consumer
attitudes?
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. I think you are quite correct that the ordinary
consumer reaction to inflation has been to cut down spending. That
has been the experience over many years.
However, there have been several periods when we have observed
a strong "buy-in-advance" psychology, whereby peoµle reason thev
should buy now before prices go up. That was certainly the case all
through 1973 and the first half of 1974, when we had a series of events
which kept the fear of future inflation more intense than concern
about the inflation which had already occurred. That is a necessary
ingredient of a buy-in-advance psychology.
In 1977, the buy-in-advance psychology did not play a very important role in stimulating consumer spending. It was a very passive
reaction to inflation. If you asked people whether it was a good time
to buv, many said that if you were going to buy anyway, you might
as well buy now; prices will never be any lower.
In 1978, we find a more active buy-in-advance psychology which
stimulated consumer spending. However, this stimulus has been primarily limited to cars, simply because car price increases have come
along so frequently, and have been so visible at a time wlien people
are interested in buying automobiles.
In my judgment, there has been some buying in advance, some
borrowing from future sales, with respect to cars. But I think there
are other reasons why auto sales are doing well, and will continue
to do fairly well the rest of this year.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The industry has been very successful in getting across the image
that a new car is an efficient package that is worth buying, and that
it will save considerable amounts of gasoline. That is a beautiful
built-in sales tool.
Senator PRoxMIRE. At any rate, your general conclusion is that the·
buy-in-advance psychology, and maybe borrowing from the future,
is rather restricted, limited to automobiles, rather than being a general
idea.
What strikes me about the reactions of all you gentlemen, particularly Mr. Schmiedeskamp and Mr. Kaufman, is the general note of
pessimism. You may be dead right, but I think there is very little recognition in the country somehow of the tremendously good economic
year we had in some respects.
In inflation, it was very serious. But we had a remarkable increase
in employment, the biggest increase in employment in the history of
this country; and consequently, a big increase in family income, real
income as well as money mcome.
It seems to me that that growth of the workforce which has grown
so rapidly is something that should give us some heartened encouragement about the economy.
What is your reaction i
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. First of all, let me try to explain why consumers are so pessimistic about the economy when, in fact, I share
your view that the economy has been doing quite well, except for inflation. One of the main reasons for pessimism, of course, is the fact
that inflation tends to produce pessimism.
Whenever inflation is intense, it is greatly resented and tends to
make people pessimistic about the future. The point is that most
people have had income gains in recent years. The world is full of
people who make $15,000 or $20,000 who have long dreamed about
making that much money, and they are in fact now little or no better
off than they were when they made much less.
If you ask people why their income went up, they say it is because
they have worked. hard. It is a meritorious increase. If you ask them
why we have inflation, they don't know. That is someone else's fault.
They have nothing to do with it.
People resent something which seems to deny them from reaping
the benefit of their hard-earned gains.
Senator PROXMIRE. You said in the course of your remarks that
consumers are resentful, and they are particularly mistrusting Government, and that this lack of confidence is a serious economic problem.
What do you think are the most important things that Government
can do to overcome that, that are practical i Obviously, we can try to
adopt policies to restrict it. Wage-price controls are not supported
politically. There is no support for them anywhere.
These other measures to hold down prices are important, but not
likely to hold down prices. In the meantime, you have inflation. Is
there anything we can do in the short run to restore that confidence,
or do you think we should follow a policy-let me put it this way:
Cutting spending, cutting the deficit, are those the important measures
that the Federal Government can take to restore confidence i
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. I think you are asking me for what is essentially a personal opinion as an economist.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

45
Senator PROXMIRE. You are not only an economist, you are an expert in consumer attitudes. You are one of the top experts in this
country.
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. From the standpoint of consumers, I think the
only thing that will really succeed in establishing- confidence is success
in getting down the rate of inflation and avoidmg a recession.
My own personal opinion is that the best way to do that is, most
importantly, as I said at the end of my testimony, to avoid Government policies which tend to lessen productivity per capita. I personally believe that it is terribly important to think in terms of per capita
rather than per worker.
For example, increasing the size of the Government tends to lessen
productivity, unless you believe-as is assumed in the standard calculation of productivity figures-that the output of the additional
Government workers is equal in value to the wages paid to them.
There are any number of Government programs, and the Gallup
business survey shows this very, very clearly, which tend to inhibit new
business investment, and thereby reduce productivity gains in the private sector.
There are any number of things which tend to lessen productivity
in general: The increased real cost of obtaining energy; the low level
of business investment; the large amounts of what business investment there is going to clean up the air and water, and so forth.
All of these things which increase costs and/or lessen productivity
tend to work their way into increased inflation. Therefore, any policy
which has as its result lessening productivity, real growth, and business investment increases inflation over the long term. And that is
why I emphasize again, I think it is terribly important to try to have
policies now which lessen the risk of recession.
In my judgment, the risk of recession is greatly more than the risk
of overheating, looking to the end of this year.
Senator PROXMIRE. My time is up.
Senator Roth.
Senator RoTH. I will be very brief. I do have one question.
We are all familiar with Proposition 13 of California. You mentioned that people are making higher incomes, but not progressing
that much as far as actual purchasing power is concerned.
Do you think that a general tax reduction would build some confidence mto the consumer market 1
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. There is no question, in my judgment, that a
tax reduction would receive the approval of consumers. When a tax
rebate was proposed last year and then taken away, the survey findings
at that time were quite clear: People were in favor of the tax cut, not
because they felt it would help the economy; not because they felt it
would help in the battle against inflation-although interestingly
enough, there were more people with that opinion than with the opposite opinion-rather people were in favor of tax cuts for the very simple
reason that they wanted the money and felt they needed the money.
That is not the answer you are looking for. That survey finding
should not be taken as a reason why we should have a tax cut or not
have a tax cut.
However, my own opinion is that one thing wrong with the economic policy recently is the fact that we have had a rather stimulative

35-570 0 - 79 - 4
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

46
fiscal stance, together with a rather restrictive monetary policy, and
that is a poor way to stimulate business investment.
Senator ROTH. From the standpoint of inflation, there are many
people who feel that you might help relieve that pressure for larger
wage demands, as well as other salary increases, if they were able to
keep more.
Do you subscribe to that theory?
Mr. ScHMIEDESKAMP. No. I believe that those two things really have
very little to do with one another. I personally believe that the main
thrust behind wage demands is the demand to make up for inflation
that has already occurred, plus inflation that is expected, and plus
productivity gains, whether they are there or not.
Just to illustrate what I mean, if you can imagine a labor-management negotiation between George Meany and management, it would
not do management any good to say, "Look, your workers are better
off and therefore should accept a lower rate of wage increases because
the air is cleaner, the water is cleaner, the Arabs are living better."
In those respects, Mr. Meany would think you had changed the subject.
He is interested in the real income of his workers. He wants to catch
up to inflation, and for productivity gains whether they are there or
not.
Senator RoTH. One economist ·has proposed, I believe from Brookings, that tax cuts be tied to keeping wage demands or price demands
down. Do you buy that?
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. I personally see very little connection between
the two from the standpoint of consumer attitudes.
Senator RoTH. Economists always interest me. It is like lawyers,
when you get several of them together, you have different points of
view.
Thank you, Senator Proxmire.
Senator PROXMIRE. Senator McClure, we have promised Mr.
Schmiedeskamp he will be able to leave early. If Senator Roth does
not have any more questions for him-you then may proceed, Senator
McClure.
Senator McCLURE. The Gallup poll shows that over 50 percent of the
American public favors wage and price controls. The last time this
occurred was in 1971 just before phase I.
Can you tell us what are the reasons underlying the causes of public
turn to controls? Would you agree with the statement that has been
made by some that part of the reason is that the public believes that
the Government is ineffective in fighting inflation, and therefore controls are the only answer?
MT. SCHMIEDESKAMP. If one is superstitious, and believes in omens,
it is worth noting that the percentages favoring wage and price controls are precisely the same, down to a decimal point, as it was in the
Gallup poll 2 weeks before President Nixon announced his new economic policy. I personally am not superstituous, and I don't think
there are good grounds to compare the two figures.
To begin with, a lot of water has gone over the dam in terms of inflation rates since 1971. The American people are terriblv upset these
days about inflation. Almost any question vou ask people about anything which holds any promise of holding down inflation tends, in my


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

47
judgment, to receive a favorable answer; and therefore, those survey
findings may be a little misleading in that connection.
The only problem with that is that there are a.n awful lot of people
who remember that controls did not work very well when they were
last tried. We were in disarray when they were taken off.
In general, it is my view that the American people lack the confidence
in the Government which wmtld be necessary to make controls work.
In my judgment, controls work when people believe they will work.
That was the situation in 1972 and 1973. If controls had been taken
off in 1972, I think history would ,regard them as having been successful. But it is the nature of controls that they are not taken off when
they are working. You wait until 1973 when they stop working before
you take them off.
Then the judgment of history is that they don't work.
Senator McCLURE. You indicated that a good many people remember controls not working, yet you say that they are for controls because they work.
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. No. They are for co11trols because they are
desperate.
Senator McCLURE. It is the drowning man grabbing for a straw,
not because he ·has faith that the straw will help, but because he has
nothing else to add.
l\Ir. ScHllHEDESKAMP. That is very largely correot, and that is why
the .figures between now and 1971 are not comparable.
Senator PROXMIRE. Thank you very much. We are delighted to have
had you, and you may leave.
Mr. SCHMIEDESKAMP. Thank you, Senator.
Senator RoTH. I regret I wasn't here in the beginning because of a
hearing being held on tax policy in the Finance Committee.
I ask t'hat my opening statement be included in the record.
Senator PROXMIRE. Without objection, so ordered.
[The opening statement of Senator Roth follows:]
OPENING STATEMENT OF HON. WILLI.AM

V.

ROTH, JB.

Our hearings on the midyear state of the economy come at a time of great challenges and a great debate on the future of the public tax policy. Our economy is
experiencing excessive rates of unemployment, inflationary pressures are increasing, GNP growth has been declining; productivity, investment and savings rates
are low, and the trade deficit is at record levels.
The economy is facing massive new Social Security tax increases and automatic
tax increases caused by inflation, and the American people are demanding tax relief. Yes despite the tax revolt sweeping the country, the Administration has.unwisely reduced its $25 billion cut to $15 billion. However, a growing number of
economists and Members of Congress from both parties now believe Congress
must enact the Roth-Kemp Tax Reduction Act.
The Roth-Kemp bill, an across-the-board tax rate reduction of 33 percent, is
designed to reduce the high rates of taxation now strangling economic growth,
choking off private initiative, pushing up prices, and retarding savings, investments, and the creation of more jobs. Its enactment will increase the incentive to
work, save, and invest, resulting in economic growth, lower prices, more jobs and
higher Federal revenues.
Today we will hear testimony that the Roth-Kemp tax cut is based on a faulty
view of history and that it would increase the budget deficit and inflation. I want
to take a minute to respond to these charges.
I have read Mr. Heller's testimony and, despite the rhetoric, the thing that
shines through, is that he admits there is a need for a major tax cut to get the
economy moving.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

48
The Roth-Kemp tax cut is modelled after the Kennedy tax cuts, the last acrossthe-board tax rate reduction enacted into law. The Kennedy tax rate reductions
lowered unemployment, eased inflation, and produced more, not less, federal
revenues. Yet we will be told that the same type of across-the-board tax rate reduction will not work today.
Assertions will be made which c'laim the Kennedy tax cuts worked only because
it stimulated demand in a slack economy. Yet recent history shows that the tax
cuts aimed only at stimulating demand-such as the Nixon tax cuts and the Ford
rebates-had nowhere near the economic impact of the Kennedy tax cuts.
The Kennedy tax cuts worked because it stimulated supply as well as demand.
The across-the-board tax rate reductions increased the supply of work effort,
savings and output in addition to increasing purchasing power. By increasing
supply as well as demand, the economy expanded enough to produce more,- not
less, federal revenues.
The increased production, savings, and investments will ease inflationary pressures. But testimony presented today will express skepticism about the increase
in savings and work effort that will result from a tax rate reduction. However,
modern economic researchers believe savings is responsive to tax changes.
Michael Bookin of Stanford University, one of the country's leading savings
experts and price theorists, has published a study documenting the fact that
savings responds, and responds strongly, to the after-tax rate of reward.
Michael Evans of Chase Econometrics has analyzed the Roth-Kemp bill and has
estimated a substantial increase in savings. And Norman Ture predicts a savings
and growth rate increase similar to Chase's.
Finally, it will be claimed that a one-year tax cut of up to $25 bilUon is needed
to offset the higher Social Security taxes and the inflation-induced taxes, but
that a three-year tax cut would be wrong.
·
But the increased Social Security taxes and the automatic tax increases caused
by inflation are not going away next year-they will only get bigger. AC(!Ording
to the Joint Committee on Taxation, Social Security and inflation tax increases
will raise taxes by $20 billion in 1979. $35 biUion in 1980, $57 billion in 1981, $77
billion in 1982, and $94 billion in 1983. Substantial tax reductions are needed
merely to offset these massive new tax increases.
Mr. Chairman, the economics of yesteryear are failing. The status quo of more
federal spending and income transfers will bring on a recession in which prices
and the deficit will rise as production collapses.
To avoid both inflation and recession, we need tax rate reductions aimed at
more savings, more jobs, and more production. The Roth-Kemp bill is a true
economic growth bill. By lowering marginal tax rates, it will produce a production surge that will reduce unemployment, increase the supply of goods and
services, and lower prices.
The Roth-Kemp bill fits the public mood for genuine tax relief. It puts Washington on notice to reduce its taxing and spending, and it will lead to the economic
growth we need to provide meaningful jobs and a rising standard of living for
all Americans.

Senator RoTH. Mr. He1ler, I have read with great interest your prepared statement on the Roth-Kemp legislation. I have to say I disagree with you.
First, up here we call it the Roth-Kemp proposal, instead of the
Roth-Kemp bill.
Second, in reading through your prepared statement, it puzzles me,
it seems to me somewhat inconsistent. I am not an economist, and I
admit that. But you, in my judgment, set up a number of strawmen,
and then you knock them down; a very good technique that politicians
often use. But when I read the whole thing through, I think what you
are saying is that you support a very major tax cut, and basically for
the same reasons that I have argued for.
You said, lest I be misunderstood, I want to add a few comments on
the wisdom of the tax cuts; and you say that ,gigantic tax cu,ts do not
apply to a moderate tax cut of $15-$20 billion dollars.
I would point out that the first stage of the Roth-Kemp tax cut is
within that ball park. We propose it for the same reasons; at least I do.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

49
It seems to me that we have, as you point out, we have unemployment at 6.1 percent; you admit that operating rates are around 84 percent rate of capacity, although there is some disagreemen~ on thatl and
that there is still a sizable margin of unutilized supply, a margm to
accommodate a $15 to $20 billion tax cut.
Let me make a oouple of comments on your beginning statements. I
just want to clarify the record.
.
.
.
On the national debate on taxes, we will have a lot of thmgs said.
I have never said Kennedy tax cuts were powerful as a tax re~uction.
In fact, I have used exactly the same words that you have used m your
prepared statement.
.
.
Again, I have never asserted that the revenue generatmg effects of
the 1964 tax cut were not foreseen. Again, I have quoted both President Kennedy and ·Wilbur Mills, on what revenue gains were expected
from the tax cuts.
I was not a Member of the Congress in the early 1960's, but I have
done some reading, and perhaps they were inaccurate. But it is my
understanding that when the Treasury Department, as so quoted in
the many articles in 1963, that they did not foresee the revenue gains.
Why didn't the Treasury foresee the gains? Because I understand
they relied on models that did not take into account supply-side
variables. You only have to look at the administration which you were
a part of.
But basically, it seems to me that you might disagree in some of the
particulars, but that a substantial tax cut is very much in order.
But I would like to ask you this : ·we're faced with something like
$98 billion in spending increases; $94 billion even without the energy
tax, over the next 4 years. You recommend one $25 billion tax cut. You
will let taxes rise by $73 billion.
Are you going to let the public guess what is coming? If we want to
really restore confidence, aren't we better off offsetting these taxes now
up front in a way that almost specifically does that?
Mr. HELLER. Senator, I find myself in the position of trying to combat a radical position with a conservative and moderate point of view,
which I am noted for.
I read very carefully what you have said, and I had the pleasure of
some give-and-take with Congressman Kemp last night.
I have also read very carefully what I believe the objective, careful,
penetrating analysis of the Brookings Institution has said in "Setting
National Priorities," their annual analysis of the U.S. budget.
They tell us that in terms of a realistic look at both the expenditures
and the tax side of the picture, as well as the capability of the
economy-and indeed it was somewhat of a disappointment to me and
a surprise-that we have a total of about $25 billion of tax cut capacity
between now and 1981 if we want a balanced budget at 21 percent of
GNP in 1981.
As I said, as a conservative observer of the scene, I would like to
see a balanced budget in a balanced economy at full employment.
Senator RoTH. I welcome you to the group of us. I think Senator
Proxmire and I, and Senator McClure are all in agreement about that
goal.
But one of my concerns is that people who talk along these lines not
too often do muoh on the spending side. I think a balanced budget can

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

50
be reached in many ways, and one of them is to hold down the growth
in tJhe rate of spending. I believe Mr. Kaufman addressed that, and
pointed out that there have been substantial increases.
During our consideration of the budget resolution, Senator Proxmire and I proposed, and led a fight, for a number of reductions in
spending.
Unfortunately, that has not met with too much success, although
the last couple of days we have seen a somewhat changed attitude on
the part of the Senate, possibly because of a reaction to California's
Proposition 13.
But I would like to ask, as I said to the Secretary of the Treasury,
who was before us in the Finance Committee today, here he is leading
the fight for restraint, asking labor to hold down the size of their
increases, asking business to hold down their increases, asking the
American people to be moderate in what they demand, and yet we find
that that Department, the Treasury Department, whose appropriation
was up yesterday, increased 31 percent over the prior year.
Part of that can be explained by an unavoidable cost in social security this year. I recognize that.
But the subcommittee's responsibility for the appropriations for
that Department criticized that Department because they had a 21-percent increase in travel. You can't tell me there isn't a lot of waste.
Senator Proxmire asked for a 5-percent cut in the budget resolution.
What I am saying to you is, when you talk about $25 billion, if you
take the administration's rate of growth some of us are suggesting that
the better approach is to do in a sense what Kennedy did. At least he
said it was his intent in his statements to Congress: "Let's give the
private sector a chance to show what it can do." He said, "Admittedly
we can decrease Federal spending, but I want to choose the latter way."
That is what we are trying to do, give the private sector a chance to
see what they can do.
I understand my time has expired.
Mr. HELLER. May I comment on that? I said at the end of my prepared statement, Senator Roth, it is extremely hard not to be misunderstood in this type of discussion. I do think one should define rather
sharply the difference between your advocacy of tax cuts and my advocacy of tax cuts.
I am in favor of a tax cut that will make use of supply capability
of this economy; and we still have a lot of unutilized supply capability. I think we can establish a tax cut without having it worsen our
inflation problem. We are not in the excess demand area.
But that is roughly a $20-billion tax cut this year, which I would
phase in rather gradually in 1979, perhaps in two steps, something like
Congress did with the 1964-65 tax cut. But that is a far cry from saying the economy should absorb-apparently, I underestimated the size
of your cut in my opening statement-a $20-million cut in 1979; $35
billion in 1980; $57 billion in 1981 or a total cut of $98 billion in 3
years.
Supposedly, because of some enormous and unprecedented increase
in the supply capability of the economy through a tremendous surge
in work incentives and business incentives, supply would rise to meet
demand. Nothing in economic experience or analysis supports this. The
result would be-big deficits and bigger inflation.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

51
. I am just trying to take a ~oderate approac~ to_the tax cut proposition, and to harken to ~he evidence o_f.ec~nom1c lustory about the impact of tax cuts, that 1t operates primarily on the demand side and
'
only over a long :period of tim~, on the prol':uctivity side.
We took that mto account m the Kennedy tax cut. I am not here to
argu~ against Kennedy's tax cut. I think it did increase productivity.
But 1t would not set off any surge that Mr. Ture assumes in his model.
There is no historical precedent.
As Rudolph Penner said, "It can't be three or four or five times anything we have seen in history." I do think we should in that sense be
very clear on the issues that stand between us, even though we may
stand shoulder-to-shoulder on a $20- or $25-billion tax cut this year.
Senator RoTH. I want to reemphasize again that what the RothKemp bill proposes is a tax reduction less than the higher taxes that
are resulting from social security, energy, and inflation taxes.
For example, social security tax and inflation tax increases will raise
taxes by $20 billion in 1979; $35 billion in 1980; $57 billion in 1981;
$77 billion in 1982; and $94 billion in 1983. So when you are talking
about $25 billion, you are not talking about a tax cut. You are talking
about a tax increase.
Senator PROXMIRE. Senator Roth's time is up.
Senator McClure, you have 8 minutes left, and then we will go to
Senator J avits.
Senator McCLURE. Professor Heller, for many years economic policy
has been based on the short-run Keynesian policy which focuses on the
impact of fiscal policy on disposable income and spending; changes in
demand have been the main policy tools.
In other words, little if any attention has been given to the impact
of fiscal policy on aggregate supply.· For example, fiscal policy has
ignored that change in tax rates as an incentive or disincentive rate
that could shift the average supply function.
Consider a reduction in tax rates. It is not just increased disposable
income. It also increases the aftertax rate of return to workers' effort
and investment. In an economy like ours, that relies on incentives, it
seems pointless to ignore the incentive effects of fiscal policy.
We now have on public record many statements saying that fiscal
policy and economic models used to estimate its, effects do not take into
account the supply-side effects.
For example, Mrs. Alice Rivlin, the Director of the Congressional
Bud~t Office, has said, the models do tend to neglec~ the influe1;1ce of
the tax rate and others on the rate of supply and capital format10n.
The Office of Management and Budget has said, the models do not
include any relative price effects from an individual tax rate re!1-uction · no incentive to work longer, to save more, to take greater risks,
to b~ more innovative. Disposable income is increased, which raises
consumption, and that is the only direct effect.
Mr. Mike Edwards, president of Ohase Econometrics, has said,
these models which are now used by virtually all economic policymakers are constructed in a way such that they a.re much better able
to simulate the effects of tax policies on aggregate demand than on
aggregate supply. Thus, the use of these models may have directed
policymakers toward tihose policies which have visible short-term ef
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

52
foots on aggregate demand without considering their likely intermediate and long-term effects on productivity capacity.
Professor Robert Lucas and Thomas Sargent state that the econometric models are incapable of providing reliable guidance for public policy, be.cause they look at a sound econometric base. .
Do you think that this neglect of the supply-side effect of fiscal
policy could account for the appeamnce of simultaneous irttlation and
unemployment which produces a dilemma for senior mana,,,o-ement, so
to speaki
Mr. HELLER. Yes. I will stop beating mv wife.
Senator McCLURE. She will be pleased to know that, too. [Laughter.]
Mr. HELLER. Touche. The way you posed the question does not
rea~ily permit an answer. But let me try to make a couple of observations.
One, my prepared statement explicitly, Senator McClure, tried to
show that we did indeed take the incentives, supplies, investment
stimulus aspect of the 1961-64 tax cut very much into account.
·
We started with the investment credit and eased depreciation guidelines. Those were aimed primarily at the supply side. As I have written
about that experience in the past, I talk about a two-track policy, the
demand side, which was predominant in the 1964 tax cut, and the supply or productivity side, which played a very important role in our
thinking as a stimulant to growth and curb on inflation.
The demand eide operates faster. I'd like a tax cut that engages the
unutilized resources and unemployed labor and puts them to work.
That works much faster than the supply side.
What I have sa;id essentially to Senater Roth is that the Roth-Kemp
bill is assuming you were going to have an explosion of supply capabilities, which 1s absolutely unsupported by any experience in history.
Spread out over a long period of time, as a balanced part of a supply
stimulus versus demand stimulus, it could work. But to concentrate
such gigantic tax cuts in such a short period of time is an open invitation to inflation and big deficits, and also, appropos Mr. Scihmiedeskamp's comment, would bias the economy much more toward consumption and away from invPstment.
That is to say, because of this incredible fiscal expansion, you have
to have very tight money to offset it. As a consequence, you would
squeeze down investment through monetary policy, high interest rates,
as an offset to stimulative fiscal policy.
One other thought: It troubles me that in supporting the KempRoth approach, that the emphasis is entirely put on the one side of the
incentive picture, as fa,r as labor is concerned; that labor responds
with more work because you increase the attractiveSenator McCLURE. Do you mean organized labod
Mr. HELLER. No. I mean, you, me, all of us as human beings that
are interested in working and increasing standards of living, and improving our income, and so fortih.
But there is a dual response. One response is that if you have a
lower tax rate, you work harder, because you get more per hour of
~vork. The other response is to say, look, I am achieving my target
mcome a lot more rapidly because we have a lower tax rate, and
therefore, I will work Jess hard.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

That, indeed, in large part is what the American worker-and I
am using workers comprehensively-'-did in the 11J60's to respond to
the increase in the after-tax income, which is larger than that which
the l{ot:lh-Kemp bill would provide.
Most of it was taken out in additional leisure, not in the form of
working harder and longer hours.
As Herbert ,8tein put it at a meeting last Monday, we don't even
know the sign of the elasticity of the labor supply in response to a
change in atter-tax income. ~esults of studies to date range from
minus 0.2 to plus 0.3 or so at the outside, not even within striking
distance of supporting the Kemp-Roth assertions. I am citing an authority from a side of the political and economic fence that is perhapo
closer to you than to me.
I agree with Mr. Stein, for example, that we ought to have a good
deal more research on the feedback, that we have not given enough
emphasis to the supply side. But that does not mean we can leap from
what we have done in the past to a conclusion that a tax cut will have
this ~normous supply-side effect-1:ihere is simply no evidence to support 1t.
Senator McCLURE. Nor is there any evidence to refute it. We need
the research.
Therefore, I am not sure that you have made a case, other than for
the fact that we need more basic knowledge, and until we get it, we
are guessing, which I guess is where we always end up, particularly
with a panel of economists.
Mr. Kaufman, Data Resources Corp., argued before this committee
that a tight fiscal and monetary policy would reduce inflation while
expanding the economy. Do you agree that this policy would reduce
interest rates j
Mr. KAUFMAN. To some extent, I would share that view.
Indeed, one of the great problems of the last 3 years has been that we
have had a very stimulative fiscal policy which has hampered monetary policy. The expansion in Federal expenditures here, as I indicated,
in the past 3 or 4 years, has 'been extraordinary. In many ways, it has
been unprecedented.
This has resulted in massive demand by the Federal Government
and its agencies way above anything we have seen in the postwar
period, either in dollar terms or percentiagewise. Therefore, it has hampered, to some extent, the appreciation and the value of financial
assets, and in turn, has hampered the incentives for the private sector.
In turn, it has complicated monetary policy implementation. It has
contributed to a somewhat larger monetary expansion than probably
the Federal Reserve would have desired.
In that 'sense, it is unfortunate. As you know from my testimony,
this is going on right in 1978, at the very time when Federal expenditures should have been slowed apprecirubly.
Senator JAVITS. Senator Proxmire, I came down because I welcome
this debate very much, and I cannot think of better people to debate
the issues than ,the people before us.
It is an open secret that I am in very much sympathy with the views
of Mr. Heller, and indeed, with those of Senator Danforth of Missouri. We have proposed a tax cut proposal, which in essence follows
the lines that he has in mind with a heavy emphasis on dealing with

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

54

depreciation in order to stimulate the moderniza.t.ion of American
pla.nts, which we suspect are growing obsolete under our very eyes,
and also to stimulate capital investment through better treatment of
investment tax credit.
Our tax proposal is sort of 50-50 for business, and individuals, with
the assistance to individuals in the form of a readjustment of tax
brackets.
This will be a hot debate. Superficially, what the Roth-Kemp bill
is trying to do is very attractive. Who doCIS not wa.nt a tax cut? Life
would be much simpler if the attitude could be taken: If they want to
cut $70 billion, fine; let them do it and also worry about the consequences.
But it is so hard in a democracy to get through reasoning along the
lines of, tomorrow you will sufl'er :for that which you imbibed last
night.
I like what Senator McClure said: Until y;e get the information, we
are guessing. That is just what we are doing with this so-called Laffer
curve. The last laugh will be on us. We are guessing. It is just too serious to guess about.
I want to ask you a question. My colleague, Senator Roth, said that
you are not even making up for the raises in social security, inflation,
and the cost of energy with these massive tax cuts.
What is your answer to that?
Mr. HELLER. My answer is in forms of what I was suggesting to Senator McClure, that we have to look at the fiscal policy side of things,
comprehensively, both the expenditures and the tax side. That is whai.,
the Brookings Institutions did in its annual review.
This review this year was quite critical of the Carter administration in many respects. It is an objective undertaking already-progra.med expenditure increases-including benefit increases a.ttached to
a lot of these tax increases, like payroll tax increases, would lead to a
situation in which, if you want to achieve a Federal hudget that is at
about 21 percent of gross national product--and I want to interrupt
to say that I accept President Carter's objective of that kind of a
budget, that he should bring it down from the height to which the Republican administration pushed it, around 22 to 23 percent of GNP,
and to bring it back down to 21 percent of GNP. I accept that.
Given that objective, and given the objective of a balanced budget
by fiscal 1981, there is about $25 billion of leeway for tax cuts.
If Senators Roth and McClure were to cut the Federal budget well
below the 21 percent, or were they to accept a sizable deficit, then there
would be room for more tax cuts.
In the longer run, well managed tax cuts, well balanced investment
stimulus and consumption stimulus, not ·excessive, can step up our
increase in productivity. But that will not operate in 1 year or 2 years.
Senator JAVITS. Mr. Kaufman, you know the enormous regard I have
for your views. I have consulted you before, and I will continue to
consult you, if you allow me to.
But I noticed what you said about the need for cutting expenditures. Isn't it a ::fact that if we go for this ~amble, which is what RothKemp is, and we get in trouble-even small trouble---the first attack is
going to be not only to cut expenditures, but also to cut them to the
bone to a void disaster?
1


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

55
Isn't the tax cut one of the great issues in this country1 'Should we
fatten up demand for 85 percent of the Americans who live quite well,
but starve the 15 percent of Americans who are in the poverty class,
and make their situation even worse, because that is where the expenditure cuts will come 1
Who is kidding who about this matter l May I have your opinion~
Mr. KAUFMAN. I suspect that I am somewhere in the middle.
First of all, I think the rate of Federal expenditures has been
increasing at an unprecedented pace. It used to be said, in Keynesian
policy, that we would work toward reducing Federal expenditures as
economic activities increased. We have not done that at all in this
cycle. There is no indication of adequate surveillance over Federal
expenditure. The budget deficit, either in percentage terms or aggregate terms, is unprecedented.
I think there 1s an urgent need to assert discipline, even if we accept
a rule of thumb that further expenditures should not increase in the
aggregate, by more than 5 or 6 or 7 percent per yea.r. It should be up
to you and to the other people up on the Hill, to determine the application of those expenditures. I think that is a political decision.
The aggregate figures should be set in terms of economic requirements. The distribution of those expenditures, that is what you are
asking.
I think it's an important point. But raising up expenditures without
adequate regard for the economic consequences is an inappropriate tool
of national policy.
Senator JAVJTS. I appreciate what you have said, and I agree with
you. But there is only one thing that worries me about these 5- and 2percent cuts.
What happens is that the expenditure proposals we cut initially
recur in supplementals; there is much proof that the final total somehow or another gets to be the same, so that we haven't actually bitten
the budgetary bullet.
If you have program a, or you want to eliminate a program, or you
vote to eliminate a program, you pay for it. Let's vote for program a,
but let's not kid each other that fair adjustments will be made, because
they make adjustments that will result in the poor and the depressed
getting trimmed, and more consumption for those who already have
good consumption.
I want to ask my last question of any member of the panel. I am of
the view that if we undertake expansion of production and productivity in this country, the likelihood is that we will find we are running short of domestic markets, unless the goal is for everyone to
have three televisions, three automobiles, and we take in each other's
wash.
Isn't it a fact that a major drive to acquire greater markets is at
least equal in importance to the need to counter the obsolescence of
American plants?
Mr. KAUFMAN. Since I have the microphone, Senator, I would certainly share your view that we should enlarge our international
markets. But as you know, we are not well prepared to do that even
though the dollar has depreciated against foreign currencies. '
The fact of the matter is that the inflation rate in the United States
has J?roceeded at a much higher rate than in most European countries,
and m Japan, and the dollar depreciation has been offset by this.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

56
Additionally, we are not focusing enough, I suspect, incentives to
create a modern plant and modern machinery that will ~ake us
increasingly competitive in international markets. I hope we will slow
the rate of inflation; otherwise, it will be very, very difficult to enlarge
or export our export markets.
Mr. HELLER. If I may take up a little bit different aspect of y<_mr
observation, Senator Javits, you said that perhaps we are reaching
some point of satiety, at least in durable goods. I don't really think we
have seen that point.
But it does make the point that we are increasingly turnmg to some
of the more intangible aspects of life, cleaner air, safer working conditions, better health, and it is unfortunate, it seems to me, that as we
talk about GNP and productivity and so forth, that those intangible
elements don't get into the picture at all.
"\Ve consider it a reduction in productivity if we have to invest more
in clean air and water and greater safety, and it is, in traditional
terms, a lower productivity per unit of investment.
But I would hate to think that this country would feel that producing a better environment, cleaner environment, and safe working
conditions, that this country would believe that that is not part of the
economic and human well-being.
Senator J AVITS. My time is up.
Senator PRonnm~. Senator Hatch has come in, and I will give him
a chance to catch his breath.
Mr. Kaufman, you indicated that the employment level of 4 percent
in 1957 is equivalent to 5½ percent-not your view, but the view of
Mr. ·wachter of the Federal Reserve of St. Louis.
Is that your conclusion, too~
Mr. KAuFMAN. Senator, I am not an expert on employment and
structural problems on the employment side, but I merely indicate to
you that there is a substantial difference of opinion today as to where
the full employment level is.
It is probably significantly above 4 percent. The advocates of the
4 percent level are not as powerful and strong and theoretically powerful as they used to be. If it is not 5½ percent, perhaps it is 5 percent.
But I wo~ld i!1dicate that we cannot operate on that old margin.
My feelmg 1s that structural unemployment should be addressed,
but it ought to be addressed through selective measures, and not trying
aggregate measures. There is a problem, on the one hand of those who
are structurally unemployed, and those who are employed who have a
different problem .
. Sena~or PROXMIRE. This is a very, very pertinent and timely consideration. vVe just, 2 hours ago, in the Senate Banking Committee,
reported the Humphrey-Hawkins bill, which provides for a 4-percent
unemployment goal bv 1981.
Nobody, either Democrat or Republican, challenged that o-oal in
the course of our discussions. "\Ye had manv witnesses fron~ many
different segments. They did not challenge t'he 4 percent.
There are othe~· elements they did challenge. You are a highly
repu_table economist, and I think your observation should give us
considerable pause.
Be~ore I call on Mr. Heller, in this regard, let me ask you a followup
question, because you suggest that a 3-percent growth in the economy

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

57
over the next few years should be our target to have a sustained
growth and no inflation. That does concern me, because it seems if we
have a 3-percent growth, given anything like our historic productivity
and the growth in the work force, that that v.ould suggest that we
would have to have unemployment at the present 6-percent level.
That seems to be throwing in the sponge on 6 million people. What
is your response?
Mr. KAUFl\fAN. I feel the structurally unemployed can be brought
into the labor force over a longer period of time by training the very
young, not just on the job, bnt improving educational facilities.
Very intense and academic training over a 10- or 12-year period for
thoseSenator PnoXl\HRE. Yon don't argue that the 6 percent is all structurally unemployed?
Mr. KAUFl\IAN. Absolutely not. But I think a very significant part
is structurally unemployed. Even if the full employment is 4 percent,
the difference between what we have today, in terms of the unemployment rate and the 4 percent, is relatively small. It is one-third of the
total, but I don't believe 4 percent is unemployment.
I believe we should restate the unemployment ta,rget in the official
language of the Government. The target should be 5 to 5½ percent.
"Tith the policies now in force, we have heated up the system to a high
rate of inflation, which is in no way going to come down during the
near term. Indeed, with the policies now in place, without any change,
the rate of inflation would remain high.
This is unacceptable to a complex system such as onr society in terms
of its structure, and politica1ly. Therefore we run the risk of aggravating the inflation rate. Not only will it go higher, but the unemployment rate will be induced to go higher, and we lia-ve not accomplished
anything. That. is where my hangup is. I don't think we can go and
eliminate unemployment through aggregate economic policies. A 12percent increase in Federal expenditures will not bring down over the
longer period of time the backup unemployment mte in this country.
Senator Pnoxl\IrnE. I agree with that. I submitted the Henry Kaufman amendment. I did that in no small part after I read your report
analyzing our expenditures. Onr banking committee not only adopted
a 4-percent unemployment rate, they adopted a 0-percent inflation
goal by 1983.
Would you like to comment on the position that Mr. Kaufman has
just taken?
Mr. HELLER. First of all, I fully share your respect for my colleague,
Henry Kaufman.
Second, I a.gree ·with ·what he was saying about the change in, not
the goal, but what I like to call the pivot point of unemployment,
which is an economic concept as distinguished from the target or goal,
which is the Humphrey-Hawkins political concept.
May I just spend a moment on that, because I think there is a fair
amount of confusion out of our failure to make that distinction. The
pivot point, and some call it the NAIRU or nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment, that is a judgment as to how far you can
reduce unemployment by essentially aggregate demand measures,
monetary and fiscal policies, without escalating inflation, excess demand inflation.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

58
I would entirely agree with Henry Hau.fman, that that has moved
up because of changes in the composition of the labor force, and a lot
of other things, :from 4 percent to somewhere around 5 to 5½ percent.
Does that mean it is therefore unsound in the Humphrey-Hawkins
bill to adopt a target o:f 4 percent?
I don't think so because the structural measures that Mr. Kaufman
SJ?oke about serve as the reconciler, as it ·were, of the 5 to 5½ percent
pivot point-this economic concept where you move into accelerating
inflation-and say a longer run 4-percent unemployment goal. The
point is that the direct structural measures, direct job creation and
so forth, will not have nearly the same aggrega.te demand or inflationcreating e:ffect.
They do improve the supply side, and that is where again we have
to give some weight to the Roth-Kemp type of an approach and
emphasize the supply side.
As I say, to sum up, the pivot point may have moved up from 4 to
5 percent, but that is no reason to do a way with the 4-percent ta.rget.
Senator PROXMIRE. Let me ask Mr. Adams a question. We have been
awful easy on you.
With respect to the Roth-Kemp bill, frankly, it has great appeal to
me. It is hard to find a tax cut that I would not support. It is hard to
find a spending cut that I would not support.
The Federal Government is much too big and inefficient, and :for
some other reasons. But what bothers me about the Roth-Kemp bill,
although on balance I would support it, is that it does constitute $70
billion over 3 years in Federal Government taxes, balanced in part by
substantial increases in payroll taxes, which are highly regressive, and
then there is something, although I don't agree wholeheartedly, something to the notion that if you go that way, that that might be somewhat regressive, because you might take some of it out of the people
with very low incomes.
Do you think, on balance, that there is a way that we can handle
this that would not result in a major shift in jw,tice and equity?
Mr. AnAMS. It is very difficult when you legislate in such large
numbers, and legislate so far ahead into the future, to guarantee
that you do achieve your equity targets at the same time that you
achieve your tax and expenditure goals.
I think the point has been made that inevitably things get cut at the
margin, and they are not always the things you want cut.
It strikes me that with regard to that bill there are basically three
questions : One is how large should the Government be? Can we cut
back expenditures? Can we cut back taxes? And somehow think the
size of the Government is just right.
I think that is in large part a political decision. It depends how
larg~ Government should be and how much we are willing to pay
for it. !hese are clearly joint decisions, and if they are made jointly,
they might be made in such a way as to minimize the economic impact.
The other reaction I have is very much similar to the one that professor Heller had, which is that there is no assurance that the effects on
the supply side are going to be anywhere near as large or anywhere
near the kinds that are desired.
I can think of more specific tax legislation which will operate on
the supply side, and which should have, I think, more measurable im
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

59
pact. I am thinking of specific incentives for investment, £or example,
tax credits, depreciation, and so on. I am thinking of specific t~x incentives in the direction we want, perhaps precisely for those mdustries that have been impacted by pollution control measures, by other
kinds of Government. regulations, and perhaps by high energy costs,
and perhaps industries located in large urban centers.
We could influence the supply side in terms of taxes, but it is terribly
important to try to focus these impacts in order to direct them into
the place where we want them.
To talk in terms of general cuts, and then argue that there are
supply impacts, is operating in a fog, so to speak. vV c really don't know
exactly what will result. We will have to be very careful that the
other "impacts on the side of demand and inflation ·do not overwhelm
the desired impact on the supply side.
Sen~tor McCLURE. I have to att~nd anot_her m2eting. I know this is a
committee that has been characterized by its nonpartisan nature. That
nonpartisan rule does not apply to our witnesses, of course.
But I cannot help but observe what Mr. Heller said about the Republican administration driving expenditures to unprecedented highs.
That was almost totally the result of actions taken by Democratic
Congresses.
Mr. HELLER. I hope if I misstated it, that I will be corrected. I
should have said that they reached uprecedented highs during Republican administrations. We will leave causality out.
Senator HATCH. Mr. Heller, you mentioned Denison's law; that is,
that savings are unaffected by tax policy. Are you familiar with the
recent study by Michael Boskin that shows that savings are much
affected by tax policy?
Mr. HELLER. Yes, I am. One does have, in that sense, conflicting
evidence.
Of course, we all respect very, very much Edward Denison and the
study he has made. I don't think there is a more active observer and
more intelligent probing student of the statistics of the gross national
product, growth 0£ the economy, and so forth.
He has found this remarkable stability, which suggests very
strongly-it does merit further consideration, but suggests strongly
!hat the gross savings rate of the economy is not rei"ponsive to changes
m tax rates over the years.
Senator HATCH. Mr. Boskin stated:
The notion that saving is perfectly interest inelastic has received widespread
acceptance * * *· * * * nothing could be further from the truth • • •. • • • I
hope to point out how costly it has been (and will continue to be) to accept the
conjecture-based on evidence which is flimsy at best, and dangerously mislead•
ing at worst-that the interest elasticity of the savings rate is negligible. * • •
the notion, which has come to be called "Denison's Law" that the savings rate
is essentially constant and unaffected by changes in the tax system or other
changes in the real after-tax rate of return to capital. * • *
,
* • * A variety of • * * estimation methods all lead to the conclusion that
private saving is indeed strongly affected by changes in the real after-tax rate
of return. The estimated total * * * interest elasticities of private savings cluster
around 0.3 to 0.4. ·while this is hardly an enormous elasticity by conventional
standards, it is substantially larger than virtually all previous estimates in the
conventional wisdom, and has drastic implications for the affect of tax policy
on income, welfare. and income distribution.

Do you disagree with Mr. Boskin's conclusions?

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Mr. HELLER. As I said, this is the first study that comes to this conclusion. I think we should pay respectful attention to that study. I
think it should be considered in the course of further examinations of
the savings relationships.
But let's recognize that this is one study; it is one finding, on econometric finding, that runs counter to all previous consensus on the
subject.The fact that economists reach consensus on the subject does not
mean that it is right. But it means that we have to examine those results very, very carefully, and sort of hold off our judgment.
I would say that any well-rounded statement on the subject should
include a reference to the Boskins study. Mine did not, and I suppose, therefore, my statement is not well rounded, because I mentioned only the Denison study.
But the jury is still out. That is the main point you are making, and
I accept that.
Senator HATCH. Are you aware that we have found that Michael
Evans of Chase Econometrics has analyzed the Roth-Kemp bill, and
has estimated a substantial increase in savings. We also have heard
from many others.
In other words, Mr. Boskin is not an isolated opinion.
Mr. HELLER. I would rather not comment. I'll hold my tongue.
Senator ROTH. I would ask unanimous consent that we put in the
article by Mr. Boskin, because this whole question of savings and in~
centives is absolutely crucial.
Senator PROXMIRE. Without objection, the article will be included
in the record.
[The article referred to follows :]


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

61
[From the Journal of Political Economy, April 19781

Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of
Interest

Michael J. Baskin
Stanford University and ]Vational Bureau of Economic Research

This study presents new estimates of consumption functions based on
aggregate U.S. time-series data. The results are striking: a variety of
functional forms, estimation methods, and definitions of the real after-tax
rate of return invariably lead to the conclusion of a substantial interest
elasticity of sa,·ing. The implications of this result for the analysis of the
efficiency and equity of the current U.S. tax treatment of income from
capital are explored. In reducing the real net rate of return; current
tax treatment significantly retards capital accumulation. This in turn
causes an enormous waste of resources and redistributes a substantial
fraction of gross income from labor to capital. Rough estimates of the
lost welfare exceed $50 billion per year (a present value close to S 1
trillion!) and of the redi5tribution from labor to capital exceed oneseventh of capital's share of gross income. It also suggests that the usual
calculations of tax burdens by income class substantially overestimate
both the progressivity of the income tax and the alleged regressivity of
consumption taxes.

The effect of interest rates on economic behavior, particularly on saving
and consumption, has been a central concern of economists at least
since the development of classical macroeconomics. ::'\ot only has the rate
of interest been viewed as the mechanism. for equating saving and investment in pre-Keynesian macroeconomic models, but it also has been at the
center of virtually all microeconomic models of intertemporal consumer
behavior. It is thus curious that empirical studies of the effects of interest
I am indC'btcd to M. Abramovitz, P. David, M. Feldstein,\'. Fuchs, R. Hall, A. Harberger, M. Hurd,J. Pechman,J. Scadding. E. Shl'shinski,.J. Shoven,.J. Stiglitz, and other
participants at seminars at Stanford, Harvard, the U.S. Dl'partment of the Treasury,
r-iBER, and the :\'SF-:\BER Conference o·n Taxation for valuable- advice and encouragemC'nt: to L. Garrison for invaluable research assistance; and to the U.S. Department
of the Treasury for financial assistance.
21
© 1!178 by The Lni\'crsity of Chica!(o. 0022-3H08;78.B622-000IS02.00

(Journal of Poli/ital Econmn_l'. 1976. vol. 86, no. 2. pl.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
35-570 0 - 79 - 5
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

62
JOt:RNAL OF POLITICAL ECONO~IY

rates on sa\·ing arc few and far bctwecn. 1 ::\lost such studies conclude that
interest rates have only a negligible effect on consumption or saving. 2
The notion that saving is perfectly interest inelastic has received
widespread acceptance among empirical and policy-oriented macroeconomists. \ \"hilc I shall present below considerable evidence that nothing
could be further from the truth, it is worthwhile exploring just how important the interest elasticity of the saving rate is in the analysis of a wide
variety of vital issues of economic policy. In so doing, I hope to point out
how costly it has been (and will continue to be) to accept the conjecturebased on evidence which is flimsy at best and dangerously misleading
at worst-that the interest elasticity of the saving rate is negligible. This is
done in Section I.
Section II discusses several previous studies of saving behavior. I deal
with possible biases in previous estimates of the interest elasticity of the
saving r~te. Special attention is paid to the notion, which has come to be
called "Denison's Law," that the saving rate is essentially constant and
unaffected by changes in the tax system or other changes in the real aftertax rate of return to capital. An analysis of data for the l:nited States in
Section III leads me to conclude that no behavioral significance can be
attributed to the conventionally measured gross private saving rate: it
measures neither saving nor income in the appropriate manner, and
attempts to do so reveal a saving rate which can hardly be called constant.
~ection II I also presents detailed sets of estimates of private consumption
functions. A variety of functional forms, definitions of the variables, and
estimation methods all lead to the conclusion that private saving is indeed
strongly affected by changes in the real after-tax rate of return. The estimated total (income plus substitution) interest elasticities of private
saving cluster around 0.3-0.4. \\"bile this is hardly an enormous elasticity
by conventional standards, it is substantially larger than virtually all
previous estimates and the conventional wisdom and has drastic implications for the effect of tax policy on income, welfare, and income distribu.
tion.
Section IV reports estimates from this same body of data of Harrodneutral CES production functions. Again, a variety of estimation techniques yields similar estimates of the elasticity of substitution of approximately one-half. Combined with our estimates of the inte_rest elasticity of the
saving rate, this immediately implies that policies which raise the after-tax
rate of return will increase labor's gross share of income in the long run.
Section V summarizes the implications of the empirical results for the
analysis of the effects of various policies on income, welfare, and income
1 Thus, Break (1974, p. 151) notes, "Unfortunately, empirical evidence on the inter<'st
elasticity of the saving rate is rare."
2 A discussion of why these studil·s may have biased th e estimated interest elasticities
toward zero is presented below.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

0

63
TAXATION, SAVINO, AND THE l!lo'TEREST RATE

distribution. Briefly, policies (such as switching from an income tax to
a consumption tax) which raise the after-tax rate of return to capital will
increase income substantially, remove an enormous deadweight loss to
society resulting from the distortion of the consumption-saving choice, and
redistribute income from capital to- labor.
Section \'I concludes with a discussion of the limitations of the.study and .
avenues for further research.

I. The Isstres at Stake
I shall discuss in turn five basic concerns of economic policy: the effects of
the income tax on the distribution of income, the differential incidence of a
consumption and an income tax, the tax treatment of human and physical
capital, the cflcct of inflation on the capital intensity of the economy, and
the debate o,·er whether the saving rate is high enough in the Cnited
States. \\'c shall sec that the interest elasticity of the saving rate is the key
parameter in the analysis of each of these issues. The potential importance
of the interest elasticity of saving in the analysis of the effect of monetary
policy is obvious and well-known enough that repetition here is unnecessary.
\'irtually all empirical estimates of tax burdens by income class allocate
income taxes according to income; that is, they assume the tax is not
shifted. 3 In an economy in which either the private saving rate is sensitive
to the real after-tax rate of return or the marginal propensity of the public
sector to invest out of revenues is different from the private sector's
marginal propensity to save out of private income, this assumption is
incorrect. Since an income tax both decreases the after-tax rate of return
on capital and transfers resources from the private to the public sector, it
affects the national sa\·ing rate anc.l capital/labor ratio. If saving respond,
positively to increases in the rate of return and/or the public; propensity to
save falls short of the private propensity to save,4 an income tax retard~
capital accumulation and leads to a lower level of income and lower wage/
rental ratio than would otherwise exist. 5 Further, labor's share of gross
income will fall with increases in income taxation if the elasticity of substitution falls short of unity. 6 In these circumstances, a proportional
income tax is quite different from a tax which is borne in proportion to
income; indeed, it transfers income. from labor to capital and, hence, i~
regressive, relative to such a tax.
A closely related question concerns the differential incidence of an
J E.g .. srr Prchman and Okn,·r 197-l .
.. I prrs,·nt .-vicl.-ncr to support this position hdow.
5 s.-.. tlw analysis in F,·l,.lst<·in ( 19Ha. 1!17-lq. Also S<'<" the contributions by Sato (19Ci7
Hall (1968), and Diamond (1970).
0 I pres<'nt ,·vidmc.- to this dfect in S<'ction I\'.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

64
S6

JOL'R!'<AL OF POLITICAL ECONO!IIY

income and a consumption tax. \\'hik most economists recognize the
efficiency ad\·antages in taxing consumption rather than income, the
general argument against a consumption tax has been th~ll it is regressive
because it excludes interest incomL· from the tax base. This analysis is
correct as far as it goes, for interest income docs accrue disproportionately to the \\'ealthy. Howe\'er, it overlooks t\\'O basic points. First, the rate
structure may be set differently under a consumption tax; second, the
exemption of interest income from the tax base may increase the sa\'ing
rate, the capital, labor ratio, the producti\·ity of labor, and the wage/
rental ratio. This long-run transfer of income from capital to labor must be
offset against the short-run gain to capital from the interest income
exemption. The net outcome, of course, depends upon the particulars of
the two taxes being compared. Again, however, the prevalent view is that
of Pechman ( 1971): " ... The differential effect on cons1,1mption and
sa\'ing between an income tax and an equal yield expenditure tax is
likely to be small in this country" ( p. 65).
A related issue concerns the rdati\·e tax treatment of physical and
human capital. I have argued elsewhere (Boskin 1975) that the tax
system probably biases capital accumulation toward in\'estment in human
capital and away from physical investment because most human capital
investments are financed out of tax-free forgone earnings. This is equivalent
to instantaneous depreciation of this component of human investment.
Since we do not allow instantaneous write-off of investment in physical
capital (except R & D expenditures), the current system of income taxation probably reduces the after-tax rate of return on physical capital
relative to that on human capital. Hence, the deadweight loss from the
misallocation of a given amount of investment in physical and human
capital will depend upon, among other things, the 'interest elasticity of the
sa\·ing rate.
Attention has recentlv been focused on the economic effects of inflation.
In a Tobin-type mon~tary growth model with taxes, Feldstein (1978)
demonstrates how inflation may decrease the capital intensity of production and hence affect the real economy. Again, a key issue appears to be
whether sa\'ing responds positively to increases in the real net rate of
return.
Finally, we come to the perennial issue of whether.we are saving enough
in the Cnited States. A variety of economists and politicians have continually expressed concern over the slower rate of real economic growth in
the Cnited States than in Japan and western Europe. Hardly a day goes
by when a major speech is not given on "the capital shortage." \\'hile the
issue is complex and I can hardly hope to deal with it in detail here,
suffice it to say that under a not implausible set of assumptions a. major
component of the answer reduces to whether or not current taxes, in
driving a wedge between the gross marginal social yield and net marginal

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

65
TAXATION, SAVING, AND THE INTEREST RATE

S;

private yield on investment, distort the timing of consumption over the
life cycle; a sufficient condition for this to occur is a positi,·e (pure-substitution) interest elasticity of the saving rate. 7
Thus, if the saving rate displays some interest elasticity, our notion,
about tax incidence, about the effects of inflation on the real economy, and
about intertemporal allocative efficiency will have to be revised drastically.
I shall return to a more complete discussion of these issues in Section \"
below.
II. Previous Studies and Data Description
A. Previous Work on Saving Behavior

For several decades, econometric work on saving behavior consisted
largely of estimating Keynesian-type consumption functions. The inclusion
of an interest-rate variable in such analysis was the exception rather than
the rule. Further, when interest rates were included, nominal before-tax
rates rather than real after-tax rates were used. Feldstein ( l 9i0) ha,
demonstrated that such a procedure almost certainly biases do,vnward the
estimated interest elasticity. Since most of the early work on consumption
and saving focused on issues other than the effect of interest rates,
perhaps it is not surprising that little attention was paid to the weak, and
sometimes negative, relationship between saving and the rate of intere~ i.
Musgrave and ::\Iusgrave (1974, p. 478) report- that "studies of the relationship between saving and the rate of interest differ- in their conclusion.
Some hold that there is a substantial negative relationship, while others
attribute little weight to the rate of interest in the consumption function ...
It is curious, however, that little attention is paid to interest rates in
consumption functions in the large-scale econome.tric macromodcls in
widespread use today.
Several recent studies of saving have included interest rates. as determinants of saving. \\"right (1969) includes a measure of after-tax rates of·
return on stocks and bonds in estimating consumption functions from
U.S. annual time-series data. His estimates imply an interest elasticity 0l
saving of approximately 0.2. As he himself notes, this is substantial!:
larger than the usual assumption and, despite his efforts, may be closer r.
the total than the pure-substitution elasticity. However, his measures <,,
consumption and income suffer from several deficiencies, and his. data
refer to the period prior to 1958. Hence, at the very least, his results must
be improved and updated.
Weber (1970, 1975) examines the impact of interest rates on aggregate
consumption. He finds a posifive relationship between consumer expendi7

This qurstion is analyzrd in detail in Fddstt·in (1978).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

66
S8

JOt:RSAL OF POLITICAL ECONO!'.1Y

tu res and nominal interest rates. In the second study, he includes the
expected inflation rate as a determinant of consumer expenditures but
finds no evidence that expected inflation affects consumption.
In a study of quarterly C.S. a!{~regate postwar data, Taylor !1970)
estimates an enormous interest ela~ticity, approximately 0.B. Since his
study is directed toward other issues, he merely reports this result without
attempting to explain why his estimate is several times larger than that of
other researchers. Perhaps this is because it is unclear that he is estimating a
structural equation rather than a reduced form from some larger system.
Finally, in a thought-provokini.{ ·reexamination of Denison's Law,
David and Scadding ( 1974) document the continued constancy of the
gross private saving rate, the constancy of the saving rate augmented to
include consumer durables purchases in saving and the rental flow from
durables in income, and changes in the composition of private sadng
between the household and business sectors. They interpret this relative
eonstan·cy of the gross private saving rate as evidence that taxes-either
through a reduction in private income or a reduction in the real net rate
of return on capital-do not affect private saving behavior. \\.hile this
argument also has been made by a large number of other economists, I
shall demonstrate below that drawing such behavioral inferences from
these data is not warranted.
In brief summary, there is n:ry little empirical evidence from which to
infer a positi\-c relationship !substitution effect outweighing income effect)
between savin1; and the real net rate of return to capital. Surprisingly
little attention has been paid to this issue-particularly in light of its key
role in answering many important policy questions-and those studies
which do attempt to deal with it can be improved substantially.
B. The Data

The data used in this study came from a \·ariety of sources reporting on
aggregate C .S. annual time series from 1929 to 1969. '.\lost of the data are
derived from the complete-and consistent-accounting system for the
private sector of the C.S. economy de\·eloped by Christensen and Jorgenson (1973). These data include information on private income, gross
saving, wealth, consumer expenditure, labor compensation, property
compensation, rates of return on capital disaggregated into four sectors,
depreciation, replacement, and revaluation of assets. They are worked up
from the C .S. national income and product accounts and other sources;
Di\·isia price and quantity indexes arc used throughout.
Data arc also used directly from the national income and product
accounts, the Statistics of Income, and a variety of miscellaneous sources.
The definitions of the main ,·aria hies used in the study, with emphasis on
how they differ from conventional definitions, arc as follows:

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

67
Sg

TAXATION, SAVING, ASD THE INTEREST RATE

Gross private savi11g.--This constitutes national income accounts' (XIA)
definition of gross prh-ate saving plus personal expenditures on durable
goods plus statistical discrepancy. Christensen and Jorgenson :,1973)
include the surplus in the social insurance trust funds; for the period
under study this makes little difTcrencr. I present gross private sa\·ing
rates with and without the surplus included in tables I and 2 below.
Xet private saving.-This is gross private saving less replacement and
depreciation. Depreciation is estimated for each type of capital good and
assumed to be geometric; while this may or may not, be the best form to
TABLE 1
GRoss PRIVATE SAnsG RATES, L'.S. Ecosm1Y, 1929-69

1929 ...............•
1930 ............... .
1931 ............... .
1932 ............... .
1933 ............... .
193-t- ............... .
1935 ............... .
1936 ............... .
1937 ............... .
1938 ............... .
1939 ............... .
19-10 ............... .
19-11 ..•••••.•.•.••••
19-tl ............... .
19-13 ............... .
19-1-1 ............... .
19-15 ............... .
19-t-6 ............... .
19-17 ................ .
19-t-8 ............... .
19-19 ... : ........... .
1950 ..............•.
1951 ............... .
1952 ............... .
1953 ............... .
195-t- ............... .
1955 ............... .
1956 ............... .
1957 ............... .
1958 ............... .
1959 ............... .
1960 ...............•
1961 ............... .
1962 ............... .
1963 ............... .
196-t- ............... .
1965 ............... .
1966 ............... .
1967 ............... .
1968 ............... .
1969 ............... .

CPS GXP

GPSS'GXP

.222
.18-1
.168
.!02
.I0-1
.1-16
.173
.203
.20-1
.176
.206
.:!25
.255
.298
.28(i
.307
.275
.222
.212
.236
.239
.2-t-3
.2-H
.236
.237
.235
.2-t-6
.238
.237
.225
.227
.219
.217
.228
.227
.239
.243

.221
.183
.166
.099
.102
.144
.171
.199
.187
.163
.193
.213
.2-t-l
.282
.266
.286
.253
.245
.196
.224
.230
.240
.232
.225
.228
.228
.239
.230
.230
.225
.223
.212
.21-1
.223
.219
.231
.236
.236
.236
.230
.237

.U9
.2-18
.240
.251

Snl·1tt:l·.--(:;.,kulatetl from (:hrisu-nscn .tml Jnri:t•n«>n [l!)i31.
Xo,-1:. -(;PS ..: ~ro-.-. pri\·atr ..;a\·im: a.~ tlclmcd in text anJ GPSS = CPS
plus :mrp~us in social irnmram.·c an·ouut.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

68
JOVRNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY

S10

TABLE 2
SAVISC: Ol'."r OF PRIVATt: fNr.OME ASI> :\'F.T SAVIS<: RATF.,

U.S. Ecoso~1Y, 192!)-fj9

Gl'SiDl'I

Yrar

··········

.18
.14
.II

..........

.06
.06
.OIi
.II
.14
.l.'i
.II
.14
.17
.21
.19

1929
1930 ··········
1931 ..........
1932 ..........
1933
1934 . ·········
193.'i ..........
1936 ..........
1937 ..........
1938 ..........
1939 ..........
1940 ..........
1941 ..........
1942 ..........
1943 ··········
1944 ..........
1945 ..........
1946 ··········
1947 ..........
1948 ..........
1949 ..........
1950 ·······
1951 ..........
19.'l2 ..........
1953 ··········
19.'i4 ··········
195.'i ··········
1956 ..........
1957 ··········
19.'i8 ..........
1959 ..........
19fi0 ..........
1961 ..........
19fi2 ..........
1963 ··········
1964 ..........
1965 ··········
1966 ··········
1967 ..........
1968 ··········
1969 ..........

...

.18
.21
.21
.22
.22
.24
.24
.27
.27
.26
.28
.27
.30
.29
.29
.28
.29
.29
.29
.32
.32
.35
.31>
.38
.39
.39
.38

:\'I'S, :\':\'P

.01;2
-.00.'i
-.0'.i9
- .l.'i0
-.131
-.IHI!
.010
.0G8
.0G9
.017
.0fi7
.099
.H7
.199
.200
.229
.19.'i
.130
.108
.126
. I Iii
.122
.119
.106
.108
.099
.118
.099
.092
.072
.0113

.OH
.071
.093
.092
.109
. I lfi
.126
.119
.110
.096

::\'PSS.:\'::\'P

.061
-.007
-.042
- .l.'i3
-.134
-.050
.008
.063
.050
.002
.052
.085
.130
.181
.179
.206
.171
.Ill
.091
.112
.106
.118
.106
.093
.098
.092
.110
.090
.083
.072
.078
.066
.068
.086
.083
.099
.108
.110
.105
.097
.080

Sot·Rcr..-SC"c tahlc I for !.ourc-C".

:\cn1:.-:\PS = net pri\·ate "aviru:. XXP -..: m•t national income, and
:\PSS .:;.:: net pri\·atc sa\·inq plu!-1 surplu"i in social insurancr arcount.

impose on the data, it is probably a substantial improvement over the
NIA depreciation figures (which arc reconciled to IRS tax depreciation
figures ,vhich, in turn, bear no simple relationship to true depreciation).
use of other measures of depreciation docs not alter the conclusions
reached below.
Disposable private income.-C:nlike the XIA definition, I include retained
earnings as part of disposable income. Also inchtdcd is the rental flow from
durables.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

69
TAXATION, SAVI.NG, AND THE INTEREST RATE

S11

National income (net and .t:ross).-This includes the rental flow from
consumer durables.
Wealth.-This is the market value of private nonhuman assets.
Rates of return.-Thcse arc nominal after-tax rates of return from Christensen and Jorgenson (I 973). Also used were the :'.\loody's .-\aa bond rate,
adjusted for the average marginal tax rate on interest income, from
Statistics of /11come, and Standard and Poor's high-grade tax-free municipal
bond rate.
Expected inflatian rate.-This rate is estimated from an adaptive expectations model of price expectations, truncated after 8 years, with varying
speeds of adjustment. Expectations were projected fon-vard to form longrun average rates for 5, l 0, and 20 years.
Miscellaneous.-This category includes population, unemployment· rates,.
price data, and other components· of income from :'\I.-\ or the Economic
Report of the President. All magnitudes are expressed in constant 1958
prices from Christensen and Jorgenson (1973); aggregate magnitudes are
expressed in per capita terms.

III. Private Saving
The relative constancy of the gross private saving rate-the ratio of
gross private saving to gross national income-so well documented by
David and Scadding ( 1974) fails to reveal a variety of important features
of private saving in the United States. For the sake. of comparison, table l
presents gross private saving rates for the L' .S. economy, 1929-69, with and
without the social insurance fund :.urplus included in the measure of
gross saving. Again, the relative constancy of this ratio in years of full
employment is obvious. In the postwar period, it ranges from 20 to 24
percent, with most of the observations at 22 or 23 percent. 8
The gross private saving rate is the product of the saving rate out of
disposable income and the ratio of disposabl_e income to total income,
that is,

GPSR = GPS = GPS x DPI .
G::'\P
G::'\P DPI

(I)

\Ve know that taxes as a percentage of total income have risen substantially
over this period. Hence, the saving rate out ofdisposablcincome must have
increased substantially to offset the decline in the ratio of private to total
income. Table 2 documents this fact; indeed, the saving rate out of
private net-of-tax income has increased by more than 50 percent since the
early postwar period. The behavioral interpretation given to these data by
David and Scadding (1974) is tha.t taxes and present consumption arc
8 Recall that thl' inclusion of consumer durables raises this rate from l.'i percent to 16
percent of thl' conn·ntional measure.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

70
JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY

essentially perfect substitutes: the rise in taxes is offset by an equivalent
decline in current consumption. They go on to explore a variety of
intriguing conjectures concerning consumer behavior.
Three basic points need to be made concerning this conjecture. First,
most theories of consumer behavior relate saving to disposable income. If
this is correct, the saving rate varies substantially. A direct test of whether
disposable income or total income is the appropriate variable in a private
saving function is presented below.
Second, it indeed would be surprising if consumers made this type of
rational calculation vis-a-vis the government and business sectors in terms
of gross saving and income. Consumers know their capital depreciates.
Again, our economic theories generally relate to how consumers choose
their net position. Further, except for some possible embodied technical
change, it is net saving that is relevant to the issue of whether taxes affect
capital accumulation. Table 2 presents calculations of the net private
sa,·ing rate-net saving divided by net income. This series exhibits
substantially more relative variation than the gross series and can hardly
be called constant, even if we confine ourselves to the postwar period. 9
\\'hilc depreciation series are notoriously unreliable, use of several alternative series based on tax, replacement cost, etc. depreciation still yields
substantial variation in the net private saving rate: I take this to be a
strong indictment of the structural interpretation of Denison's Law.
Third, even if total gross income and gross saving are examined, there
still may be an independent effect of real net rates of return on saving.
Even if taxes and present consumption are perfect substitutes (the public
sector is doing its benefit-cost analyses properly, free-rider issues are
ignored, etc.), the share of private wealth consumed today (publicly or
privately) will depend upon the net, or after-tax, return to saving, whereas
gross income is the flow from private wealth at the gross return. Hence,
taxes decreasing the net return to saving may cause a decrease in saving.
Before proceeding to a variety of estimates of saving equations, it is
perhaps worthwhile to offer a brief conjecture on the apparent constancy
of the saving rate. Consider two motives for saving: smoothing of consumption over the life cycle and bequests. Further, assume bequests
(broadly construed to include provision of education as well as pure
financial bequests) arc luxuries. Hence, real income growth would tend to
increase saving. However, if saving is also positively related to the real net
return on capital, the slight decline in this rate would lead to a decrease in
saving. Hence, the two effects offset one another. Xo doubt many other
effects have been at work as well. Thus, I find it extremely difiicult to
give any structural or behavioral interpretation to the constancy of the
gross private saving rate.
9 Hone took the broadrr \'icw of sa\'ing as inclusive of human inn~stment, ust· of Kt·ndrick's (in pressi data re\·eals still more variability in the total saving rate, gross as well as

net.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

71
TAXATION, SAVING, AND THE INTEREST RATE

Merely pointing out some difficulties in interpretation of some data
docs not suffice to reject the conjecture outright nor docs it provide an
ahcrnative behavioral interpretation. Hence, I turn now to estimates of
the effect of taxes on private saving, that is, to estimates of consumption
functions.
Equation (2) presents my basic estimate of a (private) consumption
function: 10
LGCOXSP = -.3.8 + 0.56 LGDPI + 0.18 LGDPI(-1)
( 1.3) (0.12)
(0.08)
+ 0.28 LGWLTH( - I) - 0.003 LGU:\'E:\l
(0.06)
(0.0 I)

R2

=

.99;

SSR

= 0.00171;

(2)

l.07R,
(0.31)

SE= 0.0088;

where LGCO:\'SP is the natural logarithm of real per capita private
consumption, DPI is disposable private income, WL TH is wealth,
U:\'E:\l is the unemployment rate, R is the real after-tax return on
capital, ( - I) indicates a one-period lag, SE is the estimated standard
error of the regression, and SSR is the sum of squared residuals. Estimated
SEs appear in parentheses below the estimated coefficients.
The equation performs quite well by conventional standards. The
estimated SE is a tiny fraction of the mean value of the dependent variable. The individual coefficients are measured relatively precisely and
have the expected signs. The important thing to note is the positive real
rate-of-return effect; the estimated interest elasticity of saving at mean
values of the variables is approximately one-fourth. Also note that the
implied income elasticity of saving exceeds unity.
A variety of authors have conjectured on the effect of inflation on
saving. For example, Mundell (1963) argues that inflation increases
saving because it destroys the value of accumulated wealth and consumers
attempt to restore their wealth-income position. There is also an uncertainty argument which leads to a similar result: consumers hedge by
spreading the loss of income over more than one period. These effects may
offset any indirect effects of the rate of inflation acting through the real
rate of return. \\"c have thus entered the expected rate of inflation (x) as an
additional rcgressor in the basic equation. This yields
LGCOXSP

= -0.46 + 0.57 LGDPI + 0.18 LGDPI(-1)

(3)
( 1.34) (0.12)
(0.08)
+ 0.26 LG\VLTH(-1) - 0.003 LGC'XEM - 1.07 R - 0.29 x,
(0.07)
(0.011)
(0.33)
(0.06)
R2

= .99;

SSR

=

0.0017;

SE

= 0.0091.

• 0 All equations delete 19-1-1-46. The Cochrane-Orcutt adjustment for serial correlation
has been made in this and subsequent equations when necessary.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

72
Sq.

JOl'RNAL OF POLITICAL ECONO:\IY

The estimated real net ratt·-oJ:return elasticity is still substantial, virtually
unchanged at about one-quarter. The other coefficients arc hardly
ani:cted, and expected inflation does have the expected negative sign for
consumption, hole.ling r constant.
,\ Ioglinear specification gi,·es similar results:

=

-0.60 + 0.56 LGDPI + 0.17 LGDPI(-1)
(4)
t 1.29 J i'fl.12)
(0.0B)
+ 0.2B LG\\'LTll( -1) - O.OO·l LGC:'\E~I - 0.041 LGR,
,0.06)
(0.01)
(0.01 I)

u;c:O:'\SP

R2

= .99;

. SSR

=

0.0017;

SE

= 0.0088.

Again, the estimated interest elasticity is around one-four'th, and the
other estimated coefficients arc quite similar to those from the semilog
specifications. 11
The measure of the real net rate of return on capital in\'olves three
clements: the nominal rate of return, the tax rate, and the inflation rare.
I ha,-c experimented not only with alternati\'c methods (lag structure,
forward projection, adjmunerit speec.l) of estimating the expected inflation
rate but also with altcrnati\'c measures of the nominal net return. Csc of
the ~loody's Aaa bone.I rate in an equation analogous to (2) yielded an
estimated coefficient of -0.6 with an estimated SE of0.2. This implies an
interest elasticity of slightly less than 0.2. Cse of Standard and Poor's
high-grade municipal bond rate makes it unnecessary to measure marginal
tax rates on capital income; thi~ also yielded an estimated coefficient of
-0.6 with an estimated SE of 0.2; this produced an interest elasticity of
slightly less than 0.2.
There is always a problem in interpreting saving or consumption
functions estimated by single equation mt:thods. It is difficult to believe
that the rate of return (or wealth or income) is exogenous. Since the
sa\'ing function is embodied in a larger model of economic activitywhether a simple growth model or a monetary growth model or a fullscale macroeconometric model-the parameter estimates obtained with
single equation methods may be biased. Since I do not wish to specify a
complete macroeconomctric model, I proceed as tollows: I estimate
consumption functions by an instrumental variable technique using as
instruments principal components of the exogenous \'ariablcs from the
Hickman-Coen annual macroeconomctric model. The problem is thus
n:duced to one of manageable proportions. The exogenous \'ariablcs from
which the principal components arc formed include tax rates, monetary

11 Likl'wis,·. diff..rl'nt adjustment spl'l'ds for inflationary t·xp<Tla1ions and <lilli·n·nt
h·ngth of forward projt·ction of rr produn·d \'irlually idt'ntical rt"sults.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

73
TAXATION, SAVING, AND THE INTEREST RATE

instruments (such as the discount rate and reserve ratio), population,
time, etc. Use of these principal components as instruments yields consist<:,nt estimates of the structural parameters (see Amemiya 1966; Jorgenson and Brundy 1973). This procedure yields 12

=

-5.83 + 0.55 LGDPI + 0.32 LGDPl(-1)
(5)
( 1.55) (0.13)
(0.23)
+ 0.72 LGWLTH(-1) - 0.031 LGUXEM - 2.28 R - 0.36 it,
(0.03)
(0.0 I 4)
(0.62)
(0.2 I)

LGCOXSP

R2

= .99;

SSR

= 0.0087;

SE

= ,0.021.

The equation performs quite well by conventional measures. The (consistent) estimate of the interest elasticity is somewhat larger than with
ordinary least squares, slightly larger than 0.4. Again, it is measured
quite precisely. \\'hile much more work with such estimators is necessary,
these estimates are preferable to those reported above.
Finally, the estimated coefficients for the other variables are quite
similar to the ordinary least-squares estimates except for that on lagged
wealth. Allowing different combinations of the real net rates, wealth, and
income to be endogenous produced a range of estimated wealth elasticities
spanned by those reported here. It may well be that ordinary leastsquares estimates of wealth coefficients are substantially biased downward.
Since the period 1929-69 includes the depression, the mere inclusion of
the unemployment rate may not be sufficient to account for cyclical
fluctuations in saving. Hence, I reestimated the basic equation using
postwar data only:

=

-3.85 + 0.62 LGDPI + 0.007 LGDPI(- I)
(6)
( l. 76) (0.21)
(0.24)
+ 0.72 LGWLTH(-1) :_ 0.003 LGUXEM - 2.08 R + 0.007 it,
(0.05)
(0.02)
(0.81) . (0.14)

LGCOXSP

R2

= .99;

SSR

= 0.0025;

SE

= 0.0139.

The now familiar pattern of a substantial interest elasticity is repeated
with these data. The equation performs less well by the usual measures,
since there is somewhat less variation in each of the series, and the sample
size is reduced sharply when confined to the postwar era. Once again,
however, I estimate a substantial elasticity of saving with respect to the real
net rate of return, about 0.4.
Alternative measures of permanent income produced similar results.
Using the natural logarithm of current and lagged labor income yielded

1 2 Since the data on tht· principal compom·nts, which were supplied kindly by
M. Hurd, go only through 1966, this equation excludes 1967-69.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

74
S16

JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY

TABLE 3
EsTIMATED REAL AFTER-TAX RATE OF RETURN
ELASTICITY OF PRIVATE SAVl:--G

Ordinary Least
Squares
Semilog, Rl ............... .
Log-linear, Rl •....•........
Semilog, R2 and R3 ....... .
Semilog, labor income ....... .
Semilog, postwar only ....... .

Instrumental
Variables

0.4
0.4
0.3
0.60.4

Sot:RCE.-RI derived from Christcnsc.-n•Jorgenson (1973) nominal rate of return,
R2 derived from Moody's Aaa nominal bond )'ields, and R3 derived from Standard
and Poor's high-grade municipal bond )'ields.

an estimated interest-rate coefficient of - 3.32 with an estimated SE of
I. 7; this corresponds to an interest elasticity of 0.6. The worse fit and less
plai:isible estimated coefficients on the other variables are typical of this
theoretically more appealing specification and lead me to reject these
estimates in favor of those reported above.
Finally, the alternative real net rate ofreturn measures yielded estimated
interest coefficients of - 1.32 (estimated SE, 0.29) and - 1.33 (estimated
SE, 0.29) on the Moody-based real net yield on bonds and the Standard
and Poor-based real net yield on tax-free municipals, respectively; these
coefficients correspond to an elasticity of about 0.3.
Table 3 summarizes the empirical results reported above. In brief
summary, alternative sample periods, estimation techniques, measures of
the real after-tax rate of return on capital and measures of permanent
income all lead to the conclusion of a nonnegligible interest elasticity of
private saving. The range of estimates goes from just under 0.2 to around
0.6 and clusters at about 0.3 to 0.4; the estimate I prefer on statistical
grounds is that from equation (5), about 0.4.

IV. Production
In order to gain further insight into the effects of tax-induced changes
in capital accumulation on the distribution of income, I have estimated
production functions from the same data used to estimate private saving.
Recall that a key issue in my two-factor aggregate model is the size of the
elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Increases in the
capitalilabor ratio will lead to increases (decreases) in labor's share of
gross income if the elasticity of substitution is less (greater) than unity.
Further, the increase in the wage/rental ratio due to an increase in the
capital/labor ratio varies inversely with the. elasticity of substitution.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

75
TAXATIOX, SA\ IXC, A!).D THE IS1'EREST RATE
0

Since I am dealing with a two-factor- model, I estimate a CES production function with Ha!'rod-neutral teehnologicaL progress: 13

Yr= ;·[K,- 1'

+

(ELL,)-prltp,

(7)

where y is output, K is the capital input, L is the labor input, t is time,
= EL(0)e-;·', i. is the exponential labor augmenting rate,1 4 and q, the
elasticity of substitution, equals 1/(l + p).
Rearranging (7), it appears that

EL

l~g

(:L) =

c

+

(l - q) log w

+

(q - l)).t,

(8)

where c is a constant and w is the wage rate.
Estimating (8) on data for 1929-69, deleting the war years, for the
private economy yields
log

(:L) = -0.45
+ 0.554 log w - 0.0045 t,
(0.06) (0.034)
(0.002 l)

R2

= .99;

SE= 0.033;

SSR

(9)

= 0.033.

The equation fits the data quite well. The SE of the regression is a small
fraction of the mean value of the dependent variable, and the estimated
coefficients are measured rather precisely. The estimated elasticity of
substitution is 0.45, which is quite similar to the usual time-series estimates. 1 5 This immediately implies that labor's share of gross income varies
in the same direction as the capital/labor ratio. The derived estimate of).,
the labor-augmenting rate, is 0.009. 16
Fit to postwar data alone, I obtain

(Jl'L) =

log -

Y

R2

= .9?;

-0.42 + 0.52 log w - 0.005 I,
(0.18) (0.13)
(0.006)
SE= 0.016;

( IO)

SSR = 0.00-t-5.

13 Diamond (1965) has d<·monstrat<•cl that Harrod nmtrality is the only type of
technological progr,·ss compatible with balanc.-d growth. I inu·rpret my rt'sults as derived
from a Harrocl-nrutral CES production function. If t<'chnical chang<", e.g., was Hicksm·utral, th<' codlici,·nt of log 1t• is intl'rprC'lablc as a direct <·stimate of the dasticity of
substitution. lnd<·<·cl, this is the intcrpr<'tation originally gh·en by Arrow ct al. (1961).
:\011·, hO\wwr, that the t•stimatl' of th<· t·lasticitv of substitution is still about one-half:
14 This sp.-cification thus avoids th.- "impossil,ility" prohlt·m point<·cl out by Diamond
and '.\le Fadden ( 19G5).
15 Sc<' X,·rlove (1967) for a surn:y of estimat.-s of CES production functions. My
estimate is quit,· similar to usual timt· s,·rit-s t·stimates, which in turn art• usually smaller
than cross-srction <'stimat<'s. \\'hilt· tim<'-st·ri,·s estimates mav bl' biased downward bt'causc
of lagg.-d adjustml'nts, Lucas (1969) rt·j,·cts this conjl'Ct~n·. Cross-sectional <·stimatl·s
suffer from a variety ofproblt•ms; sec Lucas (1969).
16 One might think of this as including some exogenous human im·estmcnt.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

76
JOL'RNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY

The estimated elasticity of substitution is 0.48; unfortunately, while the
point estimate of the lahor-augmenting rate is quite similar to that for
the whole period, its estimated SE _is quite large.
As with the estimates of saving functions, the issue of potential bias
in the estimates must be confronted. Possible measurement error and the
endogenicity of wages in a full model lead me to follow the same procedure
as described above for consumption/saving. I use an instrumental variables
estimator, using principal components from the exogenous variables in the
Hickman-Coen model as instruments. This yields
- 0.53 + 0.56 log w - 0.005 t,
(0.02) (0.04)
(0.002)
R2

=

.99;

SE

= 0.034;

SSR

(11)

= 0.032.

Again, the equation fits quite well. The estimated elasticity of substitution
is 0.44, and the estimated labor-augmenting rate is 0.009; both estimates
are quite close to those reported above.
\\"hile increases in the capital/labor ratio will increase the wage/rental
ratio (which is probably a more insightful way to analyze tax incidence in
a growing economy than examining factor shares) regardless of the
elasticity of substitution, these results suggest that policies which increase
capital accumulation will increase labor's gross share of national income.
I now turn to a more detailed examination of the implications of my
empirical results.
V. Implications for Income, Welfare, and Income Distribution

As discussed in Section I, these results have striking implications for
tax policy. The current tax treatment of income from capital-primarily
the personal and corporate income taxes-decreases the net rate of return
to capital accumulation; the modest positive real net of interest elasticity
thus implies a substantial tax-induced decrease in saving and the capital
intensity of production, a reallocation of consumption from the future to
the present, and a substantial transfer of gross income from labor to
capital. To estimates of these effects I now turn.

A. Welfare
The welfare analysis of interteinporal resource allocation involves a
variety of complex issues which are beyond the scope of this paper. For
example, external benefits to saving and investment (e.g., learning by
doing) may render the social rate of return higher than the private rate;
other distortions (e.g., lack of a complete set of futures markets) may be
important. If, however, I proceed in the usual manner and ignore all.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

77
S19

TAXATION, SAVING, AND THE INTEREST RATE

distortions other than taxes and argue that to a first approximation the
saving rate would be effi~ienr in the absence of taxes, I may adopt the
usu~l consumer surplus measure of lost welfare: one-half the product of
the tax-induced increase in the price of future consumption and the
compensated change in future consumption. Feldstein ( 1978) shows that
this product may be written as

dll" = -1/2 (1

+ :~)

(p• ;

1

Por S.,

(12)

where P 0 and P 1 are the prices of future consumption before and after
taxes on capital income are imposed (e' -,T;i -µ> and e-' 7 ), µ is the marginal rate of tax on capital income, r is the net rate of return on capital, T
is the length of time between saving and dissaving, S 1 is saving for future
consumption, and e5 , is the compensated interest elasticity of the saving
rate.
Recall that, since the private sector is a net saver, the income and substitution effects of a change in the rate of return work in opposite directions. Hence, my estimates are lower bounds on the pure-substitution
elasticity. The real net rate of return, r, averages about 3 or 4 percent
over my sample period; T, the average length of time between saving
and dissaving, is probably around 25 years. Hence, examining (12), it
can be seen that the contribution of the real net rate-of-return elasticity
to lost welfare is magnified by the factor lirT ~ 4/3.
While Jl varies substantially by the type of capital and the progressive
rate structure of the personal income tax makes it difficult to measure
marginal, as opposed to average, tax rates, I adopt 50 percent as a
reasonable estimate ofµ. Harberger ( 1969) suggests that 60 percent is a
good approximation; Pechman and Okner (19H) argue that 40 percent
is better. The former figure does not deal adequately with the nonprofit
sector, whereas the latter fails to impute any indirect business taxes to
capital. Since S 1 is saving for future consumption, total net private
saving understates S1 because of the dissa\'ing of the elderly population
during retirement. If the population grows at 1-2 percent and real income
grows at 3 percent per year, and T = 25 years, S 1 equals about one and
one-halftimes total net private saving, about S200 billion. Estimates of the
annual welfare loss resulting from the tax-induced distortion of the timing
of consumption over the life cycle for different values of e5 , and r are
rcports:d in table 4. ::\fy preferred estimate, based on r = 0.4 and e5 , =
0.4, yields an estimate of the annual welfare loss o( close to S60 billion!
This estimate is rather insensitive to variations in r and only modestly
sensitive to variations in e5 ,.
In comparison with previous studies of the welfare loss from differential
taxation of different types of capital, these numbers are cnormous. 17 They
17

Ser Harberger 19(j6 and Sho\'rn and \\'hall .. y 1972.


35-570 0 - 79 - 6
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

78
JOL'RNAL OF POLITICAL ECONO!\IY

S20

T.\BLE 4
EsTl~IATEI> AxxUAL \\ ELFARF. CosT
OF Ct.:RREXT CAPITAL Ixco~IE TAXATIO!li
0

($Billions)
Esr

.03 ............... .
.0-¼ ...•...••.••...•
.06 ............... .

.2

.3

.4

H.6
48.0
48.3

48.3
52.0
52.3

52.1
56.0
56.3

amount to an astounding- waste of resources. Recall that these estimates
are annual costs to society. The present value of these costs is a large
multiple of the annual costs (the exact relation depending upon the
assumed rate ofdiscountj and can easily amount to hundreds of billions of
dollars. \'it'wcd another way, if we abolished. taxes on income from
capital this year, by the end of the decade welfare would have increased by
close to S200 billion, or about twice the current annual yield of the
individual income tax!
These estimates highlight the fact that the current tax treatment of
income from capital induces consumers to save less for consumption later
in life-primarily old age-than is socially optimal. It seems strange
simultaneously to reduce substantially the return to saving-and, hence,
private prO\·ision for retirement-and to attempt to increase provision for
retirement publicly through social security, which in turn may well
decrease private saving. 18 \ \'hile both the taxation of capital income and
the social security system serve other goals, they arc in basic conflict in the
attempt to pro\·ide retirement or old-age consumption.
DQ such enormous welfare costs make sense? First, extrapolating the
estimated interest elasticity over a large change in tax-induced variations
in the real after-tax rate of return may not be warranted. On the other
hand, the estimated elasticities arc a lower bound on the pure-substitution
elasticities, since they include a negative income effect of interest rate
increases on saving.
Second. substituting taxes on labor income for those on capital income
can produce a distortion in labor markets, for example, in the allocation
of work between home and market. While most estimates of labor-supply
functions suggest an a.~grcgate supply of labor which is quite wage inelastic,. it is quite dillicult to measure labor supply in the envelope sensesubsuming effort and human investment-and taxes affect human investment in a variety of offsetting ways. 19 Since one reason a person works
early in life is to save for future consumption, cross elasticities as well as
18
iq

Se,· F,·lclstcin 19Hb and :\lunn<"ll 1975.
Se,· Hoskin 19i6.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

79
TAXATION, SAVING, AXD THE IXTEREST RATE

S21

own elasticities arc important; the interested reader is referred to Feldstein
( l 978) for a detailed discussion. I merely note that my estimates must be
adjusted downward to get the m·t clTect of substituting labor income taxes
for capital income taxes.
Finally, one might expect that such an enormous inefficiency would
result in an intense pressure to revive the tax laws or to provide retirement
consumption. Indeed, social insurance benefits have grown rapidly, and
increasing!)' generous treatment of income placed in retirement plans has
been a key fc~ture of recent tax reform.
B. Income and Its Distribution

The long-run elTect of changes in the structure of capital income taxes on
income and its distribution depends upon the exact change being considered. For example, integration of corporate and personal income taxes
or switching from income to consumption as the base of personal taxation,
or both, will increase income substantially if the rise in the real net rate of
return is not offset by other policies (government saving, monetary
policy, etc.). Assuming that no other policies arc enacted which alTect the
real after-tax rate of return and that an equal current-yield consumption
tax replaces current capital income taxation,2° the real net rate of return,
with p = 0.5, will double in the short run. This will lead to an increase in
saving and in the capital/labor ratio and wage rates and to a fall in the
gross rate of return to capital.
Feldstein ( 1974a) derives the relationship between the net rate of return
to capital and capital income taxes in a growth model with factor
taxes and \·ariable saving rates. The estimates reported above (real netinterest elasticity of saving of 0.4, elasticity of substitution of 0.45, etc.)
imply an elasticity of the net rate of return with respect to capital income
tax rates of 0.3 (an elasticity of substitution of I would imply 0.6). 21
Hence, a complete abolition of capital income taxation would increase the
real net rate of return some 30 percent (or more if the elasticity of substitution is larger). Since the capital/labor ratio increases in proportion to
S/rx, where S is net saving and :x is labor's share of gross income, my estimates imply a new steady-state capital/labor ratio some 15-20 percent
larger than currently.
From the production function and competitive factor markets,
JF
log-= C +(I+ p) logk,

( 13)

T
20 It is quitr likely that a prrsonal consumption tax would. ha\'r progrrssi\'r rates:
inck('(I, this often O\'l'rlookl'cl fact makes thr distributional dfrcts ofswitc-hing from incom<'
to ronsumption taxes much more palatable.
21 Extrapolations m·•·r ~uch a large range arc somewhat hazardous. I prrsent here only
illustratiw calculations.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

80
JOt:RNAL OF POLITICAL ECONO!\fY

S22

where p is the substitution parameter in the CES form, that is, p = I /CT
- I, where CT is the elasticity of substitution. Hence, my estimate of p is
around 1.2. Thus, a 15-20 pc-rcent increase ink would result in a 33-44
percent increase ·in the wagc-:'rental ratio; the abolition of capital income
taxation transfers gross income from capital to labor.
Further,

wL
'"'rK

lo" -

=C+

p log k,

( 14)

so the 15-20 percent increase in k implies an increase in this ratio of factor
shares of about 18-24 percent. Since the factor-share ratio is currently
around 3, it would increase to about 3.6. Thus, capital's share of gross
income would fall by around I 5 percent.
,
\\"ith the general distributional pattern dewloped above, I mention
briefly two other important tax-incidence issues. First, the results presented above imply a substantial shifting of capital income taxes from
_capital to labor due to the decreased capital/labor ratio caused by current
tax treatment. Again, Feldstein ( 1974a) develops a formula to measure
this differential incidence; my estimates imply that capital shifts approximately one-half of the burden of capital income taxes onto labor. Failure
to account for tax shifting via decreased saving has led many researchers
to coneluc.le that taxes on income from capital are much more progressive
than they really are in fact; for example, the excellent study by Pechman
and Okner (1974) ignores these long-run effects: capital income taxes are
generally considered borne by capital and general income taxes in proportion to income. 22 The results reported here suggest that each of these
procedures may overstate substantially the progressivity of such taxes.
Second, my results on the interest elasticity of the saving rate suggest
that proposals to integrate the corporate and personal income tax which
arc financed by increases in labor income taxation or consumption taxation would increase saving, the capital/labor ratio, welfare, the wage/
rental ratio, and labor's share of gross income.
These transfers of gross income from capital to labor from tax policies
which decrease capital income taxation must be offset against the decrease
in taxes on income from capital and possible increase in taxes on labor
income to compare after-tax incomes. Further, the full transfer of gross
income will take a period of years to occur.
This immediately raises the issue of what to assume about tax revenue
and rates along the new growth path. Further, I have ignored government
saving. The net increase in the capital/labor ratio must net out any
22 Pcchman and Oknrr (1974) do provide careful estimatrs based on a varirty of
gem·rally accepted incidence assumptions; however. rill· casl" of a large share- of capital
incom,· taxrs being borne by labor is not included.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

81
TAXATION, SAVING, ANO THE I:STEREST RATE

changes in government saving. 23 Since the increased capital.'labor ratio
will result in a corresponding increase in per-capita output, tax revenues at
constant rates will increase well above what they would have been before
an initial year equal-yield change. One may choose to compare situations
with equal revenue year by year, or with equal shares of taxes in gross
income, or with the initial rates continuing, or with still other scenarios.
Hence, to give an accurate picture, one must compare changes in after-tax
incomes under some well-defined set of assumptions about the course of
tax rates. 24
I shall not attempt to deal with this conceptual issue here. I merely note
that, in addition to the usual efficiency arguments in favor of abolishing
taxes on interest income, 25 and the often overlooked potential horizontal
equity arguments in favor of consumption taxation, 26 the analysis and
empirical evidence described above cast serious doubt on the usual
comparison of the distributional effects of income and consumption taxes.
Again, while the net effect on income and its distribution depends upon
the specific set of assumptions made, the general argument remains the
same: the modest positive interest elasticity implies that tax policiesfrom corporate and personal income tax integration or switching to
consumption taxes-which lower taxes on income from capital will
increase saving, the capital intensity of production, income, and welfare
and, further, will transfer gross income from capital to labor.

C. The Social Opportunity Cost of Public I11veslme11t
The results reported above on the interest elasticity of the saving rate
have striking implications for the social opportunity cost of public funds
and hence the rate of discount to be used in public benefit-cost analyses.
Two schools of thought have emerged on this issue. One group of writers
suggests that the gross-of-tax marginal product of capital in the private
sector is the appropriate rate. Another group of writers suggests that the
social rate ought to be lower than the private rate due to intergenerational
external economics. Leaving the issue of reducing the social rate of discount
to account for such effects aside, I note that the gross-of-tax marginal
product of capital in the private sector is appropriate only if the public
funds arc obtained exclusively from a reduction in private investment.
This generally is assumed to occur as government borrowing drives up the
rate of interest and chokes off private investment.
2 l !\fy prdiminary •·sti111atcs r<'n·al a much lowl'r gon-rnnwnt prop,-nsity to invrst out
of n·,·,·mll's than th(' privatr s.-ctor's prop('nsity to sa, ... out of income.
2 "' And oth<'r policirs.
25 s..,. .\fusgra,·,· 19.'i9, chap. 12.
lb Sine<" cons11mp1ic,n is a morr stahk function of prrmarwnt incomr 1han is c11rrrnt
income·, a consump1ion 1ax may improve our ability to tax Jll'rsons with thf' samr p,·rmanrnt inconw at thr ,anw ra1<·.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

82
JOL'RNAL OF POLITICAL ECONO!\fY

T.\BLE .>
EsTI\IATED Soc:uL OrP0Rn·:s1TY CosT
OF Pniuc: F1·:sns

'.\Iarginal Product of
Capital

Social Opportunity Cosi
of 1'11hlic Funds
w

p

<'X,)

1'1/.,i
7 ............

:i.fi
8.Y

12 . . . . . . . . . . . .

:'.\ly results, however, suggest that such an increase in the rate of
interest will call forth an increase in pri\·ate saving. Hence, the public
funds come partly from decreased private investment and partly from
increased private saving. Hence, the social opportunity cost of the public
funds (as pointed out by Harbcrger P969J) is a weighted average of the
opportunity costs of the foregone investment and private consumption
foregone in favor of increased private saving, that is, of the gross-of-tax
marginal product of capital in the private sector and the net-of-tax real
rate of return to savers. the supply price of private sa\·ing;. The weights,
of course, reflect the relative proportion of decreased private investment
and increased pri\·ate sa\·ing in prm·iding the public funds: that is, they
depend upon the interest elasticity of investment and saving, respectively.
The formula is the following:
rSt:,
St:_,

pft/1

=

w,

where rand p arc the real net return to savers and the real ·gross marginal
product of capital, S and / arc saving and investment, and t:_, and 17 1
arc the interest elasticity of saving and investment, respeccively.
The real net return to sa\·ing, r, is much smaller than the gross marginal
product of capital, p, due to business and personal income taxes; r is
about 0.03; for the production function estimated above, p is 0.07.
Typical estimates of p based on Cobb-Douglas production functions arc
around 0.12. Table 5 presents estimates of the social opportunity cost
of public im-cstmcnt for estimates of p of 0.07 and 0.12, current estimates
of S and /, and estimates of 17 1 of - 1.0 and i:., of 0. 4. 2 7 The social opportuni cy cost of capital in each case is substantially smaller than the gross
marginal product of capital. Hence, social cost-benefit analyses should
discount future benefits and costs at a rate substantially below the marginal
product of capital in the priYate sector, irrespective of am· intergenerational external economics. Indeed, use of the g-ross marginal product of
27 Economrtric ,·,·idcnn· on T/t spans a wick ran~c; si·,· Hall and .Jor~•·nson 'IYliiJ.
Coen , 1969··. and rdi:rences cited then·in.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

83
TAXATION, SA\"ISC, AND THE ISTEREST RATE

capital as the discount rate causes both an underinvestment and an
inellicient compo~ition_ofpublic investment in favor ofshort-liwcl proj<'ct~.

VI. Conclusion

I have presented a good deal of evidence which suggests that there is a
positive relationship between private sa\·ing and the rate of return . .-\
varietv of definitions of variables, functional forms, and estimation
meth~ds all le<l to this conclusion. This relationship has immensely
important implications for economic policy. Among the more important
are that the current tax treatment of income from capital induces an
astounding loss in welfare due to the distortion of the consumption/
saving choice and that reducing taxes on interest income would i_n the
long run raise the level of income and transfer a substantial portion of
capital's share of gross income to labor. The overall distributional effects
of such a policy combine this long-run effect with that of the exemption of
interest income from taxation.
Taken as a whole, the results reported here substantially strengthen
the case for reforming the tax treatment of income from capital in the
United States, for example, integration of the corporate and personal
income taxes or, better yet, switching from income to consumption
taxation.
They also have obvious implications for the potential effectiveness of
monetary policy in the short and long run.

References
Amemiya, T. "On the L"se of Principal Components of Independent \'ariablcs
in Two-Stage Least Squares Estimation." /11/emat. Econ. Rel·. 7 (September
1966j :. 283-303.
Arrow, K.; Chenery, H.; :\linhas. B.; and Solow, R. "Capital-Labor Substitution
and Economic Efficiency." Rel'. Econ. Statis. -J.3 (.-\ugust 1961): 225-50.
Boskin • .'.\Iichael. ":Xotes on the Tax Treatment of Human Capital." Conference
on Tax Policy. Washington: U.S. Department of the Treasury, 1976.
Break, G. "The Incidence and Economic Effects of Taxation." In The Economics
of Public Finance. by A. Blinder et al. Washington: Brookings Inst., 197-J..
Christensen, L., and Jorgenson, D. "L'.S. Income, Sadng and \\'ealth, 1929-69."
Rev. Income and Wealth, series 19, no. -J. (December 1973): 329-62.
Coen, R. "Tax Policy and Investment Behavior: Comment." A.E.R. 59, no. 3
(1969): 370-79.
David, Paul, and Scadding, John L. "Private ~aving: L'ltrarationality, Aggregation, and 'Denison's Law.'" J.P.E. 82, no. 2, pt. I (:\farch,'.-\pril 1974) :_225--19.
Diamond, Peter A. "Disembodied Technical Change in a Two-Sector :\lode!."
Rel'. Econ. Studies 32 (April 1965): 161-68.
- - - . "Incidence of an Interest Income Tax.'' J. Econ. Theory 2 (September
1970): 211-U.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

84
JOt:R!SAL OF POLITIC:Al. EGONO~IY

Diamond. Peter A., and .'.\lcfadden, D ... Identification of the Elasticity of Substitution and the Bias of Technological Change." .'.\limeographed. Bl·rkcley:
Cni,·. California. l!J65.
Feldstein • .'.\lartin. "lntlation. Specification Bias, and the Impact of Interest
Rates." J.P.E. 78, no. 6 (Xo\'cmber December l!l70j: 1325-39.
- - - . ··lncidencc ofa Capital lnrnmc Tax in a Growing Economy with \·ariable
Sa,·ings Rates." Rcr. Econ. Studies .J.I (October 19i.J.;: 505-13. (a)
- - - . "SoC'ial ScC'urity, Induced Retirement. and .-\ggregate Capital .\ccumulation ... J.P.E. 82, no. 5. pt. 2 (Scptember,Octobcr 19i.J.): 905-26. (bi
- - - . ··Tax lncidcncT in a Growing Economy with \"ariablc· Factor Supply."
Q..I.E. B8 (Xon·mbcr l!li.J.i: 5:,1-H. \Ci
- - - . ··The \\ elfare Costs of Capital Income Taxes." J.P.E. ll6. no. 2, pt. 2
(.-\pril 1978' : S29-S5 l.
Economic Growth." Proceeding1 r!f the Sational Tax Association. San Francisco:
:.'\at. Tax .-\ssoc .. 19611.
Hall. R .. and Jorgenson. D. ''Tax Policy and lm·estment Beha,·ior." .·I.ER. 57,
no. 3 ;June 1967;: 3!ll-.J.l.J..
Harbl·rger . .-\mold C. "Eflit:iency Effects of Taxes on Income from Capital." In
Fjfrct.r of the Cor/1oration Income Tax, edited by .'.\larian Krzyzaniak. Detroit:
\\'ayne State Cni,·. Press, El66.
---."Introduction." In T;,r Ta"l:atiun of Income from CaJ,ital, edited by .\ruold C.
Harbc-rgcr and .'.\lartinJ. Bailey. \\'ashiugton: Brookings Inst.. t<l6!l.
- - - . ··On .'.\Ieasuring the Social Opportunity Cost of Public Funds." In
Project Ernluation, by .\mold C. Harberger. Chicago: Cni\'. Chicago, 1976.
Hickman. Ban G.: Coen. R.: and Hurd . .'.\1. •'The Hickman-Coeu .-\nnual (;rowth
.'.\lodcl: Structural Characteristics and Policy Rl'sponses." /11/ernat. Econ. Re1·.
16 , Februarv 19i5;: 20-37.
Jorgenson,
and Brundy, J. '·Consistent Efficient Estimation of Systems
of Simultaneous Equations by .'.\-leans of Instrumental Variables." Inst . .'.\lath.
Study Soc. Sci .. Technical Report no. 92. Stanford, Calif.: Inst. .'.\lath. Study
Soc. Sci., .'.\larch 1973.
Kendrick, J. The Formation and Stocks of Total Ca/1ital. Xew York: Xat. Bur. Econ.
Res .• in press.
Lucas, Robert. ''Labor-Capital Substitution in C.S. :\lanufacturing." In The
Taxation of /11cu111t· from Caj,ital. edited by .\mold C. Harbergcr and ::\I,1rtin J.
Bdiley. Washington: Bruokings Inst.. I %!I .
.'.\lundell, Robert. "Inflation and Real Interest." J.P.£. 71. no. 3 (Jurw 1%3J:
280-83.
::\-lunnell, Alicia. '·The Impact of Social Security 01°1 Pri,·ate Savings." Sat. Tax J.
( 1975).
::\·lusgra,·e, Richard.-\. The Tlieory uf Public Finance: Stur!>· in Public £comnny. Xew
York: .'.\IcGraw-Hill. 1!)59.
.'.\Iusgra,·e. Richard .-\ .• and .'.\Iusgra\'e. Peggy B. Public Fimmcr i11 Theory ,md
Practice. Xew York: .'.\k(;raw-Hill. 1973.
Xerlove, .'.\1. '"Recent Empirical Studies of the CES and Related Production
Functions." In The Tlm,r_)' a11d 1:·111/1irical Ana~vsis <if Production, edited by :1.lurray
Brown. Xew York: :'\at. Bur. Econ. Res .• l!J67.
Pechmau. Joseph .\. fi·daal Tax Pulic_r. Re\'. eel. \\"ashi11gto11: Brookings Inst..
19i I.
Pcchman,Joseph :\ .• and Okner. Benjamin,\. II "ho Bwrs the Tax Burdm? \\'ashine;ton: Brookings Inst.. l!Ji-1-.
0

D.;


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

85
TAXATION, SAVING, AND THE INTEREST RATE

Sato, K. "Taxation and ;'\eoclassical Growth." Finances /mblique 22, no. 3 (1967):
34-6-72.
Shoven, J., and Whalley, J. "A General Equilibrium Calculation of the Effects
of Differential Taxation of Income from Capital in the U.S." J. Public Econ. I,
no. 3/4- (Xo\·ember 1972): 281-322.
Taylor, L. "Saving out of Different Types of Income." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity. \Vashington: Brookings Inst., 1970.
Weber, \Varren E. "The Effect of Interest Rates on Aggregate Consumption."
A.E.R. 60 (September 1970): 591-600.
- - - . "Interest Rates, Inflation and Consumer Expenditures." A.E.R. 65
(December 1975): 84-3-71.
Wright, C. "Saving and the Rate of Interest." In The Taxation of Income from
Capital, edited by Arnold C. Harberger and Martin J. Bailey. \Vashington:
Brookings Inst., 1969.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

86
Senator HATCH. Mr. Heller, you said savings did not respond to
these tax cuts. Last week I was speaking with the Finance Minister
of Germany. He described the tax incentives given to German savers.
He said that it really works to increase savings substantially, and it
works all too well, he said, if I can recall his testimony. It was in a
special meeting.
He said their experiences with these types of approaches really do
work, and they have proven they work. I don't know whether y«;:m are
aware of that, because I think the only people there were Chairman
Bolling and myself.
Mr. HELLER. I have been a studep.t of the German economy for
many years, and I did study their savings incentives. I have to admit, it was a long time ago, in the early 1950's. At the time I looked
at it, there was a very substantial network of savings shelters in the
German income tax laws.
My conclusion at that time, and this is, as I said, in the early .fifties,
was that it mainly resulted in the transfer of savings from one form
to another, from one form that was given a tax break, to another
form that was not given a tax break.
I investigated that with German economists at the time, and they
agreed with that conclusion. That is not something in which you can
have a controlled experiment. It is the kind of thing-pitfalls exist
in this kind of research.
The statement you are quoting, I think, would have to be subjected
to pretty rigorous economic analysis before we could accept it.
Senator HATCH. To reach a balanced budget a $25 billion tax cut
is all we can afford?
Mr. HELLER. I was quoting Brookings.
Senator HATCH. We know that taxes will rise to $98 billion by 1983.
·what you are saying is that we will balance the budget by raising
taxes.
I don't know that a lot of people want the budget balanced at that
cost.
Mr. HELLER. They were projecting a cutback in the Federal budget
in terms of the ratio of gross national product to 21 percent of the
gross national product, and they were plugging in the existing programs, and they were plugging in the existing tax legislation.
That is where they came out.
Senator HATCH. In 1965, after the Kennedy tax cut, only 2 pereent of
the tax returns filed by the people who were responsible for perhaps
10 or 15 percent of the country's savings, fell into the upper tax
brackets.
Since then inflation has put 10 percent of the country's taxpayers
who do perhaps 30-40 percent of the country's savings; into these
higher marginal tax brackets. How long can we go on ignoring marginal tax brackets, and how much of our saving can we allow to be
wasted in inefficient uses?
One of the main purposes of the Roth-Kemp bill is to get marginal
tax rates down to the point where these people would not want to use
tax shelters.
Would you agree or disagree with that?
Mr. HELLER. Again, as one who has had a very substantial hand in
reducing the top rate from 91 percent to 71 percent back in 1964, as

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

87
one who has urged further reduction, and as one who has said, we
ought to go very easy on widening tax shelters or capital gains, as one
who has said that we should narrow tax shelters for oil and gas and
a lot of other things in the tax laws, so that we could reduce the marginal tax rates, the top marginal tax rates on investment income to 50
percent-in other words, that it would be much better to have a lower
marginal rate, and cut down the tax shelters-I cannot disagree with
the general direction and approach of getting mortgage rates down.
That does not mean that one endorses a particular way of .getting
there. But I am certainly in favor of that approach, because I think
there would be more incentives for investment, and there would be
less distortion of investment, if one assumes that the free market
really works in the sense of allocating resources to the best uses ; then
the distortion is created by specific tax breaks of the kind we are talking about, which would cause certain inefficiencies in those allocations.
That does not apply to measures that operate broadly across the
board like the investment credit. But as to the many distortions of
resource allocation through specific tax preferences or tax expenditures, I would be very much in fMor of cutting those back, and cutting
back on the marginal rates at the same time.
Senator HATCH. Mr, time is up.
Senator RoTH. I will be very brief because of the late hour.
One thing, Mr. Heller,. in your prepared statement intrigued me.
You stated that the record is crystal clear that the great bulk of success of the taxes came from its stimulus to demand.
I emphasize, or ask, how do you know it is crystal clear 1 The reason I ask is that you appeared before this committee last year, and
you were asked to comment on the Federal revenue gains from the
Kennedy tax cut.
At that time you said it is difficult to pin down why revenues increased so much. After studying this for 14 years and not being sure,
today you say it is crystal clear that the revenues came from a stimulus to demand. What happened during the last year that changed
your mind~
Mr. HELLER. Since I have long held the view, based on a careful appraisal of the evidence, that the bulk of the thrust of the 1964 tax cut
came from the demand side, I doubt that there is anything inconsistent between those two statements. At the same time, one cannot identify precisely where those GNP increases have generated the specific
tax revenue expansions nor precisely which factors accounted for the
size of the revenue increase.
What I am saying today is that in general, it had to be from the demand side, because in 1½ years, you could not possibly have increased
the supply capability of the economy enough to account for those revenue increases. It was a surge in demand that generated increased buying that in turn generated an increased production response, more
jobs, more income, more profits, and as a result, a fuller use, in other
words, of existing supply capabilities.
You had a much higher flow of income, and that income flow generated tax increases. That was part and parcel of our 'thinking at the
time, that we thought we would be able to balance the budget through
that increase in revenues from increased demand, and as a result, increased GNP, even if it did not all come from the tax cut.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

88
That indeed did happen. By the middle of 1965 we were running a
$3 billion surplus in the budget on.a cash basis, in terms of the calculations made at that time.
Then, of course, the bulge in expenditures £or the Vietnam war
knocked the whole thing off.
Senator RoTH. As a layman, I must confess it is somewhat difficult
£or me to reconcile the two statements. But in any event, even though
we disagree in some particulars, I am glad that we agree that a substantial tax cut is needed; at least some time this year.
One of the interesting things is to hear people talk about additional
incentives £or increased investment, because the minute that is done,
usually many people in the Congress, and some economists say, you
are trying to he,lp the rich.
For example, the Tax Subcommittee right now was considering
whether or not we should change the capital gains treatment. The
President, a couple of days ago argued that this is just to help the
millionaires.
That is one of the problems you have, £rankly, in trying to be constructive and discuss these things on a rational basis. It is easy to talk
about taxes on the basis of three-martini lunches, and you are helping
the millionaires. But that is really not getting to the main thrust.
I am not here to claim my particular bill is necessarily the best, and
it cannot be improved upon; but it is a start. I regret that our fourth
man has left, because there is one message that comes clear to me-it
certainly came clear in California, but it came even clearer to me both
on my recent stay in Delaware, and in my last effort £or reelection a
couple of years ago-that the working people of this country are very
unhappy with our taxes, and this is not likely to go away.
I£ there is one difference, one significant difference between now
and the sixties, Mr. Heller, it is that working Americans-and I don't
happen to buy the school of thought that anyone who makes more
than $17,000 is rich, as some liberals do-if you made $12,000 years
ago, you now have to make $20,000 to have the equivalent purchasing
power, and that puts you into a higher tax bracket.
vVorking Americans, it is interesting to hear how well people are
living. vVe have one man quitting Congress because he cannot afford
to send his children to college.
vVhat I am saying to you is, we better start helping the people who
earn $30,000 per year. There is nothing wrong with helping a man who
makes $30,000 a year, because they are on a downward movement.
I think that is a fact we better listen to here in Congress. As far as
I am concerned, I shall fight, and fight hard, to give working people
a break. I think they are entitled to it. I think what we are trying to
do from the supply side is to expand and increase our economy so that
there is more to share, more to share with the poor, instead of being
involved in some kind of income transfer.
I want to say that I enjoyed being here. I am sorry we did not know
about this sooner, because I am confident we could have arranged £or
Mr. Laffer to be here.
Senator PROXMIRE. I want to thank you very, very much. This has
been a marvellous panel.
The committee will recess until 10 o'clock tomorrow.
[Whereupon, at 1 p.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene at 10
a.m., Thursday, June 29, 1978.]

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

THE 1978 MIDYEAR REVIEW OF THE ECONOMY
THURSDAY, JUNE 29, 1978

MONETARY POLICY

CONGRESS OF THE u NITED STATES,
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,
Washington, D.O.
The committee met, pursuant to recess, at 10 :05 a.m., in room 1202,
Dirksen ,Senate Office Building, Hon. Richard Bolling ( chairman of
the committee') presiding-.
Present: Representatives Bolling, Reuss, and Heckler; and Senators J avits and Roth.
Also present: John R. Stark, executive director; Louis C. Krauthoff
II, assistant director; Lloyd C. Atkinson, Thomas F. Dernburg, Kent
H. Hughes, L. Douglas Lee, Deborah Norelli Matz, and M. Catherine
Miller, professional staff members; Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; and Charles H. Bradford, Stephen J. Entin, and Mark R.
Policinski, minority professional staff members.
OPENING STATEMENT OF REPRESENTATIVE BoLLING, CuAmMAN
Representative BOLLING. The committee will be in order. There will
be other members coming along.

This morning it is a pleasure to welcome the distinsi'uished Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, the Honorable G. William Miller,
to his first appearance as a witness before this committee.
You may recall that Chairman Miller was scheduled to join us previously, but we just ran into a problem of timing. It is something
I guess which is one of the chronic problems of monetary policy also.
Worries about the economy seem to be growing daily, although we
have had ia good expansion. There is increasing fear that 'a slowdown,
and perhaps even a recession, are likely next year. Productivity has
been lagging, as has been capital spending that would raise productivity. And partly because of productivity, inflation ·appears to be
accelerating, despite the evidence that the economy is overheating.
I'm sure you will explain to us the point of monetary fiscal tightening at this time, when considerable slack continues to exist in the
economy.
Yesterday a witness warned us that another slowdown mi~ht set
back the productivity, and make it more rather than less difficult to
control inflation in the future.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

(89)

90
I expect the main thing that concerns many of us is that many economists are pointing to the very recent rapid increase in Federal funding and interest rates as an indication of the Federal Reserve once
again concluding that it is the only anti-inflation game in town, and
that another costly and protracted recession is therefore becoming all
but unavoidable.
Few of us, at least those of us who have been around very long,
have been impressed by promises of a soft landing, having heard
similiar assurances a number of times before.
In 1969, we had a game plan; and in 1973, it was said we would
have to endure no more than a growth recession. The soft landing is
al ways eluding us, and at a very, very real cost.
I am sure you will address that problem.
We are very glad to welcome you to the Joint Economic Committee.
You may proceed as you wish.
1

STATEMENT OF HON. G. WILLIAM MILLER, CHAIRMAN, BOARD
OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Mr. MILLER. Thank you very-much.
I do appreciate the opportunity to be here for this first appearance.
I apologize that the timing was off earlier, when I was just coming
into office.
I hope in the future to be av,ailable to consult with you on a regular
basis. I look forward to that. It is very helpful for us to try to explain
to you and other Members of the Congress how the policies of the
Federal Reserve relate to the economic growth and prosperity of our
Nation, and how they correlate with other economic policies.
I might just comment, Mr. Chairman, on the point you just raised,
and then, perhaps, refer to my prepared statement briefly, and then
we can tum to questions.
I certainly share with you the concern that it is important in these
difficult times to make a judgment of how to continue the expansion
of the economy without accelerating the forces of inflation on the one
hand, or, on the other hand, triggering a recession-which would not
do very much to reduce inflation.
I think we will be walking through a very !).arrow valley during
the next few months in making our judgments of how to interrelate
economic policies so as to continue a moderate growth rate, without
a recession and without building inflationary forces.
It is going to be a very important period for us.
It will take tremendous skill to steer us through this passage, and
I only hope that, using what we have all leamed in the past, we will
be able to be more successful this time in, as you put it, making a
"soft landing"-or at least be able to steer through this passage
without abrupt moves toward either greater inflation or a recession.
Mr. Chairman, I would ask your permission to have my prepared
statement submitted for the record, and then maybe I will just hit
some of the highlights in it.
Representative BOLLING. The whole prepared statement will be included in the record.
Mr. MILLER. This committee is well aware of the economic background over the first half of this year. The first quarter of the year

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

1

91
was slow because of the severe winter and the coal strike; and the
second quarter has shown a very strong pattern.
So, overall, real annual growth in GNP in the first half of the year
has been ar~mnd 4 percent, which is satisfactory in the fourth year of
any expansion.
Strength in aggregate demand has allowed us to continue to expand
job opportunities.
.
It is rather encouraging that more than 2 million nonfarm Jobs
were created over the last 6 months, which lowered the unemployment
rate by more than one-half of a percentage point to just over 6 percent
of the labor force. The jobless rate for heads of households fell onehalf percentage point to 3.7 percent. The proportion of the working
age population with jobs has moved up to 58.6 percent, a new record
high. Therefore, the outlook is encouraging. The sustained strength of
demand for workers suggests that businessmen remain optimistic, and
are prepared to increase production and other activities further.
Growth, however, has recently slowed, as ,ve would expect after the
unusual pace of the spring. And yet we still see substantial lernls of
consumer spending, and of business outlays for inventories and fixed
investments. So t,he outlook is one of continued moderate growth.
But, during the first half of the year-and looking over the horizon-the price situation has worsened, so we do have a serious concern
about inflation.
The major factor in the acceleration of the inflation rate in the first
half of the year has been the effect on food prices, particularly the
increase in meat prices.
In any case, even if we exclude food and energy, retail prices have
risen at an annual rate of over 8 percent this year, which is up from
the 6.5 percent rate of increase in 1977 and, of course, is a matter of
considerable concern. Monetary policy has responded to this situation.
The faster pace of price increases in recent months along with the
sizabl~ expansion of economic activity has been reflected clearly in
financial market developments. Demands for both money and credit
have exhibited appreciable strength. The Federal Reserve, for its part,
has moved carefully in the direction of greater restraint in order to
insure that excessive money and credit supplies do not add to powerful
inflationary forces evident in our economy.
The firming of monetary policy was undertaken also in response to
the clear tendency for monetary expansion to exceed the growth ranges
that had been established. Trarn:action demands for cash balances have
been especially sizable and the narrow money stock, M-1, has grown
at an annual rate of nearly 8 percent thus far this year, somewhat
faster than the upper end of the longrun range the Federal Reserve
has set.
In the face of these conditions interest rates have risen significantly
further. Most short-term rates have risen by three-quarters to 1 percentage point since the beginning of the year and long-term bond
yields have followed much the same pattern. The rise of market interest rates has been accompanied by slower growth of savings and
small-denomination time accounts at banks and thrift institutions. As
a result, growth rates of broader monetary aO'i'!reP-"ates, M-2 and M-3,
have remained within the Federal Reserve's longrun ranges.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

92
A good deal of the rise in interest rates this year can be attributed
to the acceleration of inflation. For lenders, rising prices of goods and
services result in an erosion in the purchasing power of loan principal.
Consequently,_ when greater inflation is expected, a _rise_ in no~inal
interest rates 1s necessary to offset such losses and mamtam the mcentive to extend credit. For borrowers, higher interest rates are less of an
obstacle to incurring debt under conditions of accelerating inflation.
Greater cost savings ca,n be enjoyed by buying now rather than later,
while tangible assets purchased appreciate more rapidly in value.
Borrowers, moreover, can expect to support greater debt service burdens via faster nominal earnings growth due to accelerated rises in
prices, wages, and salaries.
The importance of suoh an anticipatory process is being demonstrated very clearly right now in the mortgage market. Evidently
mortgage borrowers, while expecting their nominal incomes to continue to rise significantly, believe prices of homes will also escalate
rapidly. Despite stiffer lending terms and higher interest rate$ on
mortgages, home sales have continued high, and the demand for mortgage credit has rem<tined strong.
The Federal regulatory agencies have taken action recently to
improve the competitiveness of deposits subject to regulatory ceilings
by authorizing two new savings instruments-variable ceiling, 6-month
certificates with interest rates tied to the discount yield on newly
issued Treasury bills, and 8-year certificates carrying ceiling rates of
73/4 and 8 percent for banks and thrifts, respectively. It is still too
early to quantify the results, but early reports indicate considerable
activity.
In the meantime, consumer borrmving and mortgage credit have
run quite high. There has been a record increase in consumer installment debt, which could be a cause for caution. Thus far, however,
households generally appear to be handling their increased indebtedness well.
Business demands for credit have expanded sharply of late, owing
partly to the growth of capital spending and the pronounced upturn
in inventories. So we can expect continued demand for credit in the
business sector. Government borrowing at all levels has also remained
high. Overall, then, the credit situation has been one of increasing
demand.
The recent acceleration of inflation has serious implications for continued growth. This, I think, is the most serious problem we face.
The administration's decision to request a delay in, and reduction of
the size of, the proposed tax cut, as well as to hold down Federal
spending 1 and to try to develop voluntary price and wage restraint are
encouragmg.
These recent steps do not constitute, by themselves, an adequate
long-term attack on the inflationary practices and policies which have
given the economy its infl3,tionary bias. Inflation 1s now the Nation's
most serious economic problem. Because high rates of inflation erode
economic value~ and r11;ise un_certainties ~bout the future, they continuously undermme the mcentives for savmg and investment. Without
adequate investment in inew, more efficient technology, growth of productivity tends to slow, lending further momentum to cost-based
inflationary pressures. It is for this reason-because deep-seated in
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

93
flation retards longrun growth and is a clear threat to sustained high
employment-that inflation must be characterized as our highest priority economic problem.
As this committee has been in recent weeks in its first series of
hearings on economic change, a major impetus to inflation lies in problems on the supply side of the Nation's economy. We have had: An
inadequate growth of the capital stock; inadequate training, experience, and mobility among many of the unemployed; inadequate price
competition in some product and labor markets; and counterproductive, and frequently inefficient, Government regula,tion of private enterprise.
Individually these supply side issues have been obvious for many
years, but during the past 3 or 4 years there has been to be a general
recognition that they must be addressed collectively and aggressively
if we hope to achieve our national economic objectives. Reorientation
of the Nation's economic policy to emphasize supply management will
take time and careful consideration of many alternatives. However,
some aspects of the necessary reorientation aiready command general
agreement. Perhaps the key element is to give renewed primacy to
technological advance and productivity growth. Surely, the sorry
productivity performance over the last decade has been a significant
:factor in the sustained inflation of the 1970's and it clearly has played
a role in weakening our international competitiveness.
Improving productivity growth involves working on three key elements: Labor, energy, and capital. Potential labor contributions to
the restoration of faster productivity growth are many and varied.
The Government has a role to play in enhancing labor productivity.
It should focus its various labor market and welfare programs on
skill training to the maximum practicable extent, and should carefully reexamine the cost and price implications of various labor market regulatory programs, and minimum wage policies.
The energy problem has two main elements: A need for research to
find new sources of energy, and a need for appropriate incentives to
encourage use of existing energy-efficient technologies. In this area,
agreement on a national energy policy is long overdue, and the conference committee should intensify its efforts to reach a compromise
on the administration's proposals.
The capital problem is even more complex. In recent years, the
stock of capital actually has declined relative to the labor force. I
call your attention to the bottom panel in chart 6 of my prepared statement. I think that it is a very revealing chart in that it shows the
trend from 1948 to 1973 in the growth of capital stock relative to the
labor force and compares this to actual performance. You will note
that the ratio tapers off in recent years.
Capital accumulation is the. chief engine of long-range growth of
labor l)roductivity and rising living standards. Yet, for an extended
period, the Nation's tax policies have not provided adequate incentives to invest in new capital. In particular, depreciation !!llidelines
rlo not approach actual replacement costs in periods of rapid inflation.
I believe a near term, partial answer is to introduce a more liberal
variant of accelerated depreciation. Oven time, careful reconsideration
of all taxes on business is essential.
Because we have been neglecting capital accumulation and because
the existing capital stock must also be adjusted to accommodate the

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
35-570 0 - 79 - 7
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

94
reality of more expensive energy, a larger share of GNP must be devoted to capital investment. It will not be enough simply to reach the
10.5 to 11 percent range that has been characteristic of past periods
of prosperity and low unemployment. The Nation should set an ambitious objective for capital investment of, say, 12 percent of GNP for
an extended period to enable us to make up for past deficiencies and
to narrow the gap between our performance and that of other strong
industrialized countries.
~undamenta_l to achieving this ai~ is an exp~nsion in the savings
available for mvestment from outside the busmess sector. To this
end, Government must have a smaller role in the economy and budget
deficits need to be eliminated over time, taking into account the ups
and downs in the economy. The private sector can take up the slack
if, over 5 or 7 years, the Federal Government curtails the growth of
its expenditures until their ratio to GNP, which is now above 22 percent, is reduced to the 20 percent range. This interim goal for Federal
expenditures clearly is attainable with a good measure of fiscal disciplme coupled with reduced public demands for Government services.
As spending is brought under control, government will move from
its position as a substantial net borrower of funds in credit markets.
Such a change would moderate demand pressures on credit markets as
well as relieve some of the pressures on prices that arise from passing
on high and rising taxes. l{esources will be more readily available to
meet needs in the private sector. Easier credit market conditions, less
inflation, and greater availability of resources should help insure adequate residential construction activity to meet the Nation's housing
needs---need\3 that are now prey to a boom and bust syndrome that
profits no one.
Another essential element of a long-term strategy aimed at a highgrowth, low-inflation economy is extensive reform of Federal regulatory activities. This subject has been discussed extensively, and 1 will
not rudd to that discussion.
Another important element that requires immediate attention, and
which should be an important part of a long-term strategy for the
U.S. economy, is a reduction of our foreign trade deficit. A sound
national energy policy that reduces our dependence on oil imports is
certainly one ingredient. In addition, we must raise the consciousness
of businessmen to the sales potential and profits that export markets
can provide. The Government can help by continuing with other governments to resist protectionist pressures, and by simplifying, and
where possible eliminating, those regulations that hinder our export
trade. In my view, our ultimate objective should be to expand the
share of exports in our national product to 10 percent or so, in line
with the secular rise in the share of imports.
I am convinced that the policy reorientation outlined above, by
directly attacking inflation-causing conditions at their root, should
lessen the burden on monetary policy and result in a better balance
between fiscal and moneta,ry policy, and thereby improve the prospects
for lower interest rates. An economic program of this type would
start the Nation on the road to becoming a model economy-an economy with a sound dollar, price stability, and sustained full employment.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

95
Our Nation has met bigger challenges, and, with a sense of commitment on the part of policymakers and citizens, I am confident that
we will meet this challenge as well. That concludes my oral testimony,
Mr. Chairman.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Miller follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HON.

G.

WILLIAM MILLER

Mr. Chairman, I appreciate this opportunity to participate on behalf of the
Federal Reserve Board in the Joint Economic Committee's mid-year review of the
economy. These sessions provide an excellent opportunity to assess economic
conditions and policies.
ECONOMIC ACTIVITY EXHIBITS HEALTHY GROWTH

The economy has continued to expand at a satisfactory though uneven rate
over the first half of this year. Industrial production, construction, and retail
sales were temporarily depressed early in the year by unusually severe weather
and the long coal strike, as shown in Chart 1. But these were transitory effectsand business activity recovered vigorously in the spring. For the first six months
of the year, real annual growth in the gross national product appears likely
to average around 4 percent-close to the pace during the latter half of 1977.
Thus, despite the considerable volatility in key areas of the economy, the underlying momentum of the expansion appears to have been well maintained.
The strength of aggregate demand has stimulated a substantial further improvement in the job market. As is indicated in the bottom panels of the Chart,
employment gains have been exceptionally strong. More than 2 million nonfarm
jobs were created over the last six months, which lowered the unemploy-ment rate
by more than one-half of a percentage point to just over 6 percent of the labor
force. The jobless rate for heads of households fell one-half percentage point to 3.7
percent. The proportion of the working-age population with jobs has moved up
to 58.6 percent, a new record high. The sustained strength of demand for workers
suggests that businessmen remain optimistic, and are prepared to increase production and other activities further.
AND GROWTH PROSPECTS REMAIN FAVORABLE

Growth of economic activity recently has slowed, ·as was expected, from the
unusually rapid pace of the spring. A moderate rate of economic growth appears
to be a reasonable prospect for the balance of the year. Both consumer outlays and
business spending should provide support for further expansion of activity. Consumers' demand for new cars has been particularly strong, and the current rate
of sales is the highest in this expansion. The advanced sales pace may, in part,
represent purchasing in anticipation of further price rises. But surveys indicate
that consumer confidence remains generally high, although there has been some
recent moderation, and if growth of income is sustained, the prospects for further
gains in consumer spending appear good.
Business ou'tlays for both inventories and fixed capital goods have contributed
significantly to the recent pace of activity. A larger rate of inventory ,accumulation was <to 'be expected, in light of the burst of final sales late last year, and the
damping effect of adverse weather on production during the winter. Inventories
in most sectors appear quite low relative to sales, and continued growth of inventory investment-albeit at a more moderate rate-should be evident over the
next few quar'ters. Business investment in plant and equipment, after lagging
early in the economic upswing, has increased at a reasoua'bly good pace over the
past two years. While recent surveys have shown little propensity for business
to scale up capital spending plans, these and other indicators of prospective capital outlays suggest further moderate growth in the year ahead.
Our foreign trade position should also lend moderate support to the economic
expansion. Some pick-up in grO'lvih abroad and our improved competitive position should help to boost exports. However, U.S. demand for import8-'both oil
and other products--is likely to remain quite high.
Among other sectors of demand, State and local go,·ernmeuts have maintained
conservative spending policies for some time, and it is likely that the reverbera-


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

96
tions of the passage of Proposition 13 in Oalifornia may be evident in an even
more cautious partern of outlays in the period -ahea.d.
Residential construction activity is expected to 1begin to taper off later this
year in response to tighter mortgage market conditions. However, housing ~ta·rts
were still above a 2 million annual rate in :\fay, virtually assuring brisk construction activity over t:he next few months.
BUT THE PRICE SITUATION HAS WORSENED

Thus in most respects the immedia1te outlook nppears generally favorable. But
in one critical regard the economic situation has deteriorated. The recent intensification of inflaition, illustrated in Chart 2, raises profound questions ,in regard
to the longer run. As can be seen in 'the Chart, the rate of price increase has
accelerated sharply both at the consumer and producer level. A major factor was
the effect on food prices of a decline in meat production. But other prices rose
at an accelerated rate as well. Excluding food and energy, •retail prices have
risen at an annual rate of over 8 percent so far this year, up from a 6½ percent
rate of increase in 1977. Actions of the Government have also played a significant
role in the recent worsening of inflation. Service prices have risen strongly, influenced importantly by the rise in the minimum wage on January 1. Moreover,
increases in social security and unemployment insurance taxes have added to
labor costs on a broad scale, while costly regulatory actions continue to put upward pressures on costs.
·There is some hope that the exceptional rate of increase in food prices will
moderate as the year progresses, but there is much less likelihood of any easing
of underlying inflationary forces. The recent acceleration in consumer prices will
add to the pressure for substantial wage boosts; and resulting higher labor costs
will largely be transmitted through to prices.
MONETARY POLICY HAS RESPONDED TO EMERGING DEVELOPMENTS

The faster pace of price increases in recent months along with the sizable
expansion of economic activity has been reflected clearly in financial market developments. Demands for both money and credit have exhibited appreciable
strength. The Federal Reserve, for its part, has moved carefully in the direction
of greater restraint in order to ensure that excessive money and credit supplies
do not add to powerful inflationary forces evident in our economy.
'The firming of monetary policy was undertaken also in ·response to the clear
tendency for monetary expansion to exceed the growth ranges 'that had been
established. Transaction demands for cash balances have been especially sizable
and the narrow money stock (::\1-1) has grown at an annual rate of nearly 8
percent thus far this year, some"~hat faster than the upper end of the long"run
range the Federal Reserve has set.
In the presence of strong credit demands, the worsening of inflat,ion, and the
Federal Reserve's efforts to contain excessive monetary expansion, market interest rates have risen significantly further. Most short-term ra'tes have risen
by three-quarters to one percentage point since the beginning of t:j:le year and
long-term bond yields have followed much the same pattern, as illustrated in
Chart 3. 'The ·rise of market interest rates has been accompanied by slower growth
of savings and small-denomination time accounts at banks and thrift institutions.
As a result, growth rates of broader monetary aggregates-M-2 and M-3have remained within the Federal Reserve's long-run ranges.
A good deal of the rise in interest rates this year can 'be attrtDuted to the
acceleration of inflation. For lenders, rising prices of goods and services result
in an erosion in the purchasing power of loan principal. Consequently, when
greater inflation is expected, a rise in nominal interes't rates is necessary to offset
such losses and maintain the incentive to extend credit. For borrowE>rs, higher
interest rates are less of an obstacle to incurring debt under conditions of accelerating inflation. Grea'ter cost savings can be enjoyed by 'buying now rather
than later, while tangible assets purchased appreciate more rapidly in value.
Borrowers, moreover, can expect to support greater deibt service burdens vlfa
faster nominal earnings gro\,ih due to accelerated rises in prices, wages and
salaries.
The importance of such an anticipatory process is heing demonstrated very
clearly right now in the mortgage market. Evidently mortgage borrowers, while


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

97
expecting their nominal incomes to continue to ,rise significantly, believe prices
of homes also will escalate rapidly. Despite stiffer lending terms and higher
interest rates on mortgages, home sales have continued high, and fue demand for
mortgage credit has remained very strong. Faced wi'th reduced deposit inflows,
thrift institutions have drawn down their liquidity and sharply increased their
borrowing in order to accommodate these credit demands.
The Federal regulatory agencies have taken action recently to improve the
competitiveness of deposits subject to regulatory ceilings by authorizing two new
savings instruments-variable-ceiling, six-month certificates with interest rates
tied to the discount yield on newly issued •.rreasury bills, and eight-year certificates carrying ceiling rates of 7¾ and 8 percent for banks and thrifts, respectively. It is still too early to quantify the contribution of the new accounts, but
early reports indicate considerable promotional activity on the part of depositary
institutions and interest on the part of savers.
CONSUMED AND BUSINESS CREDIT DEMANDS STRONG

Consumer borrowing through mortgage credit has been a principal influence
in the sustained high level of total credit demands. Consumers have also taken
on record amounts of new installment debt to finance purchases of durable goods,
especially cars ( Chart 4). The rapid rise of household borrowing Is a matter of
concern. High debt is apt :to constrain spending later on, and always carries the
risk of financial difficulties for •fuose who have borrowed heavily. Thus far, however, households generally appear to be handling their increased indebtedness
well. While the ratio of consumer and mortgage loan repayments to di-sposa·ble
income is very high by historical standards delinquency rates have only recently
edged upward and they. remain well below recession peaks.
Business demands for credit have expanded sharply of late, owing partly to
the growth of capital spending and pronounced upturn in inventories (Chart 5).
In addition, internal cash flows slowed early in the year as bad weather cut into
sales and costs were pushed up by hikes in Government payroll taxes and in the
minimum wage. Bank business loans rose at about a 20 percent annual rate over
the first five months, with the largest rises in March, April and May. With credit
demands strong banks have borrowed heavily in money markets, through the
issuance of large certificates of deposit and nondeposit liabilities.
TOTAL GOVERNMENT BORROWING LARGE AS WELL

Government credit demands also have been large, as State and local units recently issued a particularly heavy volume of advance refunding obligations to
take advantage of invested sinking fund provisions prior to a mid-May IRS ruling
restricting securities with such provisions. Furthermore, Federal agencies have
borrowed more to finance support activities in mortgage markets. Treasury borrowing-following heavy demands early this year-has moderated in recent
months with the seasonal inflow of tax receipts.
INFLATION POSES THBEAT TO THE ECONOMY

The recent acce1eration of inflation has serious implications for continued
economic growth. Unless inflation is brought under control, business and consumer confidence will be undermined, distortions and imbalances in the economy
will develop, and ultimately recession will be the result. In this regard, the Administration's decision to request a delay in-and reduction of the size of-the
proposed tax cut, as well as to hold down Federal spending, and to try to develop
voluntary price and wage restraint are encouraging.
These recent steps do not constitute, by themselves, an adequate long-term
attack on the inflationary practices and policies which have given the economy its
inflationary bias. Inflation is now the Nation's most serious economic problem.
Because high rates of inflation erode economic values and rai&.e uncertainties
about the future, they continuously undermine the incentives for saving and investment. Without adequate investment in new, more efficient technolog~, gro~th
of productivity tends to slow-lending further momentum to cost-based mflat10nary pressures. It is for this reason-because deep-seated inflation retards lo~grun growth and is a clear threat to sustained high employment-that inflation
must be characterized as our highest priority economic problem.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

98
NEED TO FOCUS ON MANAGEMENT OF SUPPLY

As this Committee has heard in recent weeks in its first series of hearings on
economic change, a major impetus to inflation lies in problems on the supply side
of the Nation's economy. Among these problems are:
Inadequate growth of the capital stock;
Inadequate training, experience, and mobility among many of the unemp'loyed;
Inadequate price competition in some product and labor markets; and
Counter-productive, and frequently inefficient, Government regulation of
private enterprise.
I~dividually these supply-side issues have been obvious for many years, but
durmg the past three or four years there has begun to be a general recognition
that they must be addressed collectively and aggressively if we hope to achieve
our national economic objectiYes. Reorientation of the Nation's economic policy
to emphasize supply management will take time and careful ocnsideration of
many alternatives. However, some aspects of the necessary reorientation already
command general agreement. Perhaps the key element is to give renewed primacy
to technological advance and productivity growth. Surely, the sorry productivity
performance over the last decade has been a significant factor in the sustained
inflation of the 1970's, and it clearly has played a role in weakening our international competitiveness.
LARGER GAINS IN PRODUCTIVITY NEEDED

Improving productivity growth involves working on three key elements: labor,
energy, and capital. Potential labor contributions to the restoration of faster pro•
ductivity growth are many and varied. The Government has a role to play in
enhancing labor productivity: it should focus its various labor market and welfare programs on skill training to the maximum practicable extent, and should
carefully reexamine the cost and price implications of various labor market regulatory programs, and minimum wage policies.
The energy problem has two main elements : a need for research to find new
sources of energy, and a need for appropriate incentives to encourage use of
existing energy-efficient technologies. In this area, agreement on a nationa'l energy polic~· is long overdue, and the Conference Committee should intensify its
efforts to reach a compromise on the Administration's proposals.
The capital problem is even more complex. In recent years, the stock of capital
actually has declined relative to the labor force, (depicted in Chart 6), and this
is undoubterly one important factor in the slower growth of productivity.
CAPITAL STOCK NOW INADEQUATE

Capital accumulation is the chief engine of 'long-range growth of labor productivity and rising living standards. Yet, for an extended period, the Kation's
tax policies have not provided aequate incentives to invest in new capital. In
particular, depreciation guidelines do not approach actual replacement cost" in
periods of rapid inflation. I believe a near-term, partial answer is to introduce
a more liberal variant of accelerated depreciation. Over time, careful reconsideration of all taxes on business is essential.
Because we haxe been neglecting capital accumulation and because the existing
capital stock must also be adjusted to accommodate the reality of more expensive
energy, a larger share of GXP must be devoted to capital investment. It will not
be enough simply to reach the 10½ to 11 percent range that has been characteristic of past periods of prosperity and low unemployment. The Nation should set
an ambitous objective for capital investment of, say, 12 percent of GNP for an
extended period to enable us to make up for past deficiencies and to narrow the
gap between our performance and that of other strong industrialized countries.
RESOURCES MUST BE FREED FOR PRIVATE SECTOR USE

Fundamental to achieving this aim is an expansion in the savings available for
investment from outside the business sector. 'I'o this end, Government must have
a smaller role in the economy and budget deficits need to be eliminated over time,
taking into account the ups and downs in the economy. The private sect~r can
take up the slack if over five or seven years, the Federal Government curtails the
growth of its expe~ditures until their ratio to GNP, which is now above 22 per
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

99
cent, is reduced to the 20 percent range. This interim goal for Federal expenditures clearly is attainable with a good measure of fiscal d°iscipline coupled with
reduced public demands for government services.
As spending is brought under control, government wiU move from its position
as a substantial net borrower of funds in credit markets. Such a change would
moderate demand pressures on credit markets as well as relieve some of the
pressures on prices that arise from passing on high and rising taxes. Resources
will be more readily available to meet needs in the private sector. Easier credit
market conditions, less inflation, and greater availability of resources should help
ensure adequate residential construction activity to meet the Nation's housing
needs-needs that are now prey to a boom and bust syndrome that profits no one.
STRUCTURAL REFORMS REQUIRED AS WELL

Another essential element of a long-term strategy aimed at a high-growth, lowinflation economy is extensiYe reform of l<'ederal regulatory activities. A critical
look at price-regulating Go,·ernment programs should be undertaken; a painstaking examination of all existing and proposed regulatory activities in the environmental and health and safety areas is also necessary. In this connection, the
President's recent executive order to improve the regulatory process is encouraging. The Federal Reserve is a participant in this vrocess and has initiated an
over-all review of its own regulations.
Another important element that requires immediate attention, and which
should be an important part of a long-term strategy for the U.S. economy, is a
reduction of our foreign trade deficit. A sound national energy policy that reduces
our dependence on oil imports is certainly one ingredient. In addition, we must
raise the consciousness of businessmen to the sales potential and profits that
export markets ean provide. The Government can help by continuing with other
governments to resist protectionist pressures, and by simplifying, and where possible elimir:ating, those regulations that hinder our export trade. In my view, our
ultimate objectiYe 1<hould be to expand the share of exports in our national
product to 10 per cent or so, in line with the secular rise in the share of imports.
I am convinced that the policy reorientation outlined above, by directly attacking inflation-causing conditions at their root, should lessen the burden on monetary policy and result in a better balance between fiscal and monetary policy,
and thereby improve the prospects for lower interest rates. An economic program
of this type would start the Nation on the road to becoming a model economy-an
economy with a rnund dollar. pric.e stability, and sustained full employment. Our
:Nation has met bigger challenges, and. with a sense of commitment on the part of
policymakers and citizens, I am confident that we will meet this challenge as well.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

100
c.... ,

CURRENT ECONOMIC INDICATORS
Per cent ~

Per cent chan. .

a

Total Construction Spending

Industrial Production
2.0

4

1.0

+
0

+0

4

1.0
F M A M

J

1977

J F M A

1978
Billion ■

1978

1977

of dollars

Retail Sales

MIiiion ■

of units

Auto Sales
10
62

8
6
4

58

Foreign
2

F M A M

J

1977

J

1978
MHllona of

1977

F

M A M

1978

-er■

Per cent

Unemployment Rate

Payroll Employment
86

I

84

7

82

8

80
J

1977


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

J

F M A M

1978

1977

F M A M

1978

101
Cllart 2

MEASURES OF AGGREGATE INFLATION

PERCENTAGE CHANGE FROM PREVIOUS PERIOD, ANNUAL RATE

GROSS DOMESTIC BUSINESS PRODUCT
Fixed-Weighted Price Index

9

6

3

1975

1976

1977

a1

1978

'79

CONSUMER PRICES
All Items

9

6

3

DecemberApril change

1975

1976

1977

1978

'79

I

~RODUCER PRICES
Total Finished Goods

r

9

6

3

DecemberMay change

1975


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1976

1977

1978

'79

102
Chart 3

INTEREST RATES

Per cent

12

10

NewlssueJ

Aaa Utility Bonds

8

Prime Commercial Paper
90-119 Day

8

3-Month Treasury Bills

1974


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1975

1976

1977

--

1978

4

103

Cbart 4

HOUSEHOLD BORROWING

Annual rate, blUlona of doli.a

140

100

Home Mortgages

80

-'
Instalment Debt

20

+
0

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

HOUSEHOLD DEBT REPAYMENTS
Relative to Disposable Personal Income

Per cent

20

11

11

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

* Monthly net change in amount outstanding of Total Consumer Instalment CredH.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

104

Chart 5

SELECTED BORROWING BY
NONFINANCIAL BUSINESS

Bllllona of dollara

280

220

180

Commercial
Paper

1974


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1975

1976

1977

1978

105
Chert

e

RATIO OF BUSINESS FIXED
INVESTMENT TO GNP

Per cent

11

10

9

1967

1969

1971

1973

RATIO OF CAPITAL STOCK
TO LABOR FORCE

1975

1977

Thousands of constant dollars
per person

12

11

10

9

1967

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1969

1971

1973

1975

1977

106
Representative BOLLING. Thank you, Mr. Miller. The first question
I will ask is somewhat long and difficult. It is only because I feel very
strongly that we must devise better techniques for the longrun coordination of all of the elements of government, the Federal, the Executive,
and the Congress, that I burden you with this kind of a question.
As you undoubtedly know, this committee has long been concerned
about the coordination between fiscal and monetary policies. In our
annual report, page 47, we recommended as follows:
The Federal Reserve should issue a written report to the Congress shortly
after the receipt of the Economic Report of the President. * • • The Federal
Reserve's report would be expected to meet three basic requirements : One, it
would analyze the desirability, consistency, and feasibility of the quantitative
goals for employment growth, and inflation for the forthcoming fiscal year as set
forth by the President; two, it would provide the Federal Reserve's own quantitative forecast of economic activity for the forthcoming year on a quarterly
basis; three, it would discuss in quantitative tf:'rms how the proposed monetary
policies are designed to reconcile the President's targets and the Federal Reserve's own forecast.

We went on to organize that:
This reform would eliminatf:' many serious policies. It would provide this committee with the informatior, it needs to perform its policy coordination role
effectively. It would also insure tl:iat monetary and fiscal policies aim at the same
goals rather than work at cross purposes * • •. Such biases as the one that has
supported consumption but held back investment during the course of the current
recovery would be eliminated.

One of the reasons that I have supported that approach, or at least,
as a strong suggestion, and one of the reasons that I was glad that
something like it was included in some of the drafts of the HumphreyHawkins proposal, has been my reading of history.
There is naturally an inevitable built-in conflict among all three
different forces that affects the overall economy, the Executive, Federal Reserve, and the Congress.
But in reading what I guess is the authorized biography of Marrine r
Eccles, I notice that the key to the success, and I think it was a success,
of monetary and fiscal policies during the period, of his holding of the
position of the Chairman of the Federal Reserve, is that while he often
disagreed in details, some of which were not triYial, that in one way or
another, there was worked out on a wry informal basis, but relatively
systematically, some kind of an effective coordination.
People say that the Congress is more diverse; that power is more
diffused; that there cannot be that kind of coordination.
I would like very much to have your comment on tihe problem, and
not in rel-ation to a specific situation now, and your suggestions, if
you have any, on this question.
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Chairman, without addressing the details of your
report, let me first say that I concur with the principle that you are
setting forth. That principle is tihat there ought to be a better method
of consultation and exchange of ideas-before the :fact-so that there
is at least a better opportunity for coordinating monetary, fiscal, and
other policies to achieve national goals.
I believe we all agree on what the national goals are. The national
economic goals-and these are not the only goals-are -full employment, price staMlity, and a sound dollar.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

107
Where we disagree occasionally is about how to achieve them and
how they interrelate. I concur with your gene,ral proposition. And I'm
rather pleased, personally, because in recent weeks we have been working with the Senate Banking Committee on language for the Humphrey-Hawkins bill which follows the lines of your report-not in
detail, but it is consistent with it.
Let me describe to you what we have worked out. We would arrange
for two written reports from the Federal Reserve to Congress each
year-one be:fore February 20, and one before July 20.
The first report wou]d indicate the expected monetary policy guidelines over the ca]endar vear and relate them to the President's Economic Report. This report would take into account the factors of
production and prices, unemployment and employment-the whole
series of economic specifics that allows for complete interchange of
information. Our report wou]d set forth the Federal Reserve's view
of the economy, indicating the policies that we expect to foJlow and
how they relate to the President's report.
Then there would be a second report in July which would update
information and indicate the direction of Federal Reserve policy until
the end of the calendar year and for the following year, to give Congress a perspective, and help it prepare for the next plannmg cycle.
I hope that is consistent with what you have in mind. I think it is.
I believe it would be helpful.
Representative BOLLING. It is very responsive.
I have one comment on Humphrey-Hawkins. I gather that when
it came out of the Senate Banking Committee on a sequential referral
:from at least one other committee, the Senate Budget Committee, it
also came out with an amendment adopted which made the goal on
inflation zero inflation by 1983.
That is certainly a desirable goal. I think it also may ha,ve an undesirable effect. I think it may kill the bill.
Mr. MILLER. Some people may think it is desirable and some may
think it undesirable. I would just comment on that, if I maY.·
I think it is wise to have in the Humphrey-Hawkins bill the recognition that reducing inflation has to be a primary objective. We will
not achieve full employment if we have high inflation rates, because
high inflation rates tend to breed disinvestment, and disinvestment
tends
tends to breed re. to breed unemplovment, and unemplovment
.
cess10n.
My personal preference, which probably will not be reflected in the
bi11, would be to leave to Congress a lot more flexibility in setting
numerical targets'-because the world changes.
I think Humphrey-Hawkins does a great service in setting objectives and measuring our policies against our ability to achieve those
objectJives. But I think we live in a changing world, and each and
every Congress may want to look at the forces at work, over several
years aihead, and adjust the targets up or down.
It may be that some periods will be ripe for zero inflation and 2
percent unemployment. Maybe other periods will be ripe :for 2 percent inflatiion and 5 percent unemployment. I think there Congress
should have some flexibility in setting numerical targets.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

.

108
Representative BOLLING. I entirely agree with that. I am hopeful
thait you would think we might .achieve informally good times witih
relatively full employment, zero inflatiion. I also look at the yea.rs when
we got down to 1.2 or something like that, in remarkable good years.
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Chairman, many people say we will not achieve
our national goals. I am not that pessimistic.
w·e look at the complexity of our problems, and we assume that
tihey can never be solved. But if we look at our history, we will see
that problems that looked like they could not be solved were solved.
I£ we look back at our history, we will see that from 1961 through
1965 we had full employment, we had price stability, and we had a
sound dollar. That is the record.
During that period, tJhe inflation rate was less than 1 percent-zero,
if your measurement a0eounts for the improvement in the quality of
goods and services produced.
So we have experienced a period of 4 years with zero inflation for
all practical purposes. I don 1t know that we can replicate that condition very often, but I don't want to foreclose recreating such a
period.
Remember from 1961 to 1965 we had a doubling in the aggregate
dollars going into investment. I think that is what we need to do
again-to stimulate the investment side of our economy so that we do
work on this productivity issue, we do bring our unit costs clown, we do
bring our units costs of the use of energy down-thereby producing the
best chance for providing employment and at the same time combating
inflation.
Representative BOLLING. I am delighted to have your view on that.
I share that view precisely.
I think that those who say that it is impossible to achieve anything
based on the record of past achievements in this country must be very
wrong, clearly.
It is possible to do what is considered by many people very nearly
impossible. I think our charge now clearly is to establish full employment, wi~ont inflation, for all practical purposes.
While it is true that no country has done it for a long period of time,
that is no proof that this country is not able to do it for a long period
of time.
I think if we get to the point where all policymakers more or less accept that approach, we have made a great stride, because the doomsayers often bring on part of the doom themselves.
But I do think it takes an enormous amount-and I know you share
this view-of fresh analysis and fresh effort, because the economy is so
different today than it was in 1961-65.
It is very difficult to say that the same things would have the same
results. That is one of the reasons why I have been very much interested in the study that we have undertaken, the special study we have
undertaken on economic change, because the nature of the American
economy, and its relationship to the world, is almost incredibly different than they were just a few yea.rs ago for a variety of reasons, all of
which are pretty obvious from the fact that we don't have, and probably will never ha.ve again, unless we have some miracle, we will probably never again have cheap food and cheap energy, except in very
relative terms.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

100
That, of course, had a great deal to do, in part, with our post-World
,var II period functioning as well as it did.
Now we have some narrow questions. I hope in the interim some of
our absent members who planned to be here will a.rrive.
Mr. MILLER. I don't mind, because, so far I like our conversation.
Representative BOLLING. I don't know what will happen. I don't
know if it will improve or deteriorate when others get here.
I have been fascinated by what is going on politically, and I am
not asking you a political question.
But there is something curious going on politically. My own view
would be that accelerated depreciations would be mose beneficial-accelerated depreciation would be the most effective way to encourage
capital formation, that it is the way that would, let's say, please business more than any other way.
And yet we have a very curious problem, specific problem, in the
Committee on the Ways and Means, with which you are familiar.
It is a dual prdblem. We are running into people that tell us that
they will not vote for any tax decrease. They cannot relate the need to
stem inflation and the need to increase demand by a tax decrease, or
they say the only thing that they should do is to change, the capital
gains rate.
It would seem to me that a change in the capital gains rate would be
somewhere down the line. I am not trying to get you to make a comment that would be embarrassing on any part of this, because one element is certainly conservative, and the other element is essentially with
an opposite view.
But I think in most cases, they are misguided, and it is leading to a
kind of deadlock which is enormously difficult.
There are two questions, in the abstract: No. 1, can you give me your
order of preferences for changes in tax rates and so forth, in order to
achieve a higher rate of capital formation?
And No. 2, and also related, do we still need a relatively modest cut
in taxes, in the order of $15 to $20 billion?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Chairman first let me speak about priorities.
I agree with your remarks. It seems to me that one of the things :we
now need is a longer range perspective of how to overcome inflation
and achieve our other goals.
We operate on too short a time horizon. If we would look out 5 to
7 years and develop policies that would lead us toward a model economy at that time, we would have a better chance of placing in priority
the things that need to be done and of realizing that there is a time
for each and every one of them to be considered.
The first thing that is needed in the short run is to introduce fiscal
discipline, to start on a course of action which, over the years, will
bring us to a balanced budget with full employment.
I commented on efforts to curtail the amount of the tax cut; and deferring it is a very encouraging step in the rig-ht direction. Our pattern should be to bring the deficit below $50 billion in fiscal year 1979;
below $40 billion in fiscal year 1980; below $20 billion in fiscal year
1981; and to a balanced budget in fiscal year 1982.
If we believe that that kind of gradual program is important, sensible, and realistic, then we must time our tax measures to be consistent

with it.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
35-570 0 - 79 - 8
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

110
My view is that a tax cut on the order of magnitude of $15 to $18
billion, starting January 1, would fit into that program well. There
needs to be relief from the effect of inflation on real income, and from
the effect of the progressive income tax, which drives inflated incomes
into a higher tax bracket.
I personally would not want to suggest to Congress what it should
do. But there should be some relief for individuals and some relief
that would stimulate business investment.
I think business, ge111erally, would prefer a tax proposal that reduces
tax rates. I prefer, as you do, accelerated depreciation, because while a
reduction of corporate taxes does relieve the burden on corporations,
it does not affect how the money released will be used. It might be
used for higher profits or dividends. If we go to accelerated depreciation on the other hand, we know the tax relief will be used in exchange for investment. I think that would head the eccmomy in a
strong direction; that would be my preference.
I would put any reform in the categories of capital formation, entrepreneurship, venture enterprises-reforms we need to build our
technology-downstream in my priorities, considering them as we get
on that course to a balanced budget. But I would put the first priority on a commitment to a discipline that will reduce the deficit.
Then we could consider some of the more interesting, but at this
time I think premature, actions.
I hope that helps you.
Representative BOLLING. Thank you.
I have to absent myself. I apologize. I will ask Congressman Reuss
to take over.
Mr. MILLER. Thank you very much. I enjoyed it.
Representative REuss [presiding]. Thank you.
Mr. MILLER. Thank you. I have been before your committee more
than any other.
R~presentative REuss. Advancement is very rapid in the armed
services.
Let me especially welcome you because our relationship, both professional and personally, has bee111 most excellent since you arrived
here.
I am thus sorry that a cloud-which I hope can be dispelled here
and now-has come across that. I read your interesting prepared
statement, and particularly what you reiterated, that "the budget
deficit needs to be eliminated." Amen.
Some weeks a,go you came to see me, which I appreciated, on a gem
of an idea which you and your colleagues at the Fed had about an arrangement whereby, in effect, you would take up to a billion dollars
of taxpayers' money each year, and instead of turning it over to the
Treasury so it could help reduce that deficit, it would turn it over to
the banks, largely the largest banks, because they are the ones that
keep the greatest reserves.
I told you then that I thought it was a problem that very much
needs consideration by the Congress, that we would cooperate fully,
but that it was, under the Constitution, a matter for the Co1I1gress to
legislate. We stand for election every 2 years, and the people tell us
whether they want us back or not. And like it or not, that is the way
the constitution sets things up.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

111
You replied that someone in your legal office, some anonymous soul,
had put out a piece of paper which suggested that the Fed had the
right to legislate on this matter, not the Congress.
Senator Proxmire, who you were also kind enough to see, took a
similar view, and a series of calls and letters ensued. In your letter to
me of June 12 you said, "If your respective committees agreed with
your interpretation, it would seem to me unlikely that the Board
would go ahead and act in the absence of appropriate congressional
approval."
That was a pleasant way of telling us that you did not quite take
our word for it, that you wanted the word of the House Banking Committee.
So I have undertaken to find out what the House Banking Committee thinks of it. So far as I know unanimously, it believes that the
matter of reserves and payments, is indeed a matter of congressional
constitutiwial duty, and that it is not entrusted to members of the
administration, or members of independent bodies, however, worthy.
Early this week, however, I received another letter from you containing a copy of a proposed, quite complex Federal Reserve proposal, along the lines I have generally described, having to do with
reserve requirements, and payment of interest on reserves, and universal requirements, and charging of services of various sorts, et cetera, et cetera.
This piece of paper, which I have before me, quite clearly, as I read
it, suggests that, despite what I have just said, the Federal Reserve
seems to think that it is the duly elected Congress of this land.
I will read from the last paragraph of your enclosure to me:
To aid in consideration of the Board's proposal, interested persons are invited
to submit relevant data, views, or comments. Any such material should be addressed to the Secretary of the Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. 20051,
to be received within 90 days. All material should contain the docket number
R-000.

I also read an article in last evening's Washington Star which said:
:.\filler has said Fed lawrers assure him that the agency already has the power
to make the payments out of the massiye income it receives from its massive
portfolio of securities. In his current letter to Reuss, :.\iiller said he would be asking for legislation imposing uniform reserve requirements on all depooitory institutions. However, he was less clear about the interest payment issue. A Fed
spokesman said the likely result of tomorrow's session--

That is the Board of Governors meeting this afternoon?
Mr. MILLER. Yes.
Representative REUSS [ continues reading] :
Would be a proposed regulation to be put out for public comment. We would
certainly hope that Congressman Reuss would comment.

If I might, I would like to comment, in a friendly way, that the
Federal Reserve can go jump in the lake. ,ve are trying to be cooperative. ·lre have before us an excellent bill put in by our fine ranking
minority member, Congressman Stanton, cosponsored by 12, which
attempts to address itself to the problem. I invite the Federal Reserve
to bring us a bill. ,v e cannot operate from a vague statement such as
that which you apparently intend to act on this afternoon, and, of
course, we will take prompt action on any important matter like this.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

112
But I consider this as a totally unnecessary constitutional confrontation. If I may say so, it is not worthy of you.
I have commented. I invite your comment.
Mr. MILLER. This is the Joint Economic Committee hearing, Congressman Reuss, but I might _say that I did not ~·ealiz~ and I am _not
aware that there is a constitutional or any other kmd of confrontation.
As you know, one of the problems that I have fac~ in my new ro_le
as chairman of the Federal H,eserve has been the eroding membership
in the Federal Reserve. We are slowly losing members which means
that we are losing the amount of deposit& subject to the control of
the Federal Reserve, and that the amount of earnings on our assets
going to the Treasury is slowly eroding.
It is also apparent that, as a result of a changing world, there is now
a verv inequitable mode of competition among depository institutions;
banks that are members of the Federal Reserve are required to maintain sterile reserves, reserves that yield no income; banks that are
not members of the Federal Reserve are able, in almost all jurisdictions, to maintain their reserves in interest-bearing form or as assets
that help their competitive position.
Membership in the Federal Resen~e involves, i£ you will, an_ additional "tax" in the form of non-interest-bearing reserves-Representative REuss. Let me say, I will stipulate, and have for
many years, to the problem. It needs solution. 1Ve of the House
Banking Committee have offered a solution before your body 2 years
ago which has not been taken. It has been on our minds.
We want to be most cooperative in finding a solution that will give
us sound monetary policies. So my question is, why, in the face of
what I am telling you, is the Federal Reserve, apparently with your
consent, going on this afternoon to put out a regulation which sounds
as if the Federal Reserve Board intends to do this thing, rather than
the Congress, and indeed, by some coincidence, gives the final date for
comment 90 days from today, which happens to be, as all the world
knows, precisely the day on which the current Congress goes out of
business, according to its schedule.
Am I unjustly suspicious i
Mr. MILLER. I think so.
Representative REuss. You were not going to do it this afternoon,
theni
Mr. MILLER. If you would let me give the background for my views,
as you did with Y.<_>urs, I would be happy to do so. If you merely
want me to respond man adversary way, I will .
. Representative REuss. You may, but the problem here is not the
mceties of reserve requirements or charging for services of various
kinds, but the problem of whether it should be done by the Congress
with the cooperation and advice of the Federal Reserve, or whether
the Federal Reserve should attempt to do this by regulation.
Mr. MILLER. Let me explain; people can understand our action
only if they understand the motivation.
T!:ie m?tivation, for my pa.rt, is to find a constructive solution to
an _meqmta?le _metho~ of ~.ompetitio~ among financial institutions,
which also mdirectly 1mpa1rs the efficiency and the cost effectiveness
of our payments mechanism. X ot only did I describe an inequity
among banks, but member banks now are also competing with thrift

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

113
institutions and other kinds of financial institutions which can provide lower cost services because they do not carry the burden .of
membership. So we find that the banks' share of the total financial
mechanism for providing money and credit is generally shrinking.
So I have addressed myself to how this can best be solved and have
asked our staff to come up with some suggestions. I have describedsince March, when I first appeared before your committee-the elements of a plan for how we could relieve the burden of the membership, retain and enlarge our membership, and thereby contribute to
a growth in income for the Treasury.
In this context, one of the ways to relieve the burden of membership
is to pay some compensation on sterile reserves to make the situation
for member banks comparable to that of nonmember banks. However,
I also believe-looking to the efficiency of banking operations-that
it would be wise for the Federal Reserve to unbundle services. It has
tried to make up for the burden of membership by giving away services. Since banks have to maintain reserves and they get no mcome
for them, our effort has been to give them services. That is unsound,
because it builds up a system of services that is not monitored or
measured for its effectiveness. So it seems to me that we also should
unbundle services and charge banks for them and create a competitive
climate: More services might be performed by other financial institutions, and our own services would be measured by some standard of
efficacy.
Putting all those elements together, it had been my hope to consult with you and members of your committee-to get your viewpoint
and to shape and explain each element for your consideration. As
events have taken place, we have not found the time to do that. Now
that the preliminary memo sent to you has been made public, I think
we can proceed from here on the basis that we wanted to originally;
that is, we will submit to you and to the Senate Banking Committee
an outline of a plan we think would be workable and ask for you to
hold hearings on it and to take legislative action that would authorize
us to go forward. I know of no other draft document and no intention to do otherwise. It would be very desirable for the Board of
Governors to give their approval this afternoon to submitting this
document. You would then have what you asked me for this week-a
document from the Federal Reserve on which you can hold hearings
and on which you can take le~islative action.
Representative REuss. There has been a misunderstanding, then,
because what we would like from you-and I thought I had been clear
from the beginning-is a piece of legislation, not just a statement of
principles accompanied by a justification. Twelve members of the
House Banking Committee, led by Congressman Stanton have introduced a bill Jooking in this general direction. "\Ve are anxious to hold
hearings on that. We are anxious to hold hearings on any bill the Fed
may care to submit, either as an amendment to the one now before us
or as an independent bill. But I do not think it is useful to just send
us a statement of principles and-Mr. MILLER. May I suggestRepresentative REuss [continuing]. Then produce a bill for you in
a few days.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

114
Mr. MILLER. May I suggest a procedure1 What you have been dealing with is a memo which I sent to you. We had intended to supplement this memorandum with legislative proposals.
Representative REuss. Let me say that the memo you sent to me personally was released to the world by the Fed. That did not bother me. I
am not charging bad faith.
Mr. MILLER. It was not released by the Fed.
Representative REuss. It certainly was not released by me; and indeed, you sent to the House Banking Committee hal£ a hundred copies.
Mr. MILLER. That is true. If you-Representative REuss. That is not that great a degree o:f confidentiality.
Mr. MILLER. May I suggest a procedure and see if it is satisfactory to
you. We intended to ask the Board o:f Governors to approve a plan
as the basis on which legislation could be drawn. We intended to have
two pieces o:f legislation to submit with the proposed plan. And I
must say that I an personally appreciative o:f your wrningness to take
on this issue and bring it to a head. The Congress could decide that
our proposal is a good one or a bad one. It could decide that parts of
it are good and parts· o:f it are bad or write.in its own judgment o:f a
solution; I would be perfectly willing to live with the judgment o:f
Con.Q:ress.
What I am anxious to do is get a decision as to whether we want
to build the membership o:f the Federal Reserve or let it decfow. What
we planned to do was to submit an outline of the proposal with as
much detail as available. We had intended to send two pieces of legislation to you: The first, a bill that would require universal reserves
so that all financial institutions would be on an equal basis; and thl'
second, legislation that would appropriately cover this question of
interest on reserves. If we could get the Board of Governors to approve-which I will try to do, because I cannot offer this proposal
just on the staff recommendation-if the governors should bless the
proposal, we would send you a memo, the two pieces of legislation,
which woul~ :form the basis for your committee hearings and actions
on those legislative proposals.
Representative REuss. Almost, but not quite. "\Ve would like from
the Fed legal language to illuminate the entire Federal Reserve proposal. Let us, the Congress, be the judges o:f what the Constitution requires us to do. Give us your entire proposal in legislative language.
"\Ve will then act promptly on it and on any other proposals made.
Mr. MILLER. I am not sure I understand vou; the language would
be legislative language for a law to be enacted by Congress.
Representative REuss. That is right, but you said you would give it
to us on two subjects. Give it to us on the entire proposal.
Mr. MILLER. There are two subjects on which legislation is involved.
Representative REuss. There you go with your executive "I make the
decisions" attitude. You have got the Congress to deal with, and cantankerous though we may be, we haw unanimously decided that we
want to review in the public interest the entire proposal to take around
$1 billion a year :from the taxpayers' pockets and put it in the banks'
pockets. It may well be an excellent proposal just as you submit it, but
this is what we would like to do.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

115
Second, I think it is improper that you put out a Federal regulation
for public comment that which Congress, in light of what you have
said, expects you to submit to us. We cannot get to your bill this afternoon because, one, it is not drawn; second, we will go into recess tonight. But I would hop~ by July 10, when we return, the Fed will
present to us a comprehensive piece of legislation, either by way of
amendment to a bill before us or by way of separate legislation. And
I will be pleased to introduce that, by request, so that it is before us
the day it arrives. And I would further hope that you would not-I
repeat-not go ahead with the suggestion that the Fed proceed in this
matter as if this were all a nice little matter for the Federal Reserve
and that it is sufficient, as your spokesman says, that Congressman
Reuss can come around and comment.
Mr. MILLER. I do not intend to do that. I intend to follow the regular legislative procedures.
'
Representative REuss. So why not follow the Constitution?
Mr. MILLER. Congressman Reuss, I will. But I do not know what you
mean, and I will submit some legi~lation; you can reject it. But I
cannot submit something when I do not understand what you are saying. As I said, I will submit some legislation and you can consider it ;
if you do not like it, throw it out. That is what I am going to do; and
you can decide whether you want to act or not, as you indicated; I
hope you will act as promptly as you promise me you would.
But your telling me that I cannot prepare a memo without your
blessing is not acceptable. I am going to write memos to go with legislation any time I am ready. Is that all right?
Representative REuss. All right.
Mr. MILLER. Thank you. What is the next subject for today. That is
enough on that.
~epresentative REuss. You may think it is enough, but I want to say
a httle more-Mr. MILLER. Fine.
Representative REuss [continuing]. Because I want it to be clear. I
hope that the bill you send up to us will come as promptly as your
staff can prepare i t Mr. MILLER. Tomorrow.
Representative REuss [continuing]. And approve it. I hope that bill
will be comprehensive, so we may look at the entire Federal Reserve
proposal. I further hope that the Federal Reserve will not take action
this afternoon to proceed as if it were going to act by administrative
regulation in a matter where the House Banking Committee has clearly
indicated it considers it has jurisdiction and where it has answered
the question you propounded in your June 12 letter when you said,
"Of course, if Con~ress thinks this is for Congress, then the Federal
Reserve will go along." Congress does think it is for Congress. So
again, I express the hope that you will promptly get to u$ a comprehensive piece of legislation. We will make it an order of priority to consider it and other legislation on the same subject matter before us.
We will try to turn out something serviceable. But we are very upset
that the Federal Reserve continues to believe it can just go ahead and
legislate in matters which under the Constitution are reserved for the
Congress. I have had my say.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

116
Mr. MILLER. The Federal Reserve had no intention of implementing
any regulation without first providing for congressional review. We
are planning to submit legislation for your consideration.
But first, the amount of money involved in the plan, if it were
adopted, is not $1 billion. The net cost in 1981, at today's level of
membership, would be $250 to $300 million. Retaining and building
membership, instead of losing it, offsets a larger loss to the Treasury.
So I wish, Congressman Reuss, that we would please not get this $1
billion figure repeated, because it is incorrect and it will create an inflammatory situation. w·e intend to protect the Treasury with a plan
that would assure we retain membership and retain deposits to the
benefit of the treasury.
Second, we are gomg to submit to you legislation to authorize us to
carry out this plan if Congress feels that it is proper. And, if Congress feels that it is not proper, as I have said, it can make that de~ision. We will know where we stand, and we will proceed on other
issues.
It is an important issue and deserves to be addressed. If the Congress feels that the answer is to retain the present system, or not to
change the system, or to change it in some other way, that would be
satisfactory to me. But this decision should be made.
Representative REuss. OK. As you say, let us now go on to something else.
Mr. Miller, many witnesses before the Joint Economic Committee
have testified that high interest rates are a serious impediment to the
recovery of capital spending. Yesterday one of our witnesses warned
us that another slowdown would set back the recovery of productivity
and make it more, rather than less, difficult to control inflation in the
future and suggested the desirability of a shift in the mix of policy
in favor of a tighter fiscal and easier monetary policy.
Since Congress is in the process of slowmg spending and tearing
down and delaying tax reduction, isn't it time for the Fed to consider
holding off further increases in interest rates?
Mr. MILLER. Congressman Reuss, as you know, I think it is very
encouraging to see the prospect 0£ tighter fiscal policy. This will be
extremely helpful in developing a better balance in policies, as you
suggest. I think you have made this suggestion ever since I have been
in Washington; you started off with it the first day we met at your committee hearings.
Let me point out, as I have in the past, that the Federal Reserve
does face a verv serious dilemma-or at least did face such a dilemma
when I first took office. With rising inflation, and with a rapidly expanding base for money and credit, if the Federal Reserve failed to
take restraint, then surely inflation would accelerate and surely, in
due course, there would be a very serious rise in interest.rates from inflationary forces. There would be disinvestment in housing, there would
be disinvestment in business, and there would be a serious recession.
On_ the other hand, the Federal Reserve has every hope that its
actions will be balanced by some fiscal discipline, so that such restraint,
necess:iry to dampen inflationary forces, will not trigger a short-term
recession.
I think that is the main task we face right now. Can we move through
the balance of this year with appropriate Federal Reserve monetary
restraint and with overshooting so we trigger a recession?

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

117
On the other hand, will there be time £or fiscal policy to oome into
play to dampen the effect of Federal. deficits, so as_ to allow less restraint and an improved environment for the exei•cise of monetary
·
policy1
I believe that with the type of coordination and dialog we now have,
the opportunity for moving through this period successfully is quite
high. And I believe that a lot has been gained in the last few months
in the way of a better understanding and better program for balancing these policies.
Representative REuss. The range projected by the Fed £or some
months for the growth of M-1 has been 4 to 6½ percent. Yet, in £act,
this has happened in the past too, but particularly significant in the
last few mcnths, in £act, the growth rate of ~f-1 has been more than
20 percent, over the top side of the Fed's target.
It is impossible to quantify how much of the international disturbance of the dollar and the uneasiness at home, is caused by the money
managers' failure to stay within their target, but certainly it has some
discombobulatory effect.
1Vouldn't it be an idea worth considering of modestly raising the
top of our target for the present, not the 8 percent that you are actually
hitting, but somewhat over the 6½ percent which you mock by not
coming close, and then staying within that target 1 Wouldn't that be
a healthy tonic £or the world 1
Mr. MILLER. Congressman Reuss, I think you have a point. Conditions have changed, and it may be that the range for M-1 in relation
to the kind of velocity we are now experiencing-which is different
than expected-needs to be reexamined. You are on Eound ground.
I would point out that all is not lost, becauEe the Federal Reserve's
range for M-2 and M-3. So out of three measurements, two are within
bounds; the other has been more difficult to aEsess bec~.use of changes
in the economy such as you mentioned. Therefore, you are right: it is
worth while to reconsider whether there has been rnme change in
the mix of activities or in velocity and whether those ranges are
appropriate.
Representative REuss. Unfortunately, vcu see, the world is clearly
Friedmanized and everybody looks at M-i.
Mr. MILLER. They pay too much attention to it, I think.
Representative REuss. It may well be, but the Fed, if I may say so,
and occasionally the Congress, tends to defy M-1. Thus people take
it very seriously when there are consistent deviations on the up side.
So I am very glad that we are harmonious on this.
There is an Open Market Committee meeting coming up in midJuly, I think, and I know it will be on your agenda-Mr. MILLER. Congressman Reuss, I think you are well aware of this,
but may I point out to you that we need to continue to examine these
issues and to improve our techniques.
.
One of the items that is pending, to be effective on November 1, is
a change in regulation Q to permit-for individuals only-automatic
transfer from savings accounts to checkin8" accounts. That will have
some influence on the data for M-1. So it is important not only to look
at M-1 as we now know it, but to be prepared to make the technical
adjustments for the new kind of M-1 that will result from new payments techniques. I hope that you will bear that in mind.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

118
Representative REuss. To turn to energy, there is your call for early
congressional action on the energy conference report. I have boon
calling for it for many months without success, and I wish the President had it in hand before he goes to Bonn in a few weeks. I hope
he will.
If Congress does pass an energy bill, and if that energy bill, by way
of deregulation or by way of taxation, raises the price level, if the
Federal Resen'e failed to accommodate that increase-check me if
you think I am going wrong here-that this could be a, recessionary
scenario. Can Congress pass such an energy bill with some assurance
that the Federal Reserve will help to accommodate such a price increase that comes about through, not excess demand, but through what
the Congress and the President felt is necessary in order to get us in
a better energy position?
Mr. MILLER. I can only speak for myself, and as one member of the
Federal Open Market Committee. But it seems to me that when you
have an exogenous circumstance ·which may effect a structural change,
you ought to take it into account and accommodate to it. vVe do not
want to become doctrinaire or take technical action for its own sake,
but we do want to act with some feel for the real world and the economy. That is my personal viewpoint; it is a matter for the FOMC to
decide.
Domestic oil price rises have an inflationary impact, but-to the
extent that we restrain the demand for foreign oil and improve the
condition of the dollar-have a counterforce that would reduce inflationary pressures. So, over time, we will find ourselves in a much
better condition if we do adopt a strong energy policy.
Representative RE"Gss. Thank you very much, Mr. Miller. Before
recognizing Senator Roth I have one question which I will ask you,
but I do not want to take further time, so I will just ask you the
question and you can perhaps submit it for the record at a later date.
The difficulty with attempting to slow inflation by slowing the
growth of GNP is that it is difficult to predict how the slower growth
will be divided between less inflation and less real growth.
In Germany the Bundesbank announces in advance how much nominal GNP growth it will finance. This tells business and labor how
much prices and wages can rise without slowing real growth and without increasing unemployment, and this puts pressure on business and
labor to reach a wage-price restraint consensus.
What is your reaction to this approach which attempts to combine
monetary policy with incomes policy? Do you think it could be workable in the United States? I think it is something that you could submit
for the record.
Mr. MILLER. I will be happy to address that.
[The following information was subsequently supplied for the
record:]
There are substantial similarities between the procedures followed by the
Bundesbank and by the Jfederal ReserYe. Both central banks set monetary growth
ranges that they believe to be consistent with what would be an acceptable performance of the economy, given current conditions. In reaching this decision,
consideration is given to such matters as the trend growth of productive capacity,
existing levels of unemployment of labor and plant, "bmlt-in-" cost pressures, and
the behavior of velocity. Both central hanks then announce their projected rates
of monetary expansion. The Bundesbank goes one step further, however, by also

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

119
announcing the growth of nominal GNP that it believes consistent with the
specified increase in "Central Bank Money."
Whether or not there is particular advantage in this further step is, it seems
to me, uncertain at this point. It will take some time to determine its efficacy.
At first glance, it would seem reasonable to expect that the announcement of the
GNP figure would focus attention more clearly on a trade-off between real output
gains and inflation and thus provide an incentive for wage and price restraint.
But one can point to several probable complications.
First, there is no mechanical trade-off between inflation and real output growth;
if inflation were to slow unexpectedly, for example, it is possible that real output
growth would increase by more than is contemplated in a nominal GNP projection
(assuming a given money stock). Second, and a related point, ther~ is in general
a loose linkage between short-run movements in money and nominal GNP, and
certainly projections of GNP-money relations are subject to substantial ranges of
error. I believe that German experience, as well as our own, bears this out. Third,
to the extent that projections pro,·e unreliable, they probably lose much of the
desired impact on economic decisiohs, casting further doubt on the value of such
projections.
Much of the benefit in terms of influencing expectations and economic decisions
may, howeyer, be achieved through the announcement of monetary growth ranges
alone. Theoretical and empirical work by economists indicatE"s that the trends in
monetary expansion have, over the longer run, little impact on the behavior of
real output and employment-the primary impact being on prices. Thus, if the
monetary authority makes clear its commitment to the achievement of money
stock growth rates that will ultimately be consistent with price stability, it will
have provided a reliable basis for r,lanning. This has been the direction in which
the l!'ederal Reserve has attempted to move during the past three years, and in
which we plan to continue to move in the years ahead.

Representative REuss. Senator Roth.
Senator RoTH. Thank you, Congressman Reuss.
Mr. Miller. I want to welcome vou here. I am sorry that I have not
been here, but unfortunately the .Finance Committee is also having a
hearing on taxes; and as you may know, that is a matter of considerable
interest to me.
I am very concerned, as you are, about the impact of inflationary
pressures on our economy and I would like to addre1cs, if I could, a few
questions in this direction.
Yesterday we had a well-known economist here by the name of Henry
Kaufman, who is recognized as being an outstanding scholar by both
liberals and conservativeo, and I would like to read part of his
testimony.
He said:
By a wide array of yardsticks, the fiscal posture of the Federal Government
this year is excessive and virtually without historical precedent. For example,
this year's unified budget deficit is estimated at around $52 billion. During the
comparable years of the two previous economic recoveries, the deficit totaled only
$15 billion and $6 billion respectively. Federal expenditures in this fiscal year will
increase by 12 percent.
This annual percentage increase has been exceeded only 7 times during the past
25 years and only once in the nonwar year of economic expansion.

Mr. Miller, this current budget is a tight budget. Many of us feel
that there should be effort to make substantial cuts in Federal spending. Would you agree with that and do you think that would be helpful
insofar as inflationary pressures?
Mr. MILLER. I do agree with that, Senator Roth. I do believe, however, that the right way to go about reducing in Federal spending is
not only to make a short-term reduction but also to adopt a longer
term goal, too. And I would like, personally, to see our goal-for 5 or
7 or 8 years from now-a reduction in Federal spending until it

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

120
amounts to only 20 percent o:f the GNP instead o:f the present 22 percent. "\Ve need to start a constant trend in the right direction. This
process would shift resources back to the private sector; the same size
economy could be run with more decisions about spending being made
by businesses and individuals rather than by Government.
Senator RoTH. One o:f the problems of the current budget is it authorizes $100 billion :for spending. That is a 20-percent increase, much
larger than we have ever had in the past.
One of the problems is every year we come up with the fact that authorizations are ·way ahead, so that do you :feel that, nevertheless, we
should make every effort to eliminate all fat and unnecessary spending at the current time?
Mr. MILLER. Absolutely. Nothing I say about continuing the process
should in any way detract from tue importance of startmg it right
now-but we should cut spending not just this year but next year
and the following years.
Senator ROTH. I could not agree more strongly with you because we
always find ourselves trying to catch up with those authorizations in
the future.
Mr. Miller, there is a scheduled increase in the minimum wage rate
:from $2.65 to $2.90 to be effective January 1, 1979.
Do you believe that that should be allowed to go :forward, and i:f
so, what are the economic implications of that increase?
Mr. MILLER. The minimum wage has been inflationary. The increase at the beginning o:f this year was quite large percentagewise and
showed immediately in a number of sectors of the economy-the service sector particularly-and contributed to our inflation.
I am sure when Congress enacted the provision :for scheduled increases in the minimum wage that its intention was a good one. As
it turns out, with hindsight-with inflation becoming a more serious
problem-I believe that it was a mistake.
I would personally welcome any way possible to defer or to change
what is going to haripen next January 1. I would put it off for a couple years or somethmg so that we do not have another burst o:f inflationary ripples running through a sector of the economy.
Senator ROTH. Have you made that recommendation to the President?
Mr. MILLER. I have suggested it to the administration, yes. I do
not know if anybody has done a study o:f the issues, but I would think
that the better choice would be a 2-year de:ferral rather than an attempt to undo the increase. That would, perhaps fit in with other timetables and be more logical.
Senator ROTH. You think it would be help:ful to have some type o:f
partial exemption with respect to the teenage employment, permitting the youth to be employed at something less than the standard
minimum wage?
Mr. MILLER. Senator, there is no question but that that would be a
wise move. Young people today have great difficulty in getting their
first job, particularly those without higher education. But after they
do get a job and have had it a :few years, they progress very well. They
can take up their place in society with well-paying jobs. It is in theirown self-interest, to get that first work experience, evel!l at a differential wage. Many of them are living .at home; they have less personal

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

121
expenditures; they are not married; and they can afford to go through
an apprenticeship, if you will, as many of us did in our years of learning. '!'hey learn what work is and what responsibility is. They learn
w11at it means to be a part of the team and to produce. So I don-t think
it would be socially regressive; I think it would be progressive to give
them that opportunity.
Senator koTH. Many of us feel that it would be very helpful in providing some amelioration of structural unemployment with the teenagers, particularly in the inner-city. So I am happy to see that you
would support that.
How much would you say the minimum wage increase might affect
the inflation rate ?
Mr. MILLER. I might have to turn to one of my colleagues.
The effect next year could work through to about a half percent;
the effect last January was a little more, as 1 recall.
Senator ROTH. One-half of 1 percent?
Mr. MILLER. Yes. That, of course, is a very large inflationary impact.
Representative REuss. Would the Senator yield?
Senator RoTH. Yes.
Representative REuss. I appreciate the Senator's yielding because I
am required over on the House floor and I will ask Senator Roth to
preside from here on out.
I am sorry I will miss the testimony of my old friend, Arthur Laffer,
who always has something interesting to say; and on our side, Senator
Roth, Mr. Atkinson will perhaps have a question to ask Mr. Laffer.
Mr. MILLER. Congressman l{euss, before you depart I wanted to
thank you. I am glad we could straighten out a misunderstanding. I
am glad you will give early consideration to our legislative proposal.
Thank you very much.
Representative REuss. I trust the misunderstanding is straightened
out. Did you have any doubt in your mind-Mr. MILLER. No.
Representative REuss [continuing]. When I told you that we would
give early consideration to your legislative proposal as soon as you
made it?
Mr. MILLER. I am glad we have straightened out the misunderstanding.
Representa,tive REuss. Thank you.
Senator RoTH [presidingJ. Mr. Miller, you estimated that the impact
on the economy would be one-half of a percent increase on inflation, a
not inconsiderable amount.
·what are your predictions as to what will be the rate of inflation by
next year?
Mr. MILLER. Senator, I would like to have your permission to check
that figure of one-half of 1 percent for the record.
This year, I am afraid inflation will run over 7 percent. The best
prospect I see at the moment is for something around 6½ percent next
year, which is far too high; and even that, of course, depends on
achieving some of the changes that we are all working on that would
at least start the process of bringing inflation rates back down.
But if it were 6½ percent-and part of that rate reflects the impact
of an increase in the minimum wage-there could be a significant
additional reduction from deferring that action for a couple of years.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

122
[The following information was subsequently supplied for the
record:]
It is my estimate that the boost in the minimum wage scheduled for January 1,
1979, will raise the overall level of prices by close to one-half percent.
The scheduled increase from $2.65 per hour to $2.90 per hour is likely to raise
compensation directly by 0.3 to 0.4 percent. In addition to the di-rect cost, there
will also be upward pressure on wage rates from workers above the minimum
who want to maintain their traditional relatiYe wage position and from noncovered workers who attempt to emulate the gains made by covered workers. Such
indirect effects may be roughly one-half the size of direct effects, bringing the
total expected rise in compensation to around 0.5 percent. Since no additional
productivity gain can be expected to accompany the minimum wage adjustment,
unit labor costs will be boosted by a comparable amount, and historical evidence
suggests that about two-thirds of the rise in unit labor costs is passed through
into higher overall prices. In addition, these higher prices will have secondary
effects on other wages that are linked to prices through escalator clauses. Cost
pressures resulting from these wage adjustments will be reflected partially in
further price·changes. Thus, if the January 1, 1979, minimum wage inc,rease were
deferred the rise in prices could be reduced by nearly one-half percentage point
from that which would have occurred otherwise.

Senator RoTH. ·would you favor reestablishing what Congress created some several years ago: The requirement that your larger companies give prior notice as to any price increases-a 2-month noticeand the same with banks, as a means to perhaps have a stronger talking
basis on which to hold down inflation?
Mr. MrLLER. Senator, I believe we should expect and should have the
cooperation of the private sector in the President's deceleration program. And there is no reason, as that program takes effect, that there
cannot be good coordination with the Council of Economic Advisers
and the Council on ·wage and Price Stability so that they receive
information of that type.
"\:Vhether it is timely to ha Ye a formal requirement of prenotification,
I do not know. I would prefer to get information on a voluntary 'basis,
because I think each time we impose another set of regulations or
another set of mechanical requirements we create another layer of
burden. And I would rather see the basic industries-I think that is
what you are talking about-supply information on a voluntary basis
as a sign of their willingness to cooperate.
Many people have said that there is not much teeth in the deceleration program, but I think there is a tremendous advantage to cooperation and it's in the self-interest of those businesses. If businesses
do not cooperate in finding means for deceleration, then we will have
high rates of inflation. This will create great obstacles for business in
maintaining their real profits, their real incomes, and the real values
of their assets. So I think there is a tremendous reason why they ought
to be cooperative. If there is not cooperation, I would look at the next
steps.
Senator RoTu. But for the moment vou are satisfied with the progress being made 1
•
Mr. MILLER. I would prefer to have this worked out with businesses
voluntarily.
Senator RoTH. In your prepared statement you talk about the need
of providing free resources for t,he prirnte sector. One of mv greatest
con~erns at the present time is the decline in productivity of the
Umted States; the fact that we are not competing effectively with our

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

123
foreign competitors, as witnessed by the unfavorable balance of trade.
What are the recommendations that you would make to try to
improve the productivity of the United Statesi
Mr. MILLER. One of the principal suggestions is to create a policy of
stimulating increased fixed business investment. We have had a substantial lessening of productivity gains recently, as you know. I
pointed out-on chart 6, attached to my prepared statement-that the
ratio of capital stock to the labor force has been deteriorating. And it
seems to me that this is coincident with the deterioration in productivity. It seems to speak loudly for the proposition that we should
increase our capital investment as a means of improving productivity
and combating inflation.
One of the best ways to do that, I believe, is to have a substantial
liberalization of depreciation allowances. I have recommended a 5-year
writeoff for productive equipment and processes and a 10-year ,,Hiteoff for structures used in production, as a way to create the cash flows
that would make the risks of investment less and increase the prospects
of profitability.
As a national goal. I would like to see us incre:1se capital spending
to 12 perc~t of the GNP ; now, it is about 9 percent. In previous period:;; of peak activity we have seen capital spending up at 10½ or 11
percent, but recently we have been underspending very seriously.
Japan is investing about 21 percent of its GNP; Germany is spending about 15 percent; we have been spending 8 or 9 percent. I think
it is extremely important that we develop a conscious program of increasing our capital base and our investment base jn order to make us
competitive-get our costs down, get us enough modernization, and
develop the new technologies that are essential for efficiency.
Senator ROTH. Well, as I understand it, there is no question that
our depreciation policies are much less generous than those of, say,
Germany, even Socialist Sweden, and Japan. Is that correcti
Mr. MrLLER. Generally they are less favorable, and generally I favor
higher depreciation because depreciation is a very efficient means of
giving incentive for investment. It defers tax relief; once the depreciation is completed taxes are paid. An investment tax credit, on the
other hand, is a form of reduction of taxes. Depreciation is merely
a deferral of the time of payment; the Federal Government eventually collects the tax, but at a discounted value. Depreciation also works
efficiently.
Our total rate of recapture-including investment tax credits and
depreciation-on the capital investment is slower than manv of the
other industrialized nations.
•
Senator RoTn. "\Vhat we were holding hearings on in the Finance
C~mmittee was on the capital gains, modification of capital gains,
gomg back to what we had some years ago, the so-called Steiger bill,
Steiger-Hansen bill.
One question I have is would you care to comment on that proposal, but I would also like to point out that one of the problems in
~aking any of those proposals £or capital formation, the administration has taken the attitude that they are millionaire benefits that are
not helping the average people, and you could say the same thing about


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

124
liberalization of depreciation. You are helping those that have it,
particularly the big companies. W oul~ you care to com~ent_? .
Mr. MILLER. Let me take the latter first. Recapture of capital is now
permitted. Liberalized depreciation merely improves t!?,e ~-ate ?f. recapture; it does not really create any ultimate economic favoritism .
.Moreover, business investments are made by small businesses and large
businesses; and it is this vital method of creating job and improving
productivity that helps every American. So I do not see how it favors
business over the average American ; I think it would benefit all.
But more than that, I think that most American companies are
owned by Americans-either through pension funds or direct investments or through indirect means-so ultimately the beneficiaries are
the American people. vVe have far more involvement in the ownership
of enterprises than most people realize, through direct stock and
growth of pension funds. It should be clear-and 1 believe the admin istration would agree-that an increase in business fixed investment
is desirable. Either method-investmen t tax credits or accelerated depreciation-would be desirable, although I prefer the latter.
On the Steiger bill, I feel that our priority should be to generate direct action for increased investment in operating enterprises. The capital gains tax has an indirect impact; it might bring more capital m,
which might ultimately be invested.
·we are, therefore, back to a question of fiscal discipline. I have felt
that there is no room now for another tax reduction. The Steiger
amendment or a variation of it should be considered in a later year,
when we have proved that ,vc can get this budget deficit down.
Senator ROTH. Or the alternative, we could cut the budget.
Mr. MILLER. Reduce expenditures? Fine. Yes, I am talking abom,
reducing the budget deficit. But if we are going to be stuck with spending at $499 billion in fiscal year 1979 aml we are going to collect just
so much revenue, my first dedication is get that deficit below $50 billion, and I do not want any tax cuts that would impair that. If you can
cut spending, fine. But I have not addressed the Steiger amendment
per se; I have addressed its philosophy. My philosophy is that in
due course, when it can be afforded consistent with a conscious,
continued plan for balancing the budget, those kinds of actions might
be appropriate. If we examine the great enterprises, we will see businesses started by entrepreneurs who "-cut out and developed the new
technologies; they were motivated to do that because of the incentive
of capital gains. -we see this in our computer industry, which led the
':'orld since vVorld vYar II, and in many large companies that started
literally from nothing.
Sena~or Ro1:n, I am sur: )'Ol~ are aware of the fact that many, many
econmmes believe a modificat10n of capital gains tax will increase
revenue rather than decrease re,·enne to the Federal Government.
Mr. MILLEn. Senator, I am not a student of those analyses. Some of
the!n make different assumptions about the effect on the stock market,
which would affect the revenue fommla. l\Iv belief is that there would
b: a negative effect in the first year, and that it would take some
~1:me be~ore ther~ ,vould be a positive effect. And my concern, again,
1s that if there _rn to be _a~y change in the taxation of capital gains
or double taxat10n of dividends, I want to be sure that it is timed

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

125
consistent with the primary purpose of reducing the Federal deficit.
Our primary objective is to reduce the fiscal stimulus and achieve a
balanced budget and full employment.
Senator RoTH. I would point out that some of these studies say they
would have a benefit within at least 2 years; some even predict the
first year.
I have one or two more questions, but at this time I will yield to
Congresswoman Heckler.
Representative HECKLER. I would like to say, Mr. Miller, it is a
pleasure to welcome you. ·while I am a strong admirer of the previous
chairman, I cannot think of a better replacement.
Mr. MILLER. I think I lived in your district :from time to time.
Representative HECKLER. That is exactly right.
Mr. MILLER. I do not vote there, however.
Representative HECKLER. I am really pleased with your selection
for any number of reasons and encouraged, because I think while you
have the expertise to deal with problems of the Federal Reserve,
I think you also have a perspective of the New England economy,
which we rarely see. In New England, as you know, we have deeprooted economic problems with structural stagnation in our particular
area ; and it is a source of encouragement that you would embody that
kind of understanding.
At the same time I must say as a member of the committee, one of
my primary interests is the development of the small business-sector
of the economy; and while I a,m supportive of many of the statements
you have made, I would be interested in your response to a proposal
which actually was generated by small- and medium-sized firms in
New England and relates to the· need for a stimulus.
.
Their problems of capital formation are even greater than the large
companies, and their proposal in the upcoming tax package suggests
an increase of the surtax exemptions from the present $50,000, which
was pa.rt of the tax bill passed in 1974 which raised the surtax benefit
for small businesses-set in 1938 at $25,000, which in 1978 dollars
would be equivalent to $124,000. Their proposal, which I have drafted
into legislation, would increase the surtax exemption to $150,000.
Now possibly that amount cannot be achieved, but their point is
that small business needs some fo11m of internalized mpital formation
because in times of tight money their ability to borrow is certainly
not as great as their larger competitors. A study from the Amos Tuck
School of Business Administration at Dartmouth seems to validate
that point and suggests that we could generate a very si~ificant
number of jobs, 207,000, at a cost of $10,000 each in the first year
versus $25,000 in the President's plan. I wonder how you have looked
upon this and whether or not you see the need to develop somewhat
different policies to face the particular problems of the small- to
medium-sized business sector in the country.
Mr. MILLER. Congresswoman Heckler, New England has been impacted by dramatic changes in its economy. At one time it was the
part of the Nation that was industrialized the earliest, and it had a
high percent of manufacturing employment; but for all kinds of
reasons, there has been a steady decline, and the adjustment process
has been painful.


35-570 0 - 79 - 9
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

126
One of the strengths of New England has been the growth of small
business; a lot of the technological businesses have grown up in your
State. That is important to the region and to·the Nation, because the
technological base has revolutionized many parts of our society. So
we need a whole battery of policies to encourage that kind of entrepreneurship, and I think your suggestion is worthy of consideration.
I ,-ould only point out, as one caution, that the proposal should be
desif:iNl so that it does benefit operating businesses and does not
become a basis of tax shelters for multiple corporate operations.
If you can design such a protective device, you have got a good idea.
The . roblem is that this will be used for tax purposes by the multiple
corporations; and every child in the family will have a little corporation with special tax rates. If you can solve that, you have 1a good
idea,.
Representative HECKLER. That is a suggestion that has been made
and I will pursue it.
Of course, our major interest in New England is this question of
inflation. Recently in a letter to the New York Times 1an economic
consultant said:
The trouble is the high interest rate policy of the Federal Reserve Board. Since
last summer. for example, the Federal Reserve has raised the discount rate
from 5¼ to 7 percent. This is why the consumer prices have risen drastically.
In the past 18 years consumer prices have always risen when the Federal dis,.
count rate has been raised and have only slowed down when the rate has been
lowered. If Congress would legislate an interest cut by forcing the Board to
lower the FRB rate generally back to where it was in the 1940's, before the
Board began to raise it, consumer prices would stop going up and economic
troubles would fade in due course.

This perhaps might be a statement of one who is asking for utopia,
but I wonder what your comment is.
Mr. MILLER. I guess it is a question of which came first, the chicken
or the egg. Do interest rates go up because of inflation or does inflation
go up because of interest rates? I am afraid that interest rates go up
because of inflation.
If you look back over time you will find that when the capital was
available, the American economy had fairly steady, constant real interest r3:tes of 2½ to 3 percent.
It 1s very easy now to look at mortgage rates, and see 10 percent, and
say, "That is terrible." But if you deduct from that rate the 7-percent
rate of inflation, the only real gain on the investment is 3 percent. So it
is that phenomenon that causes people to believe that inflation is caused
by higher interest rates. To the contrary, rates go up because inflation
has started them on that pattern.
Now the whole theme-not the whole theme, but a good deal of the
theme-of my statement this morning was based upon a se,ries of policy
suggestions that would better ba]ance our economy policies in orde,r to
take pressure off the monetarv side. And in my closing remarks in that
statement I said that if we do follow this reorientation, then we will
lessen the burden on monetarv policy which will give us a better balance and, at least, improye the prospects for lower interest rates.
If the Federal Reserve should do what many people would like it to
do-just take the restraint off and let money be printed to bring down
interest rates-then what would happen would be that inflation would


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

127
escalate. While things would go well for a while, it would only be a
matter of a year before we would be at 9, 10, or 12 percent inflation.
There would be disaste,r in the economy.
On the other hand, if we restrain too much, then the worries of the
consultant who wrote that letter and of other people will be fulfilled
and we will have a diffe~nt problem. So we try to walk a narrow line
and hope for better coordination ·and a better balance with other parts
of the economy. Then we can take the pre.ssure off monetary policy.
And that is what we tre trying to accomplish.
Representative HECKLER. About the offering of 6-month term certificates in denominations of $10,000 or more, commercial banks can sell
them at maximum interest rates, the same as the U.S. Treasury. The
savings and loans can sell them at one-fourth percent more than the
prevailing Treasury rate. The purpose of this policy is to keep money
in banking systems rather than in other investments such as Traeasury
bonds.
However, I am told that in the vast majority of cases no nerw money
is being raised. In fact, a survey taken in New York recently indicates
that 80 to 85 percent of the transactions :involve a mere transfer of
money rather than new money, with the concomitant result that there
rure higher operating CO$ts for banks. I am wondering what your initial
reaction is to this study. Are they beneficial? Are they a threat to
industry and the housing market? Are they inflationary and do they
increase the operating costs for banks? How do you review it?
Mr. MILLER. Congresswoman Heckler, the purpose of those instruments, as you pointed out, was to avoid disinteirmediation. The last
time we had a rise in market rates, there was a large outflow of funds
from savings accounts and thrift institutions. That outflow of funds
had an enormously adverse impact on housing; housing starts
dropped to 1.1 million, and it was a disaster.
I think it is very important, whatever other problems we have in the
economy, that we do try to maintain an adequate level in the housing
industry and a strong base. Housing starts should be at 1.8 million or
more. What we feared, with the rise in other interest rates because of
inflation, was that money would begin to move out. We already had
seen a decline in inflows to thrift institutions.
Now, at some point in time, it becomes worthwhile for individuals-particularly people with larger amounts of money-to remove them
from savings accounts and to buy Treasury bills. What happened when
we introduced those accounts was, in my opinion, that there was some
retention of money that would otherwise have flowed out. Our initial
check shows that, as far as thrift institutions, about 40 percent of the
money was new money, depending on how much they promoted it.
If they did nothing, the money was mostly shifting from one account
to another. I:f they promoted the new certificates, they were receiving
about 40 percent new money. That is not universal; you might find
New York different because of its different financial sectoF. But the
results have been rather encouraging; the first week about $3 billion
went into the 6-month certificates; 40 percent, approximately, was new
money.
Representative HECKLER. Again, on the housing sector question,
there is great concern about the new incre,ases in the credit rates. FHA


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

128
went from 9 to 9.5 percent just yesterday, I believe. I wonder how far
you expect this to go? How long will the interest rates continue to increase, and when will they peak, or begin to roll back? Can you answer
that questioni
Mr. MILLER. The answe,r is entirely tied to inflation. As soon as inflationary forces begin to abate, I think we will see interest •rates hegin to
peak and turn down.
The movement in that interest rate, which I read, as you did, I believe, was designed with the same purpose as the new savings instruments-be sure that federally insured programs would be able to continue to provide money for housing, and that they would not become
so noncompetitive as to dry up. These programs are extremely important. One of the great new developments in the housing industry
is that those programs offered by Ginnie Mae can tap sources of money
to keep the housing industry going. So I am delighted to see that move,
even though it does result in higher cost to the home purchaser. But
as least it makes possible the purchase of a home.
You ask me when the rates will go down. I wish I could predict
that. I often tell reporters who ask me that that if I told them they
would get rich and retire from journalism, and then they would not
be able to enjoy their profession! They could speculate and make a
killing in the market, so I do not tell them. I cannot tell you either, but
I hope we will see a peak in the coming quarter, so that we can end
this period of difficulty and move on to a more favorable condition.
Representative HECKLER. Thank you.
Senator RoTH. Mr. Miller, I understand that you have a luncheon
engagement and must leave at 12 o'clock, so I will let you go.
Mr. MILLER. Thank you very much.
Senator RoTH. I would now like to call Professor Arthur Laffer.
I want to welcome you to this committee and thank you for taking
time out on such very short notice. As you know, testimony was presented to our committee yest€rday iri which it was claimed that the socalled Roth-Kemp tax reduction would result in increased inflation
and massive budget deficits. Further assertions were made that tax
rate reductions would not result in increasing the work effort or savings, investment, and production.
As you know, I for one, reject these arguments. I am pleased to have
you here to discuss the Roth-Kemp tax reduction and the Laffer curve.

STATEMENT OF ARTHUR B. LAFFER, PROFESSOR, UNIVERSITY OF
SOUTHERN CALIFORNIA
Mr. LAFFER. I would like to make two points, if I could, and also, I
have a prepared statement for the record.
In looking at the effect of taxation on work output and employment,
people basically do not work to pay taxes. Basically, firms. do not locate as a matter of social conscience. Firms locate where they can get
after-tax profitability.
The important aspect of the Roth-Kemp bill, is that it reorients incentives and increases them the most where they are now the most destroyed. Let me give you an example.
When Jack Kennedy was President of the United States the lowest
tax rate was 20 percent and the highest tax rate was 91 percent. A per
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

129..
son in the lowest tax rate category, who earned a dollar paid 20 cents
in taxes and the incentive was the 80 cents he got to keep.
A person in the highest category, who earned a dollar paid 91 cents
in taxes and his incentive was the 9 cents he got.
What the Kennedy tax rate cut did was cut tax rates across the
board. He cut the lowest category down to 14 percent and the 91 percent rate down to 70 percent. It is clear what happens to incentives.
After the Kennedy tax rate cut on personal inoome, the person who
earned a dollar in the lowest category, instead of keeping only 80 cents,
got to keep 86 cents as incentive for working. His incentive went from
80 cents to 86 cents. That is an increase in incentive of 7½ percent for
a 30 percent cut in the tax rate.
But if you look at the top bracket you find that the person who
earned a dollar before and kept only 9 cents as incentive, with the new
tax rate cut of 23 percent, paid 70 cents in taxes and got to keep 30
cents as incentive. He went from 9 cents to 30 cents, an increase in incentives of 233 percent for a 23 percent cut in the tax rate.
The important point here is that people do work for incentives, and
if the tax rate is reduced there will be an increase in incentives for
working, saving, and investing.
As I look at the Roth-Kemp bill it cuts tax rates across the board
over 3 years by approximately 30 percent. It reorients incentives and
changes the constellation of taxes such that the bill increases incentives the most where they have been destroyed the most by our tax
structure. The Roth-Kemp bill would have a major effect on work output and employment, and would increase those areas exactly where
they are the most destroyed today.
On the Federal revenue level, there is quite a reasonable chance that
within a very short period of time, a year or two or three, that not
only will the cut in taxes cause more work output and employment,
but the incomes, profits, and taxes, because of the expansion of the
tax base, would actually increase.
It is very clear to me that a cut in these tax rates, along the lines you
suggested, sir, would increase State and local revenues substantially.
There is no ambiguity there. Any increase in incomes productivity
and production will increase State and local revenues substantially. If
you take the Government as a whole, it is likely that more revenues
will increase.
One additional point is that by cutting the rate as you suggested in
the Roth Kemp bill, I think we would increase employment, reduce
poverty, and Government spending on unemployment compensation,
and Government spending on poverty programs would literally diminish-not because we are spending any less per person who is in
need. We will be spending the same amount per person, but there will
be fewer people in need, and less people unemployed, and less government spending.
If you look at the Kennedy tax cut, it had a dramatic effect on unemployment. If you look at revenues you can see they rose sharply during
this period. They rose faster than did Government spending at the
Federal level.
If you look at inflation rates then, the GNP defl.ator during the Kennedy era is 2 percent, and that is not per month like now. If you look

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

180
at the wholesale price index it is slightly over 1 percent on the average
during this period.
If you look at all sorts of other measures, capacity utilization, et
cetera, real income growth averaged over that 6-yea.r period from 1961
to 1966, 5.4 percent, quite a change from what "rn have been having.
The last point I would like to mention is the effect the Roth-Kemp
bill would have on inflation.
One hears that tax cut bills will cause inflation. In fact, there exists
a proclivity to look at the trade-offs with the bill along these lines. But,
it is unambiguously clear that unemployment will fall, and as a consequence I do not think anything could be further from the truth that
such a cut will cause inflation.
Let us run a mental experiment for a moment. Hold the money supply in the United States constant and reduce the output level of the
United States to the output of Luxembourg where we have 99.999 percent employment. What do you think would happen to Luxembourg's
price level with our money supply? It would not fall, it would go
through the ceiling.
Inflation, basically, is too much money chasing too few goods. The
more goods there are, the lower prices. The faster output rises, the
lower the rate of inflation.
If you take the Economic Report of the President and just plot
quarterly the rate of inflation against the rate of growth of real output
for the last 7 years, what you find is, just as theory would suggest, as
the rate of output growth increases, the r_ate of inflation decreases, and
as the rate of output growth decreases, the rate of inflation increases.
They move in opposite directions, and as far as I can tell, the RothKemp tax cuts will have a major effect on inflation. They will reduce
the rate of inflation because they increase the supply of goods and services, and thereby put less pressure on the monetary policy.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Laffer follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF ARTHUR

B.

LAFFER

"The Roth--Kemp Bill

In the absence of a "tooth fairy" resources spent by the government are the
total tax burden on the economy's productive sector. Wether government spending constitutes much needed public sen-ices, transfer payments, pure waste, or
even worse; these resources must come from the economy's workers and producers. As such, they comprise a major part of the wedge driven between payments made for factor services and payments received by the factors themselves.
Taken alone, increases in this wedge per se raise wages paid for factor services,
lower wages received by factors and thereby lower the demand for and the supply
of productive factor inputs. Output falls.
The Roth-Kemp bill does nothing directly to impact this aggregate wedge,. To
stop here however would miss not only the essence of the Roth-Kemp bill, but
much of the lessons from the history of taxation.
Output depends as much on the constellation of individual factor tax rates as
it does on the overall tax burden. If one producth-e factor is faced with exceptionally burdensome tax rates it will withdraw from the market place. Its departure from the market place will lower output by its production potential and, in
turn, reduce the production potential of all other factors with which it is comple-mentary. High productivity and high wages for truck drivers require the existence of trucks for the drivers to drive. If trucks are taxed excessivE>ly their numbers will decline as will the wages and productivity of truck drivers. Oi;itrmt will
be impacted doubly. In the limiting case when all returns to trucks are confiscated
none will exist and wages accruing to truck drivers will be zero.: Output, too, will

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

131
be zero though there no taxes on the earnings of truck drivers. Tax receipts will
also be zero.
As a pedagogic device, imagine that we reduc-e all tax rates in the sample by
one-half. The earnings of truck drivers remain untaxed but now earnings accruing
to trucks are taxed at 50 percent instead of the previous 100 percent. Savers who
either abstain from consumption or work harder can now obtain an after tax
rate of return by accumulating trucks. There will be more trucks, higher wages,
more output and tax receipts will rise. The increase in tax receipts results exclusively from the increase in production and the lowering of tax rates.
The Roth-Kemp bill, armed with the experience of similar, but far more extreme, measures carried out by President Kennedy in the early sixties, addresses
the current counter productive constellation of individual factor tax rates. By
partially redressing the counter productive structure of current tax rates it most
likely will lead to a substantial increase in output and, in the course of very
few years, will probably reduce the ,size of goverment deficits from what they
otherwise would have been. Net revenues could well expand even though income
tax rates at each and every bracket are reduced. Part of the effect on the deficit,
of course, will occur because higher output means less unemployment, less poverty
and therefore lower total spending on unemployment benefits and poverty programs. In this sense, the Roth-Kemp bill actually reduces government spending
and the overall wedge, albeit indirectly.
People don't work and save to pay taxes. They basically work and save in
order to acquire after-tax income. It is the after-tax incentive that drives production, savings and employment. In a Newsweek column several years ago Milton
I<'riedman illustrated the sharp increase in the progressivity of personal income
taxes resulting from an across-the-board income tax surcharge. The Roth-Kemp
hill, as the earlier Kennedy tax rate cuts, is precisely a negative income tax
surcharge. Its effects will be to lower the progressive nature of income taxes. '.rhe
Roth-Kemp bill will increase those incentives the most where the incidence of
taxation is currently the highest.
Using the Kennedy income tax rate by way of illustration, when Kennedy came
in to office Federal personal income tax rates ranged from 20 percent in the
lowest brackets to 91 percent in the highest bracket. A worker in the lowest
bracket who earned $1 on the margin paid 20 cents in taxes and his incentive
was 80 cents. In the highest bracket one dollar of marginal earnings yielder 91
cents in taxes and an incentive of 9 cents. By cutting tax rates across-the-board
by about 30 percent the lowest bracket after the Kennedy tax cut was 14 percent and the highest bracket 70 percent. The incentive effects however were
radically different for the two extremes. The incenth-e in the lowest bracket
was raised from 80 cents on the dollar to 86 cents or an increase of 7½ percent.
In the highest bracket where the cut was 23 percent as opposed to 30 percent
the incentive was raised from 9 cents on the dollar to 30 cents or an increase
in incentive of 233 percent.
The Kennedy era is an excellent example of the type of impact a Roth-Kemp
bill could have. While occurring at different times the Kennedy tax program
included an across-the-board cut in personal income tax rates. The corporate
tax rate was reduced from 52 percent to 48 percent, depreciable lives for legal
purposes were shortened and the investment tax credit was instituted. In addition. major tax rate reductions were carried out under the Kennedy round tariff
cuts.
From 1961 through 1966 real GNP grew on average at a 5.4 percent annual
rate. Unemployment rates fell from 6.7 percent in 1961 (5.5 percent in 1962)
to 3.8 percent in 1966. Capacity utilization as measured by the Federal Reserve
Board rose from 77.3 percent in 1961 to 91.1 percent in 1966. Annual inflation
averaged 2.1 percent, 1.6 percent and 1.1 percent for the GNP price deflator.
consumer price index and wholesale price index respectively. For some, the
behavior of stock prices is perhaps the best indicator of the era's growth. The
ratio of the S+P 500 to GNP went from .1104 in 1960 to .1154 in 1967. The low
was the 1960 ratio but peaked at .1281 in 1965. Over the 1961-66 period stock
prices rose at an annual rate of 5.5 percent and from 1960 through 1967 at an
annual rate of 7.8 percent.
During the 1961-1966 period Federal spending rose at a rate lower than GNP
growth, 6.2 percent versus 7.5 percent. As a consequence the overall federal wedge
fell from 18.75 percent in 1961 to 17.62 percent in 1966. 'l'he deficit on the Federal
level fell consistently from the $3.1 billion level in 1961 to a surplus of $1.4 bil•


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

182
lion in 1965 and literal balance in 1966. Defense spending increases during this
era were less than non-defense increases.
While the prognosis of dire consequences were the range in the early 1960's
they didn't materialize. In many ways the situation is similar today. Unemployment is high, currently sitting a little above 6.0 percent. Federal spending, or
the aggregate wedge, stands about 22.6 percent and S & P stock prices relative to
GXP are at .045, close to their all-time low. Inflation is far higher today, running at rates well over 6 percent. The federal deficit in the most recent period is
about $45 billion.
While the Federal tax code on the surface appears less distortive today than
at the beginning of the Kennedy era other changes have occurred that could
even result in more distortions. Additional changes have also occurred that make
marginal tax rates relative to average rates even higher now than before. The
institution and expansion of State and local taxes, the systematic reduction of
real exemptions and credits combined with the highly distortive effects of inflation on the incidence of tax rates on real earnings have resulted in widely divergent marginal tax rates on different factors of production. The effects on
incentives of the current structure of taxes are quite conceivably greater today
than they were prior to the Kennedy cuts.
An across-the-board tax rate cut, as shown earlier, increases Jncentives the
most where the incidence of the tax structure is most restrictive. Without a
great deal more specific knowledge the Roth-Kemp bill would be a good first
step in an overall tax reform pac-kage. It would go a long way in reorienting
incentives with market contributions.
The Roth-Kemp bill by no means ends the need for tax reform and tax rate
reductions. Additional legislation such as the Steiger-Hansen bill and the
Stockman bill would be complementary with the Roth-Kemp bill. Looking out
into the future, indexation legislation such as former Senator Taft's bill and
legislation proposing full integration of the corporate tax structure with personal
income taxes are desirable. Even more distant would be some proposal for the
substitution of a value added tax for other far less efficient taxes. Social Security
tax and benefit reforms are also badly needed.
In analyzing the Roth-Kemp bill it is important to recognize that the bill is
a beginning to a meaningful tax reform, not an end. The need for other legislation does not mitigate the need for Roth-Kemp now. The best cannot be aHowed
to be the enemy of the good.
The Roth-Kemp bill should als'l have a good effect on inflation. Inflation is
primarily a ~onsequence of too much money chasing too few goods. Excessive
money growth has long heen recognized as a cause of inflation. It is equally as
true, however, that too few goods will also cause prices to rise.
To put this relationshir> into clear focus, one need only to imagine the following: What would happen to prices in the United States if output were reduced
to, say, the output level of Luxembourg and the amount of money stayed unchanged? Prices would skyrocket, not fall. Higher unemployment means lower
output. As such, high unemployment is, by itself, a cause of high prices.
High prices and rapid inflation increase the prospects for high unemployment. ,vith progressive income tax schedules, high price levels raise tax rates
for each level of produrtion. Rapid increases in prices result in firms underdepreciating their plant and equipment and also nnder-valuing their cost-ofgoods sold. Pretax profits are overstated. This results in higher tax rates for
lmsinesses for each level of output. The increase in tax rates that result from
higher prices and inflation reduce output directly and cause unemployment.
Fortunately, this view has two highly attractive characteristics. First and
foremost, this view is supported by a large body of experience. Secondly, the
poliry implications offer some hope to a world badly afflicted with economic
malaise. The Roth-Kemp bill would start the process in the correct direction.

Senator RoTH. Thank you, Professor.
Yesterday Professor Heller. in all candor, raised a number of strawmen and proceeded to knock them down f!S to certain Rtatements. He
asserted that some of us supporting the Roth-Kemp bill had made a
mistake, but when all was said and done, he came out himself in fa..vor
of a $25 billion increase, so that I am not sure whether it was the
authors he was opposed to or the tax cut. But the thing that he kept


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

133
saying was that the Kennedy tax cut worked, primarily, because stimulated demand and had a benign effect.
I take from your discussion that you strongly disagree with that.
Mr. LAFFER. Yes. But let us imagine that he was correct, that it
worked exclusively on aggregate demand. "Why not do it now too? Do
we have too low unemployment now? Is our inflation too low 1 If it
works through demand, let us do it that way.
There are reasonable area;s for disagreement among economists. I
just listened to President Kennedy's state of the Union message in
1963 a little while ago, when he was talking about these tax cuts, and
he stressed the incentive. In fact, I think his statement was "a rising
tide lifts all boats," and I think what he said is we are reinstituting in
America a fundamental American principle which states that if a man
works hard, if he produces more, if he shows drive and initiative, he
should be allowed to kee~ some of his product. And basically that was
strictly an incentive statement.
I guess I was an undergraduate during that time and we all studied
the economics of Walter Heller and we were all convinced at that time
that the father of the tax bill, Walter Heller, was correct in what he
did; and I guess I still believe it.
By the way, they also cut the corporate profit tax substantially, instituted the investment tax credit. You are talking about a massive tax
rate cut of very large proportions, much larger than your bill. They
also did the Kennedy tariff cuts, which are the major cut in tax rates,
and they did not have a delay factor in those tax cuts, if I remember
correctly.
Senator ROTH. Mr. Laffer, I am going to ask Congresswoman Heckler to takeover, if she will, because I have to run and vote and I will
return right afterward.
Representative HECKLER [presiding]. I would just like to have you
discuss what the increasing tax rate faced by workers and 'business is
doing to the cost of labor and the cost of investment in the United
States.
Mr. LAFFER. It has quite a substantial effect on the price paid for
labor and the price paid for capital.
There are two prices for labor and two prices for capital. There is
a price paid by the purchaser and a price received by the producer. The
difference between the price paid and the price received is what we
call the tax wedge.
If you tax a product at ·a rate of 50 percent, the price paid is twice
as high as the price received. As you raise those taxes, tbe prices paid
keep going up and it makes the industry that is exceptionally heavily
taxed uncompetitive. And as you go to very, very high tax rates any
residual competitiveness-disappears.
The same thing is true with labor and any category of factor in the
U.S. economy.
·
Representative HECKLER. In terms of our international competition,
you feel the Roth-Kemp bill is likely to place the American manufacturer of goods in a better posi,tion?
Mr. LAFFER. Very definitely. For example;the way we tax the steel
industry is discriminatory. With the corporate profit tax, OSHA
standards borne by the firm, pollution controls, there is a very high
marginal tax rate on some of the major industries, especially steel:

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

134
utilities and a few others, because replacement cost accounting is not
adopted for tax purposes.
Representaitive HECKLER. ·what evidence is there that high tax rates
are costing us revenue?
.
Mr. LAFFER. There are some experiments, though anecdotal, that
show evidence of what happens when tax rates are cut, and what happens to revenue.
In a recent experiment in the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico Governor Romero cut personal income tax rates by 5 percent across the
board. At that time they were running a deficit and the tax exempt
bond yields were about 12 percent, which puts them in the category
with New York City. Governor Romero cut the tax rates across the
board. This year I think the budget is in a slight surplus and the bond
yields have gone down to ,about 8 percent. That is one example.
Let's look at New York City. Is there any question that more should
be spent for repairing roads and more for sanitation? If you look at
the wages of city employees, part of these wages are in pensions held
in questionable asset forms. How do you get greater spending in New
York? Do you raise the t,ax rates in New York and drive the last two
businesses out or do you lower the taxes and bring the people back and
provide a larger economic base and more employment; less poverty
and more diversity of funds? Instead of welfare and unemployment,
you get the city going again; and if you look you will see that New
York City is quite a depressing sight.
But to come directly to the answer, the higher the tax rates are, the
more likely revenues will decrease. And if you lower the tax rate, the
more likely that revenues will increase. But raising revenue should
not be the only objective. In fact, far from it. Unemployment and
inflation are also important.
Representative HECKLER. Another very critical question is the issue
of the timelag between the time that a tax reduction is passed and the
time that the great beneficial consequences occur. vVhat happens to the
society in the interim and what kind of a timelag are we talking about?
Mr. LAFFER. With regard to the Federal tax rate cuts of the Kennedy era there did not appear to be a timelag. Budget deficits declined
fairly straightforwardly.
In Puerto Rico the revenues increased the next year. Also, behavior
is sometimes affected before a tax change becomes law. If manufacturers anticipate that a bill is going through they will in:est ahead of
time. Revenues increase before the actual signing of the bill because of
the anticipation of the tax cut. I do not know what kind of lag we
would have here. "\Ve have not done estimates of that. I do not think
the lag would be very great; perhaps 1, 2, or 4 years. In_ the interim
the capital market would be far more amenable to acceptmg the Federal debt during the transition period.
If you owned all of New York City's bonds and controlled t~eir
policy, would you raise the tax rates or lower them? The same thmg
is true for the United States as a whole.
Representative HECKLER. "\Yhy is it that you feel people are reluctant to accept this philosophy?
Mr. LAFFER. I am in the field of economics, not psychology. I do not
know why. Frankly, I do not understand. It seems to m~ that th.ere
are two types of error an economy can make. Type 1 error 1s changlllg

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

135
policy when you shouldn't and type 2 error is not changing policy
~hen yo~ shoul~. And it se~ms to me that in our country today there
is_ somethmg qmte wrong with the economy. Our unemployment is too
high ~oi: th~ fourth year of re:covery. In~ation rates are too high. Perhaps 1t 1s time to change pohcy. The mistake of not changing policy
can be very costly.
Representative HECKLER. I think Mr. Atkinson has some questions
he would like to ask you.
M~. ~TK!NSON. My name is Lloyd At~inson, staff economist, and I
am s1ttmg m for Congressmen Reuss while he is on the floor.
It seems to me that there is one critical issue which you have raised
and that is the extent to which a cut in taxes of the magnitude proposed by Congressman Kemp and Senator Roth would generate a
sharp increase in incentives. The opposition in large measure stems
from the fact that many people think that there has been a serious
overstatement of the impact which the tax cuts will, in fact, have on
incentives and that, in fact, all we will end up doing is stimulating
aggregate demand, and setting oft' another surge of inflation.
The comment made by Mr. Heller yesterday that he was in favor of
a tax cut was based in large measure on the fact that there has been an
increase in payroll taxes and inflation and this has drained real personal consumer income; and second, that there is some unused capacity
and it is not inappropriate to have some stimulus to aggregate demand.
The fundamental question we address in this issue of the RothKemp bill is the magnitude of the tax change itself, spaced in over
some period of time and fundamenta.Uy whether or not we can anticipate the increase in our potential GNP that presumably derives from
these improvements in incentives, and therefore, whether the increases
in ·aggregate demand would generate additional inflation; indeed, potentially could reduce the rate of inflation.
The question is, What kind of hard evidence can you bring to the
committee that will demonstrate that these incentives are as highly
responsive to changed tax rates as you say in your testimony~
Mr. LAFFER. The hard evidence is the examples looked at in the past,
and there are a number of them. They are admittedly anecdotal, but
expectations change with every piece of new evidence. There is a book
entitled "The Way the World Works" by Judy Wanniski which compares Germany and Japan to the United States and Great Britain _in
terms of the differences in their performances. There is an economist
by the name of Norman Ture who has done work on this. We have a
group of eight or nine of us developing an economic model. The purpose of the model's development is to stand as a juxtaposition against
some of the demand models. The estimates are coming out rather
nicely. Again, they are not in final form, but I 'Yould be hap:py to share
some of them. It does appear that the tax rates m the_uppe~ mcome ~ax
brackets, and especially in the lower brackets, a~e mordmately h~gh
and are costing revenue, Federal revenue. No. 2, 1t suggests that h1g~
rates are costing revenue on the State and local levels. From our estimates, and those are very limited, but it d~s _look like a cut along the
lines of the Kemp-Roth bill would have pos1t1ve revenue effects on the
Federal level because the Kemp-Roth bill cuts the lowest rates the
most. In the i~ner-city, tax rates are exceptionally high because of ~he
means test and the incomes test. For an inner-city Los Angeles family

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

136
of four whos~ income ranges from zero to $1,000 per month the average tax rate 1s 86 percent. Our preliminary estimates are m~ch in line
with ~he fact that the c~t in these rates, just using the aggregate supply side fr~mework, will lead to revenue increases. But again I and
my academic colleagues are not in the business of making your decisions, we ~i:e solely trying to provide you with help t-0 help you make
better dec1s10ns.
~r. _ATKINSON. ~et us ~eview the ~ax cut during the Kennedy era to
see if 1t had the krnd of impact which you allege. How much did our
potential GNP grow relative to what it otherwise would have been,
since that fundamentally is the key issue?
Mr. LAFFER. Average real growth was 5.3 percent per annum over
the 6 years. Unemployment rates went from 6.5 to 3.8 percent. This
fall was not because of deficit spending or the Vietnam war. The deficit
grew more slowly than the rest of the budget, which grew slowly.
Senator ROTH [presiding]. If I can interrupt for a moment, because
I know Senator J avits can only stay for a moment; he has to be on
the floor with a bill being considered to help New York City. So at this
time I would yield to Senator Javits.
Senator J AvrTs. Thank you, Senator Roth.
Professor Laffer, I am very glad to meet you, and I deeply feel this
matter deserves thorough examination.
Unfortunately, you have come here on the very day we have the
New York City bill on the floor. I am interested in pursuing your
thesis. Therefore, I asked Senator Roth whether you were likely to
return, and he said you probably would before this matter comes to
the action stag, and so I am going to ask the chairman to recall you,
s.ubject to your convenience, so that we may have a panel discussion.
I respect what you believe and am very interested in listening to your
views. I have never been found lacking in interest in new ideas, and
yours are new ideas and a new approach.
Although I think your approach is more of a gamble than we ought
to take, I am willing to listen and see what the proof is.
Obviously, this matter is high in your personal priorities. If yo_u
are agreeable, it might be interesting f you would take the Heller testimony and answer it point by point. If it would be simpler for you,
subject to my approval, and I will carefully monitor it and sign the
letter myself, I would be willing to have my staff actually raise Mr.
Heller's points and questions.
But you may prefer simply to take the testimony yourself and
answer it point by point.
Mr. LAFFER. Why don't I take it and answer it point by point. I
think that is better.
Senator JAVITS. I think that may be better because you might not
agree that we are paraphrasing it correctly. I appreciate your cooperation, for this would give us a document so that when you do appear again-and I very much hope you do-we will be able to tackle
the matter with some preliminary analysis before us.
Mr. LAFFER. I would enjoy that, sir.
Senator JAVITs. '\Vhen should we hold the panel, in 2 weeks, 3 ,veeks?
Mr. LAFFER. Let me go back and check. I have got to go to Europe
shortly, and as they once said, I shall return.
Senator J AVITS. Thank you very much.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

137
Senator ROTH. Thank you, Senator.
One of the things that disturbed me, Mr. Laffer, is that in the testimony yesterday Mr. Heller said that really taxes have no impact on
savings; that the rate of savings of the American people pretty much
runs the same irrespective. Would you agree with that?
Mr. LAFFER. No. There are two things that we want to separate
here. Mr. Heller referred in his testimony to Denison's law, which
is that savings are, roughly speaking, 16 percent of national income.
There are two effects of increasing incentives on savings. If you increase incentives for saving, you increase savings and as savings expand, investment expands and in turn income expands. Both savings
and income expand by an increase in incentive for savings.
Now, the question is, Does one of those expand more rapidly than
the other? The only reason people save or invest is to consume in the
future. To save is not the objective unless they can someday convert
it back to consumption. So if you increase the incentive for savings,
you increase the numerator of the savings ratio and increase the denominator of the total income; and the question is which is more dominant. And there is no reason in my mind for one to dominate the
other. The ratio of savings to investment could stay the same-savings
to income-but you could expand both at a more rapid rate. But there
is nothing inconsistent with a constant savings rate and having increased incentives to savings, increased absolute savings and absolute
income at the same time.
Senator ROTH. If we have a tax cut, just for business without cutting tax rates for individuals, will we get enough savings to fund the
credit demand of big business and government?
Mr. LAFFER. Basically, businesses do not pay taxes. Their employees
and shareholders do and consumers do, but businesses do not pay taxes;
and people couldn't care less, frankly, where their taxes are taken
out. What they care about is how much they get after all taxes. If you
look at the structure and constellation of taxes, the sharp distinction
between business taxes and personal income taxes is really missing.
There is a precise correspondence between any given business tax rate
cut and another personal income tax rate cut; precise correspondence
because people pay taxes.
Senator ROTH. Are you familiar with the so-called Javits-Danforth proposal?
Mr. LAFFER. Not very much.
Senator ROTH. One of the charges made is that if we adopt the
Roth-Kemp tax cut that the people who are really going to pay for
that legislation are the poor and the disadvantaged; that it is going to
create tremendous deficits, and because of tremendous deficits there
will be less opportunity to help those on the lower end of the economic scale.
Would you agree with that 1
Mr. LAFFER. No, I would not. I addressed the deficit question a little bit, but let me address the income distribution question. We know
from economic theory that the incidence of a tax is not the same ,as
the burden of a tax.
If you tax one group, the higher income group, you will hurt the
lower bracket. Let me give you an example.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

138
I grew up in Ohio. In that area there were ~lways truckdrivers ';l,nd
their wages were low when there we1;e no ~rucks a!'°und to ~~ve.
Unless you give a person an after-tax mcentive for either abstammg
from consumption or working harder to provide the requisite capital
to back the company, you will not get truck~ and the wages wi!l remain
low. If you lower the tax rate you mcrease mvestment and raise wages
of drivers.
We are very much in that situation in the United States. My f!e,rsonal belief is we are taxing cert.ain groups so much that we are losmg
the necessary capital to raise the wages of the lower income groups.
In fact, to help the :f?O?r today I think it is important to reduce some
of our exorbitantly high marginal rates.
The Kennedy tax rate cuts were very much along these lines. By
cutting rates and increasing incentives the most where the tax rates
were the highest, the unemployment rate fell and real wags rose. 1Ve
are very much in that situation today that to help the lower income
people you want to reorient taxes-in order to tax the rich there have
to be some rich around to tax. But if you tax them too much they will
be gone. Then the burden falls upon the poor. We are in that arena
today.
·
Senator RoTH. In one sense it seems to me that what we a.re trying
to do is increase the size of the pie so there is more to share so that
the poor and disadvantaged move up into the million-dollar class
rather than on the low end of the economic scale.
Mr. LAFFER. Yes. The only way a poor person can ever get rich is
by earning income. But if you tax income excessively, you preclude
any poor person from ever getting rich.
Senator RoTH. The one thing that bothers me the most about those
who are opposing our reduction is that it does not benefit the low end
of the economic scale the most, but it does cut roughly 33 percent
across the board. But the thing that bothers me is the fact that there
seems to be an attitude of soak the middle class and I am bathe.red
by the fact that a man making $20,000 today might be making $35,000
a few years from now and he will have the same amount of purchasing
power yet they are pushed into a higher tax bracket. They cannot buy
as much as before because they have to pay taxes.
I think it is time some of these people in Congress, some of the big
spenders, listen to what happened in California. People are concerned
with the fact that they are working harder, wives are working harder,
and they cannot keep the same standard of living.
As I have said many times, we are in the midst of a tax revolt and
we had better begin listening to the complaints of the people.
Is there any reason why a general tax reduction cannot have the
same beneficial impact that it did in Kennedy's 1960's 1 We agree that
the situation is not analogous in every regard, but even Mr. Heller
admitted that capacity is not being used. He admitted that there is
high inflation and high unemployment. And won't our legislation promote wages too 1
Mr. LAFFER. I believe it will take care of that in the short run. I
believe the wages are similar to the 1960's. 1Ye had high unemployment
rates and low capacity utilization, and the tax rate cuts today would
do much of what this did then.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

139
Mr. ATKINSON. Coming back to this issue, there is a curve for which
your name is associated, I understand.
Mr. LAF1''Jm. Yes, though I did not name it.
Mr. A·rK.INSON. Obviously it is important in terms of the kind of
illustrations which you provide on the side of the curve you are on~
Mr. LAFFER. Yes.
Mr. ATKINSON. Because obviously, to the extent that we are on the
side of the curve different from the side you are suggesting, a tax cut
would have exactly the opposite effects, lower output.
Mr. LAFFER. No, no, please. The curve has only to do with the
revenue. It has nothing to do with output. It is assumed to always
respond to incentives. We are just talking about revenues on that cur-ye.
The tax base always expands when you cut the tax r_a~s on the m~rgm.
Mr. ATKINSON. How would we go about determmmg the optimum
tax rate?
Mr. LAFFER. The longer you wait the more likely it is that revenues
increase. If a guy builds a plant, let us say, and presumes a 10-percent
tax, and the day it is built the tax jumps up, he does not throw the
plant away. When something wears out he just does not repair it. It
takes a long time to build capital stock and a long time to destroy it.
The longer you wait the more revenue you are going to lose.
One of the Henry George theorems is whm you want to tax for
revenue purposes you want to tax the most that factor that can escape
the tax the least and tax those factors the least that can escape the
most. It appears to me that we are taxing the most those who can
escape the most, and we are taxing the least those which can escape
the least. For example, a plant can move from New York to Chicago,
to Bermuda, anywhere; yet that is where we are taxing heavily. The
next area is the inner city. Inner city inhabitants can go into a subculture and deal in a nonmarket economy, avoiding taxes. If you look
at a lot of the activities, it is all done on a cash basis. Yet we tax the
inner city among the highest, and they have all of these escape valves.
This seems to me to be the incorrect structure of taxing for the purpose
of revenue, and that is all we are talking about here.
Admittedly no one has the precise estimation of what these rates
would do and never has had them on any model. But being imprecisely
correct is not as bad as being precisely wrong.
Mr. ATKINSON. Why are we to believe this tax cut will lead to a large
upsurge in work in •response to an increa.'38 in pay? In the Kennedy
era there was a response of working shorter hours and ta;king longer
holidays. They opted for more leisure time.
Mr. LAFFER. Do not confuse the effects of a tax rate cut on and individual with the tax rate cut on the economy. We know that there are
income effects of tax ra.tes on individuals. But there is also a cumulative
~ffect on the overall economy and the closed economy net income effect
1s zero.
Let me give you the ex!llmple of an income change and the price of
apples, the classic case Hicks used. If the price goes up, positive income
effects occur because more is needed to be produced. There is a negative
effect in that a few will buv less than before. The net income effect in
the closed system is zero. However, the substitution effects cumulate
right aoross the board. So that while individuals may be affected negatively, they net out across the whole economy; so that the emphasis is

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

140
plain wrong unless you can show major distribution effects on different
groups. Then you could get a different answer, but in general the effects
net to zero.
Mr. ATKINSON. But the fundamental question, as I said before, there
would be very little disagreement with Kemp-Roth if we felt there
would be the kind of expansion in our potential GNP as suggested. Yet
we do tend to find that there should be an increase in work effort in
the aggregate, which is the basis for the expansion of our potential
GNP. Why do we find that seems to have worked the opposite before?
Mr. LAFFER. I am using the Economic Report of the President, and
real income growth from 1961 to 1966, our real income grew at 5.4
percent. That is not a slowing down to me. Unemployment went from
6-plus percent to a little lower than 4 percent. That does not seem to
be a worsening to me either. I do not know what you are refurring to.
Maybe people chOO:Se te, take some longer vacations. If total output has
expanded and sonie volunta,rily choose longer vacations, I do not see
any rea.son why we should not do so. I see nothing wrong with individual vacations.
Senator ROTH. I would like to make one comment on attached rates.
I am not an economist, but if anyone goes back on their constituencyand there is no question about the fact that the American people feel
taxes are too high. I th:i:nk proposition 13 is one example of that. Another example of the fact that your tax rates are too high would be the
development of subterranean economies to avoid the tax impact.
Would that not be some evidence?
Mr. LAFFER. Sure, of course.
Senator RoTH. One final question, Mr. Laffer. Are you at all concerned about the spending side of the equation? I know that we all
agree that long range will do more for the economy, but what should
we be trying to do to hold down spending currently?
Mr. LAFFER. I am less concerned about spending because in many
areas GoveTll!Illent spending should actually be increased. For example,
in New York City it would be a shame to hold down spending when
the roads are in the shape they are in and the sanitation is in the shape
it is in.
My perspective on spending comes from the time I was here in
Washington. If a department's budget is cut, they usually do not cut
the fat. They usually cut the lean. And the only way, I think, to oot
spending is to permit private alternatives to Government spending
and thereby make more efficiency. But seriously, an overall spending
ceiling I would not go along with personally. In fact, I would be opposed to it.
Senator ROTH. Thank you very much.
[Whereupon, at 12 :45 p.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene at
10 a.m., Tuesday, July 11, 1978.]
[The following letter and article were subsequently supplied for the
record by Senator Roth:]


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

141
STAFF LETTER TO ARTHUR B. LAFFER TRANSMITTING ADDITIONAL WRITTEN
QUESTIONS POSED BY SENATOR ROTH
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
.
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,
Washington, D.O., July 14, 1978.

Prof. ARTHUR B. LAFFER,
Rolling Hills Estates, Oalif.

DEAR PROFESSOR _LAFFER: During your testimony before the Joint Economic
Committee on June 29, 1978, Senator Roth requested that I submit to you in
writing additional questions for your written response. Per Senator Roth's request, the following questions are hereby submitted :
(1) Whether the tax cuts proposed by Kemp and Roth are appropriate is
heavily dependent on (a) the magnitude of the increases in aggregate spending
that they bring about and (b) the magnitude of the increase in our potential
GNP-however measured-that they induce.
Many economists favor a relatively simple tax cut in 1979 on the order of $15$25 billion. A tax cut of this size is deemed necessary in view of (a) the continued
presence of slack within the economy and (b) the losses in purchasing power
attributable to the "inflation tax" and the legislated increases in payroll taxes.
In the minds of most economists, then, the tax cut is needed in order to raise
aggregate spending above what it would otherwise be in order to ensure a 'level
of economic activity that is closer to our potential.
Moreover, it is likely that the tax increases attributable to the "inflation tax"
and the payroll tax are likely to be sizable for the next several years, and future
offsetting legislated tax cuts in 1980 and 1981 might well be called for in order to
ensure that our economy continue to operate at or close to our GNP potentiat In
view of the fact that we have, at best, very imprecise knowledge about the future
course of aggregate private and government spending, do you think it is appropriate for the government to lock itself into sizable tax cuts of the magnitude proposed by Roth and Kemp for 1980 and 1981 without a better idea of the magnitude of the tax cuts that might be needed in order to ensure a high level of economic activity consistent with a non-accelerating rate of inflation?
(2) You state in your testimony: "By partially redressing the counterproductive structure of current tax rates, (the Kemp-Roth bill) most likely will
lead to a substantial increase in output, and in the course of very few years, will
probably reduce the size of government deficits from what they otherwise would
have been." Moreover, you go on to state that the effects of the Kemp-Roth bill
"will be to lower the progressive nature of income taxes."** * (It) will increase
those incentives the most where the incidence of taxation is currently the
highest."
The implications of your views are that the Kemp-Roth bill will have a decidedly positive impact on our potential GNP as well as our actual GNP, and further that tax revenues will be larger than otherwise (which is consistent with
the view that we are currently operating in the prohibitive range of the so-called
"Laffer Curve").
(a) Now, the revenue feedback resulting from the Kemp-Roth bill will exactly
equal the initial tax reduction only if the growth of actual GNP per dollar of tax
reduction is equa'l to the reciprocal of the overall marginal federal tax rate.
Under present law, this rate is about 25 percent which implies a tax multiplier
of 4-a numerical value that is significantly larger than the implied tax multipliers calculated from most econometric models of the U.S. economy. How do you
reconcile your revenue feedback conclusions with those econometric models that
imply less than proportionate revenue feedbacks? And what evidence can you
provide to this Committee in support of the im{ilied numerical value of your tax
multiplier?
( b) Using CEA estimates of the gap between our potential GNP and our
actual GNP for the years 1979--1981, and assuming as our -baseline, current tax
law, a tax cut of the size proposed by Kemp and Roth produces both higher
inflation and lower tax revenues than otherwise. Even Norman Ture's projections

35-570 0 - 79 - 10

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

142
and those developed by Michael Evans imply smaller future tax revenues than
otherwise. How do you reconcile these results with your own conclusions respecting the tax revenue impact of the proposed Kemp-Roth tax cut?
(o) If the Kemp-Roth tax cut is to produce "a substantial increase in output",
"a good effect on inflation", and an expansion of tax revenues, there must of
necessity be a huge increase in aggregate spending and an increase potential
GNP as well. Can you explain to this Committee (i) how the tax cut will affect
our potential GNP, (ii) how the change in potential GNP feeds back to affect
aggregate spending and (iii) how one would go about determining the value of
the "tax multiplier" in the face of this aggreate demand and potential output
interaction.
I would very much appreciate your reply within the next two weeks. I thank
you for your cooperation.
Sincerely,
LLoYD C. ATKINSON;

Senior Eoonomist.

[EDITOB's NoTE.-The above letter was not responded to by Mr. Laffer at time
of printing the hearings.]


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

143
[From thP Pnhlk InterPst. Summn 1!17SJ

The

breakdown
of the

Keynesian model
PAUL CRAIG ROBERTS

T;,

much talk these days
about "the crisis in Keynesian economics." That some such crisis
exists is evident from the bewilderment and impotence our economic policy makers are displaying in their confrontation with economic
reality. But what exactly is the nature of this crisis? What went
wrong and what can put it right?
The answer, I would suggest, is almost embarrassingly simple.
Today in the United States, public economic policy is formulated in
bland disregard of the human incentives upon which the economy
relies. Instead it is based on the Keynesian assumption that the gross
national product ( GNP) and employment are determined only by
the level of aggregate demand or total spending in the economy.
Unemployment and low rates of economic growth are seen as evidence of insufficient spending. The standard remedy is for government to increase total spending by incurring a deficit in its budget.
GNP, it is believed, will then rise by some multiple of the increase
in spending. Keynesian economics focuses on estimating the "spending gap" and the "multiplier" so that the necessary deficit can be
calculated.
This view of economic policy is enshrined in the large-scale
econometric forecasting models upon which both Congress and the


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

144
THE BREAltDOWN OF THE KEYNESIAN MODEL

21

Executive Branch rely for simulations of economic policy alternatives. It is a view that is extraordinary in its emphasis on spending.
True, it is obvious that if people did not buy, no one would produce
for market. It also seems obvious that the more people buy, the
more will be produced and, therefore, that the use of government
fiscal policy to increase total demand will increase total production
or GNP. All this is so obvious to Keynesians that they believe any
fiscal policy that produces an increase in government spending, even
a spending increase matched by a tax increase, will produce an increase in GNP.
The concept of the "balanced-budget multiplier" illustrates the
primacy that Keynesians give to spending as the determinant of
production. According to this concept, government can increase total
spending and, thereby, GNP by raising taxes and spending the revenues. The reasoning is as follows. People do not pay the higher
taxes only by reducing their spending (consumption); they also reduce their savings. Therefore, when taxes are raised, the decrease
in private spending is less than the increase in government spending. Conversely, a cut in tax rates, matched by a decrease in government spending, would result in a reduction in total spending ( i.e.,
saving would increase), a fall in GNP, and a rise in unemployment.
For years after the 1964 Presidential election, college students
were asked a standard question on economic exams: What would
happen if Barry Goldwater's prescription for a tax cut, matched by
a spending cut, were implemented? They missed the answer if they
did not reply that there would be a reduction in aggregate demand
and, therefore, a fall in GNP and employment. Alas, for too many
policy makers that is still the answer.
Since the "balanced-budget multiplier" implies that the greater
the increase in taxes and in government spending, the greater the
increase in GNP, it is a wonder no one ever asked what happens to
production as tax rates rise. This question confronts economic policy
with the incentive effects it has disregarded. It should be obvious
even to Keynesians that when marginal tax rates are high, people
will prefer additional leisure to additional current income, and additional current consumption to additional future income. As work
effort and investment decline, production will fall, regardless of how
great an increase there might be in aggregate demand. Such a recognition of disincentives implies a recognition of incentives, and
Keynesians are gradually having to rethink the answer to their
standard question about Barry Goldwater. Once one recognizes that
people produce and invest for income, and that income depends on

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

145
D

tax rates, one has reached the realization that fiscal policy causes
changes not ;ust in demand but also in mpply.
The economics of supply

The economics of spending has thoroughly neglected the economics of supply. On the supply side there are two important relative prices governing production. One price determines the choice
between additional current income and leisure; the other determines
the choice between additional future income (investment) and
current consumption. Both prices are affected by the marginal tax
rates. The higher the tax rates on earnings, the lower the cost of
leisure and current consumption, in terms of foregone after-tax
income.
As an illustration, consider the decision to produce. There are two
uses of time-work and leisure. Each use has a price relative to the
other. The price of additional leisure is the amount of income foregone by not working, and it is influenced by the tax rates. The higher
the tax rates, the smaller the amount of after-tax income foregone
by enjoying additional leisure. In other words, the higher the tax
rates, the lower the relative price of leisure. When the marginal tax
rate reaches 100 percent, the relative price of additional leisure becomes zero. At that point, additional leisure becomes a free good,
because nothing has to be sacrificed in order to acquire it.
We often hear that a person works the first five months of the year
for the government, and then starts working for himseH. But that is
not the way it goes. The first part of the year, he works for hixnseH;
he only begins working for the government when his income reaches
taxable levels. The more he earns, the more he works for the government, until rising marginal rates discourage him from further work.
Take the case of a physician who encounters the SO-percent rate
after six, eight, or 10 months of work. He is faced with working
another six, four, or two months for only 50 percent of his earnings.
Such a low after-tax return on their efforts encourages doctors to
share practices, to reduce their working hours, and to take longer
vacations. The high tax rates thus shrink the tax base by discouraging them from earning additional amounts of taxable income. They
also drive up the cost of medical care by reducing the supply of
medical services. A tax-rate reduction would raise the relative price
of leisure and result in more taxable income earned and also in a
greater supply of medical services.
The effect of tax rates on the decision to earn additional taxable

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

146

income is not limited to physicians or to the top tax bracket; it
operates across the spectrum of tax brackets. Studies by Martin
Feldstein show that the tax rates on the average worker practically
eliminate the gap between his after-tax take-home pay and the level
of untaxed unemployment compensation he could be receiving if be
did not work. In this case, a marginal tax rate of 30 percent ( including state and Federal income taxes and Social Security taxes) reduces the relative price of leisure so much that, by malcing unemployment competitive with work, it bas raised the measured rate of
unemployment by 1.25 percent and shrunk GNP and the tax base
by the lost production of one million workers.
It is useful to give another example to illustrate that it is not just
the top marginal rate that causes losses to GNP, employment, and
tax revenues by discouraging people from earning additional taxable income. Blue-collar workers do not yet encounter the top marginal tax rate ( although if inBation continues to push up money
incomes, and the tax-rate structure remains unadjusted for inflation,
it will not be many years before they do). Nevertheless, the marginal
tax rates that many blue-collar workers already face are high enough
to discourage them from earning additional taxable income. Take
the case of a carpenter facing only a 25-percent marginal tax rate.
For every additional $100 he earns before income tax, he gets to
keep $75. Suppose that his house needs painting and that be can
hire a painter for $80 a day and hire himseH out for $100 a day.
However, since his after-tax earnings are only $75, be saves S5 by
painting his own house, so it pays him to choose not to earn the
additional $100. In this case, the tax base shrinks by $ 1 ~ which
$100 is the foregone earnings of the carpenter, and $80 is the lost
earnings of the painter who is not hired. (Also, the productive efficiency associated with the division of labor vanishes.)
Suppose, instead, that the marginal tax rate on additional earnings
by the carpenter were reduced to 15 percent. In this case, bis aftertax earnings would be $85, and it would pay him to hire the painter.
The reduction in the marginal tax rate would thus expand the tax
base upon which revenues are collected by $180.
Studies by Gary Becker have made it clear that capital and labor
are employed by households to produce utility through non-market
activities ( e.g., a carpenter painting bis own house). Utility produced in this way is not purchased with income subject to taxation.
Therefore, the amount of household-owned capital and labor supplied in the market will be inBuenced by marginal tax rates. The
lower the after-tax income earned by supplying additional labor and

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

147
'l'IIIE PVSUC IN'IUUT

capital in the market, the less the utility that the additional income
can provide, and the more likely it is that households can increase
their utility by allocating their productive resources to non-market
activities. A clear implication of the new household economics is
that the amount of labor and capital supplied in the market is influenced by the marginal tax rates.
Now consider bow relative prices affect the choice concerning
the use of income. There are two uses of income, consumption and
saving (investment), and each bas a price in terms of the other.
The price of additional current consumption is the amount of future
income foregone by enjoying additional current consumption. The
higher the tax rates, the smaller the amount of after-tax future income foregone by enjoying additional current consumption. In other
words, the higher the tax rates, the lower the relative price of current consumption.
Take the case of an Englishman facing the 98-percent marginal
tax rate on investment income. He has the choice of saving $50,000
at a 17-percent rate of return, which would bring him $8,500 per
year before taxes, or purchasing a Rolls Royce. Since the after-tax
value of that $8,500 additional income is only $170 per year, the
price of additional consumption is very low: He can enjoy having
a fine motor car by giving up only $170 per year of additional income. This is why so many Rolls Royces are seen in England today.
They are mistaken for signs of prosperity, whereas in fact they are
signs of high tax rates on investment income.
A tax-rate reduction would raise the price of current consumption
relative to future income, and thus result in more savings, making
possible a growth in real investment. A rate reduction not only increases disposable income and total spending, it also changes the
composition of total spending toward more investment. Thus, labor
productivity, employment, and real GNP are raised above the levels
that would result from the same amount of total spending more
heavily weighted toward current consumption.

Tu cuts and rebates
The econometric models upon which the government relies for
simulations of policy alternatives do not take into account these supply-side effects on GNP of these relative price changes. Consider
the alternatives faced by the Keynesian policy maker who wants
"to get the economy moving again.• His goal is to increase aggregate
demand or total spending. How can he do this? He has the choice

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

148
THE BREilDOWN OP THE UYNUIAN MODEL

between the balanced-budget multiplier (i.e., increaruig both taxes
and government spending) or a deficit. He will discard the balancedbudget multiplier, because it is relatively weak and deficits are more
politically acceptable than legislating higher tax rates. Having settled on a deficit, he has to choose how to produce it. He can hold
tax revenues constant and increase government spending, or be can
hold government spending constant and cut tax revenues. In the
latter case, he has a choice between rebates and permanent reductions in tax rates. Wanting the most stimulus £or-his deficit dollar,
he will ask for econometric simulations of his three policy alternatives: a tax rebate, a tax rate reduction, or an increase in government
spending programs.
The simulations, all based on Keynesian assumptions, will show
that a revenue reduction of a given amount, whether in the form
of a rebate of personal income taxes or a reduction in personalincome-tax rates, will raise disposable income-and thereby spending
and GNP-by the same amount. The policy maker may prefer the
rebate for reasons of "flexibility." The spending stimulus may not
be required in the following year, and, if it is, he bas the option
of providing it either by another rebate or by an increase in government spending programs. But on the basis of the econometric simulation, he will be indiJierent as to the choice between rebates or rate
reductions. As for his third option, an increase in government spending programs, the simulation may report that, dollar for dollar, an
increase in government purchases (as contrasted with transfers) will
have a more powerful impact on GNP because the government
spends all of the money, whereas if it is returned to conswners they
will save part of it Based on the econometric simulation of his alternatives, he will conclude that there is no compelling economic
reason in favor of any of the three, and he will make his choice on
a political basis.
But the econometric models have misled the policy maker. Unlike
a reduction in personal-income-tax rates, a rebate affects no individual choice at the margin. It does not change the relative prices
governing the choices between additional current income and leisure
or between additional future income and current consumption. It
does not raise the relative prices of leisure and current consumption.
Therefore, a rebate directly stimulates neither work nor investment.
For any given revenue reduction, a rebate cannot cause as great an
increase in GNP as a rate reduction, because it does not affect the
choices that would cause people to allocate more time and more
income to increasing production for the market.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

149
THE PUSUC INTEREST

An increase in government spending fares no better by comparison,
and may fare even worse. It too fails to raise the after-tax rewards for
work and investment. Furthermore, it increases the percentage of
total resources used in the government sector. If the government
sector uses resources less efficiently than the private sector, as seems
to be the case, the result is a decline in the efficiency with which
resources are used-which means GNP would be less than it otherwise would be. Yet the econometric simulations of the policy maker's
alternatives will pick up none of the incentive and disincentive ef.
fects of these relative price changes. Instead, they focus on the
effects of these alternatives on disposable income and on spending.
There are a number of adverse consequences of this extraordinary
preoccupation with spending. One is that the models eraggerate the
net tax-revenue losses that result from cutting tax rates. The only
"feedback effect" on the tax base and tax revenues that they provide
for is the expansion of GNP in response to an increase in demand.
They do not provide for the expansion in GNP that results from
higher after-tax rewards for work and investment. The supply-side
"feedback effects" are ignored. Similarly, revenue gains from taxrate increases will be overestimated, because the disincentive effects
are left out.
A second consequence follows from the popular misidentification
of a tax rebate as a tax cut, and from a similar tendency on the part
of most policy makers to see rebates and rate cuts as variations of
the same policy instrument. If Milton Friedman is correct that personal consumption is a function of permanent income, a temporary
rebate has little impact even on spending. Thus, on the basis of experience with rebates, tax cuts per se might come to be seen as
relatively ineffectual, leaving the field open to proponents of government spending programs.
A third consequence is that the true effects of large tax increases
( such as the proposed energy taxes, or the $227-billion increase in
the Social Security tax over the next decade) will not be accurately
calculated. Policy makers see these tax increases as withdrawals
from disposable income and spending, and their only concern is •to
put money back" into spending so that aggregate demand does not
fall. However, these tax increases change the re'lative prices and incentives of leisure and work, consumption and investment They
produce resource reallocations that have adverse implications for
employment and the rate of economic growth. Yet the econometric
models, as now constructed, flash no warning lights.
Consider what Arthur Lafler, in the Wall Street Journal, has called

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

150
11IE auAJtDOWN OP THE UYNUJAN MODEL

the ..tax wedge." The Social Security tax increase provides a good
example of this phenomenon. It is a tax on employment, and, as
economists should know, a tax on employment will reduce employment. The employer's decision to hire is based on the gross cost to
him of an employee. The employee's decision to work is based on
his after-tax pay. We know that the higher the price, the less the
quantity demanded, and the lower the price, the less the quantity
supplied. The Social Security tax both raises the price to the demander and lowers it to the supplier. By increasing the Social Security tax. policy makers reduced both job opportunities and the
inclination to work. 1 They raised the cost of labor relative to capital
for the employer, and they narrowed the gap between unemployment compensation and after-tax take-home pay for a wider range
of workers. Since the revenues available for paying Social Security
benefits depend on both the tax rates and the number of people
paying into the system, the increase in rates will be offset to some
degree by a decrease in the number of people paying into the system. It is hard to see how the Social Security system can be saved
by decreasing employment, or how increasing the demand for unemployment compensation is likely to free general revenues for Social Security benefits.

"Crowding out" investment
There are at least two other important points on which economic
policy is misinformed by the neglect of incentives and of choices
made at the margin. One is the impact on GNP of reductions in the
corporate-income-tax rate, and the other is the controversy over
whether government fiscal policy •cro'Wds out• private investment.
Simulations run by the Congressional Budget Office and the House
Budget Committee on two of the three large-scale commercial econometric models show declines in GNP as a result of reductions in
corporate-tax rates. In one of the models, corporate investment did
not depend on after-tax profits in a very strong way, but was very
sensitive to changes in interest rates. Since interest rates rise as the
Treasury increases its borrowing to 6nance the deficit resulting from
Theoreticaily, the ellect on work effort depends on the present value of the
Social Security benefits and taxes. If the increased tax means increased future
benefits, the employee's work decision will take into account his increased future
income, as well as his reduced current income. However, the recent changes
in the Social Security law raised taxes and reduced benefits as a proportion of
pay before retirement. As the Wall Street Journal put It, "the extra money will
go to pay people now or soon to be on the retirement rolls, not to finance your
own high living in the 21st century• (February 6, 1978).

1


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

151

•
the tax cut, investment falls, and the model predicted a decline in
GNP as the result of a ta:c-rate reduction that increaaed the profitability of inoestment. 2
The other model predicted that a corporate-tax-rate reduction
would slightly raise real GNP after a lag of a couple of quarters, but
it predicted a lower nominal GNP for two years. Nominal GNP declined because the corporate-tax-rate reduction reduced the user
cost of capital, the price mark-up, and thereby the inllation rate,
thus lowering the nominal price level.
To the extent that Keynesians think about the "crowding out" of
private investment by fiscal policy, it is in terms of upward pressure
on interest rates as a result of government borrowing to finance
budget deficits. They do not realize that investment is crowded out
by ta:cation, regardless of whether the budget is in balance. To understand how, consider the following example. Suppose that a IOpercent rate of return must be earned if an investment is to be undertaken. In the event that government imposes a SO-percent tax
rate on investment income, investments earning 10 percent will no
longer be undertaken. Only investments earning 20 percent before
tax will return 10 percent after tax. Taxation crowds out investment
by reducing the number of profitable investments. When tax rates are
reduced, after-tax rates of return rise, and the number of profitable
investments increases.
So "crowding out" cannot be correctly analyzed merely in terms
of events in the financial markets: "Crowding out" occurs in terms
of real output. It is the preempting of production capacity by government outlays, regardless of whether these outlays are financed
by taxing, borrowing, or money creation.
Responding to incentives
A concern with the supply-side effects of fisca1 policy is incompatible with the concept of economic policy that currently reigns
in the Congress and in the Executive Branch. Members of the House
Budget Committee asked Alice Rivlin, Director of the Congressional
Budget Office, and Bert Lance, then Director of the Office of Management and Budget, about the neglect of the incentive effects of
tax-rate changes on supply and also about the econometric predic• According to staff in the Office of Management and Budget, there have recently been changes in the model, but one can still get the perverse result because
a reduction in the tax rate dire...-tly and su~tantially reduces multi-unit housing
ltarts.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

152
111E BREAkDOWN OP

nu

UVNUIAN MODEL

tions that GNP would fall in response to a reduction in corporate
tax rates.

Dr. Rivlin said that she and her staff had been *particularly
troubled" by model findings that GNP declines if corporate tax rates
are reduced. However, she went on to say:
Studies have generally found that tax-rate changes are less important
than changes in the cost of capital and changes in levels of national output in influencing the level of investment. It follows that an investment
tax credit or liberalized depreciation will increase investment more than
a corporate-tax-rate reduction of equivalent revenue loss. While we do
not believe that corporate-tax-rate cuts reduce investment, it would not
be surprising to find that tax cuts had only a minor expansionary effect.
The 0MB staff reply to this question was ambiguous.
Both CBO and 0MB realized that the question about incentive
effects most fundamentally challenged their concept of economic
policy. The comments of Rivlin, Lance, and the 0MB staff all unequivocally acknowledged that the econometric models upon which
they rely for guidance in the choice of economic policy alternatives
do not include any relative price effects of changes in personal-income-tax rates. However, since they believe that the performance
of the economy is a function of spending levels, not of production
incentives, they expressed no concern over this neglect. They said
that economic theory and empirical studies leave it unclear whether
the neglected supply-side effects are important; regardless of how
the issue is resolved, they questioned the practical importance of
supply incentives for short-run policy analysis.
There are two parts to this argument. One is that it is unclear
whether lowering personal-income-true rates will increase or.reduce
work effort. The other is that it is unclear whether any incentive
effects on work effort and investment would show up as quantitatively important in a short-run policy framework. The first proposition questions the existence of the incentive effects; the second questions whether they would be effective in time to deal with an immediate problem of economic stabilization.
It is easy to dispose of the latter point. The long-run consists of
a series of short-runs. If policies that are effective over a longer
period are neglected because they do not have an immediate impact,
and if policies that are damaging over the longer period are adopted
because they initially have beneficial results, then policy makers
will inevitably come to experience, sometime in the future, a period
when they will have no solution for the crisis they have provoked_
In the United States, that future might be now.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

153

•
As for the first point, Rivlin acknowledged that a personal-inoometax-rate reduction raises the relative price of leisure, and that work
effort will increase as people substitute income for leisure. This is
known in economics as the •substitution effect," and ··it works to increase supply. However, Rivlin also said:
It is also theoretically arguable that when a tax cut provides people
with more after-tax income, many of them will reduce effort through
what is called the income effect. For most people, leisure has some
positive value, and it may even be a "luxury" good; these people could
respond to a tax reduction by reducing their working hours, benefiting
from more leisure time and still maintaining their after-tax income.
For other people who like their work, there may be little or no labor
supply response to the income or the substitution effect. In much of
the United States economy, work weeks are fixed, leaving little possibility for individuals to make marginal adjustments in hours of work.

In other words, CBO believes that the "income effect" works to decrease supply.
Rivlin then went on to say that it was an empirical question
whether the "income effect" offset the "substitution effect." referred
to a narrow range of studies that left the question unresolved, and
concluded: "In the range of policy options that we have been dealing with, I think the assumption that changes in marginal tax rates
have no quantitatively significant effect on labor supply is quite
·
plausible."
But the concept of a targeted or desired level of income unaffected by the cost of acquiring such income is foreign to the pricetheoretical perspective of economic science. Rivlin's idea that people
respond to a cut in income-tax rates by maintaining their existing
income levels while enjoying more leisure implies that, if their tax
rates went up, they would work harder in order to maintain their
desired income level. Lester Thurow has actually employed this
reasoning to argue for a wealth tax. According to Thurow, a wealth
tax is a costless way to raise revenues because the "income effect"
runs counter to and dominates the "substitution effect." He assumes
that people have a targeted level of wealth, irrespective of the cost
of acquiring it. Therefore, he says, a tax on wealth will cause people
to work harder in order to maintain, after tax, their desired wealth
level.
Note the perverse ways in which people respond to incentives
and disincentives according to the Rivlin-Thurow line of argument:
When tax rates go down and the relative price of leisure rises, people demand more leisure; when tax rates go up and the relative price

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

154
'l'Blt auAKDOWN OF 1HE DYNUJAN MODEL

JI

of leisure falls, people demand less leisure. In economics, any time
the "income effect• works counter to the "substitution effect," we
have the relatively rare case of what is called an "inferior good"
( i.e., people purchase less of it as their income rises). Since income
is command over all goods, Rivlin's argument implies that all goods
are inferior goods: A tax cut will cause people to purchase only
more leisure, not more income ( i.e., goods). What kind of people
are these? Well, the only kind of people who fit this kind of economic analysis are people who respond to a monetary incentive in
perverse ways.
Perhaps Rivlin merely meant to say that lower tax rates would
allow people to have a little more income for a little less work. Even
so, as long as she maintains that the "income eflect" works counter
to the "substitution effect," her argument carries the implication
that goods in general are inferior.

A perverse logic
Whatever the weight one assigns this point, there is a more fundamental defect in her argument. Notice the stunning inconsistency:
People respond to a tax-rate reduction "'by reducing their working
hours ... and still maintaining their after-tax income." But it is impossible for people in the aggregate to reduce their work effort and
maintain the same level of aggregate real income! If people respond
to tax cuts by working less, real GNP would fall, and it would be
impossible to increase real disposable income, spending, and demand
in the aggregate. Rivlin's argument is directed against the effectiveness of incentives in raising aggregate output, but if she were
correct, it would mean that Keynesian fiscal policy also is ineffective!
The fatal error in the Rivlin-Thurow argument can be put this
way: It derives from trying to aggregate a series of partial equilibrium analyses (individual responses to a change in relative prices)
and, in the aggregate, ignoring the general equilibrium effects.
There are various ways a non-economist can grasp this point Assume that the government cuts taxes and maintains a balanced
budget by reducing spending. In this case, the higher income accorded the taxpayers whose rates are reduced must be matched by
a negative impact on the incomes of recipients of government spending. Some or all of these may be the same people. Assume, for
example, that both the tax burden and government spending are
evenly distributed. In this case the "income effect" ( the substitution
of leisure for work) "nets out" for each individual. Since the ag
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

155

•
gregate income eiect is zero, it cannot offset the "'substitution effect"
( the substitution of work for leisure).
If taxes are cut and government spending is unchanged (resulting
in a budget deficit), the nominal disposable income of taxpayers as
a group wi11 rise relative to the nominal disposable income of the
recipients of government spending as a group. The former will be
able to bid real resources away from the latter. The real income gains
of the former wi1l be matched by the real income losses of the latter. Since the bidding will raise prices, the real income loss might
be suffered by individuals who hold money. Regardless of who loses
and who gains, the individual income effects "'net out,• leaving only
the "substitution effects," which unambiguously increase work ef.
fort.
There can be no aggregate "income effect• unless the impact of
incentives is to raise real aggregate income. Economic theory makes
it perfectly clear that a tax-rate reduction wi1l increase work effort
and total output.
In the final analysis, Rivlin's argument is not that the supply-side
incentive effects are unimportant, but the equally false argument
that their impact is perverse-that is, only a tax-rate increase can
produce a rise in real national income! She may not actually believe
any such thing, of course-but that is where her reasoning leads her.
From economics to politics

An economist might see the Baw in the Rivlin-Thurow argument,
but it is not obvious to politicians. Take something simple, like
Rivlin's assertion that a fixed work-week precludes adjustment of the
labor supply to tax-rate changes. To an economist her assertion is
obviously false, but to the politician it sounds reasonable enough.
He will not realize that the "'adjustments" will be reflected in absenteeism rates, turnover rates, the average duration of unemployment,
labor negotiations for shorter work-weeks and more paid vacation
rather than higher wages, and in the quality and intensity of work.
Nor will he think of the entrepreneur who, because of high tax rates,
loses his incentive to innovate-to make the economy itself ( all of
us) more productive.
Besides, one has to have an idealistic view of government to believe that politicians even want to know. The Keynesian concept of
the economy is that of an unstable private sector that must be
stabilized by fiscal and monetary policies of the government. This
view has served as a ramp for the expansion of the interests of gov
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

156
THE aJtEAJa>OWN OF THE DYNUIAN MODEL

J3

ernment. It has also served the interests of economists by transforming them from ivory-tower denizens to public-spirited social activists,
a transformation which has much increased their power and enlivened their life styles. Unemployment can always be said to be
too high. And the rate of economic growth can always be found to
be below "potential." This means that there is always a "scientific"
economic reason for expanding government spending programs that
enlarge the constituencies of the Congress and of the Federal bureaucracy. From the standpoint of the private interests of policy
makers, Keynesian economic policy will always be judged a success.
To write about all of the problems of econometrics and economic
policy would require a book, not an article, but one other important
problem must be mentioned in closing. Professor Robert Lucas has
demonstrated that the standard econometric models assume that the
structure of the economy remains invariant under wide variations in
policy paths. What this means is that the models assume that people
do not learn. But people do learn, and their expectations change as
they experience various policies: They may not repeat the same behavior in response to the same policy at different times. Therefore,
the policy simulation may always misinform the policy makers. This
is not an optimistic note on which to end an article about public
policy in a country that believes we need a great deal of it. But our
faith in public policy has exceeded our knowledge, and we will find
out that, in this area, there is no such thing as free faith.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

THE 1978 MIDYEAR REVIEW OF THE ECONOMY
TUESDAY, JULY 11, 1978

INVESTMENT IN THE CURRENT RECOVERY

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE,
W (l8hington, D.O.
The committee met, pursuant to recess, at 10 :25 a.m., in room 6226,
Dirksen Senate Office Building, Hon. Lloyd Bentsen ( vice chairman
of the committee) presiding.
Present: Senators Bentsen and Hatch.
Also present: Louis C. Krautho:ff II, assistant director; Jack Albertine, Lloyd C. Atkinson, William R. Buechner, Thomas F. Dernburg, and M. Catherine Miller, professional staff members; Mark Borchelt, administrative assistant; and Robert H. Aten, Charles H. Bradford, .Stephen J. Entin, and Mark R. Policinski, minority professional
staff members.
OPENING STATEMENT OF SENATOR BENTSEN, VICE CHAIRMAN
Senator BENTSEN. Gentlemen, I apologize for the lateness of the
start of the hearings. I had a conflict in my schedule.
1'he sluggish recovery of business fixed investment during the current recovery is a serious cause for concern. It has been an nnport&nt
contributing :factor to our poor productivity performance, a,nd it ha,s
therefore ex&cerbated inflationa,ry preSffilres. It has slowed the rate of
growth of our potential output, it has reduced the international competitiveness of our industries, and it raises the specter of a possible recurrence of the shortages and bottlenecks of 1973.
The upswing in real business fixed investment from the trough of
the recent recession in 1975 has been ma,rkedly woo.ker than the a,veira,ge experience for other postwar recovery periods. The investment ratio reached a peak of 11 percent in 1966. Today, that ratio is an unsatisfactory 9.3 percent. If we net out those Government-mandated expenditures for su~h outlays as pollution abatement-which do not add
to productive capacity-the picture is worse still. There is, finally,
little indication that much improvement is to be expected in the near
term.
A year ago, the administration's targets :for 1981 called for a reduction of the unemployment irate to 4¾ percent, a reduction in the rate
of inflation to 4/0 percent, and a balanced Federal budget with Federal
expenditures equal to 21 percent of GNP. It was recognized that at-


35-570 0 - 79 - 11
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

( 157)

158
tainment of these targets re.quired extraordinary strength in the private sector, in particular a rate of growth of real business fixed investment of 10 percent for 5 successive years. However, fixed investment
has shown no sign of proceeding at such a rate, and the targets-with
the possible exception of the employment target-are therefore
unattaina;ble.
Why are rates of return on investment so much lower today than
they were in the midsixties? Is it true, as many economists have alleged, that the real culprit is inflation~ Or is it oppressive taxation?
Or are there basic trends in technoloe;y and resource supply that are
making for an economy that is less capital intensive 1
I am hopeful that the panel of experts here today will provide us
with some answers to these questions and a solution to our investment
dilemma. A number of other countries-most notably Germany and
Japan-have been successful in attaining much higher rates of capital
formation than we have in the United States. What accounts for these
difierences 1 And what can we in Government do to speed up the rate
of capital formation? Will a reduction of the capital gains tax do the
trick~ Is there any evidence to suggest that a tax cut of the sort J?rOposed by Senator Roth and Congressman Kemp will increase incentives
for savmg and investment1 What would be the impact of an enlarged
and expanded investment tax credit? What should be the role of monetary policy in supporting capital formation?
I am hopeful that this distinguished panel will provide us with the
guidance we so badly need.
Our witnesses today are: Mr. Michael K. Evans, president of Chase
Econometrics; Mr. Martin Feldstein, professor of economics at Harvard University and president of the National Bureau for Economic
Research; Mr. Gary Fromm, director, Stanford Research Institute ;
and Mr. Charles D. Kuehner, director of security analysis and investor
relations, American Telephone & Telegraph Co.
Gentlemen, welcome to this hearing of the Joint Economic Committee.. Let us proceed in alphabetical order. Mr. Evans, will you please
begm.
1

STATEMENT OF MICHAEL K. EVANS, PRESIDENT, CHASE ECONOMETRIC ASSOCIATES, INC., BALA CYN\VlD, PA.
Mr. EvANS. Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
I am very pleased to have the opportunity to discuss investment and
the c~rrent recovery and discuss my somewhat controversial views this
mornmg.
. T?-e pre~nt economic recovery has been distinguished for its longevity 1f not 1t~ robustness. The current upturn is now longer than any
other peacetime postwar expansion, and is within hailing distance of
the alltime record.
Yet, it is extremely curious that fixed business investment spending
has had virtually nothing to do with this sustained upturn.
In some of the figures I have in my prepared statement, we can see
tha~ plant and. equipment spending is still below 1973 peak levels,
w:h1le consumption h~s actually outstripped the average gain in previous postwar expansions.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

159
So the present boom we are now in has consisted a]most entirely of
consumer behavior improving with ri.9 assist at all from investment
spending.
If we look at figure 2, it shows much the same picture.
Figure 2 shows the ratio of fixed business investment to GNP and
by any measure this ratio has dropped off sharply in the past 4 years
from the peaks it had reached in the mid-1960's and early 1970's.
If we adjust investment for the fact that much of investment in
capital stock that has been in nonproductive areas, that is, in Government mandated measures with respect to pollution and other measures, we see that this investment has dropped to an alltime postwar
low.
Clearly, something is wrong. Investment has not recovered, even
though the rest of the economy is not doing badly. Unemployment has
dropped below 6 percent, and we are beginning to see various bottlenecks emerge.
Why has investment done so poorly j One answer, it seems to me, is
with respect to investment and tax rates. We have had three investment
booms in the postwar period, one 1955 to 1956 ; one, 1964 to 1966; and
one, 1972 to 1973.
Each of these investment booms was preceded in a previous year by
a change in the tax code favorable to investment.
In 1954, we ended the excess profits tax, and we also had a liberalization of depreciation allowances.
In 1962, we had an increase, or the beginning of the investment tax
credit of 7 percent, and a liberalization of the depreciation tax levies
of 20 percent.
Finally, in 1964, we had a corporate rate cut of 10 percent, which resulted in an increase in investments of 20 percent the next year, the
only time that has ever happened.
Finally, in 1971, we had the reinstatement of the investment tax
credit and a further 20-percent reduction in taxes.
So, we have a 1-to-1 correspondence with changes in the tax code
favorable to investment and investment booms in the next year.
For the last 4 years, the tax code has turned unfavorable to investment. We have had the end of the loopholes, and the net effect is. to
raise the overall tax rate.
The next figure, figure 4, shows a very close correlation between the
investment ratio and the ratio of stock prices to construction costs.
This ratio lags 1 year, to indicate the time necessary for a change in
market forces to result in new plant and equipment spending.
According to this theory, when the cost of equity capital is relatively
low, the stock market is relatively high, and firms will expand by building new facilities. On the other hand, when the cost of equity capital is
high and the stock market is very low, firms will expand by buying out
existing businesses rather than building new ones.
I might say that the argument which is shown graphically in figure
4 is a bipartisan argument. The figures behind this have appeared both
in the 1977 Economic Report of the President by Mr. Alan Greenspan
and in the 1978 report by Mr. Charles Schultze.
So the ratio of investment to the stock market would appear to be
well established and in fact documented by both administrations.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

160
In view of these factors that the major factors determining investment would appear to be the effective rate on corporate income and
the value of the stock market relative to construction costs, it seems
to me that if we want to stimulate investments, as I think almost
everyone would agree we can do, we need to undertake changes in the
tax code that could accomplish these objectives; namely, reduction
in corporate tax rates and increases in the value of the stock market,
and thereby a d<ecrease in the cost of equity capital.
There are many ways in which this could be done. The best way that
I know of would be reduction in the maximum rate of taxes on capital
gains, and it is this suggestion which I believe the chairman has
referred to as being somewhat controversial.
Particularly, the finding which we have come up with; namely, that
a rise in stock market prices would be very substantial and in particular
a reduction in the maximum rate of capital against taxes from 49.1 to
45 percent would, indeed, raise the stock market by 40 percent over the
next 2 years.
This 40-percent figure has been claimed as being much too high,
and, yet we need to know that something is amiss with the stock
market. During the last 8 years, the gross national product has increased at an average ra.te of 9 percent per year and corporate rate
profits have increased at an average rate of 11 percent a year.
Yet, the stock market has shown, actually, no increase at all. The
Standard & Poor's index of 500 stocks, for example, is no higher than
it was in 1969, the last year in which capital gains taxes at the maximum rate of 25 percent existed.
This is an amazing performance of the stock market considering the
rather robust growth of the economy, and we find that of this stagnation stock market, approximately half of it is due to the fact that
inflation has increased and, therefore, corporate profits are overstated
and approximately half is due to the increase in the capital gains taxes
to 49 percent.
This works out to 4.3 percent a year retardation in the stock market
which has occurred because of higher capital gains taxes.
In particular, we note that the stock market declined sharply in
1970 when higher capital gains taxes were first raised, and probably
more importantly, a fact which has been ignored by some, the stock
market declined very sharply in 1977, even though corporate profits
were up 11 percent, real GNP grew 5 percent and the general employment situation was favorable.
In fact, there seems to be no other economic factor that turned sour
in 1977, except for the further increase in the maximum tax rate for
capital gains.
The reduction in capital gains rates, then, would, I think, result in a
40-percent increase in stock market prices over 2 years and represents
a natural reversal of the trends which have been ailing the stock market
over the past 8 years.
Now, in making this argument, I am a ware of the fact that in the
postwar period, capital gains taxes have not declined. They have only
risen. So, some critics of this approach have argued that the argument
may not be symme.trical.
They say what I have done is to imply what would happen for a
dec~ine in capital gains taxes when the only evidence that we have is
an mcrease.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

t.61
In doing further research, I went back and discovered the fact that
a wide variety of taxes, including capital gains taxes, were actually
reduced in the early 1920's.
Before the First World War, we had no income tax, and an income
tax was put on during the First World War and, in fact, reached
a maximum rate of 73 percent at one point.
After the war, the tax rates were dropped and that rate was reduced
to 55 percent and, finally, to 25 percent in 1926.
Now, we have some figures about what happened in the 1920's, and
let us take the class of very wealthy people, the class that Secretary
Blumenthal says are getting a fair advantage if we were to lower
capital gains taxes.
A millionaire would translate into someone with an income of $300,000, then. The translation is not exact. But let's look at the amount of
taxes paid by individuals with an income of $300,000 or more in 1922
when the tax rate was 55 percent and in 1972, when the tax rate was 25
percent.
We are :not talking a,bout all taxpayers, but about millionaires, these
people who are going to get all the tax benefits from lower capital
gains.
In 1922, this group of people paid total taxes to the Federal Government of $77 million. Five years later, with a lower tax rate, they paid
$230 million. They paid three times as many taxes at a lower tax
rate.
Senator BENTSEN. What were these yearsi
Mr. EvANS. 1922, when they paid $77 million, and 1927, 5 years later,
when they paid $230 million. The tax rate in 1922 was 55 percent maximum, and in 1927, it dropped to 25 percent maximum.
So, I realize this happened a long time ago, but it is direct, irrefutable evidence that lowering tax rates can result in higher payments
to the Treasury even among the upper income groups, who are presumably ripping off the rest of society if we reduce capital gains tax.
I think all of tJhe evidence needs to be considered, and in this case,
we have discovered a rare tax bill, where cutting the rates actually
result in higher revenues to the Treasury.
In fact, we have estimated that a reduction in the maximum capital
gains rate from 49 percent to 25 percent would result in a decrease in
the Federal deficit of $16 billion over a 5-year period.
'.f\here are a number of other ways which could be nsed to cut corporate taxes, and increase investment, and I think that many of these
other ways also need to be considered favorably.
I refer to the cut in corporate income tax rates, the revaluation of
depreciation of replacement instead of historical costs, the integration
of personal and corporate income tax schedules, and the expansion of
the investment tax credit.
While I think that all of these would have some beneficial effects
upon society and on capital formation, I think that we have to rank
them in order to decide which bill should be passed first, and in my
own personal ranking, I would put the capital gains first, the cut in
corporate taxes second, the revaluation in capital investment third,
and the investment tax credit would be fifth out of five.
I have listed these in that order, considering, first of all, the efficacy
of the tax cuts, how much bang for the buck, how much increase in
GNP do you get per dollar of lost revenue.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

162
In the case of capital gains, you don't lose any revenue.
. .
In the other four, you lo~,e s,>me revenue, bm, not as much as the onginal tax cut.
The second is the question of mobility of capital. The less restrictions there are on capital mobility, the greater the opportunity for
capital to flow into its most efficient use, and by using the capital gains
tax and moving money from municipal bonds back into the equity
market, I think this helps increase efficiency more than any of the
others.
Finally, the investment tax credit, which, as I say, is last on my list,
although still useful, as it is currently structured tends to favor equipment over structures and tends to create tax shelters where none
existed before, and, therefore, creates less dollars for tax expenditure
than the other four.
In summary, it is clear something needs to be done to increase investment since the investment outlook and the investment performance of
this recovery has been by far the worst in the postwar period.
In view of the past historical evidence, I would suggest that this
problem is man made. If we were to turn over the investment slump
and examine it, we would find stamped on the bottom, "Made in
Washin~on."
This 1s not a problem of the free market, but of the onerous tax
legislation which has crept up over the last 5 years, and this needs to
be reversed.
If we do so with capital gains and income tax reduction, it is my
opinion that we could have an investment boom that would last intv
ihe early 1980's.
Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Evans follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF MICHAEL

K.

EVANS

InveatmeJl,t in the Current Recooery
The present economic recovery has been distinguished for its longevity if not
its robustness. The current upturn is now longer than any other peacetime postwar expansion, and is within hailing distance of the all-time record. Yet it is
extremely curious that fixed business investment spending has had vi-rtually
nothing to do with this sustained upturn. Indeed, as shown in Figure 1, plant
and equipment spending is still below 1973 peak levels, while consumption has
actually outstripped the average gain in previous postwar expansions. Figure 2
indicates that the ratio of fixed business investment to GNP in constant prices
has declined from a peak level of approximately 11 percent in the mid-1960's
and early 1970's to about 9½ percent today, and the decline is even more dramatic
if we exclude that portion of capital spending which has been diverted to nonproductive uses mandated by the Federal Government.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

163
FIGURE 1

-------------.

12S~-----

CONSiµHPTION IN CONST ANT DOLLARS

THIS RECOVERY
SOLID
S ~ I FREOICTE]) - THIS RECOVERY
PREVIOUS FOUR RECOVERIES
DASH

120

1 116

8
~

i.J

G.

I I0

104

9

2

I

3

'4

S

e

7

8

9 10 11 12 13 I ◄ IS Ie 17 18 19 20

LAST PEAi< PRIOR TO TROUGH

12e.....-----PL_A_N_T_A_N_D_E_Q_U_I_P_HE'.C'.'"N~T~SP-=E'.""':'ND:::-:I:::N-:::G:------,

IN CONSTANT DOLLARS
116

THIS RECOVERY
SOLID
SOLID 0 PREDICTED - THIS RECOVERY
PREVIOUS FOUR RECOVERIES
DASH

0

I

2


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3

'4

S

e

7

8

9 10 II 12 13

I◄

LAST PEAi< PRIOR TO TROUGH

IS

,e

17 18 ,a 29

164

RATIO OF FIXED BUSINESS INVESTMENT TO GNP
IP!
CURRENT DOLLARS
IP2
CONSTANT DOLLARS
IP3
PRODUCTIVE INVESTMENT, CONSTANT DOLLARS
10.90

10.40
I

' I
.•. I

•

9.90

: I
: I
: I
: I
• I
: I

0
H

I-

~
9.40

.

.

8.90

,/

✓, \

✓\

_,

'' '
,,

'

/
/

8. ◄ 0 _.__ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __

55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77
DATE ANNUAL•
1/55 - 1/77

FIGURE

2

This problem is pa·rticularly critical because investment has failed to improve
significantly even though total sales have risen rapidly, capacity utilization has
now increased to the point where previous investment booms have started, and
both internal and external funds have been plentiful in the current recovery. Yet
even the eternal optimists have just about given up hope for 1:he resurgence of
capital spending in the next year or two, and the most depend-able surveys show
an increase in fixed business investment of only 4 percent to 6 percent this year
in real terms, with the estimate for next year at even lower levels.
We at Chase Econometrics have studied the determinants of investment for
many years, and have concluded that one of the major determinants of capital
spending is the effective rate of taxation on corporate income. The relationship
between these variables is shown in Figure 3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

165
30...------------------------------,--7.5

X CHANGE IN FIXED BUSINESS INVESTMENT
& CHANGE IN LEVEL OF EFFECTIVE TAX RATE

SOLID LEFT INVESTMENT, CONSTANT DOLLAR
DASH RIGHT PREVIOUS YEAR a-tAN6E IN EFF TAX RATE

20

5.0

110

2.5

Ill
(!)

z
u

Ill

!z
Ill

<

Ill

u

(!)

°'ll.

E
u
l!ill.

.0

0

-10

- 2e-1-...--..........--,----..--9..,s-0""'s.,.....,1,...s2..,,...s3-,,-s◄..,.,.,,.s5==ss~s=-1!C'.s-:-arc-:-=-:-=-==-c:::-:-=,r,:=-=+5 · 0
YEARLY
FIGURE

3

TCl summarize the information given in that graph, the U.S. economy has
undergone three investment booms in the postwar period: 1955-1956, 1964--1966,
and 1972-1973. Each of these booms has a common characteristic : it was preceded in the previous year by a major change in the tax code which was favorable to investment. Hence 1954 marked the end of the excess profits tax from the
Korean War and the first liberalization of depreciation allowances. The investment tax credit was introduced at a 7 percent rate in late 1962 and was accompanied by a 20 percent .reduction in accounting tax lives; when this was followed
by a reduction in the corporate income taxe rate from 52 percent to 48 percent in
1964, capital spending climbed 20 percent in constant prices in 1965, the only time
in the postwar period that has occurred. Finally, in 1972 the investment tax
credit was reinstated at 7 percent and accounting tax lives were reduced by an
additional 20 percent.
We also note that the sharp increase in tax rates in 1969, caused by the imposition of the 10 percent income tax surtax and the suspension of the investment
tax credit, was sufficient to canse a decline in investment in 1970 even though the
economy was still operating at high utilization rates.
However, the correlation between changes in investment and changes in the
effective corporate income tax rate is not perfect. In particular, the sharp declines
in investment in 1958 and 1975 appear to be unrelated to changes in the tax code,
and were indeed caused by the severe recessions which occurred in those years.
This anomaly disappears when we correlate the investment ratio and the ratio
of stock prices to construction costs, lagged one year. As shown in Figure 4, this
ratio captures both the cyclical and secular movements in the investment ratio.
This fact has received bipartisan support, as it was prominently'discussed in
both the 1977 and 1978 issues of the Economic Report of the President.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

166
1.,

12.

11.

1.3

11.

...I

18.

~

...I

!!

18.

.9

J!'IGURE

4

The theory behind this ratio is fairly straightforward. When stock prices are
high relative to construction costs and equity capital is relatively inexpensive,
businesses will expand by building new plants and filling them with new equipment. However, when stock prices are relatively depressed, businesses will
expand by buying smaller existing businesses, rather than by investing more in
new capital assets. The course of the stock market is thus of extreme importance
in determining the growth in investment. Since stock prices are very sensitive
to the rate of taxation on capital gains, this is one factor behind the widespread
popularity of the recent proposal to reduce capital gains taxes.
What many would-be experts on investment theory fail to understand is that
it is not the level of cash flow or output which is the primary determinant of
investment, but rather the expected future rate of return and the incentives to
entrepreneurship which are affected by the various tax rates on corporate income
and on capital. This area of investment theory has received much less attention
than the traditional links between investment, output, and capacity utilization,
and deserves to be studied in further detail.
The spur to fixed business investment spending through corporate tax rate
reduction con be accomplished by one or a combination of five different methods,
which are as follows :
(1) A reduction in capital gains taxes.
(2) A reduction in the corporate income tax rate.
(3) Revaluation of depreciation allowances in replacement instead of historical terms.
( 4-) Ending the double taxation on corporate income.
(5) Expansion of the investment tax credit.
These are listed in decreasing order of recommendation.
The reduction in capital gains taxes is most highly recommended for three
principal reasons. First, it will have the greatest effect on increasing the efficiency of capital by unlocking capital gains 1µ1.d drawing money out of municipal
bonds and other forms of tax-sheltered income. Second, it will stimulate the
rebirth of risk capital, which has almost completely disappeared in the past
decade and will be left virtually untouched by the other four types of corporarate tax reduction. Third, it is the only one of the five alternatives listed above
that will result in a decrease in the Federal budget deficit during the next five
years. Because of the timeliness of this issue, and also the present controversy

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

167
surrounding some of the alleged efl:ects of this reduction, I will confine the
remainder of my remarks to the benefits of cavital irain~ ta:x, _red-qction.
The legislation which has been proposed to return the maximum rate on capital
gains to its earlier level of 25 percent on JIIIluary l, 1980 for both individuals
and corporations would be quite beneficial· to the overall economy. The rate of
growth in constant-dollar GNP for the period 1980-1985 would average 3.6 percent, compared to a 3.4 percent annual average growth rate otherwise. An additional 440,000 new- jobs would be created by 1985. Expenditures for plant and
equipment would rise 5,7 percenfper year in constant prices, 'compared to 4.7 percent otherwise. In addition, the Federal budget deficit would be $16 billion less by
1985 than would be the case without this reduction in capital gains taxes.
The reduction in capital gains taxes stimulates economic activity through the
following combination of events :
(1) A reduction in capital gains taxes raise!! stock prices.
(2) Higher stock prices lead to a faster rate of growth in capital spending.
(3) Higher stock prices lead to more equity financing, which reduces the debt/
equity ratios of corporations. As a result, interest rates are lower than would
otherwise be the case.
( 4) More investment creates higher levels of output, employment, and income,
and reduces inflationary pressures by increasing productivity and raising maximum potential GNP.
(5) The increase in economic activity raises Federal government revenues,
hence reducing the budget deficit. This in turn leads to lower interest rates and
lower rates of inflation.
Economists generally agree that an increase in capital gains taxes will depress
the stock market, while a reduction will raise stock prices. However, the link
between these two variablies has not often been measured. Some studies which
purport to show a link between capital gains taxes and economic activity merely
assert that such a relationship does exist without providing empirical justification. However, as shown in Figure 5, the relationship is extremely important.
The sharp declines in the stock market in 1970 and 1977 are due in large part
to the Tax Reform Acts of 1969 and 1976.
220...----------------------------,

S

&

P INDEX OF 500 COMMON STOCKS

SOLID
DASH
SOLID 0
DASH 0
&
I

170

HISTORICAL DATA
HISTORICAL DATA ASSUMING
LOWER CAPITAL GAINS TAX
BASELINE FORECAST
FORECAST ASSUMING LOWER

/

/

~

CAPITAL GAJ:NS TAX

(')
~

I

~

~

I

~

a

~ 120

70 64 65 66 67 68 88 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 78 80 81 82 83

8◄

85

FIGURE 5
The latest version of the CEAI model contains an equation relating stock prices
to capital gains and five other variables: corporate profits, disposable income,


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1.68
the ratio of dividends to profits, the prime interest rate, and the overstatement
of profits due to inflation (CCA adjustment). The capital gains tax rate figures
prominently in this equation, and the coefficient of this term indicates that a
10 percent change in the capital gains tax rate will result in a 17 percent change
in stock prices. This result is empirically determined from multiple regression
analysis and is not simply an assumption generated in order to emphasize the
beneficial aspects of capital gains tax reduction.
Some economists have indicated that the 40 percent increase in stock prices
over the next two years which we claim results from a 25 percent reduction in
the maximum capital gains tax rate far overstates what would actually happen.
Since this appears to be a fAirly common misconception, we explore the matter
in greater detail.
To put the reduction in average stock market prices in perspective, the average
price/earnings ratio for the 1964-1968 period-after the reduction in the maximum personal income tax rate but before the increase in the capital gains rate-was 17.4; in 1977 it was only slightly above 9. This discrepancy cannot be
explained without recourse to the change in capital gains taxes.
In 1969, the last year that capital gains were taxed at a maximum rate of
25 percent, the Standard & Poor's 500-stock price index averaged 97.8 (19411943=10). In 1977, it averaged 98.2, for a decidedly inferior growth rate of
0.0 percent. During the same period, GNP and aftertax corporate profits advanced at average annual rates of 9 percent and 11 percent respectively. Interest
rates were not a factor, since the prime rate averaged 8.0 percent in 1969 compared to 6.8 percent in 1977. Two factors appear to have caused this stagnation
on the stock market. First the sharp increase in inflation led to an undel"Statement in depreciation allowances · and hence an overstatement of book profits.
Second, the maximum rate on capital gains is now 49.1 percent instead of
25 percent.
The econometric analysis which we have performed indicates that if capital
gains taxes had remained at pre-1970 rates the stock market will be some 40 percent higher. Over an 8-year period that means that stockprices would have risen
only 4.3 percent per year, compared to the no-growth situation which actually
existed. Even this figure would be way below the average increase in either
GNP or profits. Seen in this light, the 40 percent figure does not seem so remarkable after all.
The total change in stock prices caused by a change in capital gains taxes
does not occur instantaneously because of the Ioele-in effect. Higher capital gains
taxes reduce the number of individuals willing to sell their stock at any given
time; since these capital gains remain unrealized, less new funds are available
for purchases of other stock and hence prices gradually decline. We have found
that this effect usually takes about 2 years to become fully operative. Similarly,
a reduction in capital gains taxes will not cause all individuals to sell their
assets immediately. However, many investors will sell sooner; as this happens
more funds will be committed to purchases of equities. This will raise stock
prices and cause an increasing number of investors to realize their capital gains,
thus providing even more funds for equlity financing. Hence we would expect
the full effect of a reduction in capital gains taxes on stock prices to occur in
1981 and 1982.
Some economists have claimed that to make capital gains rate cuts revenue
neutral, sellers would have to liquidate large parts of their portfoliios and these
liquidations would act as a dampener on asset price increases. The trouble with
this analysis is that it overlooks one blade of the scissors. It concentrates solely
on supply without realizing the massive increase in demand that would result
from a lowering of capital gains taxes. Since investors would unlock their capital
gains and use these funds to purchase additional equities, market performance
would improve. In addition, billions of dollars would flow from sources such as
tax-free municipal bonds into the stock market, hence raising the demand still
farther.
We now turn to the critical issue of the effect of a reduction in capital gains
taxes on the Federal budget deficit. Economicts, businessmen and politicians
are in general agreement that reducing tax rates has some positive effect on
economic growth and employment. 'l'he major drawback to tax cuts.is that they
increase the size of the Jj'ederal budget deficit, which is thought to lead to higher
interest rates and a faster rate of inflation.
. __ ·
Some economists have argued that the Jj'ederal budget deficit can actually
be decreased through a reduction in personal or corporate income tax rates.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

169
The·logic supporting this hypothesis suggests that the economic effects stemming
from these tax cuts will be so large that the increase in revenue will offset the
initial decline. However, this claim is unsupported by empirical evidence. In
1977, Federal government revenues accounted _for exactly 20 percent of total
GNP. Thus in order for an income tax cut tci leave the deficit unchanged, the
implicit spending multiplier would have to be about five, far greater than the
investment multiplier of about two. While we have often argued for a reduction
in personal and corporate income tax rates because of their ])0£ntive effects on
productivity and incentives and their beneficial long-term effects in widening
the private sector tax base, we have never claimed that such a move would
actually decrease the size of the Federal budget deficit.
The capital gains tax, however, is unique in its leveraged effect on the economy. The major reason for this, and the factor which distinguishes the capital
gains tax from all other levies, is that the taxpayer can in large part determine
whether or not he wishes to pay the tax. For most individuals who are unhappy
with their high marginal tax bracket, the only (legal) option is to earn less
income. Tax avoidance and tax shelters provide some limited relief, but the
options are sharply constrained. However, the owner of a capital asset can
delay his tax indefinitely by the simple expedient of not selling the asset. Such
a decision is economically inefficient, for it restrains capital from flowing to its
most productive use and hence retards growth in productivity and output.
However, this option is available to taxpayers with capital assets, and most of
them use it.
As a result, the revenue raised from capital gains taxes is minuscule relative
to the levels of Federal personal and rorporate income taxes. Figures for capital
gains taxes are not readily available, bnt Joseph A. Pechman has prepared estimates through 1973 for both personal and corporate taxpayers, which are given
in Table 1.
TABLE 1.-ESTIMATES OF CAPITAL GAINS TAXES
(Dollar amounts in billions)
Total cap_ital
Pechman estimates
Year

Individual 1

Corporation

(1)

(2)

1960_________________________________
$1. 9
$0. 6
1961_________________________________
2. 9
•8
1962_________________________________
2.1
•7
1963_________________________________
2. 3
•7
1964_________________________________
2. 7
•7
1965_________________________________
3. 4
•8
196L_______________________________
3. 4
•9
1967_________________________________
5. 0
I. 0
1968_________________________________
7. 2
I. 3
1969_________________________________
4. 8
I. 4
1970_________________________________
2. 3
I. I
1971_________________________________
3. 8
I. 3
1972_________________________________
5. 3
I. 8
1973_________________________________
5.
0
2.
0
1974 ____________________________________________________________ _
1975 ____________________________________________________________ _

Total

indi~i~~!I
income tax
returns

Percent
change, st.ock
prices

(3)

(4)

(5)

$2. 5
3. 7

$5.1
7.6
5.8
6.4
7.9
10.0
9.7
13.5
17. 7
14.3

-2.7
18. 7
-5.9
12. 0
16. 5
8.4
-3.3
7. 8
7.4
-.9
-14.1
18.1
11. I
-1.6
-22.9
4.0

2.8

3.0
3.4
4.2
4.3
6.0
8.5
6. 2
3.4
5.1
7.1
7.0
2 5.6
• 5. 5

8. 7

13.1
16. 7
16.1
13. 5
13. 7

• Including fiduciaries.
• Preliminary.
Sources: Cols. (1)-{3), Joseph A. Pechman: Federal Tax Policy, 3d ed., table C--13, p. 352; col. (4), Statistical Abstract.

Two facts are immediately apparent from these figures. First, the amount of
tax collected is relatively small, generally less than 5 percent of Federal income
tax.· Second, and of particular interest for this study, the amount of capital
gains tax pa.id in 1970, when rates were increased to a maximum of 35 percent.
was less than in 1968 and 1969, the last years of 25 percent maximum rates.
Furthermore, tax collections have remained below 1968 peaks through 1975 and
are unlikely to be higher for 1976 and 1977 in view of the dismal performance
of the stock market.
The counterargument to be made is that capital gains taxes have declined since
1968 because of the relatively poor performance of the market since that date.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

170
This argument .is not well taken, however, for two reasons. First, the stagnation
of the market itself is due to the higher capital gains taxes, as we have already
shown. Second, the amount of capital gains taxes is relatively insensitive to the
yearly :fluctuations in the market, as can also be seen from the figures presented
m Table 1. The capital gains taxes in 1971 and 1972, whlich were relatively good
years for the market, were only about $1 billion greater than in 1974, which
was a disastrous year.
During the postwar period, the two major changes in capital gains taxes have
both been in the upward directJion. Thus some critics of the Steiger-Hansen legislation have argued that we have no concrete evidence of what might occur if
they were lowered. However, capital gains taxes-- and income taxes in generalwere lowered substantially during the 1920's. Before the U.S. entered World
War I, the maximum tax rate on personal income was 15 percent, but this rate
rose dramatically to a peak of 73 percent. It was cut to 55 percent in 1922 and
25 percent in 1926.
It is extremely instructive to learn what happened to taxes paid by millionaires-that group which has been singled out by Messrs. Carter and Blumenthal
as unworthy of further tax relief. To adjust for the differentials caused by inflation, we consider those taxpayers with incomes of over $300,000 in 1922 and in
1927, although even this adjustment is an understatement of tJhe true effects of
rising prices. In 1922, thds group paid taxes of $77 million, while in 1927, the
year after the reduction in rates, they paid a total of $230 million. Not only d:id
the economy benefit signi:llcantly, but the millionaires themselves--those undeserving rich who would presumably unfairly benefit by capital gains tax reduction-paid three times as much in taxes with lower rates.'
In conclusion, the sorry performance of capital spending during the past four
years is not primarily a product of natural economic forces. In fact, if we were to
examine this slump more closely, we would see "Made in Washington" stamped
in block letters. For the shift of the tax code in favor of consumption and against
investment started as early as 1968, but has intensified during the past five years.
If we are to increase the investment ratio by the 2 percent necessary to return
productivity growth to earlier postwar levels and resume our upward course in
the standard of living, it will be necessary to cut corporate income tax rates
more than personal income tax rates during the next few years. While a variety
of methods is available which will accomplish this, the one which gives the most
"bang for the buck"-both in terms of increase in GNP and increase in capital
spending-is the reduction in the rate of taxation on capital gains.

Senator BENTSEN. Thank you, Mr. Evans.
Your testimony raises a number of questions, but I am going to
defer those until all of the witnesses have had an opportunity to testify.
Mr. Feldstein, would you proceed.

STATEMENT OF MARTIN FELDSTEIN, PRESIDENT, NATIONAL
BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH, AND PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS, HARVABJ) UNIVERSITY
Mr. FELDSTEIN. Thank you, Senator.
In the invitation that the staff addressed to me, they asked me to
talk specifically about the impact of inflation on capital formation.
I also have some views and have done some work on the question
Michael Evans has just talked about-the impact of reductions in the
capital gains tax-which I would be happy to talk about during the
questioning period, but I want to focus my remarks on the effect of
inflation as such.
·
I think inflation has had a verv substantial adverse effect on capital
formation in the United States-because of the way our tax system
operates in inflationary times.
1

These figures are taken from "The Mellons." by David E. Koskolr, p. 238.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

171
During the past decade, effective tax rates have increased dramatically on capital gains, on interest income, and on direct returns to
investment in plant and equipment. Investors in stocks and bonds now
pay tax rates of early 100 perce11t, and in many cases more than 100
percent, on their real returns.
This change has taken place without debate and without legislative
action. It has occurred almost by accident because our tax system was
designed for an economy with little or no inflation. But if current
rates of inflation persist, the existing tax laws will continue to impose
effective tax rates of more than 100 percent on investment incomes. To
make matters even worse, the current tax laws imply that future tax
rates will depend haphazardly on future rates of inflation and therefore cannot be predicted at the time that investment decisions are being
made.
These extremely high tax rates and the uncertainty about future tax
rates are a cloud that hangs over both the stock market and business
investment decisions.
This morning I will describe the results of several recent studies at
the National Bureau of Economic Research that quantify the effect of
inflation on the taxation of investment income and therefore on the
incentive to investment. I am submitting two of these studies for the
record of these hearings.
~ will first discuss the impact of inflation and the taxation of capital
gams.
Inflation distorts all aspects of the taxation of personal income but
is particularly harsh on the taxation of capital gains. As you know,
when corporate stock or any other asset is sold, current law requires
that a capital gains tax be paid on the entire difference between the
selling price and the original cost even though much of the nominal
gain only offsets a general rise in the prices of consumer goods and
services. Taxing nominal gains in this way very substantially increases
the effective tax rate on rea\ price-adjusted gains. Indeed, many individuals pay a substantial capital gains tax even though, when adjustment is made for the change in the price level, they actually receive
less from their sale than they had originally paid.
In a recent study at the National Bureau of Economic Research, we
measured the total excess taxation of corporate stock capital ~ins
caused by inflation and the extent to which this distortion differs
capriciously among individuals. For this study we used the Treasury
Department's sample of individual tax returns for 1973. Our sample
consisted of over 30,000 individuals and more than 230,000 stock sales
in 1973. Although the individuals are not identified, the sampling rates
are known; the sample can therefore be used to construct accurate
estimates of totals for all taxpayers.
What did we find? We found that in 1973 individuals paid capital
gains tax on $4.6 billion of nominal capital gains on corporate stock.
"When the costs of these shares are adjusted for the increase in the
consumer price level since they were purchased, this gain becomes a
loss of nearly $1 billion.
Senator BENTSEN. I will interrupt there and ask you what period of
time did you use?
Mr. FELDSTEIN. We looked at all the sales actually made in 1973 by
individuals.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

172
Senator BENTSEN. You actually went back and traced that~
Mr. FELDSTEIN. We had that from the tax returns. We had the actual
data from the tax returns, the same way that the TreasurySenator BENTSEN. You had the date of purchase and the date of sale
and the inflation rate during each period 1
Mr. FELDSTEIN. Exactly, sir; and, if you do that, you find that, although people pay taxes on $4.6 billion of gain, they actually had lost
in real terms almost $1 billion.
1
Senator BENTSEN. Incredible.
Mr. FELDSTEIN. The $4.6 billion of nominal capital gains resulted in
a tax liability of $1.1 billion. The tax liability on the real capital gains
would have been only $661 million. Inflation thus raised tax liabilities
by nearly $500 million, approximately doubling the overall effective
tax rate on corporate stock capital g~ins.
Let me again clarify for you just what we did. We recomputed each
individual's capital gain on the basis of a price-adjusted basis and
calculated how much tax he would have paid if that had been the gain
rather than the tax that he actually paid. The result is to cut in half
the tax liability that individuals had.
Although adjusting for the price change reduces the gain at every
income level, the effect of the price level correction is far from uniform.
In particular, the measurement of capital gains is most severe for
taxpayers with incomes under $100,000.
Exhibit 1, which is at the back of my prepared statement, compares
the nominal and real capital gains and the corresponding tax liabilities
for each income class.
The figures are in millions, $86 million up to $4.6 billion for the
total.
Row 2 presents the corresponding real net capital gains. In the
highest income class there is little difference between nominal and real
capital gains. Individuals with incomes over $500,000 had nominal
capital gains of $1.2 billion and real capital gains of $1.1 billion.
Senator BENTSEN. Is there some pattern which gives that result i
Mr. FELDSTEIN. Basically, our analysis suggests that these are individuals who have very low basis stock, which they might have
acquired when a company was formed.
Senator BENTSEN. I see.
Mr. FELDSTEIN. For them, the inflation effect is very small. You can
take a 10-cent stock and multiply it by a lot of inflation adjustment,
and it still remains a 10-cent stock.
In the highest income class, therefore, there is little difference between nominal and real capital gains; in contrast, taxpayers with
incomes below $100,000 suffered real capital losses even though they
were taxed on positive nominal gains.
The tax liabilities corresponding to these two measures are compared in rows 3 and 4. In each income class up to $50,000, recognizing
real capital gains makes the tax liability negative. At higher income
levels, tax liabilities are reduced but remain positive on average; the
extent of the current excess tax decreases with income.
Let me summarize the study. It showed inflation has substantially
increased-roughly doubled-the effective tax rate on corporate stock
gains.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

173
Although this relates to 1973, since that is the only year this type of
data is available from the Treasury, the continuing high rate of inflation means the rate is likely to be even greater.
Let me turn to the second of the major problems that inflation causes
in the tax system-the treatment of depreciation. As you know, the
amount of depreciation allowed on any asset under current law depends on its original cost. When inflation raises the price level, th~
real value of these depreciation allowances is reduced. This reduction
in the real value of depreciation that is caused by the historic cost
method of depreciation is equivalent to a substantial increase in the
rate of tax on corporate and other investment income.
We are currently doing a study of this problem at the National
Bureau of Economic Research. Although I therefore cannot tell you
as much as I hope we will eventually know, I want to mention one
very important figure. We estimate that the historic cost method of
tax depreciation caused corporate depreciation in 1977 to be understated by more than $25 billion.
Senator BENTSEN. Does that mean that profits are overstated 1
Mr. FELDSTEIN. Yes; for tax purposes, by $25 billion. As a result,
corporate liabilities are increased by $12 billion, a 20-percent increase
in total taxes; or, to look at it a different way, this extra inflation tax
reduced net profits by 23 percent of the total 1973 net profits of $53
billion. Although I do not have more to say at this time about the adverse effect of historic cost depreciation, I want to stress that I think
that this is the single most important adverse effect of inflation on
capital formation.
This brings me to the final tax problem caused by inflation, the failure to distinguish between nominal interest and real interest. This
problem is fundamentally different from the problems involved in
capital gains taxation and in depreciation. The nature of this difference is still not widely appreciated. It is extremely important, however, because it implies that changing the tax treatment of interest
is less urgent that the other changes. Let me explain why.
It is clear that taxing nominal interest income imposes an unfair
burden on bondowners and other lenders.
But allowing a deduction for nominal interest expenses also provides an unfair benefit to corporations and othP-r borrowers. When
financial markets have had a chance to respond fully to the higher
rate of inflation, interest rates will adjust to reduce the unfair burden
on borrowers and to reduce the unfair advantage of lenders. If all
borrowers and lenders had the same marginal tax rate, the market
adjustment of interest rates would eliminate all inequities, leaving
borrowers and lenders with the same real aftertax rates of interest
that they would have in the absence of inflation.
Let nie emphasize, however, that this rough, longrun justice would
only be achieved if the current method of depreciation is replaced by
price-indexed or current-cost depreciation. If we stay with our current system of depreciation, interest rates will fail to adjust fully and
bondholders will suffer a substantial permanent fall in their real
aftertax returns.
A recent NBER study showed that, roughly speaking, with our
current system of depreciation and taxation, each 1 percent rise in
the expected rate of inflation will induce a 1-percent rise in the mar35-570 0 - 79 - 12

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

174
ket rate of interest. The real rate of interest will remain unchanged,
but the real aftertax rate of interest will fall sharply. This is, in
effect, the mechanism by which firms transfer some of the adverse
effect of historic cost deJ?reciation to bondholders.
The magnitude of this effect is large enough to imply effective tax
rates of more than 100 percent on interest income. Consider what has
happened since the early 1960's. The infla.tion rate was then only 1 percent, and the 5 percent nominal yield on Baa corporate bonds provided a real yield of 4 percent. An investor with a 40 percent marginal rate obtained an aftertax yield of 3 percent, and a real aftertax
yield of 2 percent.
By comparison, during the past 3 years a Baa bond yielded 10 percent, but consumer prices rose 6 percent. An investor with a 40 percent
marginal rate obtained a 6 percent aftertax yield but a real aftertax
yield of zero. In short, the effective rate of tax on real income was
100 percent.
The meaning of this calculation is clear. If historic cost depreciation is continued, taxpaying bondholders will receive little or no aftertax income. This can be remedied by allowing bondholders and other
lenders to include only real interest receipts m their taxable income.
But this should be seen as only an imperfect way of dealing with
the more basic problem of depreciation.
Moreover, it is important to limit this change in the treatment of
interest to bondholders; reducing the deduction taken by corporations
to their real interest payments without adjusting depreciation rules
would only transfer the full burden of mismeasuring depreciation
to eauity investors.
Only "if we made the adjustment in depreciation, only then would it
be correct to change the taxation of interest payments for bondholders,
and so forth.
Replacing the current method of depreciation is, therefore, the key
problem. If this is done, adjust~g- the taxation of interest income is of
secondary importance. The specific method of depreciation that is
adopted-replacement cost depreciation, general price indexing ·or
immediate expensing of investment-is a much less important issue
than the general principle that the value of depreciation must be insulated from the effects of inflation.
Let me summarize what I have said this morning.
Inflation reduces capital formation because even moderate rates of
inflation cause very large increases in the effective rates of tax on investment income. The tax system must be changed to revive the
needed incentives to invest and to reintroduce greater predictability
of future effective tax rates. The key change that should be made is to
use a real cost adjusted basis for calculating both depreciation and
capital gains. While reducing inflation should remain a principal goal
of economic policy, changi~ our tax system to recognize the real basis for depreciation and capital gains would eliminate one of the most
harmful effects of inflation on capital formation and therefore on our
economic prosperity.
That concludes my oral statement. Thank you.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Feldstein, together with the studies
referred to, follows :]


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

175
PREP.A.BED STATEMENT OF MARTIN FELDSTEIN

1

The Impact of Inff,ation on Capital Formation

Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am very pleased to have this opportunity to testify
again before this distinguished committee.
In your invitation, you asked me to discuss the impact of inflation on capital
formation. I believe that inflation has a very substantial adverse effect on capital formation in the United States. Our tax system is the most important reason
for this harmful effect of inflation on capital formation.
During the past decade, effective tax rates have increased dramatically on
capital gains, on interest income and on the direct returns to investment in plant
and equipment. Investors in stocks and bonds now pay tax rates of nearly 100
percent-and in many cases more than 100 percent-on their real returns. This
change has taken place without public debate and without legislative action. It
has occurred almost by accident because our tax system was designed for an
economy with little or no inflation. But if current rates of inflation persist, the
existing tax laws will continue to impose effective tax rates of more ban 100
percent on investment incomes. To make matters even worse, the current tax
laws imply that future tax rates will depend haphazardly on future rates of
inflation and therefore cannot be predicted at the time that investment decisions
are being made.
These extremely high tax rates and the uncertainty about future tax rates are
a cloud that hangs over the stock market and business investment decisions. This
morning, I will describe the results of several recent studies at the National Bureau of Economic Research that qualify the effect of inflation on the taxation
of investment income and therefore on the incentive to investment. I am submitting two of these studies for the record of these hearings.
INFLATION AND THE TAX OF CAPITAL GAINS

Inflation distorts all aspects of the taxation of personal income but is particularly harsh on the taxation of capital gains. As you know, when corporate stock
or any other asset is sold, current law requires that a capital gains tax be paid
on the entire difference between the selling price and the original cost even
though much of the nominal gain only offsets a general rise in the prices of consumer goods and services. Taxing nominal gains in this way very substantially
increases the effective tax rate on real price-adjusted gains. Indeed, many individuals pay a substantial capital gains tax even though, when adjustment is
made for the change in the price level, they actually receive less from their sale
than they had originally paid.
In a-recent study at the National Bureau of Economic Research," we measured
the total excess taxation of corporate stock capital gains caused by inflation and
the extent to which this distortion differs capriciously among individuals. For
this study we used the Treasury Department's sample of individual tax returns
for 1973. Our sample consisted of over 30,000 individuals and more than 230,000
stock sales in 1973. Although the individuals are not identified, the sampling
rates are known; the sample can therefore be used to construct accurate estimates of totals for all taxpayers.
We found that in 1973 individuals paid capital gains tax on $4.6 billion of nominal capital gains on corporate stock. When the costs of these shares are adjusted
for the increase in the consumer price level since they were purchased, this gain
becomes a loss of nearly $1 billion.
The $4.6 billion of nominal capital gaims resulted in a tax liability of $1.1
billion. The tax liability on the real capital gain:s would have been only $661
million. Inflation thus raised tax liabilities by nearly $500 million, approximately
doubling the overall effective tax rate on corporate stock capital gains.
·
Although adjusting for the price change reduces the gain at every income level,
the effect of the price level correction is far from uniform. In particular, the
mismeasurement of capital gains is most severe for taxpayers with incomes under
1 President. National Bureau of Economic Research, and professor of economics, Harvard
University. The views expressed here are my own and not necessarily that of either the
NBER or Harvard.
• M. Feldstein and J. Slemrod. "Inflation and the Excess Taxation of Capital Gains",
National Bureau of Economic Research (to be publlshed in the National Tax Journal,
June 1978).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

17.6
$100,000. Exhibit 1 compares the nominal and real capital gains and the corresponding tax liabilities for each income class. The first row presents the net capital gains as defined by the current law. Row 2 represents the corresponding real
net capital gains. In the highest income class, ,there is little difference between
nominal and real capital gains; in contrast, taxpayers with incomes below $100,000 suffered real capital losses even though they were taxed on positive nominal
gains.
The tJax liabilities corresponding to ithese two measures are compared in rows
3 and 4. In each income class up to $50,000, recognizing real capital gains makes
the tax liability negative. At higher income levels, tax liabilities are reduced but
remain positive on average; the extent of the current excess tax decreases with
income.
Inflation not only raises the effective tax rate, but also makes the taxation of
capital gains arbitrary and capricious. Individuals who face •the same statutory
rates have their real capital gains taxed at very different rates 'because of differences in holding periods. For example, among taxpayers with adjusted gross
incomes of $20,000 to $50,000, we found that '.>nly half the tax liability on capitaI
gains was incurred by taxpayers whose liabilities on real gains would have been
between 80 and 100 percent of their actual liabilities. The remaining half of tax
liabilities were incurred by individuals whose liabilities on real gains would have
been less than 80 percent of their actual statutory liabilHies.
In short, our study showed that inflation has substantially increased-roughly
doubled-the overall effective tax rate on corporate stock capital gains. Although
this estimate relates to 1973 (because that is the only year for which da'ta of this
type is available), the continuing high rate of inflation means that the tax distortion for more recent years is likely to be even greater.
DEPRECIATION

The second major problem that inflation causes in our tax system is in the
treatment of depreciation. As you know, the amount of depreciation that is
allowed on any asset under current law depends on Hs original cost. When inflation raises the price level, the real value of these depreciation aHowances is
reduced. This reduction in the real value of depreciation that is caused by the
hiestoric cost method of depreciation is equivalent to a substantial increase in
the rate of tax on corporate and other investment income.
We are currently doing a study of this problem at the National Bureau of
Economic Research. Al'though I therefore cannot tell you as much as I hope we
will eventually know, I want to mention one very important figure. We estimate
that the historic cost method of tax depreciation caused cor,porate depreciation
in 1977 to be understated by more than $25 billion. The understatement increased
corporate tax liabilities by $2 billion, a 20-percent increase in corporate taxes.
This extra inflation tax reduced net profits by 23 percent of the total 1973 net
profits of $53 billion.
Although I do not have more to say at this time a'bout the adverse effect of
historic cost depreciation, I want to stress that I think that this is the single
most important adverse effect of inflation, on capital forma'bion.
REAL INTEREST RATES

This brings me to the final tax proMem caused by inflation, the failure to distinguish between nominal interest and real interest. This problem is fundamentally different from the problems involved in capit,al gains taxation and in
depreciation. The nature of this difference is still not widely appreciated. It is
extremely important, however, because it implies that changing the tax treatment of interest is less urgent than the other changes. Let me explain why.
It is clear that 'taxing nominal interest income imposes ,an unfair burden on
bond owners and other lenders. But allowing a deduction for nominal interest
expenses also provides an unfair 'benefit to corporations and other borrowers.
When markets have lrad a chance to respond fully to the higher rate of inflation,
interest rates will adjust to reduce the unfair burden on borrowers and to reduce
the unfair advantage of lenders. If all borrowers and lenders had the same
marginal :tax rate, the market adjustment of interest rates would eliminate all
inequities, leaving borrowers and lenders with the same real aftertax rates of
interest that they Wl)Uld face in the absence of inflation.
Let me emphasize, however, that this rough, long-run justice would only be
achieved if the current method of depreciation is repl,aced by price-indexed or

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

177
current cost depreciation. If we stay with our current system of depreciation, interest rates will fail to adjust fully and bondholder~/ will suffer a substantial
permanent fall in their real aftertax returns. A recent NBER study• showed
that, roughly speaking, with our current system of depredation and taxation,
each 1-percent rise in the expected rate of inflation will induce a 1-percent rise
in the market rnte of interest. The real rate of interest will remain unchanged,
but the real aftertax rate of interest will fall sharply. This is, in effect, the
mechanism by which firms transfer some of the adverse effect of historic cost
deprecia'tfon to bondholders.
The magnitude of this effect is large enough to imply effective tax rates of
more than 100 percent on interest income. Consider what has happened since
the early 1960's. The inflation rate was then cmly 1 percent, and the 5 percent
nominal yield on Baa bonds provided a real yield of 4 percent. An investor with a
40-pereent marginal rate obtained an aftertax yield of 3 percent, and a real aftertax yield of 2 percent. By comparison, during the past 3 years a Baa bond yielded
10 percent, but consumer prices rose 6 percent. An investor with a 40-percent
marginal rate obtained a 6-percent aftertax yield but a real aftertax yield of
zero. In short, the effective rate of tax on real income was 100 percent!
The meaning of this calculation is clear. If historic cost depreciation is continued, taxpaying 'bondholders will receive little or no afte·rtax income. This can
be remedied by allowing bondholders and other lenders to include only real interest receipts in their taxable income. But this should be seen as only an imperfect way of dealing with the more basic problem of depreciation. Moreover,
it is important to limit this change in the treatment of interest Ito bondholders;
reducing the reduction taken by corporations to their real interest payments without adjusting depreciation rules would only transfer the full burden of mismeasuring depreciation to equity inves'tors.
Replacing the current method of depreciation is, therefore, the key problem.
If this is done, •adjusting the taxation of interest income is of secondary importance. The specific method of depreciation that is adopted-replacement cost
depreciation, general price indexing or immediate expensing of investment-is
a much less important issue than the general principle that the value of depreciation must be insulated from the effects of inflation.
SUMMARY

Let me summarize what I have said this morning. Inflation reduces capital
formation because even moderate rates of inflation cause very large increases in
the effective rates of tax on investment income. The tax system must be changed
to revive the needed incentives to invest and to reintroduce greater predictability
of future effective tax rates. 'The key chan~e that should be made is 1to use a real
cost adjusted basis for calculating both depreciation and capital gains. While
reducing inflation should remain a principle goal of economic policy, ehanging
our tax system to recognize the real basis for depreciation and capital gains
would eliminate one of the most harmful effects of inflation on capital formation
and therefore on our economic prosperity.
EXHIBIT 1
CAPITAL GAINS AND ASSOCIATED TAX LIABILITIES
[In millions of dollars]
Adjusted gross income class

I. Nominal caoital gains ___
2. Real capital gains _______
_on nominal capital
3. Taxgains
________________
4. Tax on real capital gains_

More
Zero $10,000 $20,000 $50,000 $100,000 $200,000
Less
th•n
to
to
to
to
to
to
than
zero $10, 000 $20,000 $50,000 $100,000 $200,000 $500,000 $500,000

All

86
-15

77
-726

I
0

-5
-25

369
21
-895 -1, 420

719
-255

942
437

'I, 135
839

I, 280
I, 125

4,629
-910

80
-52

159
58

215
141

291
235

374
337

1,m

23
-34

• M. Feldstein and L. Summers, "Inflation, Tax Rules and the Long-Term Interest Rate",
1978.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

178
INFLATION AND THE EXCESS TAXATION OF CAPITAL GAINS ON CORPORATE STOCK

(By Martin Feldstein and Joel Slemrod) •
SUMMARY

The present study shows that in 1973 individuals paid nearly $500 million
of extra tax on corporate stock capital gains because of the distorting effect of
inflation. A detailed analysis shows that the distortion was greatest for middle
income sellers of corporate stock.
In 1973, individuals paid capital gains tax on more than $4.5 billion of nominal
capital gains on corporate stock. If the costs of these shares are adjusted for the
increases in the consumer price level since they were purchased, the $4.5 billion
nominal gain becomes a real capital loss of nearly $1 billion. As a result of this
incorrect measurement of capital gains, individuals with similar read capital
gains were subject to very different total tax liabilities.
These findings are based on a new body of official tax return data on individual sales of corporate stock.
Inflation distorts all aspects of the taxation of personal income but is particularly harsh on tl:ie taxation of capital gains. When corporate stock or any
other asset is sold, current law requires that a capital gains tax be paid on the
entire difference between the selling price and the original cost even though :mju.ch
of that nominal gain only offsets a general rise in the prices of consumer goods
and services. Taxing nominal gains in this way very substantially increases the
effective tax rate on real price-adjusted capital gains. Indeed, many individuals
pay a substantial capital gains tax even though, when adjustment is made for the
change in the price level, they actually receive less from their sale than they had
originally paid.
The present study shows that in 1973 individuals paid nearly $500 mililon of
extra tax on corporate stock capital gains because of the distorting effect of inflation. The detailed evidence presented below shows that this distortion is -greatest
for middle income sellers of corporate stock.
More specifically, in 1973 individuals paid capital gains tax on more than
$4.5 billion of nominal capital gains on corporate stock. If the costs of these
shares are adjusted for the increases in the consumer price level since they were
purchased, the $4.5 billion nominal gain becomes a real capital loss of nearly $1
billion. As a result of this incorrect measurement of capital gains. individuals
with similar real capital gains were subject to very different total tax liabilities.
These findings are based on a new body of official tax return data on indivfdual
sales of corporate stock. The first section of the paper describes the data and the
method of analysis: The basic results are presented in section 2. The third section analyzes the extent to which equal real gains are taxed unequally under
current rules. Several alternatives to the current law are then examined in
detail. A final section examines how a permanel!t inflation rate of 6 percent
would quadruple the effective rate of tax on capital gains.'
1. THE DATA AND ESTIMATION METHOD

Each year the Treasury Department and the Internal Revenue Service select a
large scientific sample of tax returns with which to study various aspects of
income sources and tax liabilities. In order to provide adequate information
on high income taxpayers, the sample contains a much larger fraction of high
income returns than of low and middle income returns. Since the sampling rates
are known, the sample can be used to construct accurate estimates for the entire population.
In 1973, the information collected for the annual sample of tax returns was
extended in a special study to include detailed data on capital asset transactions.
The complete record on each sale of a capital asset (as recorded in Schedule D
• Harvard University and the National Bureau of Economic Research. This study Is
Part of the NBER nroirram of research on business taxation and finance We are itrateful
to Daniel Frisch, Sv Rottenberg, and Shlomo Yltzhakl for helpful discussions. to the U.S.
Treasury for prQvldlng the data, and to the Natlounl S"lence Fonudatlon for financial support. This paper has not been reviewed by the NBER Board of Directors.
1 For previous discussions of the tavatlon of capital 1:alns In an Inflationary economv see
Brinner '1973, 1976) and Diamond (1975\. The theory of the eft'Pct of Income taxation
In an Inflationary economy, Including the tax treatment of Interest and capita! gains. Is
developed In Feldstein, Green and Sheshlnskl (1978).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

179
of Form 1040) was combined with the other information from that taxpayer's
return. In the current study, we consider only the sales of corporate stock. Our
sample consists of information for 30,063 individuals -and 234,974 individuals
corpomte stock sales in 1973."
.
.
.
.
.
.
We supplemented the record. for each t.ra;_sact1on by calculating a pnce mdexed capital gain. More specifically, we multiplied the acquisition price of the
stock by the ratio calculated by dividing the consumer price index (CPI) for
1973 by the CI'I for the year of purchase. This has the effect of restating the
cost of the stock in 1973 dollars. Subtracting this price-index cost from the
amount for which the stock was sold in 1973 yields a correct real capital gain
in 1973 dollars. Since the CPI was higher in 1973 than in any previous year, the
real capital gain is less than the nominal gain for all regular sales and greater
than the nominal gain for all short sales.•
Of the $4.63 billion in nominal capital gains, transactions representing $1.79
billion do not have a correctly coded year- of purchase, presumably because the
taxpayer failed to provide this information on this tax return. In order to calculate the price-adjust cost of these stocks, we estimated the year of purchase by
using the adjusted gross income (AGI) of the taxpayer and the ratio of the selling price to the original cost of the transaction. More specifically, all of the
transactions for which we have correctly coded years of purchase were classified
into one of eight AGI groups and one of 25 classes of the ratio of selling price to
original cost. For each of these 200 categories, the average holding period was
calculated. This avemge holding period was then applied to each of the transactions that had no purchase date on the basis of the taxpayer's AGI and the
transaction's ratio of sale price to purchase price. When the holding period predicted in this way involved a fraction of a year, the price index was interpolated
between the two bordering years' indices.•
· To assess the excess tax that resulted from the mismeasuring of the capital
gains, we must calculate the tax liability that individuals incurred in 1973 on
their nominal capital gain and the liability that they would have incurred if
the real capital gain had been included instead. To do this we use a special computer program that incorporates the relevant features of the income tax law as of
1973 and that calculates each individual's total tax liability for different measures of the capital gain.• Comparing the total tax liability based on the nominal
capital gain (or loss) as recorded for 1973 with the liability if there were no
gain (or loss) on corporate stocks provides the value for each individual of the
actual capital gains tax on nominal gains. Similarly, comparing the total tax
liability with the real capital gain for 1973 as described above with the liability
if there were no gain provides the value for each individual of the capital tax
on real gains. These tax calculations distinguish short-term and long-term capital gains in the usual way.
All calculations are done using the provision of the law of 1973 that limited the
loss to be charged against current income to $1,000. Because using a real capital
gains measure makes capital losses much more common than they now appear
to be, we also i<how the effect of removing the loss limitation. Several other
changes in the tax law were also studied and will be described bel-0w.•
• In a relatively small numher of transactions, there Is a discrepancy between the reported gain or loss and the difference between the reported purchase and sale prices. Th1>se
non-matching transactions were dropoed from our sample, reducing the total capital
gain on corporate stock from $5.01 billion to $4.63 billion. Our sample also excludes transactions In which the taxpayer did not specify the asset type and transactions recorded on
partnership and fiduciary returns. Our estimate of the excess tax paid because of Inflation
Is therefore an underestimate of the true value.
·
• Since the seller generally does not get the use of the proceeds of short sales, this also
tends to understate the true excess tax.
• Although there is no reason to believe that our procedure introduces any bias In the
calculation of the excess tax. there is no way to test this directly. As a partial test of our
method. the real !!'alns of the transactions with known purchase dates were calculated
using the predicted holding period rather than the actual. The resulting distribution ot
real gains Is very similar to the actual real gains. To the evtent that the transactions with
purchase year mlssinit are similar to those with a correctly coded date, our procedure will
accurately aoproxlmate tlle real gain.
• The program Includes such features as the alternative tax, the ·preference tax and the
limit on tax losses as well as full information on each Individual's Income. deductions, etc.
This TAXSIM program Is described and used in Feldstein and Frisch (1977).
• Because of the new Treasury data, our method represents a substantial improvement
over the estimation procedure used b:v Brlnner (1976). He worked with published ·data on
capital gain In 1962 and did not have adequate measures of Individual marl!'lnal tax rates
on capital italns. Moreover, 1962 came after a period of relative price stability: the CPI
rose at an average annual rate of less than 1.3 percent during the previous decade. Brlnner
was of course careful to warn his readers of these limitations.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

180
2, THE EXCESS TAX ON CAPITAL GAINS

The current practice of taxing uominal capital gains resulted in a tax liability
of $1,138 million on the sales 'of corporate stock in 1973.7 If capital gains were
measured instead in real terms, the tax liability would only have been $661
million.• The excess tax wns thus $477 million, an increase of more than 70
percent. If the current limit on deducting capital losses were also eliminated,
the tax on real capital gains would only have been $117 million.
Table 1 shows the detailed calculations by inrome class that underlie these
total figures. The first row presents the net capital gain as defined by the current law. For each of the eight adjusted gross income (AGI) classes, the net
capital gain figure is the weighted sum of all of the individual net capital gains
or taxpayers in that A.GI class; the weights reflect the sampling probabilities,
making our total figure a valid estimate of the total net capital gailn for all
taxpayers in that class.• Note that the current law's nominal measure of the
capital gains implies that there is a positive net gain in each income class. The
&um of these gains is ~.63 billion.
TABLE 1.-CAPITAL GAINS AND ASSOCIATED TAX LIABILITIES
(In millions of dollars!
Adjusted 1ross income class
Less
than
zero

l. Nom!nal capital
pins ••..•....••
2. Real capital pins •.
3. Tax on nominal
capital 1ains...••
4. Tax !'n real capital
gains .••••••.••.
5. Tax on nominal
capital ,ains, no
loss limit.•.•••••
6. Tax on real capital
,ai ns, no loss
limit. ••.....••.•
7. Total tax liability,
those with
corporate stock
capital Jain .•..•.
8. Total tax liability,
all individuals ••..

86

-15

Zero
to

$10,000
to

$10,000

$20,000

77
-726

21
-895

More
$50,000 $100,000 $200,000
to
than
to
to
to
$50,000 ~100, 000 $200,000 $500,000 $500,000

All

1,280
l, 125

4,629
-910

$20,000

369
-1,420

719
-255

942
437

l, 135
839

l

-5

23

80

159

215

291

374

l, 138

0

-25

-34

-52

58

141

235

337

661

0

-7

-6

-31

91

·191

288

372

897

-1

-38

-94

-259

-97

72

209

325

117
16,450

10

224

1,556

5,492

3,986

2,467

l, 582

l, 133

16

15,490

40,895

32,275

10,367

4,922

2,480

1,638 108,084

Note: See text for source and method. All fi1ures relate to capital pins on corporate stock sold in 1973.

Row 2 presents the corresponding real net capital gains. This adjustment for
the rise in the price level changes the $4.63 billion nominal gain into a $910
million real loss. Although adjusting for the price change reduces the gain at
every income level, the effect of the price level correction is far from uniform.
For taxpayers with AGI's below $100,000, the price adjustment indicates that
real capital gains were negative. This group had $1.27 billion of nominal capital
gains but, after adjusting for the rise in consumer prices, had a real capital
loss of $3.31 billion. In contrast, taxpayers with A.GI's above $100,000 had nominal gains of $3.36 billion and real gains of $2.40 billion.
• Recall that our sample excludes sales ln partnership and trusts and· omits a small
fraction of sales ln which the reported gain or loss did not correspond exactly to the dlf•
ference between selllng price and original hasls.
8 This calculation and all other calculations in the current paper are based on the
actual stock sales In 1973. Changing the law to tax only real capital gains would of course
increase the amount of stock that ls sold. On the sensitivity of common stock sales to the
taxation of capital gains, see Feldstein and Yltzhakl (1978) and Feldstein, Slemrod and
Yltzhakl (14178).
• See footnote 7 above.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

181
The tax liabilities corresponding to these two measures of capital gains are
compared in rows 3 and 4. Iil caleulating these tax, liabilities, individual losses
are subject to the limit of $1,000. In eaeh AGI ·class up to $50,000, recognizing
real gains makes the tax liability negative. · At higher income levels, tax liabilities are reduced but remain positive on average; the extent of the current
excees-both absolutely and relatively-decreases with income. Thus taxpayers
with AGI's between $50,000 and $100,000 paid an excess tax of $101 million or
nearly three times the appropriate tax on their real capital gains. By contrast,
taxpayers with AGI's over $500,f)OO paid an excess tax of $87 million or only
11 percent more than the tax on their real capital gains. This pattern of capital
gains and of tax liabilities shows why the total tax on real capital gains remains positive even though total real capital gains are negative.
The substantial real capital losses for taxpayers with AGl's below $100,000
that are shown in row 2 suggest that the limit on the deductability of capital
losses has a substantial effect on tax liabilities when capital gains are measured
in real terms. Lines 5 and (I show the tax liabilities corresponding to nominal
and real capital gains if the loss limitation is disregarded.'" For nominal capital
gains there is only a modest differenee since the general rise in prices substantially reduces losses. The total tax liability is reduced from $1.14 billion to $0.90
billion, with almost all of the difference in the liabilities of taxpayers with AGI's
between $20,000 and $100,000. By contrast, with real capital gains the current
loss limit raises tax liabilities by $544 million or more than 80% of the $661
million tax liability.
The importance of the current excess taxation of capital gains can be seen by
comparing the excess tax with the total tax liabHities shown in rows 7 and 8.
now 7 shows the total tax liabilities for taxpayers who had any capital gain or
loss on corporate stock. The excess tax liability can thi1s be compared with the
total liability for the same groups of individuals. With the current loss limitation
retained, this excess tax is roughly constant as a percentage of total tax for all
groups with AGI's over $20,000. For example, individuals with AGI's between
$20,000 and $50,000 paid $132 million in excess tax or 2.4 percent of their total
tax liability of $5.49 billion. For individuals with AGI's between $100,000 and
$200,000, the extra tax is $74 million or 3.0 percent of their total tax of $2.47
billion. A maximum of 3.3 percent occurs for those with AGI's over $500,000.
3, TAXING EQUAL GAINS UNEQUALLY

The mismeasurement of capital gains does more than raise the effective tax
rate on real capital gains. It also introduces an arbitrary randomness in the
taxing of capital gains. Two individuals with the same real capital gain can pay
tax on very di1ferent nominal gains. This section presents striking evidence that
equal real capital gains are taxed unequally to a very substantial extent.
Table 2 compares the tax liability that would be due on real capital gains
\\ith the tax liability that was aetually assessed on nominal gains.11 There is
very substantial variation among individuals in the ratio of the tax liability
on real gains to the liability on nominal gains. Consider for example the taxpayers with adjusted gross incomes between $20,000 and $50,000. Only 26.5 percent of the actual tax liability on nominal gains was incurred by taxpayers whose
liabilities on real gains were between 90 percent and 100 percent of these nominal
liabilities. An additional 18.4 percent of the actual tax liability was incurred
hy taxpayers whose liabilities on real gains would have been between 80 and
90 percent of their actual liabilities. The remaining 55 percent of actual tax
liabilities were incurred by individuals whose liabilities on real gains would
have been '1e~s than 80 percent of their actual statutory liabilities.
10 Recall that we are looking only at the stocks actually sold in 1973. Allowing unlimited deduction for losses would induce more sales of stocks with accrued losses. Our
estimates should he interpreted as the el'tent of overtaxation of the stocks actually sold
rather than as estimates of the effect of changing the law to remove the limit.
11 We have considered here only those returns with a positive nominal gain so as to
avoid ambiguity in interpreting the sign of the ratios.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

182
TABLE 2.-DISTRIBUTION OF ACTUAL TAX LIABILITIES BY TAX LIABILITY ON REAL GAINS AS A PERCENTAGE
OF TAX LIABILITY ON NOMINAL GAINS
[In percent[
Adjusted gross income (in thousands of dollars)

Tax liability on real gains as percentage
of tax liability on nominal gains:
Less than zero ____________________
Zero _____________________________
10 percent. ______________________
20 percent. ______________________
30 percent. ______________________
40 percent. ______________________
50 percent_ ______________________
60 percent. ______________________
70 percent. ______________________
80 percent_ ______________________
90 percent_ ______________________

0-10

10-20

13. 5
21.7
.8
1. 6
3.8
9. 0
9. 7
8. 5
2.3
16. 0
24. 5

11.0
8.8
1.7
.8
4. 5
9. 3
5. 3
5.1
9. 2
16. 0
28. 4

20-50 50-100

6.1
3.8
.8
1.7
5. 0
2. 0
4. 4
17. 1
14.1
18. 4
26. 5

5. 6
4.1
I. 3
2. 1
4.1
3. 6
3.4
6. 2
12. 9
20. 3
36. 3

100-200

2. 5
I. 6
1.0
1.8
1.7
2. 3
3. 5
7. 0
11.7
18. 6
48. 2

200-500

1.1
1.1

.4
.8
1. 2
1.7
2. 5
4.1
8. 5
16. 2
62. 3

500+

0. 3
.4
.1
.8
.3
1.1
.6
2. 0
3. 9
11.2
79. 3

All
taxpayers

3. 4
2. 6
.7
1. 3
2. 4
2. 5
2.9
6. 7
9. 6
16. 4
51.5

Note: Each entry is the percentage of the tax liability on the nominal capital gains as actually incurred by taxpayers in
that AGI class. Computations consider only those returns which showed a positive nominal gain on corporate stock capital
gains.

The disparities are even greater for taxpayers with lower AGL Among those
with AGI's between $10,000 and $20,000, 27 percent of actual liabilities were
incurred by taxpayers whose liabilities on real capital gains were less than 40
percent of their actual statutory liabilities ,vhile an equally large amount (28.4
percent) of liabilities were incurred by taxpayers whose liabilities on real gains
would have been nearly as large as their liabilities on nominal gains.
Table 3 shows this paUern of unequal taxation of real capital gains in a
different way. This table shows the numbers of taxpayers at each level of
liability on real capital gains who pay quite different amounts on nominal gain."
Thus, more than 220,000 of the taxpayers with real capital losses paid tax on
nominal capital gains. ·within this group, more than 3,000 paid capital-gain taxes
of over $2,000 and nearly 1,000 paid taxes of over $5,000. Similarly, among taxpayers who had real gains but with corresponding tax liabilities of less than
$1,000, more than 40,000 paid tax liabilities of more than $1,000 and nearly l,OQQ
paid tax liabilities of more than $5,000.
The same sense of substantial and arbitrary randomness is evident if we look
at the rows of the tal.Jle. For example, if we look at the 3,355 taxpayers who
incurred tax liabilities of $20.000 to $30,000, we find that 463 would bave had
liabilities of less than $10,000 on their real gains.
In short. the effect of taxing nominal gains rather than real gains is of very
little significance for some taxpayers but involves a very substantial distortion
for others.
TABLE 3.-NUMBERS OF TAXPAYERS CLASSIFIED BY TAX LIABILITIES ON REAL GAINS AND NOMINAL GAINS
Tax liability on real capital gains (in thousands of dollars)
Negative

0-1

1-2

2-5 5-10 10-20 20-30 30-50

50- Over
100 100

Tax liability on nominial Capital gains
(in thousands of dollars):

iI[~I('.t('.L'.'.'.C· ~~n11 l.-o~niri ~~ir~~i~~i:;;tt?t//?~'.'.?t'.
10-20___________________________
20-30_____________ ______________
30-50___________________________
50-100__________________________
Over 100________________________

196
54
23
12
1

174
34
13
9
5

49
127
10
4
O

616 2,617 6,402 --------·-·-··-·--··--40
208 1,049 1,843 ________________ _
19
30 135 722 2,111 ----------5
6
13
42 359 1,804 ____ _
1
O
2
3
19 234 1,810

Note: "Tax liability on nominal capital gains" is the actual 1973 liability. The "tax liability on real gains" is the corresponding liability if real gains were calculated by adjusting the basis for the change in the CPI.
12 Our calculation Ignores the small number of taxpayers whose short sales meant that
their nominal gain would actually be less than their real gain.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

183
4. ALTERNATIVE TAX RULES

This section examines the implication of price indexing the basis of capital
gains in combination with two other proposals that have been frequently advocated: (1) taxing all corporate stock capital gains like short-term capital gains,
i.e., eliminating the alternative tax method and the current exclusion of one-half
of long-term gain, and (2) limiting income tax rates to 50 percent on so-called
"unearned income" as well as "earned· income." 13 Again we limit our attention
to the tax consequenoos for the stocks actually sold in 1973 and thus disregard
the way in which portfolio selling would be altered by these tax changes.
The current treatment of capital gains could be modified in either of two
different ways. First, the current method of excluding one-half of long-term
capital gains and of allowing the alternative tax could be ended while still
limiting the deductible losses to $1,000. Alternatively, the limit on loss deductibility could be suspended at the same time. Table 4 shows the effects of applying
each of these rules to the corporate stock sales in 1973.
TABLE 4.-TAX LIABILITIES WHEN CAPITAL GAINS ARE TAXED LIKE ORDINARY INCOME
[In millions of dollars!
Adjusted gross income class
More
Less
Zero $10,000 $20,000 $50,000 $100,000 $200,000
than
than
to
to
to
to
to
to
zero $10,000 $20,000 $50,000 $100,000 $200,000 $500,000 $500,000

1. Tax _on nominal capital

gains. ___ . ____ . ______ •

2. Tax on real capital gains __
3. Tax on nominal capital
gains; no loss limit. ___
4. Tax on real capital gains;
no loss limit_ _________
5. Tax on nominal capital
gains with all gains
treated
as short-term
gains _________________
6. Tax on real capital gains
with all gains treated
as short-term gains ____
7. Tax on nominal capital
gains with all gains
treated as short-term
gains; no loss limit.._.
8. Tax on real capital gains
with all gains treated
as short-term gains;
no loss limit. _________

1
-0

-5
-25

23
-34

80
-52

159
58

215
141

291
235

All

372 1, 138
337
661

-0

-7

-6

-31

91

191

288

372

897

-1

-38

-94

-259

-97

72

209

325

117

9

30·

109

406

469

562

676

804 3,065

6

-8

14

174

285

421

569

736 2,196

7

19

44

183

340

514

665

799 2,571

4

-38

-112

-216

14

302

523

715 1, 193

Note: See text for source and method. All figures relate to capital gains on corporate stock sold in 1973.

For convenience, the first four rows show the tax liabilities based on the
current exclusion and alternative tax rules. The next four rows show the corresponding tax liabilities when the exclusion and alternatiYe tax rules are
eliminated. Simply eliminating these features while retaining the use of nominal
gains and the loss limitation would have raised the tax liability from $1.14
billion (row 1) to $3.06 billion (row 5). Taxing only real gains but eliminating
the exclusion and alternatiYe tax would nearly double the 1973 tax liability
from $1.14 billion to $2.20 billion (line 6). Only the combination of no loss limit
and the taxation of real capital gains (row 8) would leave the total tax essentially unchanged at very different from the actual 1973 tax liabilities: liabilities
would almost double for those with AGI over $200,000 with offsetting falls for
those with incomes under $100,000.
A maximum tax rate of fifty percent would have little effect if the current
definition of taxable income is maintained. This is shown in rows 5 through 8
of Table 5. The standard results for the current law and for price indexed
capital gains are shown for comparison in rows 1 through 4. The combination
of a 50 percent maximum rate and the elimination of the capital gains exclusion
and alternative rate (rows 9 and 10) significantly raises total tax liabilities.
13

Tax rates can still be somewhat higher than this because of the minimum tax.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

184
Only if this is combined with the taxation of real gains only and a full offset
of losses is the total tax kept to its current level. Again, there is a substantial
redistribution within this total.
TABLE 5.-TAX LIABILITIES ON CAPITAL GAINS WHEN THE MAXIMUM TAX RATE IS 50 PERCENT
[In millions of dollars)
Adjusted gross income class
Less
Zero $10,000 $20,000
than
to
to
to
zero $10,000 $20,000 $50,000
1. Tax on nominal capital
gains ___________________
2. Tax on real capital gains ..•
3. Tax on nominal capital
geins; no loss limit... ___
4. Tax on real capital gains;
no loss Ii mit... ___ •• ____

1
0

-5
-25

23
-34

80
-52

$&0,000
to
$100,000

$100,000
to
$200,000

$200,000
to
$&00,000

159
58

215
141

291
235

More
than
$500,000

All

374 1, 138
661
337

0

-7

-6

-31

91

191

288

372

897

-1

-38

-94

-259

-97

72

209

325

117

2
1

-25

-5

23
-34

80
-52

164
64

211
142

255
207

293 1,022
265
568

MAXIMUM TAX RATE OF
50 PERCENT
5. Tax
on___________________
nominal capital
gains
6. Tax on real capital gains ___
7. Tax on nominal capital
gains; no loss limit. •• ___
8. Tax on real capital gains;
no loss limit .• __________

0

-7

-6

-31

99

190

252

292

789

-1

-38

-94

-258

-85

81

187

255

49

7
5

29
-9

109
13

402
171

453
276

49i
374

537

s8i 2,615
535 1,819

MAXIMUM TAX RATE OF 50
PERCENT-ALL CAPITAL
GAINS TREATED LI KE
SHORT-TERM GAINS
nominal capital
9. Tax
on___________________
gains
10. Tax on real capital gains ___
11. Tax on nominal capital
gains; no loss limit. _____
12. Tax on real capital gains;
no loss limit._._ •• ______

m

6

18

44

180

329

m

529

580 2,137

3

-38

-112

-218

15

269

419

520

857

Note: See text for source and method. All figures relate to capital gains on corporate stock sold in 1973.
5. CONCLUDING COMMENTS

The evidence presented in this paper shows that the taxation of capital gains
is grossly distorted by inflation. In 1973, the tax paid on corporate stock capital
gains was $1,138 million, nearly twice the $661 million liability on real capital
gains. If the limit on the deduction of real capital losses is disregarded, the net
tax liability falls to only $117 million. By this standard, nearly all of the tax
paid on nominal capital gains represents an excess tax caused by inflation.
Moreover, our current tax rules introduce an arbitrary randomness in the taxing
of capital gains ; with inflation, taxpayers with equal real capital gains are
often required to pay tax on very different nominal gains.
The taxation of capital gains is distorted because, when there is inflation,
our current tax rules mismeasure capital gains. Other aspects of capital income and expenses, primarily interest and depreciation, are also mismeasured in the presence of inflation. The taxation of capital income is therefore more severely distorted than the taxation of wages and salaries which are
correctly measured. All types of personal income, including wages and salaries
as well as capital income, are subjected to artificially high tax rates because of
the progressivity of the tax structure, but this "bracket rate effect" is small in
relation to the distortions that result from mismeasurement.
Our estimates relate to 1973 because that is the only year for which data of
the type that we have analyzed is available. There is, however, no reason to
think that the tax distortion for 1973 was any greater than for other recent
years. Indeed, since share prices were relatively high in 1973. the ratio of real
capital gains to nominal 11:ains would also be expected to be high. More generally,
it is useful to consider the effect of our current tax law on an individual who
invested twenty years ago in a diversified portfolio of common stock and sold


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

185
this stock at the end of 1977. According to the Standard and Poor's Index, the
price of such a portfolio approximately doubled between 1957 and 1977. However,
the CPI also doubled in this twenty-year period, implying that there was no real
increase in the value of the stock." If the investor pays a 25 percent tax on
the nominal capital gain when the stock is sold in 1977, he will actually have
lost about 15 percent in real terms on his investment over the 20-year period.
The problem of excess taxation of capital gains when there is inflation is not
peculiar to the past 20 years but is inherent in our current tax system. Unless
this aspect of the tax law is changed, the problem will continue in the future. If
we abstract from fluctuations in the price-earnings ratio, the effect of retained
earnings should make the real value of common stock rise at about 2 percent a
year. 1" If these accruing capital gains are taxed at an effective rate of 20 percent,
the net after-tax yield is 1.6 percent a year. With a 6 percent steady rate of inflation and a constant price-earnings ratio, share prices would be expected to
rise at 8 percent a year.
This still leaves the same real before-tax increase of 2, percent that would
occur without inflation.1° But a 20 percent capital gains tax on the 8 percent
nominal capital gain leaves an after-tax nominal gain of only 6.4 percent. After
subtracting the 6 percent inflation, the real after-tax gain is only 0.4 percent.
The effective tax on real capital gains is thus 80 percent when the inflation rate
is 6 percent. An 8 percent rate of inflation would make the effective tax rate
equal to 100 percent!
The distorting effect of inflation on the taxation of capital gains could be
remedied by adjusting the original cost of assets for the rise in the general
price level.17 This would reduce the effective rates of tax on real capital gains
and would thereby reduce the loss in economic welfare that results from such
taxation of capital income. 18 Measuring capital gains in real terms would have the
further advantage of reducing the penalty for switching assets which currently
distorts investor behavior.
BIBLIOGRAPHY

Andrews, William D., "A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income
Tax," Harvard Law Review, Vol. 87, No. 6 (April 1974).
Brinner, Roger E., "Inflation, Deferral, and the Neutral Taxation of Capital
Gains," National Tax Journal, Vol. 24, No. 4 (December 1973).
- - - , "Inflation and the Definition of Taxable Personal Income," in Henry
Aaron (ed.) Inflation and the Income Tax, The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 1975.
Diamond, Peter A., "Illlflation and the Comprehensive Tax Base," Journal of
Public Economics, Vol. 4, No. 3 (August 1975).
Feldstein, Martin S. "The Welfare Cost of Capital Income Taxation," .Journal
of Political Economy (forthcoming, 1978).
Feldstein, Martin S., and Daniel Frisch, "Corporate Tax Integration; The
Estimated Effects on Capital .Accumulation and Tax Distribution of Two
Integration Proposals," National Tax Journal, Vol. 30, No. 1 (March 1977).
Feldstein, Martin S., Jerry Green, and Eytan Sheshinski, "Inflation and Taxes
in a growing Economy With Debt and Equity Finance," Journal of Political
Economy, (forthcoming, 1978).
Feldstein, Martin S., Joel Slemrod, and Shlomo Yitzhaki, "The Capital Gains
Tax and Common Stock Sales," (in preparation).
Feldstein, Martin S., and Shlomo Yitzhaki, "The Effect of the Capital Gains
Tax on the Selling and Switching of Common Stock," Journal of Public
Economics, (forthcoming, 1978).
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Blueprints for Basic Tax Reform, Washington,
D.C., 1977.
14 The increase in both the Standard and Poor's Index and the CPI was actually between
115 percent ancl 120 percent.
15 If we correct the measurement of rPtainecl Ntrnings for the artificial depreciation and
inventory figures. the ratio of retained earnings to price ayeraged 1.8 percent for the
period from 19!'iS through 1977.
10 Our caleulations show that the effectivP rntP on rPalizP!l nominal capital gain was 24.!\
percent in 1973. Since then tax lPgislatlon has raised significantly this efl'PctiYP tax rate
through changes in thP minimum tax and maximum tax. We use a 20 percPnt effpcffrp
rate on accruing capital gains to reflect the adYantages of postponement.
17 The substitution of a cash-flow or Pxpencliture type incomP tax for our current system
would also eliminate all such problems. See Anclrews (1974) and U.S. TrPasury (1977).
18 See Feldstein (1978) for a discussion of the welfare loss of capital income taxation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

186
WORKING PAPER SERIES-Continued
Number and author

Title

Date

176-lrving B. Kravis and Robert E. Lipsey ____ Export and Domestic Prices under Inflation and Ex- May 1977.
change Rate Movements.
177-James J. Heckman ___________________ Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous
Do.
Equation System.
178-Benjamin M. Friedman and V. Vance Investors' Portfolio Behavior Under Alternative April 1977.
Roley.
Models of Long-Term Interest Rate Expectations:
Unitary, Rational, or Autoregressive.
179-Benjamin M. Friedman and V. Vance Identifying Identical Distributed Lag Structures by
Do.
Roley.
the Use of Prior Sum Constraints.
ISO-Linda Nasif Edwards and Michael An Economic Analysis of Children's Health and In- May 1977.
Grossman.
tellectual Development.
181-lrving B. Kravis and Robert E. Lipsey ____ Price Behavior in the Light of Balance of Payments June 1977.
Theories.
182-lrving B. Kravis and Robert E. Lipsey ____ Export Prices and Exchange Rates __________________ July 1977.
183-Richard Butler and James A. Heckman ___ The Government's Impact on the Labor Market Status June 1977.
of Black Americans: A Critical Review.
184-Gary S. Becker__ _____________________ A Theory of the Production and Allocation of Effort ____ July 1977.
185-Lee A. Lillard ________________________ Estimation of Permanent and Transitory Response
Do.
Functions in Panels Data: A Dynamic Labor Supply
Model.
186-Martin Feldstein _____________________ Do Private Pensions Increase National Saving? ______ _
Do.
187-Eytan Sheshinski_ ____________________ A Model of Social Security and Retirement Decisions __
Do.
188-Jerry Green _________________________ Notes on the Public Debt and Social Insurance ______ _
Do.
Do.
189-David Coleman, Paul Holland, Neil A System of Subroutines for Iteratively Reweighted
Kaden, and Virginia Klema. ·
Least Squares Computations.
190-Bert G. Hickman, Yoshimi Kuroda, and The Pacific Basin in World Trade: Part 1, Current- August 1977.
Lawrence J. Lau.
Price Trade Matrices, 1948-1975.
191-Bert G. Hickman, Yoshimi Kuroda, and The Pacific Basin in World Trade: Part II, ConstantDo.
La¥.rence J. Lau.
Price Trade Matrices, 1955-1975.
Do.
192-Bert G. Hickman, Yoshimi Kuroda, and The Pacific Basin in World Trade: Part llll An
Lawrence J. Lau.
Analysis of Changing Trade Patterns, 1955-b75.
Do.
193-Martin Feldstein and David Hartman ___ The Optimal Taxation of Foreign Source Investment
Income.
194-Daniel A. Graham ____________________ Cost-Benefit Analysis Under Uncertainty __________ _
Do.
195-David E. Coleman_. __________________ Finding Leverage Groups ________________________ _
Do.
Do.
196-John E. Dennis, David M. Gay, and Roy An Adaptive Nonlinear Least Square Algorithm _____ _
E. Welsh.
197-Thomas E. Cooley, Steven J. DeCanio, An Agricultural Time Series-Cross Section Data Set.
Do.
and M. Scott Matthews.
198-Ann P. BarteL ______________________ The Economics of Migration: An Empirical Analysis
Do.

199-Jacob Mincer _______________________ • Fa:if~ ~:~ilo~e~~~~~i~-~h-~~~'.~_0!_J_~~~~~~1 '.~~Do.
200-Anna Luiza Ozorio de Aleida ___________ Share-Tenancy and Eamily Size in the Brazilian
Do.
Northeast.
201-Martin Feldstein ____ •. _____ • _________ The Welfare Cost of Permanent Inflation and Optimal
Do.
.
Short-Run Economic Policy. .
.
202-Robert T. MIchaeL. _•• _______ •••• ___ Two Papers on the Recent Rise 1n U.S. Divorce Rate __ September 1977.
203-Eytan Sheshinski_ ___________________ Taxation, Inflation, and Monetary Policy____________
Do.
204-Michael J. Boskin and Michael D. Hurd._ The Effect of Social Security on Early Retirement.___
Do.
205-Benjamin M. Friedman and V. Vance Structural Models of Interest Rate Determination and
Do.
Roley.
Portfolio Behavior in the Corporate and Government Bond Markets.
206-Martin Feldstein and Anthony Pellechio_ Social Security and Household Wealth Accumulation: October 19 77
(revised).
New Microeconomic Evidence.
207-Martin S. Feldstein and Daniel Frisch. __ Local Government Budgeting: The Econometric Com- October 1977.
parison of Political and Bureaucratic Models.
208-H. M. Shefrin and Richard Thaler.
An Economic Theory of Self-Control.. _____________ _
Do.
209-W. F. Sharpe ________________________ Bank Capital Adequacy, Deposit Insurance and
Do.
Security Values, Part I.
210-William M. Landes ___________________ An Economic Study of U.S. Aircraft Hijacking, 1960- November 1977.
1976.
211-Victor R. Fuchs ______________________ The Service Industries and U.S. Economic Growth
Do.
Since World War II.
Do.
212-Martin S. Feldstein and Anthony Social Security Wealth: The Impact of Alternative
Pellechio.
Inflation AdJustments.
Do.
213-Linda N. Edwards and Michael The Relationship Between Children's Health and
Grossman.
Intellectual Development.
214-John S. Flemming ____________________ Aspects of Optimal Unemployment Insurance:
Do.
Search, Leisure and Capital Market Imperfections.
215-Jerry R. Green _______________________ Mitigating Demographic Risk Through Social
Do
Insurance.
216-John B. Shoven ______________________ An Evaluation of the Role of Factor Markets and
Do.
Intensities in the Social Security Crisis: A Progress
Report.
'
Do.
217-William Landes and Richard Posner ____ Altruism in Law and Economics___________________
218-Zvi Bodie and Benjamin M. Friedman ___ A Heterogeneous-Expectations Model of the Value of December 1977.
Bonds Bearinij Call Options.
219-Dov Chernichovsky and Douglas Coate __ The Choice of Diet for Young Children and Its RelaDo.
tion to Children's Growth.
220-B. Peter Pashigian ___________________ Occupational Licensing and the Interstate Mobility
Do.
of Professionals.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

187
WORKING PAPER SERIES-Continued
Number and author

Title

Date

221-Michael J. Baskin and Lawrence J. Lau __ Taxation and Aggregate Factor Supply: Preliminary December 1977.
Estimates.
222-J. Huston McCulloch __________________ The Cumulative Unanticipated Change in Interest
Do.
Rates: Evidence on the Misintermediation Hypoth-

esis.

223-Martin S. Feldstein ___________________ The Private and Social Costs of Unemployment_ ____ January 1978
224-James L. Medoff _____________________ The Earnings Function: A Glimpse Inside the Black
Do.
Box.
225-Richard B. Freeman __________________ Job Satisfaction as an Economic Variable___________
Do.
226-Robert E. Hall _______________________ Fluctuation in Equilibrium Unemployment__________
Do.
227-William M. Landes and Richard A. Salvors, Finders, Good Samaritans and Other
Do.
Posner.
Rescuers: An Economic Study of Law and Al truism.
228-Michael D. Hurd _____________________ Estimating the Family Labor Supply Functions DeDo.
rived from the Stone-Geary Utility Function.
229-Victor Zarnowitz. ____________________ On the Accuracy and Properties of Recent MacroDo.
economic Forecasts.
230-Edward P. Lazear and Robert T. FamilySizeandtheDistributionof Per Capita Income_
Do.
Michael.
231-Benjamin M. Friedman _______________ Who Puts the Inflation Premium into Nominal In- February 1978.
terest Rates?
232-Marti n S. Feldstein and Lawrence Inflation, Tax Rules, and the Longer Term Interest
Do.
Summers.
Rate.
233-Geor~e J. Borjas _____________________ Job Mobility and Earnings Over the Life Cycle.______
Do.
234-Martin S. Feldstein and Joel Slemrod ___ Inflation and the Excess Taxation of Capital Gains on
Do.
Corporate Stock.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

188
MARTIN FELDSTEIN
National Bureau of Economic Research and Harvard University
LA WREN CE SUMMERS
National Bureau of Economic Research and Harvard University

Inflation, Tax Rules, and
the Long-Term Interest Rate
the return to capital is a focus of research in both macroeconomics and public finance, each specialty has approached this subject
with an almost total disregard for the other's contribution. Macroeconomic studies of the effect of inflation on the rate of interest have implicitly ignored the existence of taxes and the problems of tax depreciation.1 Similarly, empirical studies of the incidence of corporate tax changes
have not recognized that the effect of the tax depends on the rate of inflation and have ignored the information on the rate of return that investors
receive in financial markets. 2 Our primary purpose in this paper is to begin
AL THOUGH

Note: This study is part of the program of Research on Business Finance and
Taxation of the National Bureau of Economic Research. We are grateful to the
National Science Foundation for financial support, to several colleagues for useful
discussions, and to Dale Jorgenson and Barbara Fraumeani for making unpublished
data available. This paper has not been reviewed by the Board of Directors of the
National Bureau.
1. For a review of recent empirical studies, see Thomas J. Sargent, "Interest
Rates and Expected Inflation: A Selective Summary of Recent Research," Explorations in Economic Research, vol. 3 (Summer 1976), pp. 303-25. This criticism applies also to Martin Feldstein and Otto Eckstein, "The Fundamental Determinants
of the Interest Rate," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 52 (November 1970),
pp. 363-75, and Martin Feldstein and Gary Chamberlain, "Multimarket Expectations
and the Rate of Interest," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 5 (November
1973), pp. 873-902.
2. The prominent econometric studies include Marian Krzyzaniak and Richard
A. Musgrave, The Shifting of the Corporation Income Tax: An Empirical Study of
0007-2303/ 78/000J.<)061$00.2$/0 @ Brookings Institution


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

189
62

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

to build a bridge between these two approaches to a common empirical
problem.
The explicit recognition of corporate taxation substantially changes
the relation between the rates of inflation and of interest that is implied
by equilibrium theory. The Fisherian conclusion that the nominal rate of
interest rises by the expected rate of inflation, leaving the real rate of interest unchanged, is no longer valid when borrowers treat interest payments as a deductible expense and pay tax on profits net of accounting
depreciation. 3 A more general theory is discussed in the first section and
is used there to analyze the expected impact of changes in inflation with
the tax and depreciation rules fo effect during the past twenty-five years.
The analysis shows that changes in the rate of inflation are likely to be
significantly nonneutral even in the very long run.
Since the long-term interest rate measures the yield available to individual investors, analysis of it provides an operational way of studying
the incidence of changes in corporate tax rules. Oddly enough, this natural way of measuring tax incidence has not been exploited before. The
first section shows how to translate the postwar changes in tax rates and
depreciation rules into the changes in the interest rate that would prevail
if no shifting occurred; it thus lays the foundation for econometric estimates of the actual degree of shifting set out in later sections. This approach requires separating the effects of inflation from the effects of tax
changes. Since most of the postwar changes in corporate taxation have
been in depreciation rules and investment credits, the eff~ct of these
changes on the long-term interest rate is of obvious importance in determining their potential stimulus to investment.
In a previous theoretical paper, Feldstein analyzed how an increase in
Its Short-Run Effect upon the Rate of Return (Johns Hopkins Press, 1963); Robert
J. Gordon, "The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax in U.S. Manufacturing,
1925-62," American Economic Review, vol. 57 (September 1967), pp. 731-58; and
William H. Oakland, "Corporate Earnings and Tax Shifting in U.S. Manufacturing,
1930-1968," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 54 (August 1972), pp. 235-44.
Other major empirical studies include Arnold C. Harberger, "The Incidence of the
Corporation Income Tax," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 70 (June 1962), pp.
215-40, and John B. Shoven and John Whalley, "A General Equilibrium Calculation of the Effects of Differential Taxation of Income from Capital in the U.S.,"
Journal of Public Economics, vol. 1 (November 1972), pp. 281-321. None of this
research refers to either inflation or financial-market return.
3. One statement of Fisher's theory can be found in Irving Fisher, The Theory of
Interest (MacMillan, 1930).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
35-570 0 - 79 - 13
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

190
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

63

the rate of inflation would alter the interest rate in an economy in steadystate growth. Although that model brought out the important nonneutrality of inflation and the need to revise Fisher's theories to reflect taxation,
its relevance is severely limited by the assumptions that all investment is
financed by debt and that capital goods do not depreciate. Both of these
restrictive assumptions were relaxed in a subsequent paper in which firms
were assumed to finance investment by a mixture of debt and equity and
in which capital depreciates. 4 Introducing depreciation permits an analysis of the effect of allowing only historic-cost depreciation for tax purposes. This more general model shows that the way inflation affects the
real interest rate depends on two countervailing forces. The tax deductibility of interest payments tends to raise the real interest rate while
historic-cost depreciation lowers it. The net effect can be determined only
by a more explicit specification of depreciation and tax rules than was
appropriate in that theoretical study. Such an explicit analysis is presented
in the first section below. Equally important, the empirical analysis of the
subsequent sections does not assume that saving is inelastic or that all
forms of investment are subject to the same tax rules.
The three main sections of our paper might almost be regarded as three
separate studies tied together by the common theme of inflation, taxes,
and the interest rate. In the first section, we extend previous theoretical
studies of the interaction of taxes and inflation by making explicit calculations based on the actual tax rules of the past two decades. These calculations show how changes in tax rules and in inflation rates have altered
the maximum nominal interest rate that firms could pay on a standard
investment. An important implication of this analysis is that Fisher's
famous conclusion is not valid in an economy with taxes on capital
income.
The second section is an econometric analysis of the observed relation
between inflation and the long-term interest rate. A novel feature of this
analysis is the use of an explicit predicted inflation variable which is derived from an optimal forecasting equation based on an ARIMA ( autoregressive integrated moving average) process, as described there.
4. See Martin Feldstein, "Inflation, Income Taxes and the Rate of Interest: A
Theoretical Analysis," American Economic Review, vol. 66 (December 1976), pp.
809-20; and Martin Feldstein, Jerry Green, and Eytan Sheshinski, "Inflation and
Taxes in a Growing Economy with Debt and Equity Finance," Journal of Political
Economy (forthcoming).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

191
64

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

The third section studies the effects of changes in tax rules and in pretax profitability. This section is the most ambitious in its attempt to link
the econometric estimates to the analytic method developed in the first
section. We regard its results as preliminary because all of our estimates
are conditional on specific assumptions about the mix of debt and equity
used to finance marginal investments and about the relative yields on debt
and equity that the market imposes. We believe that it is important to explore a wider range of assumptions and that our method provides the
correct framework for such an extended analysis.
A brief concluding section summarizes the major findings.

The Analytic Framework
The central analytic feature of this paper is the operational method
of converting any change in tax rules and in expected inflation into the
implied change in the long-term interest rate that is consistent with a fixed
marginal product of capital. This method is presented in the current section and is then used ( 1 ) to analyze the effects of specific changes in tax
rules, (2) to derive the relevant generalization of the Fisherian relation
between inflation and the interest rate, and ( 3) to calculate the implied
equilibrium interest rate for each year from 1954 through 1976. These
estimates underpin the empirical analysis in the rest of the paper.

A SIMPLE ILLUSTRATIVE MODEL

It is useful to begin by analyzing a simple illustrative case in which all
marginal investment is financed by debt. 5 Moreover, the aggregate supply
of loanable funds is taken as fixed. 6 We assume also that all investment
5. That the marginal investments of all firms are financed by debt does not preclude their ·using retained earnings to finance investment; this view is developed by
Joseph E. Stiglitz in "Taxation, Corporate Financial Policy, and the Cost of Capital,"
Journal of Public Economics, vol. 2 (February 1973 ), pp. 1-34, and Stiglitz, "The
Corporation Tax," Journal of Public Economics, vol. 5 (April-May 1976), pp.
303-11. For a contrary argument, see Martin Feldstein, Jerry Green, and Eytan
Sheshinski, "Corporate Financial Policy and Taxation in a Growing Economy,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming).
6. This implies that the volume of saving is fixed and that the demand for money
is interest inelastic.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

192
65

Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

is subject to the same tax and depreciation rules. 7 While these assumptions do not even approximate reality, they do permit a simple exposition
of our method. Working through this simple case makes it e~sier to
examine the more general framework with mixed debt-equity finance, an
elastic supply of loanable funds, and differential tax rules.
We start by examining an economy with no inflation and see how tax
changes alter the rate of interest. We then see how the interest rate responds to inflation under alternative tax and depreciation rules.
The diagram below illustrates the traditional determination of the
equilibrium interest rate (i0 ), which equates the inelastic supply of loanable funds (S) to the downward-sloping investment-demand schedule
(I). In the absence of taxes, each point on the investment schedule indiInterest rate

s

1'

1

lo

Investment

7. This assumption ignores, for example, the difference between the tax treatment of investment in plant and equipment and of investment in residential real
estate,


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

193
66

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

cates the internal rate of return on the marginal project at the corresponding aggregate level of investment. 8
The introduction of a corporate income tax with proper economic depreciation and the deductibility of interest payments docs not shift this
investment schedule; any investment that could pay a maximum interest
rate of i before the introduction of the tax can pay exactly the same rate
subsequently. 9 In contrast, an investment tax credit or acceleration of
depreciation would raise the maximum potential interest rate on every
project and would therefore shift the investment-demand schedule to the
right to line I'. Given a completely inelastic supply of investable funds,
such a tax change simply raises the interest rate without any increase in
investment.
Tax Changes. Analyzing quantitatively the effect of tax changes (and
later of inflation) calls for an operational method of translating tax
changes into changes in the interest rate-that is, a method of calculating
i1 in the diagram; the method must be comp~. '..i.ble with a fixed marginal
product of capital. To do this, we select a hypothetical "standard investment" and calculate the internal rate of return under different tax regimes.
Consider a standard investment in equipment in which the real net output
declines exponentially at 8 percent a year10 until the project is scrapped
at the end of T years; the initial value of net output (a 0 ) is chosen so that,
in the absence of any tax, the project has an internal rate of return of 12
percent. 11 Such a project has net output a 0 (1 + 8)-t in the tth year of its
8. This is essentially Keynes' formulation of the schedule for the marginal efficiency of investment. We implicitly assume that mutually exclusive options are
described by Irving Fisher's incremental method and that multiple internal rates of
return can be ignored. For a cautionary note about this procedure, see M. S. Feldstein and J. S. Flemming, "The Problem of Time-Stream Evaluation: Present Values
versus Internal Rate of Return Rules," Bulletin of the Oxford Institute of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 26 (February 1964), pp. 79-85.
9. The pretax situation may be described by f'(I) - i = 0, where f'(I) is the
marginal product of investment; a tax at rate -r with the deductibility of interest does
not change the implied value of i in (1 - -r) f (l) - (1 - -r )i 0.
10. Note that this is "output decay" and not "depreciation"; see Martin S. Feldstein and Michael Rothschild, ''Towards an Economic Theory of Replacement Investment," Econometrica, vol. 42 (May 1974 ), pp. 393-423, for an analysis of these
concepts.
11. This is based on our earlier estimates of the pretax return on private investment in nonfinancial corporations; see Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers,
"Is the Rate of Profit Falling?" BPEA, 1:1977, pp. 211-27. We raised the average
return of 10.6 percent for 1948-76 reported there to 12 percent because we regard
that sample period as overrepresenting cyclically low years, but the choice of any
constant pretax rate of return does not alter our analysis.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

=

194
67

Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

life, where tzo is selected to satisfy

Pi
T

(1)

ao

+

(1
o)-1
(l.12)1 = 1.

In practice, it is important to distinguish between investments in equipment and in structures because the depreciation rules and tax credits
affect the two very differently; for example, the investment tax credit does
not apply to structures. Our "standard investment" is therefore specified
to be a mix of equipment and structures in the ratio of 1.95 to l.1 2 The
specification of equation 1 is used to describe an investment in equipment
with a ten-year life and an exponential decay rate of 13 percent. The net
output of the investment in structures is assumed to decay at 3 percent a
year and the structure is scrapped after thirty years; the output of a dollar's investment in new structures is also chosen to make the pretax rate
of return equal to 12 percent. The standard investment is a thirty-year
"sandwich" project, of which 66.2 percent of the investment in the first
year is in a standard structure and the remainder is in equipment; the
equipment is then replaced at the end of ten and twenty years.
The maximum potential interest rate corresponding to any given tax
regime (that is, the value of i1 in the diagram) is defined as the interest
rate that can be paid on the outstanding balance of the loan used to
finance the project, where the balance is reduced to zero at the end of the
life of the project. Il L 1 is the loan balance at time t and x 1 is the net cash
flow of the project during t ( except for interest expenses), the internal
rate of return is the interest rate i that satisfies

Lt - L1-1 = iL1-l -

(2)

Xi,

t = 1, ... 'T,

where L 0 = 1 and LT = 0. In the special case of the pure equipment
project and no tax, equation 2 reduces to

Lt - L1-1 = iLt-1 - ao(l

(3)

+ 0)-

1;

the solution of this equation with L 0 = 1 and LT = 0 is exactly equivalent
to the familiar definition of the internal rate of return given by equation 1.
When a tax at rate T is levied on the net output minus the sum of the
interest payment and the allowable depreciation (d,), the loan balance
changes according to

(4)

L, - L1-1

= iL1-1 -

Xi+

-r(x1 -

d1 -

iL1-1).

12. This figure, when used in conjunction with the procedure described below,
yields an investment mix corresponding to the average composition over the past
twenty years.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

195
68

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

The value of i1 corresponding to any tax regime is therefore available
by solving for the value of i that is consistent with equation 4 for our xt
"sandwich" with LT = 0 and L 0 equal to one minus the investment tax
credit.
lnfiation. The preceding method of analysis can also be used to analyze the effect of inflation on the investment-demand schedule and therefore on the equilibrium rate of interest if the supply of loanable funds is
inelastic. More generally, the method can be extended to decompose the
increase in the interest rate induced by a rise in inflation into one part due
to the shift in the demand for funds and one due to a shift in the supply; we
return to this decomposition below.
It is ago.in easiest to begin by examining the case in which marginal
projects are financed by debt only. Consider first the situation in the absence of taxes. In terms of equation 2, the effect of introducing a constant
expected inflation at rate 1r is to raise the future net profit in each year
by a factor ( 1 + 1r) t and thus to convert the fundamental equation to
(5)

L, - L,_1 = iL,-1 - (1

+ 11-)!x,,

t = 1, ... , T.

For any sequence of real net profits, the internal rate of return i that satisfies the initial and terminal equations ( L 0 = 1, LT = 0) is increased by
exactly the rate of inflation. 13 With a fixed supply of loanable funds, this
increase in the maximum potential interest rate on all projects would
raise the equilibrium interest rate by the rate of inflation.
This Fisherian conclusion is no longer valid when taxes are considered.14 Equation 4 now becomes
(6)

L, - Li-1 = iL,_1 - (1

+ 1r)1x, +

r[(l

+ 1r)'x1

- d(1r), - iLc-1],

where d ( 1r) t is the depreciation allowed for tax purposes when there is
inflation at rate 1r. Depending on the depreciation rule, the nominal maximum potential interest rate may rise by more or less than the rate of inflation. To see this, it is useful to consider the special case in which there is
no depreciation. Equation 6 can then be written15
(7)

L, - L,_1 = (1 - r)iL,-1 - (1 - r)(l

+ 1r)'x,.

13. There is actually a second-order term: the internal rate of return rises from
i without inflation to ( 1 + i) ( 1 + 1r) - 1 i + 1r + i1r with inflation. But the i1r term
vanishes if interest is compounded continuously.
14. These remarks are developed extensively in Feldstein, "Inflation, Income
Taxes, and the Rate of Interest," and Feldstein, Green, and Sheshinski, "Inflation
and Taxes."
15. Note that the asset appreciates in nominal value but there is no tax due on
this appreciation as such.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

=

196
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

69

This is exactly the same as 5 with the real project output replaced by an
after-tax value, (1 - r )xt, and the interest rate by its after-tax value,
( 1 - r) i. The effect of inflation is therefore to raise the after-tax potential
rate of interest by exactly the rate of inflation: d[(l - r)i]/d,r = 1, or
di/d,r = 1/(1 - r). With the U.S. marginal corporate tax rate of r
= 0.48, this implies that the maximum potential interest rate rises by almost 2 percentage points for each 1 percent of inflation. If the supply of
loanable funds were perfectly inelastic, the equilibrium interest rate
would also rise by nearly 2 points.
The same relationship prevails if the asset depreciates and if the historic-cost basis of the depreciation is increased in proportion to the price
level. 16 Although this degree of sensitivity of the interest rate may seem
surprising at first, it is easily understood: each percentage point of inflation permits an increase of 2 points in the interest rate because the aftertax cost of this increase is only 1 point. 11 Moreover, this "excess adjustment" of the pretax interest rate is just sufficient to keep unchanged the
after-tax return to a lender with the same marginal tax rate. 18
The practice of allowing only historic-cost depreciation reduces the
real value of depreciation allowances whenever the inflation rate increases.
It is equivalent to levying a tax on the accruing increases in the nominal
value of the asset. This extra tax implies that the real net-of-tax yield to
lenders must be reduced by inflation and therefore that an increase in
inflation raises the nominal pretax yield by less than 1/ ( 1 - r). Explicit
calculations of this effect will now be presented. 19
Internal Rates of Return with Pure Debt Finance. Table 1 presents
the calculated maximum potential interest rate with pure debt finance for
our standard investment under seven tax regimes. The rates are calculated
first on the assumption of no inflation and then on the assumption of a
constant 6 percent rate of inflation.
16. See Feldstein, Green, and Sheshinski, "Inflation and Taxes."
17. Note that with price-indexed depreciation there is no capital-gains tax on the
accruing increase in the nominal value of the assets or, equivalently, on the decreasing real value of the liabilities.
18. If borrowers were taxed on the real capital gains that resulted from the decreasing real value of their liabilities, the interest rate would rise only by the rate of
inflation. To leave lenders with the same after-tax real return, the real capital losses
that result from the decreasing real value of their liabilities would have to be a
deductible expense.
19. The theory of this relation is discussed in Feldstein, Green, and Sheshinski,
"Inflation and Taxes"; see in particular the appendix to that paper by Alan Auerbach.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

197
70

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

Table 1. Maximum Potential Interest Rate with 100 Percent Marginal Debt Finance,
Alternative Tax Regimes and Inflation Rates
Percent

Inflation rate
Tax regime (corporate tax rate, depreciation
method, and other provisions)
(A) No tax
(B) 52 percent; straight-line depreciation
(C) 52 percent; accelerated depreciation as of 1960
(D) 52 percent; investment tax credit of 5.6 percent;
depreciation as of 1963: 4 with Long amendment
(E) Same as D, except Long amendment repealed
(F) Same as E, except 48 percent
(G) Current law: 48 percent; investment tax credit of
9 percent;• asset depreciation range

0

6percent

12.0
12.4
13.3

18.0
21.6
22.6

14.0
14.2
14.0

23.7
23.8
23.0

14.9

24.3

Source: Derived by method described in text.
a. See text note 21.

Consider first the results corresponding to no inflation-column 1 of
table 1. By constructii:m, the maximum potential interest rate (MPIR) in
the absence of both taxes and inflation is 12 percent for our standard investment. Imposing the tax regime that existed until 1954 (a 52 percent
corporate tax rate and straight-line depreciation) leaves the MPIR essentially unchanged at 12.4 percent.2° Successive tax regimes liberalized depreciation and raised the MPIR. The accelerated-depreciation options
introduced in 1954 were adopted only gradually, but by 1960, the mix
of depreciation patterns implied an MPIR of 13.3 percent. The introduction of the investment tax credit raised it further, to 14 percent in 1963.
Currently, because of a 10 percent investment tax credit and the assetdepreciation-range (ADR) method of depreciation, the MPIR has reached
14.9 percent. 21 The tax changes since 1954 have thus raised the MPIR
by one-fifth of its original value. 22
20. The MPIR is increased in the shift from regime A (no tax) to regime B because straight-line depreciation is slightly more generous than true economic depreciation.
21. The effective rate of tax credit of 9 percent shown in the table differs from
the statutory rate of 10 percent because of limitations on loss offset and carryover.
Also, certain firms and types of investment are not eligible for the credit. In all our
work, we use the effective rate.
22. Note that because interest is deductible, a lower tax rate actually lowers the
MPIR, as illustrated by the tax cut in 1964 (switching from regime E to F).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

198
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

71

Comparing the two columns of table 1 reveals the ways in which taxation changes the way inflation affects the rate of interest. With no tax, a 6
percent rate of inflation raises the MPIR by 6 percentage points-from
12.0 to 18.0. In contrast, with a 52 percent tax and straight-line depreciation (regime B), the 6 percent inflation raises the MPIR by 9.2 points
(from 12.4 percent to 21.6 percent). Thus di/d1r = 1.53 in this regime.
Note that a lender (bondholder) thus experiences an increase in the real
rate of return from 12.4 to 15.6 percent. However, since the personal tax
is levied on the full nominal return, the lender will receive a reduced real
return after tax unless his marginal tax rate is less than 35 percent. At a
personal tax rate of 50 percent, for example, the real after-tax yield on
bonds falls from 6.2 percent with no inflation to 4.8 percent with 6 percent
inflation.
The same pattern can be followed with all of the other tax regimes of
the postwar period. The figures in column 2 show that under every regime,
a 6 percent inflation rate would raise the nominal rate of return by between 9 .0 and 9. 7 percentage points.
Although the assumption that marginal investments are financed completely by debt is a useful analytic simplification, the implied interest rates
shown in columns 1 and 2 are clearly inconsistent with market experience.
The real long-term interest rates are not (and never have been during the
postwar period) even remotely close to the high values presented in
table 1. We tum therefore to the more relevant case of investments
financed by a mix of debt and equity.
THE INTEREST RATE WITH MIXED DEBT-EQUITY FINANCE

Our view of the role of debt and equity finance starts with the observation that issuing more debt increases the riskiness of both the bonds and
the stocks of the firm. 23 Issuing additional debt thus raises the interest rate
that the firm must pay and lowers the price of its shares. The firm therefore does not finance all incremental investment by debt but selects a
debt-equity ratio that, given tax rules and investor preferences, minimizes
the cost of its capital. If the firm is in equilibrium, the mix of debt and
23. This view is developed explicitly in Feldstein, Green, and Sheshinski, "Corporate Financial Policy and Taxation." The traditional Modigliani-Miller conclusion
that the cost of capital is independent of the debt-equity ratio holds generally only
in a world without taxation and bankruptcy.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

199
72

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

equity used to finance an incremental investment is the same as its average
debt-equity investment. 24 The interest rate that a firm can pay on a "standard investment" depends on this debt-equity ratio and on the relation.
between the equity yield and the debt yield that is consistent with the
preferences of portfolio investors.
In our analysis, we assume that the ratio of debt to total capital is one
to three, roughly the average ratio of nonfinancial corporate debt to the
replacement value of that sector's capital during the past decade. Although it would clearly be desirable to extend our analysis to make the
debt-equity ratio endogenous, this generalization must be postponed until
later research.
Our basic assumption about the preference of portfolio investors is
that, because equity investments are riskier than debt investments, portfolio equilibrium requires a higher yield on equity than on debt. We consider two variants of the yield differential. First, we assume that the real
equity yield ( denoted by e) must exceed the real interest rate ( i - 1r) by
a constant risk premium, D. 25
(8)

e

=[i -

1r

+ D.

We shall examine several different values of D. Our alternative specification relates the risk premium to the difference in real after-tax rates of
return to an investor. Computational results analogous to table 1 are
presented for both specifications and both are examined in the econometric analysis below.
If the portfolio investor has a marginal personal tax rate 0, the real
after-tax return on a bond may be written in= (1 - 0)i - 1r. Specifying
the real after-tax yield on equity ( en) is more complex. Let p be the fraction of the real equity yield that is paid out and ( 1 - p) the fraction that
is retained. The part that is paid out is taxed at rate 0 while the retained
earnings are subject' only to an eventual tax at the capital-gains rate. We
use 00 to denote the "equivalent concurrent capital-gains tax rate"-that
is, the present value of the future tax equivalent to taxing the retained earnings immediately at rate 0u· In addition to these taxes on real equity earn24. If the firm issues no new equity, it establishes its desired debt-equity ratio
by its dividend policy and its debt-issue policy.
25. Since we assume a constant debt-equity ratio, changes in the risk premium
are not induced by changes in that ratio. Note also that e includes the real gains
that accrue to equity investors at the expense of bondholders.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

200
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

73

ings, the stock investor must also pay a tax on the nominal capital gains
that occur solely because of inflation. With inflation at rate 71', the resulting
nominal capital gain at rate 71' is subject to capital-gains tax at effective
rate 0fl" The real net return may therefore be written:
e,. = [p(l - 8)

+ (1

- pXl - 80 ))e - fJfl1r.

Our after-tax alternative to equation 8 is therefore
(9)

e,.

= i,.

+ D,

or

(10) [p(l - fJ)

+ (1

- pXl - fJ11))e - 6071' = (1 - fJ)i - 1r

+ D.

For our numerical calculations, we assume the reasonable values
p = 0.5, 0 = 0.4, and 011 = 0.10.
The method of calculating the maximum potential interest rate used in
the pure-debt model ( discussed above) can be applied to find the values
of i and e that satisfy either equation 8 or 9 for our "standard investment."
Note that a firm's net cost of funds (N) is a weighted average of the netof-tax interest that it pays and the yield on its equity. In nominal terms,
(11)

N

= b(l

- T)i

+ (I

- bXe

+ 1r).

In the special case of pure-debt finance, N = (1 - T )i; the solution of the
difference equation 6 provides a value for i and, since T is known, for N
as well. More generally, regardless of the mix of debt and equity finance,
the solution of equation 6 can be interpreted as equal to NI ( 1 - T) ; that
is, it is equal to the cost of funds to the firm stated as if all these costs were
deductible from the corporate income tax.
To calculate the value of i corresponding to any tax regime we therefore proceed in three steps. First, we solve equation 6 to obtain a value
of NI ( 1 - T). Second, we multiply this by ( 1 - T) to obtain N. Finally,
with this known value of N we can solve the two equations simultaneously
( 11 and 8 or 10) for i and e.
Table 2 presents the interest rates corresponding to the pretax portfolio-balance rule of equation 8. Separate results with and without inflation are presented for three risk premiums (D = 0.06, 0.08, and 0.04).
Note first that the implied interest rates, especially those corresponding to


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

201

74

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1978

Table 2. Maximum Potential Interest Rate with One-Third Debt Finance and
Selected Pretax Risk Differentials for Alternative Tax Regimes and Inflation Rates
Percent
Pretax risk differential (D)

Tax regime (corporate tax
rate, depreciation method, and
other provisions)

(A) No tax
(B) 52 percent; straight-line
depreciation
(C) 52 percent; accelerated
depreciation as of 1960
(D) 52 percent; investment tax
credit of 5.6 percent; depreciation as of 1963: 4
with Long amendment
(E) Same as D, except Long
amendment repealed
(F) Same as E, except 48
percent
(G) Current law: 48 percent;
investment tax credit of 9
percent;a asset depreciation
range

6percent

8percent

4 percent

Inflation rate

Inflation rate

Inflation rate

0
(I)

6
(2)

(3)

6
(4)

0
(5)

6
(6)

8.0

14.0

6.7

12.7

9.3

15.3

2.4

7.7

0.8

6.1

4.0

9.3

2.9

8.3

1.3

6.7

4.5

9.9

3.3

8.9

1. 7

7.3

4.9

10.5

3.4

9.0

1.8

7.4

5.0

10.6

3.8

9.4

2.2

7.8

5.4

11.0

4.4

10.2

2.8

8.6

6.0

11.8

0

Source: Derived by method described in text.
a. See text note 21.

D = 0.06, are much closer to observed experience than the results based
on complete debt finance in table 1. 26
The numbers in column 1 (zero inflation rate) deserve comment for
two reasons. First, unlike the results in the pure-debt model of table 1, the
introduction of the corporate income tax significantly lowers the implied
bond yield. This reflects the payment of a significant tax, which must reduce both the equity and debt yields. Similarly, in contrast to table 1, the
reduced corporate tax rate in 1964 now causes an increase in the MPIR.
Second, the various liberalizations of depreciation and the introduction
26. Note that in regimes B through G the values for D = 0.08 and D = 0.04
differ from the corresponding values for D = 0.06 by 0.016. This constant difference
holds to the three-decimal-place accuracy of our table but is not an exact relation
when the corporate tax rate ,,. changes.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

202
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

75

of the investment tax credit raise the MPIR. The absolute increase is
smaller than in the pure-debt case of table 1, but the proportional rise is
substantially larger.
The effect of a 6 percent inflation rate is seen by comparing columns 1
and 2. With no tax, the MPIR rises by the full amount of the inflation; a
6 percent inflation raises it from 8.0 percent to 14.0 percent. The presence
of tax.es again changes this relation but the effect is very different with
mixed debt-equity finance than in the pure-debt case. In each of the tax
regimes, a 6 percent inflation rate raises the nominal interest rate by only
about 5.5 percent: di/d1r = 0.92. This implies that the real rate of return
on debt falls even for the lender (bondholder) who is not subject to any
personal tax. For a lender who pays a significant marginal tax rate, the
equilibrium real net internal rate of return can easily be negative. Under
regime C, the real net yield to a 50 percent taxpayer falls from 1.45 percent to -1.85 percent. With the most recent regime (G), the 6 percent
inflation rate reduces the real net yield from 2.2 percent to -0.90 percent.
Table 3 presents the corresponding maximum potential interest rates
for the net-of-tax portfolio-balance rule of equation 10. Again, the corporate income tax causes a substantial reduction in the real interest rate.
The liberalized depreciation rules raise this interest rate substantially but,
even in the absence of inflation, it remains significantly below the value
without taxes. The most important difference between the results of tables
2 and ,3 is the greater sensitivity of MPIR to inflation with the net-of-tax
portfolio-balance rule of table 3. Comparing columns 1 and 2 shows that
a 6 percent inflation rate would raise the nominal MPIR by 7 .5 percent
under regime B, implying di/ d1r = 1.25; this result is essentially independent of the differential (D) that is assumed. The faster writeoffs that
are incorporated in the succeeding tax regimes reduce the extent to which
inflation lowers the value of the tax depreciation. The smaller adverse
effect on the value of depreciation raises di/ d1r; the value of 1.25 under
regime B becomes 1.32 with regime D and 1.33 with the current regime
(G).

The maximum potential interest rates shown in tables 2 and 3 have
two very important implications. First, inflation severely depresses the
real net rate of return (i,.) that can be paid to a bondholder on the basis
of our standard investment project. Consider an investor whose marginal
tax rate is 40 percent. Table 2 implies that with current law and a risk
differential of D = 0.06, a 6 percent inflation raises the nominal before-


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

203

76

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

Table 3. Maximum Potential Interest Rate with One-Third Debt Finance and
Selected Net-of-Tax Risk Differentials for Alternative Tax Regimes and Inflation Rates
Percent

Net-of-tax risk differential (D)

Tax regime (corporate tax
rate, depreciation method,
and other provisions)
(A) No tax
(B) 52 percent; straight-line
depreciation
(C) 52 percent; accelerated depreciation as of 1960
(D) 52 percent; investment tax
credit of 5.6 percent; depreciation as of 1963: 4
with Long amendment
(E) Same as D, except Long
amendment repealed
(F) Same as E, except 48
percent
(G) Current law: 48 percent;
investment tax credit of 9
percent;a asset depreciation
range

6percent

4percent

5 percent

Inflation rate

Inflation rate

Inflation rate
6

0

6

0

6

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

0
(5)

(6)

8.0

14.0

9.3

15.3

8.6

14.3

0.9

8.4

3.4

10.9

2.2

9.6

1.5

9.1

4.0

11.6

2.8

10.4

2.0

9.9

4.5

12.4

3.2

11.2

2.1

9.9

4.6

12.4

3.4

11.2

2.6

10.3

5.1

12.8

3.9

11.6

3.3

11.3

5.8

13.8

4.6

12.6

Source: Derived by method described in text.

a. See text note 21.

tax return from 4.4 to 10.2 percent, but reduces the real net return from
2.6 percent to 0.1 percent. With the more favoraqle assumptions of table
3, a 6 percent inflation reduces the real return from 2.0 percent to 0.8 percent. This has obvious effects on the incentive to save and to make risky
portfolio investments.
The second implication relates to the firm's incentive to invest. It is
frequently argued that, because their real net borrowing rate has fallen,
firms now have a greater incentive to invest than they did a few years ago.
The calculations of tables 2 and 3 show that the inference is wrong because inflation also reduces the maximum real net borrowing rate that
firms can afford to pay on any investment. Table 2 with D = 0.06 implies
that in the absence of inflation a firm could afford to pay an after-tax iry-


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

204
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

77

terest cost of 2.3 percent on the standard investment project. 21 Inflation
at 6 percent reduces the maximum real after-tax interest rate for this
project below zero to -0.7 percent! 28 The real net cost of debt finance
must thus fall by 3.0 percentage points to avoid reducing the incentive
to invest. Similarly, with table 3, the firm could afford a net interest cost
of 1.7 percent in the absence of inflation but only a negative cost, -0.1
percent, with 6 percent inflation. It is clear that the usual way of evaluating investment incentives in terms of the real net cost of finance is very
misleading with the U.S. tax system when injlation is signi:ficant. 29
THE EFFECT OF A VARIABLE SUPPLY OF
INVESTABLE FUNDS

Until now, all of our calculations have referred to the same standard
investment project and therefore implicitly to a fixed supply of investable
funds. Moreover, we have assumed that inflation has no effect on the
supply of loanable funds to the nonfinancial corporate sector. The econometric estimation of the actual effect of changes in the corporate tax requires attention to both of these issues.
Once again we begin by considering an economy in which there is no
inflation and all marginal investment is :financed by debt. The notion of a
fixed supply of loanable funds (the vertical S line of the first diagram)
rested on the assumption that our analysis relates to the entire economy
and that the supply of saving is interest inelastic. It is important for subsequent empirical analysis to drop these two assumptions. Our econometric analysis will deal with the long-term corporate bond rate; but the
demand for long-term credit comes not only from business firms, but also
from investors in residential real estate, from state, local, and federal governments, and from abroad. These investment demands are not directly
affected by the investment tax credit, accelerated depreciation, or changes
in the corporate tax rate. This implies that the supply of loanable funds
to the nonfinancial corporate sector is an increasing function of the longterm bond yield and that this supply function is not shifted by the changes
in corporate tax rules. This supply elasticity would be increased by a posi27. (1 - ,-)i = 0.52(0.044) = 0.0229.
28. (1 - ,-)i - 1r 0.52(0.102) - 0.06 -0.0070.
29. The empirical results of the next two sections suggest that the actual real net
interest rate falls by about enough to keep incentives to invest unchanged despite the
low maximum potential interest rate.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

=

=

205
78

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

tive response of domestic saving and international capital flows to the net
interest rate.
The diagram presented below is therefore a more appropriate representation than the first one. A more liberal depreciation policy ( a shift
from I to I') has a more limited effect on the long-term interest rate. The
magnitude depends on the elasticity of the supply of loanable funds to
the nonfinancial business sector and therefore on both the relative size of
the rest of the debt market and the degree of substitutability in investors'
portfolios.
Interest rate

s

I'

I

Investment

The ratio of the actual change in the long-term interest rate (i2 - i0 )
to the change that would have occurred (i1 - i0 ) if investment and therefore the marginal product of capital had remained the same thus measures
the extent to which the tax change is shifted from corporate capital to
capital elsewhere and to labor.
Our empirical analysis below focuses on the extent of tax shifting in
this general sense. We look at the tax changes as summarized by the

35-570 0 • 79 • 14
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

206
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

79

change in the corporate maximum potential interest rate and ask what
impact this potential change actually had on the yields available to portfolio investors with uncommitted funds. The ratio of (i2 - i 0 ) to (i1 - i 0 ) is
analogous to the definition of the incidence of corporate tax changes used
in previous empirical studies. 30 This measure of incidence should be distinguished from the more general concept of the fraction of the tax change
borne by capital in all sectors. A change in the corporate tax might be
borne solely by capital even though the corporate sector bore only a
modest fraction. 31 Our estimate of the ratio of (i2 - i0 ) to (i1 - i0 ) therefore does not measure the shift of the tax change from capital to labor.
We return later to consider how well our empirical analysis of the taxinduced change in the long-term bond rate measures the impact of the
tax on the yield to capital in general and not just on the capital invested
in the corporate sector.
To implement this approach, we could calculate the maximum potential interest rate for our hypothetical "standard investment" under the tax
regime of each quarter during the sample period. This would yield the
i1 values of the second diagram corresponding to different tax rules. We
could then estimate an equation relating the actual interest rate (i2 ) to
these values. In practice, however, it is necessary to allow also for changes
in inflation that shift the supply of available funds.
The response of supply to changes in the rate of inflation depends on
three basic factors: ( 1) the effect of nominal interest rates on the demand
for money; (2) the effect of the real net interest rate on saving; and (3)
the effect of inflation on the real yields available in other forms of investment open to portfolio investors. Our empirical analysis does not attempt
to disentangle:these aspects or to model explicitly the effect of inflation
on yields of alternative assets. 32 Instead, we distinguish only between the
30. See, for example, Krzyzaniak and Musgrave, Shifting of the Corporation
Income Tax, and Oakland, "Corporate Earnings and Tax Shifting." However, these
authors analyzed the effect, not on uncommitted funds, but on the return of existing
investments.
31. See, for example, Harberger, "Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax,"
for an explicit analysis of the incidence of a change in the corporate tax in an economy with more than one sector.
32. Benjamin Friedman's explicit modeling of the supply of and demand for corporate debt might usefully be extended in this direction. See, for example, Benjamin
M. Friedman, "Financial Flow Variables and the Short-Run Determination of LongTerm Interest Rates," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 85 (August 1977), pp.
661-89.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

207
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1978

80

changes in the rate of interest caused ( 1) by the inflation-induced rise in
the nominal rate of return, and (2) by all other effects of inflation.
This distinction is illustrated in the third diagram. In the absence of
inflation, the equilibrium interest rate is i0 and investment is / 0 • The effect
of inflation at rate 71' is to raise the investment-demand schedule to I'. In
a pure Fisherian economy, the vertical displacement of this schedule
would equal the rate of inflation: i1 - i0 = 71'. But with taxes and historiccost depreciation, this vertical shift is likely to be somewhere between
71' and 71' / ( 1 - T), as it is in the diagram. Inflation will also shift the supply
schedule of loanable funds from S to S'. In the pure Fisherian world, this
vertical displacement would also equal the rate of inflation: i2 - i0 = 71',

Interest rate

'1T

io+--

1-T

s

io


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

I

lo

Investment

208
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

81

implying i 2 = i 1 • 33 More realistically, the supply shift will depend on the
three factors identified in the previous paragraph. The change in the
equilibrium interest rate will depend on the shifts and the slopes of both
the demand and supply schedules.
As this analysis indicates, an empirical study of the relation between
inflation and the interest rate should not be construed as a test of Irving
Fisher's theory. With a complex structure of taxes, Fisher's conclusion
would not be expected to hold. The purpose of an empirical study should
instead be to assess the response of nominal long-term interest rates to
inflation and therefore the effect on real after-tax yields. The statistical
analysis presented below therefore begins by trying to measure this response of the interest rate to expected inflation; 34 in terms of the third
diagram, this coefficient equals (i3 - i0 )/rr. Our analysis can also go further and estimate how much of the increase in the interest rate would be
due to a shift in the demand for funds with the supply schedule fixed
(i4 - i0 ) and how much to the shift in supply with a fixed demand schedule (i5 - i0 ). With linear demand and supply schedules, this procedure
provides an exact decomposition of the observed changes: i3 - i0

= {i4 -

io)

+ (i6 -

io).

The current discussion of the effect of inflation when all marginal investments are financed by debt is extended and applied below to investments in which debt finance provides one-third of marginal capital and
equity finance, two-thirds. Our analysis assumes that the debt-equity ratio
is unaffected by the rate of inflation and that the real rates of return to
debt and equity have a constant net or gross differential.

Estimating the Effect of Inflation
In this section we begin the empirical investigation of the impact of
expected inflation on the long-term rate of interest. As we emphasized
above, we do not regard this as a test of Fisher's conclusion since there
is no reason to expect such a one-for-one impact of inflation on the interest rate in an economy in which taxes play such an important role.
Instead, our aim is to estimate the net impact of expected inflation on the
nominal rate of interest in order to assess the effect of inflation on the real
33. Note that if the supply is perfectly inelastic (that is, if the schedule is vertical), the Fisherian result can occur with no shift in supply.
34. The operational specification of expected inflation is discussed below.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

209
82

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1978

cost of capital and the real return to investors. If the supply of loanable
funds for the purchase of bonds were fixed, we would expect the equilibrium interest rate to rise in the same way as the maximum potential
interest rate. In fact, however, the supply schedule is likely to be neither
completely inelastic nor independent of the inflation rate. Without a much
more detailed analysis, we must regard a wide range of inflation impacts
as plausible a priori.
At this stage we focus on the relation between the interest rate and
expected inflation. The next section introduces the effects of changes in
tax and depreciation rules. Since adding the tax variable does not alter
the conclusion about the effect of inflation, we prefer to start with the
simple specification in which we can concentrate on making expected inflation an operational concept.
In all of our analyses, we measure the long-term interest rate by an
average of yields on new issues of high-grade corporate bonds, adjusted
to be comparable to the Aaa rate. 35 The use of new-issue yields is important because seasoned issues with lower coupon rates will also have lower
market yields owing to the more favorable tax treatment of capital gains.
The new-issue yield, however, is influenced by the call-protection feature,
which may make it respond more to inflation rates than it would otherwise.
The expected rate of inflation is defined in terms of the price of consumer goods and services as measured by the deflator of personal consumption expenditures in GNP. In principle, our analysis should recognize that wage rates and the prices of consumption goods, of investment
goods, and of the output of nonfinancial corporations do not move proportionately and would be expected to have different effects on the supply
and demand for investment funds. In practice, it is not possible to include
more than one inflation variable and the choice does not alter the results
in an essential way. We use expectations of the consumption price for
three reasons: ( 1 ) This is the price that should affect household decisions.
(2) Although firms produce investment and intermediary goods, they
also purchase these goods; the consumption price may therefore be a good
approximation of the price of sales by the nonfinancial corporate sector
to the rest of the economy. (3) The future movement of nominal wage
rates may be approximated best by the expected movement in consumer
prices.
35. Data Resources, Inc., made this series available to us.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

210
83

Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

This section develops two approaches to specifying the expected future
rate of inflation. The first uses the familiar distributed lag on past inflation
rates, with the identifying restriction that the weights on past inflation
must sum to one. Recognizing that this restriction may be invalid, we
explore an alternative approach based on a series of separate optimal
forecasts of inflation. In practice, the two approaches lead to very similar
results.
Consider first the distributed-lag approach that has been used ever
since Irving Fisher's own pioneering work on this subject. We posit that
the interest rate (i) is related to expected inflation ( 1r*) according to
(12)

where
(13)
with
T

:z::;
W;
j=O

(14)

= 1.

Substituting equation 13 into equation 12 yields the estimable equation
(15)

it

=

fJo

+

T

/11 :Z::: Wj1Tt-i•
:i=O

The key coefficient {31 is estimable only because of the identifying restriction of equation 14.
Equation 15 was estimated by assuming that the weights on lagged
inflation (that is, ; > 0) satisfy a second-order polynomial and that T
= 16 quarters; the coefficient of the concurrent inflation rate (j =0) was
unconstrained. The basic parameter estimates are presented in equation 16. (The numbers in parentheses here and in the equations that follow are standard errors.)
(16)

it

= 3.05

+ 0.19

(0.17) (0.05)

16

'lrt

+ fJ1 :Z::: Wfll"t-i
i=l

16

/31 :Z::: W; = 0.64.
;-l

(0.06)

Sample period: 1954:1-1976:4; R2 -= 0,82; Durbin-Watson= 0.21.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

211
84

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978
111

The identifying restriction that~ w1 = 1 implies that /31 = 0.83. 88 With
J=O

no inflation, the interest rate would be 3.05 percent; with a sustained
(and hence expected) inflation rate of 6 percent, the nominal interest rate
would rise to 8.03 percent.
Sargent has rightly emphasized that the identifying restriction of equation 14 may be unwarranted. 87 The optimal weights (the w 1 ) depend on
the nature of the process that is being forecast. If the 1rt remain constant
for a long time, it is clearly appropriate that the weights sum to unity and
therefore predict that the same ?Tt will continue. But where the historic
pattern of the ?Tt is more varied, a different set of weights will be optimal.
Dropping the restriction of equation 14 leaves {3 1 in 15 underidentified.
This apparently led Sargent to abandon the estimation of /3 1 and to attempt to test Fisher's conclusion indirectly by examining a rational-expectations model of unemployment. 88 We do not think that so circuitous a
route is necessary, and propose instead to develop an explicit optimal
forecast measure of expected inflation for use as a regressor to estimate
equation 12 directly.
To derive forecasts of inflation rates, we use the optimal ARIMA forecasting procedure of Box and Jenkins. 89 We assume that the forecasts
made at any time are to be based only on the information available at that
time. This requires reestimating a separate Box-Jenkins equation for each
quarter based on the observations available as of that quarter. To relax the
assumption that inflation rates are generated by the same stochastic
process over the entire postwar period, we specify that the ARIMA
process estimated at each date is based only on the most recent ten years
of data. 40 After some preliminary analysis of the data, we selected a first36. That is, 0.64 + 0.19, the latter being the coefficient of ,,-1•
37. See Thomas J. Sargent, "Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest,
and the Natural Rate of Unemployment," BPEA, 2:1973, pp. 429-72.
38. Sargent concludes that his indirect evidence was ambiguous. When taxes are
recognized, even the theoretical link between Sargent's equation and the inflationinterest relation is unclear.
39. In principle, of course, the Box-Jenkins procedure is too restrictive and one
should derive forecasts from a completely specified econometric model. Unfortunately, doing so requires projecting all of the exogenous variables. The more general
procedure that requires estimates of monetary and fiscal policy for many years ahead
would not necessarily yield better forecasts than the simpler Box-Jenkins procedure.
See George E. P. Box and Gwilym M. Jenkins, Time Series Analysis: Forecasting
and Control (Holden-Day, 1970).
40. Since our sample begins in the first quarter of 19S4, it is not appropriate to
use a ten-year history of inflation that stretches back into World War II. The earliest


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

212
8S

Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

order autoregressive and first-order moving-average process. With the
inflation rates measured as deviations from the ten-year sample means,
denoted by 1r, this ARIMA process can be written as
(17)

1T1

=

c/nri-1

+

E1 -

Oei--1,

where Et is a purely random disturbance. Equation 17 was estimated by
the Box-Jenkins procedure for changing samples ending in each quarter
from 1954: 1 through 1976:4. The minimum mean-square-error forecast
of the inflation rate in quarter t + 1 as of quarter tis
(18)

A

'll"t+i

,-cf, -

f

=,1 - OL 1ri,

where Lis the lag operator.
A striking result of these estimates of the predicted inflation rate,
shown in table 4, is the implied change in the sum of the optimal forecast
weights on past inflation rates. 41 Because we assume that inflation rates
follow a stationary process, our specification implies that the optimal
weights always sum to less than one. 42 Until 1970, the implied sum of the
weights was always between 0.30 and 0.40. During the 1970s, the sum
of the weights has risen markedly, from 0.45 in 1970 to 0.55 in 1973 to
0.71 in 1976. Since the mean lag has remained almost constant, the
rapidly rising weights imply an increased sensitivity of the optimal inflation forecast to recent experience. 43 This has potentially important implications for the changing evidence on the "accelerationist hypothesis"
and other issues that we shall not explore in this paper. 44
inflation observation used is the first quarter of 1947; the sample is extended until
a full ten years is available.
41. It follows from equation 18 that, when the process is represented as an autoregressive process, the sum of the weights is ( ¢ - 8) I ( 1 - 8).
42. Recall that our estimates are based on deviations from the sample mean so
that a constant inflation rate would eventually be predicted accurately.
43. The mean lag, 1 / (1 - 8), was approximately 1.4 quarters until 1970 and has
since been between 1.5 and 1.6 quarters.
44. The coefficients of the distributed lag on past inflation have been regarded
as a test of the accelerationist hypothesis that the long-run Phillips curve is vertical.
This implicitly accepts an identifying restriction like our equation 14. The evidence
of an increasing coefficient on lagged inflation might be better interpreted as a
changing relation between past inflation and expected inflation. For evidence of the
increasing coefficients on past inflation in this context, see Robert J. Gordon, "Inflation in Recession and Recovery," BPEA, 1:1971, pp. 105-58, and Otto Eckstein
and Roger Brinner, The lnfiation Process in the United States, A study prepared
for the use of the Joint Economic Committee, 2:92 (Government Printing Office,
1972).


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

213
86

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

The expected inflation rate that affects the long-term interest rate involves a long horizon and not merely the next quarter. We can use equation 18 to calculate iteratively a sequence of inflation rates in future quarters. We define the expected inflation rate 1r~ as the weighted average of
the quarterly predicted inflation rates during the subsequent ten years,
where the weights reflect discounting of future inflation by the interest
rate. Moderate changes in the averaging period would have no appreciable
effect on our analysis. 46
Equation 19 presents the estimated interest-rate equation based on the
optimal inflation forecast:

i,

(19)

= 2.9 + 0.94 11-1.
(0.09)

Sample period: 1954:1-1976:4; .R 2 = 0.53; Durbin-Watson= 0.13.

The estimate of 0.94 is very close to one and certainly not significantly
different. Thus, this estimate, based on an optimal Box-Jenkins forecast
of future inflation, is very similar to the traditional distributed-lag estimate of equation 16.
Forecasting inflation on the basis of past inflation is clearly more appropriate at some times than at others. If the reduction in inflation rates
after the Korean War was properly anticipated, the estimates of expected
inflation based on past inflation rates would be too high for the early years
in table 4. We have therefore reestimated equations 16 and 19 for the
period beginning in 1960. The results are quite similar to the estimates for
the entire sample: the weights sum to 0. 7 5 with the polynomial distributed
lag, and the coefficient is 0.88 when the predicted-inflation variable (1rD
is used.
The very low Durbln-Watson statistics of our estimated equations indicate an extremely high firs!-order autocorrelation of the stochastic
errors. This is just what we would expect in an efficient market for longterm bonds. The change in the long-term interest rate from quarter to
quarter (and therefore the change in the price of the asset) would be expected to depend on changes in such fundamental determinants as the
expected inflation rate with a stochastic disturbance that is serially uncorrelated and that therefore cannot be predicted. This serial independence
45. When we return to explicit analysis of the internal rate of return in the next
section, the inflation forecasts can be incorporated directly into its calculation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

214
Martin Feklstein and Lawrence Summers

87

Table 4. The Long-Term Interest Rate and the Predicted Inflation Rate, 1954-76
Percent
Year

1954
1955
195(;;
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972

Long-term interest Predicted inflation
rate (ic)
rate (11":}

2.9
3.2
3.7
4.4
4.0
4.8
4.7
4.4
4.2
4.2
4.4
4.5
5.4
5.8
6.5
7.7

8.5
7.4
7.2

1973

7.7

1974
1975
1976

9.0
9.0
8.3

2.9
2.7
2.6
2.6
2.2
2.3
2.4
1.9
1. 7
1.7
1.7
1.8

2.0
1.9

2.3
3.1
3.3
3.6
3.2
4.3
8.0
5.2
5.2

Sources: the long-term interest rate is an average of yields on new issues of high-grade corporate bonds
adjusted to the comparable Aaa rate. The series was provided by Data Resources, Inc. The predicted
inflation rate is the weighted (discounted) average of ten years of quarterly Box-~enkins forecasts (lee
text).

in first differences corresponds to the observed high autocorrelation when
the level of the interest rate is the dependent variable. The high autocorrelation of the residuals implies that our method of estimation is inefficient
and that the standard errors are underestimated. We have not, however,
followed the common statistical procedure of estimating the equation in
first-difference form ( or, more generally, after an autoregressive trans.;.
formation) because we believe that doing so would introduce a substantial errors-in-variables bias. Specifically, we recognize that a variable like
1r1 is only an imperfect measure of expected inflation. Because inflation
(and presumably expected inflation) has changed substantially during
our sample period, most of t1!_e variance in the 71'; series will reflect the


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

215
88

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

variance of the true (but unobserved) expected inflation. A relatively
small amount of "noise" will cause a correspondingly small downward
bias in the coefficient of the 'IT~ variable. In contrast, taking the first differences of the 'IT: series would eliminate most of the systematic component of its variance while leaving the measurement error. The result
would be a very substantial bias in the coefficient. In terms of the meansquare error of the estimated coefficient, it is better to accept the inefficiency of ordinary least-squares estimation of the untransformed equation
than to subject the estimates to a much more serious bias.' 6
To explore this view, we did estimate equation 19 with a first-order
autoregressive transformation. The maximum-likelihood procedure implied a serial correlation of 0.99 and parameter estimates as follows:
(20)

i1

= 5.0 + 0.14 'II"~ + 0.99u1-1.

(1.8) (0.08)
Sample period: 1954:1-1976:4; R1 = 0.97; Durbin-Watson

= 1.8.

We regard the very low parameter estimate of 0.14 as an indication of the
relative error variance in the quarterly changes in 'ITi rather than as evidence that the true coefficient of 'IT~ is so low. This conclusion is supported by using an instrumental-variable procedure to estimate equation
19 in first-difference form: 47
(21)

it -

i1-l

= 0.04 + 0.66 ('11"~ - 'll"~-1).
(0.04) (0.22)

Sample period: 1954:1-1976:4; Durbin-Watson = 1.86.

The estimated inflation coefficient of 0.66 ( with a standard error of 0.22)
is much closer to the basic parameter values of equations 16 and 19.
Although our evidence is thus roughly consistent with Irving Fisher's
conclusion that the interest rate rises by the rate of inflation, both the
mechanism and the implications are quite different. The rise in the nominal rate of interest reflects the impact of the tax and depreciation rules.
Although the nominal interest rate rises by approximately the increase in
expected inflation, the net result is far from neutral. For the individual
lender, the rise in the nominal interest rate is sufficient to keep the real
46. As noted in the text, the substantial autocorrelation does, however, imply
that our standard errors are underestimated.
47. The first-difference specifis;:ation is essentially equivalent to the maximumlikelihood transformation of equation 20.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

216
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

89

return before tax unchanged, but implies a sharp fall in the real return
after tax. For example, a lender with a 50 percent marginal tax rate could
find a real net yield of 3 percent in the absence of inflation reduced to zero
by a 6 percent inflation.
Inflation is also not neutral from the firm's point of view. With an increase in the interest rate equal to the increase in inflation, the real net
interest cost to the firm falls substantially. But, as tables 2 and 3 showed,
the potential real net interest rate that the firm can pay also falls. There
is neutrality with respect to the firm and therefore with respect to investment only if the actual rate falls by an equal amount. Equivalently, there
is neutrality only if the actual and potential nominal interest rates rise by
an equal amount. If the first rises by more than the second, the firm must
adjust by reducing investment.

Changes in Tax Rules, Inflation, and Pretax Profitability
We return now to the method of analyzing the effects of changes in tax
rules and inflation rates that was developed in the first section. We extend
this method here to deal with forecasts of changing inflation rates and
with fluctuations in the pretax rates of return.
Our analysis begins by deriving for each quarter between the first quarter of 1954 and the final quarter of 1976 the maximum potential interest
rate that is compatible with our "standard investment" project. For this
calculation we assume that debt finances one-third of the investment. One
series of such internal rates of return is derived on the assumption of a
constant 6 percent risk differential between the pretax yields on debt and
equity. We refer to this variable as MPIR33G to denote a maximum
potential interest rate based on 33 percent debt finance and a gross-of-tax
risk differential. As table 2 showed, changing the risk differential from
6 percent to any other constant would change all of the internal rates of
return only by a constant and would therefore not alter the regression
results; in more formal language, the risk-differential parameter is not
identifiable on the basis of available experience. A second series is derived
on the assumption of a constant 6 percent risk differential between the
net-of-tax yields on debt and equity; we denote this MPIR33N. The riskdifferential parameter is again not identifiable.
Three factors determine the changes in the MPIR variable from quarter


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

217
90

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

to quarter: tax rules, inflation, and pretax profitability. For each quarter
we use the tax rules that were appropriate for that quarter and assume
that they would not be changed during the life of the project. We also use
an optimal Box-Jenkins forecast equation to obtain quarterly forecasts of
inflation rates on the basis of the information then available. The tax rules
and inflation forecasts are combined using the method outlined in the first
section to obtain an estimated internal rate of return.
In performing that operation, it is also appropriate to relax the assumption that the "standard investment" project has the same pretax
profitability in every period. In practice, the actual pretax rates of profit
have experienced substantial gyrations during the past twenty-five years.'8
A permanent rise or fall in the pretax profitability of investment would
cause an equivalent shift in the demand for funds; even a temporary
change could cause some shift. To allow for this possibility, we have also
calculated an MPIR series based on the assumption that the pretax internal rate of return is not a constant 12 percent but varies from quarter
to quarter.''
Our analysis of changing profitability is based on the series for the "net
profit rate" developed in our previous paper. This rate is measured as the
ratio of corporate profits before tax plus interest payments to the sum of
fixed capital, inventories, and land. The data relate to nonfinancial corporations and are corrected for changes in the price level. Both profits
and capital stock are net of the Commerce Department estimate of economic depreciation. We have interpolated the annual series to obtain
quarterly figures.
It would be incorrect to assume that firms extrapolate short-run variations in profitability to the entire life of their investments. We posit instead
that the demand for funds is based on a cyclically adjusted value of profitability. Specifically, we follow our earlier analysis of profitability and relate the profit rate to the concurrent rate of capacity utilization. We then
use this equation to estimate the profit rate that would be expected in each
quarter if the capacity utilization were a standard 83.1 percent, the average for the sample period. This cyclically adjusted profit rate is then used
to recalibrate the maximum potential interest rate for each quarter. We
use the suffix AP to denote a variable expressing the internal rate of return
48. See Feldstein and Summers, ..Is the Rate of Profit Falling?"
49. This is equivalent to changing the parameter a0 of equation 1 each quarter
to recalibrate the pretax rate of return.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

218
91

Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

Table s. Values of Maximum Potential Interest Rate for Standard Investment
Project, 1954-76"
Percent

Constant pretax
profitability
Year

MPIR33G

MPIR33N

1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960

5.7
5.9
6.0
5.5
6.0
6.1
6.1
6.0
6.4
6.5
7.1
7.3
7.3
7.2
6.9
6.5
6.8
7.4
7.7
7.9
8.4
8.3
8.2

5.4
5.6
5.7
5.9
5.7
5.8
5.8
5.6
6.0
6.2
6.8
7.2
7.1
7.1
6.7
6.4
6.9
7.6
7.9
8.3
9.6
9.0
8.8

1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976

Varying pretax
profitability
MPIR33GAP

MPIR33NAP

4.6
5.3
4.1
4.0
4.2
5.0
4.6

4.1
4.9
3.5
3.3
3.5
4.5
4.0

4.9
5.8
6.1
7.0
7.4
6.8
6.2
5.7
4.2
3.9
4.9
5.0
3.8
2.7
5.2
4.8

4.3
5.3
5.7
6.7
7.2
6.6
5.9
5.3
3.7
3.4
4.6
4.6
3.5
2.8
5.2
4.8

Source: Derived by method explained in the text.
a. All MPIR variables are based on debt financing for one-third of the investment and risk differentials
of 6 percent. See text for definitions of the symbols.

that has been adjusted for variations in profitability; thus MPIR33NAP
is the MPIR variable that is based on a risk differential net of tax and that
has a varying profitability.
Table 5 shows the four MPIR variables corresponding to differentials
gross of tax and net of tax and to fixed and varying profitability. Note that
differences in the average level reflect the risk differential. Variations over
time within each series are therefore more important than differences
among the series.
These MPIR values can now be used to estimate how tax changes


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

219
92

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

affect the actual long-term rate of interest. If the supply of funds to the
nonfinancial corporate sector were completely inelastic, the actual interest rate would be expected to rise by the same amount as the MPIR.
In the traditional language of public finance, the full effect of changes in
the tax rules would then be borne by capital in the corporate sector. More
generally, however, the supply of capital to the nonfinancial corporate
sector is not fixed but is an increasing function of the nominal rate of interest. The elasticity of the supply of funds to nonfinancial corporate
business and the elasticity of the demand for funds by those firms together
determine how much a tax-induced shift in the demand for funds raises
the return to capital. For a given demand elasticity, the effect on the equilibrium interest rate of a shift in demand varies inversely with the elasticity of supply. The greater the supply elasticity, the greater will be the
increase in corporate investment relative to that in the rate of interest.
Although an estimate of the elasticity of supply of funds to the nonfinancial corporate sector is not available, the relative magnitude of the
funds raised by this sector is informative. Between 1970 and 1975, the
funds raised in credit markets by all nonfinancial sectors totaled $1,029
billion. 50 Of this, corporate bonds accounted for only $107 billion. The
total funds raised by corporations, including bank borrowing and mortgages as well as bonds, totaled $334 billion, or only about one-third of
total funds raised. The obligations of state and local governments alone
accounted for $89 billion; net borrowing for residential mortgages was
$253 billion. It is clear that fluctuations in the demand for borrowed
funds by corporations due to changes in tax rules and productivity may
be small relative to the total flow of funds in credit markets. The potential
supply of long-term lending from abroad and the elasticity of financial
saving with respect to the real rate of interest strengthen this conclusion.
Although a more extensive analysis of this issu~ would be desirable, these
crude figures do suggest that the elasticity of supply of funds to the corporate sector may be substantial. If so, the effect of changes in MPIR on
the actual interest rate will be correspondingly small.
In using the MPIR variable to estimate the effect on the interest rate
of the shifts in the demand for funds induced by tax changes, it is important to adjust for the concurrent shifts in supply caused by changes in
expected inflation. To control for such changes in the interest rate, our
SO. The statistics in this paragraph are from the Flow of Funds Accounts of the
Federal Reserve System.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

220
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

93

regression equation relates the interest rate to the expected rate of inflation ('II'*) as well as to the appropriate MPIR variable: 31
(22)

The coefficient of the MPIR variable can therefore measure the net effect
of tax changes; in terms of the last diagram, this net effect is (i4 - i0 ) /
(i1 - i0 ) , or the ratio of the change in the interest rate that would occur
with a fixed supply curve of funds ( i4 - i0 ) to the change that would occur
if that supply were perfectly inelastic (i1 - i0 ). 52 The total impact of an
increase of 1 percentage point in the expected rate of inflation can be
calculated as the sum of ( 1) the coefficient of the expected inflation variable, a 2 , and (2) the product of the coefficient of the MPIR variable and
the value of dMPIR/d'II' implied by calculations leading to table 2.
Although time is required to change investment and thereby to alter
the equilibrium return on investment, the prices of bonds and stocks can
adjust very quickly to reflect this eventual long-run equilibrium. A failure
to adjust quickly would otherwise provide opportunities for profitable
speculation. We therefore specify that the interest rate adjusts to changes
in MPIR within the quarter.
The estimated coefficients of equation 22 for each of the concepts of
MPIR are presented in table 6. Note first that the evidence favors the less
restricted polynomial distributed-lag specification of shifting inflation
expectations ( equations 6-1 to 6-4) over the Box-Jenkins forecast ( equations 6-5 to 6-8). 58 We will therefore concentrate our comments on the
results based on the former specification and return to the remaining equations afterward. It is not possible to choose between the gross-risk-dif51. Our analysis uses both the polynomial distributed-lag specification and the
variable constructed from Box-Jenkins forecasts. Factors other than inflation also
shift the supply of funds available to the nonfinancial corporate sector: ( 1 ) shifts
in saving behavior; (2) shifts in liquidity preference; and (3) shifts in the demand
for funds by governments, by the rest of the world, and by investors in residential
real estate. Although none of these shifts is likely to be caused by the changes in the
tax rates that shift the demand by nonfinancial corporate business, we cannot be
certain that the shifts in supply that are not caused by inflation are uncorrelated
with our explanatory variables.
52. This method assumes that the response of the interest rate to a change in the
demand function is the same regardless of the cause of the shift-tax rules, inflation,
and pretax profitability.
53. This may reflect the fact that the MPIR variable already contains the BoxJenkins inflation forecast.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

~

"'
"'..,'

Table 6. Effects of Changes in Taxation and Inflation on the Long-Term Interest Rate"

0

0

Independent variable

..,'

Summary statistic

<0

;;;

11

Equation and
concept of MP/Rb

6-1

MPIR33G

6-2 MPIR33GAP
6-3 MPIR33N
6-4 MPIR33NAP

6-5 MPIR33G
6-6 MPIR33GAP
6-7 MPIR33N
6-8 MPIR33NAP

Inflation rate
Constant

MPIR

0.53
(0.84)
1.99
(0.56)
1.38
(0. 79)
2.39
(0.45)
-3.53
(-0.96)
0.97
(1.07)
-2.54
(-0. 76)
1.44
(0.83)

0.43
(0.14)
0.18
(0.09)
0.32
(0.14)
0.12
(0.07)
1.13
(0.16)
0.30
(0.16)
1.10
(0.14)
0.25
(0.13)

...,

0.15
(0.05)
0.23
(0.05)
0.14
(0.06)
0.21
(0.05)

~r,_,
I

Predicted
inflation rate
r•

0.54
(0.07)
0.65
(0.06)
0.53
(0.08)
0.64
(0.06)

Watson

Implied
inflation
effect"

0.83

0.24

1.11

0.82

0.25

1.05

0.82

0.19

1.10

0.82

0.24

1.01

0.69

0.28

1.61

0.54

0.15

1.38

0.71

0.16

1.72

0.54

0.14

1-.37

R•

Durbin-

t.:)

0.52
(0.10)
1.09
(0.11)
0.25
(0.12)
1.04
(0.10)

Source: Text equation 22.
a. The dependent variable in all equations la the long-term interest rate. All equadons are estimated for 1954: 1 to 1976: 4. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.
b. Defined in the text.
c. The implied inflation effect Is the sum of (1) the inflation coefficients and (2) the product of the MPIR coefficient and dMPIR/dr for regime G In tables 2 and 3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

~

~

222
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

95

ferential concept of MPIR (equations 6-1 and 6-2) and the net-riskdifierential concept ( 6-3 and 6-4) on the basis of the goodness of fit of
the equations. 64 Similarly, the evidence does not favor either the MPIR
variable based on constant pretax profitability ( 6-1 and 6-3) or that based
on changing profitability. Fortunately, the same basic conclusions are
implied by all four specifications.
First, a shift in the demand for funds appears to raise the long-term
interest rate by approximately one-fourth of the increase in the MPIR; a
rise of 100 basis points in MPIR would thus raise the long-term interest
rate by approximately 25 basis points. 56 This indicates that the supply
of funds to the corporate sector is quite elastic. Apparently, investment
incentives aimed at the corporate sector do raise investment rather than
dissipating because of offsetting increases in the return to debt and equity
capital. In terms of the third diagram, the estimate implies that i, - i0 is
only about one-fourth of i1 - i0 because the expansion of corporate investment reduces the pretax rate of return on investment.68
The extent to which the increase in corporate investment represents an
increase in total national investment depends on the offsetting effect of
the high~r interest rate. If the total supply of investable funds were fixed,
traditional investment incentives would succeed only in transferring investment to corporate business from other sectors, such as homebuilding.
But the supply of investable funds is not fixed. Total investment can increase because savings rise, the net international capital flow to the United
States increases, or the government reduces its deficit. Indeed, a principal
rationale for investment incentives has been to maintain aggregate demand with a smaller government deficit. The effect of tax-induced changes
in MPIR on total national investment requires an analysis that goes beyond the current framework.
The present study can also provide only partial information about the
54. The .R. 2 values are extremely close; although this is not itself an accurate
guide in the presence of high serial correlation, the Durbin-Watson statistic and the
.R 2 together imply that the evidence offers little basis for choice between the models.
55. The point estimates vary between 0.12 with MPIRJ3NAP and 0.43 with
MPIR33G.
56. Robert E. Hall and Dale W. Jorgenson are not far from the truth in their
assumption that the interest rate remains constant when tax incentives vary; to the
extent that their assumption is wrong, they overstate the tax-induced changes in the
desired capital stock. See their "Tax Policy and Investment Behavior," American
Economic Review, vol. 57 (June 1967), pp. 391-414.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

223
96

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1978

incidence of changes in the corporate tax rules. The estimate that a 1 is
approximately 0.25 suggests that only a small part of the increase in
MPIR is shifted to the corporate bondholder. The more general question
of the extent to which the incidence of the tax change is shifted from
capital in general to labor cannot be answered accurately on the basis of
current information. The answer depends on the change in the return to
capital outside the corporate sector and on the share of the corporate
sector in the total capital stock. Consider, for example, a change in the
corporate tax that implies an increase of 100 basis points in MPIR and
that causes a rise of 25 basis points in the long-term bond rate. If the
return to all other forms of capital also increased by 25 basis points and
if corporate capital accounted for one-third of the total privately owned
capital stock, 75 percent of the benefit of the tax change would fall on
capital and 25 percent on labor. 67 Since corporate bonds and other securities are not perfect substitutes, it would probably be more reasonable to
assume that the average rise in the yield on capital is less than 25 basis
points. This in tum would imply that capital as a whole bears less than
75 percent of the effect of stimulative changes in corporate tax rules. The
remainder would be shifted to labor through the higher productivity and
wages that result from increased investment. This estimate must be regarded as preliminary and subject to substantial error.
The estimated effect of changes in expected inflation support the conclusion of the second section that the long-term bond rate rises by approximately the same amount as the increase in inflation. Although the
corporate MPIR variable rises by about one-fifth more than the increase
in inflation, the effect of inflation on the supply of funds to the corporate
sector implies that the net change is smaller than this. In terms of the last
diagram, if the investment-demand schedule is shifted by inflation alone,
i 1 - i0 would exceed 1r. But i 1 - i0 is found to be approximately equal to
1r, which implies that inflation substantially reduces the real net return to
lenders.
We turn finally to the estimates of equations 6-5 to 6-8, which use the
Box-Jenkins variable to indicate shifts in the supply of funds. These equations provide a less satisfactory explanation of variations in the interest
57. More generally, the share of a corporate tax change that is borne by capital
in general equals the rise in the average return to capital (relative to the change in
MPIR) divided by the corporate share of the capital stock.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

224
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

97

rate. The results are also quite sensitive to whether MPIR is adjusted for
changes in profitability. With no such adjustment, the results are quite
unsatisfactory. 58 In contrast with the cyclically adjusted MPIR variable
( equations 6-6 and 6-8), the results are very similar to the estimates
based on the distributed-lag specification of inflation. Moreover, when
these equations are estimated in first-difference form (using instrumentalvariable estimation) the parameter values are quite stable. The coefficient
of MPIR33GAP is 0.53 (with a standard error of 0.44) and the coefficient of 71"e is 0.96 (0.57); with MPIR33NAP, the corresponding coefficients are 0.31 (0.27) and0.91 (0.46).
To examine the possibility that the long-term interest rate responds to
cyclical conditions directly, we reestimated the equations of table 6 with
capacity utilization as an additional variable. In general, its coefficient
was small and statistically insignificant. In one key specification, corresponding to equation 6-2, the capacity-utilization variable was significantly positive (implying that an increase of 1 percentage point in capacity utilization has the direct effect of raising the long-term interest rate by
5 basis points) and the coefficient of the MPIR variable was reduced to
0.07 with a standard error of 0.10. This suggests a further reason for caution in interpreting the point estimates of the coefficient of the MPIR
variable but supports the conclusion that the actual interest rate is changed
very little by tax-induced shifts in the maximum potential rate of interest.
Obviously, the estimates presented in this section must be treated as
preliminary and regarded with caution. However, they offer no grounds
for rejecting the conclusion of the second section that an increase in the
rate of inflation causes an approximately equal increase in the nominal
pretax interest rate. This conclusion supports the analytic results of the
first section that the tax deductibility of interest payments just about offsets the historic-cost method of depreciation. Finally, the results of this
section suggest that the supply of funds to the nonfinancial corporate sector is elastic enough to make a tax-induced change in the maximum potential interest rate cause a substantially smaller change in the actual interest
rate.
58. The coefficients of the MPIR variables in equations 6-S and 6-7 are both
unreasonably high. When these equations are estimated in first-difference form
(using instrumental-variable estimation) the MPIR coefficients become very small
and statistically insignificant.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

225
98

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

Conclusion
The primary emphasis of this paper has been on the interaction of
taxes and inflation in determining the interest rate on long-term bonds.
The current U.S. tax system makes the impact of inflation much more
complex than it was in Irving Fisher's time. The basic Fisherian conclusion that anticipated inflation has no effect on real variables is no longer
correct.
We began our analysis by calculating the interest rate that a firm can
pay on a "standard investment" project if its investment is :financed onethird by debt and two-thirds by equity. The deduction of interest payments in calculating taxable income implies that this maximum potential
interest rate rises by more than the rate of inflation. Offsetting this is the
use of historic-cost depreciation, which makes the MPIR rise less than
the rate of inflation. On balance, we find that the maximum potential interest rate rises by approximately the same amount as the rate of inflation,
with the sign of the difference depending on the assumption about the
relation between debt and equity yields.
Our econometric estimates of the relation between inflation and the
long-term interest rate confirm that the nominal rate rises by approximately the rate of inflation. This implies that the real interest rate net of
tax available to investors is reduced dramatically by inflation. For example, an investor who pays a 50 percent marginal tax. rate will find that
a real net-of-tax return that is 2 percent in the absence of inflation vanishes
when there is a 4 percent rate of inflation.
The fall in the real net rate of interest received by investors also corresponds to a fall in the real net cost of debt capital to firms. It is wrong,
however, to regard this as a major stimulus to investment. The analysis
of the first section shows that an inflation-induced fall in the real net-oftax rate of interest at which firms can borrow is not a stimulus to investment because, given the tax and depreciation rules, inflation also reduces
by about as much the maximum real net-of-tax interest rate that they can
afford to pay on a standard investment.
Although our analysis has emphasized the interaction between taxes
and inflation, we have also been interested in the effects of corporate tax
changes themselves. The results of the first section showed that the
changes in tax rates and depreciation rules during the past twenty-five


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

226
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

99

years would, in the absence of inflation, have increased the maximum interest rate that firms could afford by about 2 percentage points. Our
econometric estimates in the third section suggest that the elasticity of the
supply of funds to purchase corporate debt is great enough that the interest rate actually rises by only about one-fourth of the potential increase'
induced by changes in corporate rules. The tax changes that were designed to stimulate corporate investment were therefore not offset by the
resulting increases in the interest rate.
We believe that we have a useful analytic method for studying the
effect of alternative tax rules. By translating the changes in tax rules and
inflation into corresponding changes in the maximum rate that firms can
pay for capital, we can study the changes in investment incentives and in
the response of market yields. We plan to extend our analysis to include
a more general model of corporate finance and to study a wider range of
problems.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

227

Comments and
Discussion
William J. Fellner: The paper before us has the merit of analyzing a problem that clearly deserves more attention than it has received: the dependence of Fisherian conclusions on Fisherian assumptions. We should
appreciate the opportunity of giving consideration to this problem.
My comments on specific elements of the argument may turn out to be
overly critical, because it is so much easier to express reservations about
the results of this type of research than to perform it. The gist of my
criticism is that, after carrying us through many combinations of a large
number of individual assumptions, the paper never gets rid of assumptions that eliminate some of the most essential real-world properties of
the problem.
To begin by accentuating the positive, I think the authors are quite
right in stressing that, with a nonindexed tax structure and with deductible
interest costs, we should reject the proposition that the money rate of
interest will generally tend to rise by the number of basis points expressing the expected rate of inflation. This Fisherian relation depends, of
course, on specific assumptions; for example, it does not take account of
the shifting of part of the increased nominal interest cost from the borrower to the Treasury, through the deductibility of that cost from the
borrower's taxable income. Nor is the Fisherian proposition intended to
take account of various other complicating factors. Hence, as the authors
rightly suggest, in our world the Fisherian relation can be expected to hold
only when offsetting forces happen to be at work in the right proportions.
We do need to think the problem through on modified assumptions.
However, to my mind, the minimum complexity that useful modified
assumptions would have to accommodate to preserve essential aspects of
the problem would reflect the recognition that expectations are not single100


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

228
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

101

valued. There is variance (dispersion) about the mean value of expectations concerning the inflation rate as well as concerning other variables.
These characteristics of the expectational system are disregarded in the
paper's conclusion that the bond rate borrowers feel they can afford to
pay for an unchanging amount of loans will rise by twice the number of
basis points expressing the expected rate of inflation. This is the conclusion of the authors for a 50 percent corporate income tax and deductible
interest, and neglecting at this point the distorting effect of depreciation
rules and of changing tax credits. As the authors realize, this conclusion
implies that borrowers fail to react to the observed substantial variance
about the actual inflation rates.
Let us be somewhat more specific and assume in a first step that, in
accordance with the Fisherian relation, the bond rate does rise by precisely the equivalent of the expected inflation; and let us assume in the
next analytical step that when this Fisherian-type relation holds the borrowers are paying less interest for a given amount of loans than they think
they can afford to pay, because they are gaining back 50 percent of the
increase in nominal interest cost through deductibility. Accepting the
qualification Feldstein and Summers make concerning depreciation rules
and changes in investment credits and the like, this reasoning should put
us on the way to concluding along their lines that, for an unchanging
amount of loans, the borrowers will tum out to bid up the nominal interest rate by twice the equivalent of the expected inflation rate.
But are we really on the way to that conclusion? In the first place, borrowers are apt to have nonlinear utility functions and to be strongly influenced by the possibility that the actual inflation rate may not be the same
as its probabilistically "expected" value. Hence the "expected" inflation
rate--or, with a 50 percent tax, twice the expected rate--is not the sole
relevant determinant of the inflation-induced change in the bidding behavior of borrowers who are likely to be risk averse. Not only does the
public know that the actual inflation rate may tum out to be different from
the "expected" rate, but in inflationary circumstances the risk that other
relevant variables will deviate from their probabilistically expected values
would also be apt to increase, even if the debt-equity ratios of the borrower remained unchanged. Further, and equally important, by way of
simplification the paper admittedly disregards the increase of the risks
perceived by the borrowers when, as a result of a sufficiently elastic loansupply function, the debt-equity ratios rise, as they typically do under in-


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

229
102

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

flationary conditions. My conclusioq thus is that even aside from the
authors' explicit qualifications concerning depreciation rules and changing tax incentives, we have no good reason to accept the hypothesis of a
rise in money interest on a given amount of loans by about twice the expected inflation rate.
I would plead ignorance even about whether, quite aside from depreciation rules and changing tax incentives, the money rate would tend to
rise more or less than is suggested by the "Fisherian" relation. In my appraisal, assuming away the problem of shifts between long- and shortterm funds worsens the difficulties of relating the Feldstein-Summers
analysis to reality. To become manageable, a problem of this complexity
does, of course, have to be simplified; but I believe that the kind of conceptual simplification adopted in this analysis buries too much of what
jumps to the eye in the real world.
As for the empirical tests performed and discussed by the authors,
these are intended to demonstrate that influences tending to taise the
money interest rate by more than the equivalent of expected inflation have
been roughly offset by opposing influences. The Fisherian relation does
therefore appear to hold by and large, but in our environment not for the
reasons Fisher regarded as relevant on his assumptions. I must admit that
I have remained unconvinced by the argument that these tests have come
out reasonably well. This is only partly because my nontechnical ( common-sense) judgment tells me that many of the residuals listed in the
paper are disturbingly large. It is also partly because I do not follow the
reasoning of the authors according to which we should acquiesce in the
finding that one way of performing a test involves an error in variables,
while other ways of performing it reveal other significant deficiencies of
the results.
As a reader and a di~cussant who has expressed a number of reservations, I want to add that a paper as intriguing and thought-provoking as
the one before us performs a very useful function.

Robert J. Gordon: The Feldstein-Summers paper deals with questions of
great concern for policy. The United States is entering its third year of
inflation at a relatively constant and well-predicted rate. Traditional economic analysis attaches quite small welfare costs to a steady and fully
anticipated inflation, but this analysis is valid only in the absence of taxation, or in the special case of a tax system that is completely neutral with


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

230
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

103

respect to inflation. The paper attempts to quantify the degree of nonneutrality in the present U.S. tax system. It shows convincingly that a
steady inflation, no matter how well anticipated, substantially reduces the
real after-tax return to savers, distorts the incentives for both investment
and saving, and results in a continuing redistribution of income from
savers to the government.
In the absence of taxation, and with an inelastic supply of loanable
funds, anticipated inflation would raise the nominal interest rate and leave
the real interest rate unchanged. With neutral taxation, the real after-tax
interest rate would remain unchanged while the nominal before-tax rate
earned on investment projects would increase by the rate of inflation times
1/ ( 1 - T). If the total tax on capital (.,.) is SO percent, then an acceleration of 5 percentage points in inflation, such as the United States has had
since the early 1960s, would raise the nominal interest rate by 10 percentage points. That large a rise obviously has not occurred, and as a consequence real after-tax returns on bonds for savers have fallen substantially.
That would create only a minor problem if corporations were financed
entirely by debt, due to the deductibility of interest payments. This is the
case laid out in table 1. The source of the nonneutrality arises from the
interaction of three features of the tax system: the corporation income
tax levied on the nominal (rather than real) returns on equity; the double
impact of the personal income tax, which further taxes nominal equity
returns paid out as dividends; and the historical-cost basis for depreciation, which reduces the tax saving yielded by depreciation deductions as
compared to replacement-cost accounting.
In the first section of their paper the authors have developed a potentially useful method for analyzing the effect of inflation and alternative
tax systems on before-tax and after-tax returns. Unfortunately, as it
stands, the paper provides only a preliminary application of the method.
It devotes excessive attention to the second-order effects of minor changes
in tax rules while ignoring the first-order effect introduced by the artificial
assumption that the risk premium on equities is both large and fixed.
The risk premium, which inserts a large wedge between the real yields
on equities and bonds, is the most important factor accounting for the low
(and sometimes negative) after-tax real yields on bonds received by
savers reported in tables 2 and 3. A paradox emerges: savers are willing
to put up with a negative real rate of return on bonds, because bonds are
so desirable! All an investor has to do to avoid a negative real after-tax


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

231
104

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 :1978

yield is to switch from bonds to a diversified portfolio of equities. In all
the examples such a switch results in a positive after-tax real return. Can
we really ignore the endogeneity of the risk premium between bonds and
equities? Surely, the Feldstein-Summers story represents only the first
stage of an adjustment process. Savers would react to a succession of
negative real after-tax returns on bonds and substantial positive real aftertax returns on equities by reevaluating the exogenous and arbitrary equitybond yield gap. In the standard mean-variance framework for portfolio
analysis, the extra risk investors are willing to accept on the risky asset
depends on the net mean return on the portfolio, which in this case is
reduced by inflation when the tax system is nonneutral.
Not only should the risk differential properly be treated as endogenous,
but a question can be raised about the large value assumed for the fixed
risk differential in the paper. The yield gap between stock dividends and
bond interest shifted from a premium to a discount in the 1960s. While
the authors do not offer any empirical support for the values of the risk
premium that they have assumed, any attempt to calculate a historical
average would be extremely sensitive to the sample period used for the
calculation ( that is, the fractions of the sample made up of the premium
years of the 1950s and the discount years of the 1960s).
Tables 2 and 3 present alternative results for a risk premium applied,
respectively, to before-tax and after-tax yields. But no allowance is made
for the shift in the composition of bondholders from those subject to high
tax rates to those subject to low ones. As inflation raises taxable nominal
yields, there is an increased incentive for taxpayers in high tax brackets
to shift to tax-free municipal bonds, and thus for tax-free institutions to
hold a higher fraction of corporate bonds. Nor is any explicit account
taken of the loss-offset provisions that make the variance component of
the equity yield essentially tax free.
The second section of the paper contains a number of regressions of
the nominal interest rate on various estimates of the expected inflation
rate, designed to test whether the response of the nominal interest rate to
inflation has been unity, in which case the taxation of nominal yields
would have caused a decline in real after-tax returns. This section is only
weakly related to the first section of the paper, and in fact is contradicted
byit.
After an extended demonstration of the impact of inflation on the real
interest rate, the authors present regressions in which the real interest rate


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

232
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

105

is constrained to be constant, thus introducing a specification error. The
influence of the balance of commodity and money demand on the real
interest rate (the "IS-LM effect") is also neglected, despite its important
role in earlier work by Feldstein in collaboration with Otto Eckstein and
Gary Chamberlain. The first of these specification errors is corrected in
the third section of the paper, but not the second error.
The alternative estimates of the expected inflation rate all neglect an
important criticism previously directed at attempts to capture expectations by techniques that use only past values of the variable to be forecast.
The purely autoregressive source of information in both the adaptive and
ARIMA variants in the paper excludes additional information possessed
by economic agents. As a particularly dramatic example, purely autoregressive expectations of inflation in 1947-48 would have yielded very
high positive forecasts, whereas the Livingston survey ( of academic, business, and labor economists) indicated that a substantial deflation was
actually expected. Actual forecasts took account of the special information that a war had just concluded, and the experience of 1919-21 was
regarded as more relevant than that of the immediately preceding years
and quarters. 1
The autoregressive method used by the authors overestimates expected
inflation in the pre-1959 period by attaching weights estimated from the
post-1959 era to the actual inflation experience of the Korean War and
the 1956-57 period, both of which were treated at the time by the Livingston panel as unique and transitory. While the 1960s pose no problems,
with the autoregressive and Livingston estimates in the same range, difficulties with "special knowledge" arise in the 1970s. The measured price
indexes on which the authors base their autoregressive estimates contain
major sources of variance that were clearly perceived at the time as transitory (particularly the wage-price controls and the food and oil shocks)
and that would not have been incorporated into ten-year price forecasts.
The result in table 4 that the expected rate of inflation over a ten-year
horizon jumped from 3 percent in 1972 to 8 percent in 1974 is thus highly
dubious.
1. I have previously pointed out that failure to make special allowances for
World War I invalidates virtually all previous studies of the inflation-interest rate
"Gibson paradox" for the pre-1930 period. See Robert I. Gordon, "Interest Rates
and Prices in the Long Run: A Comment," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
vol. S (February 1973), pt. 2, pp. 460-63.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

233
106

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I :1978

While the third section of the paper corrects one source of misspecification of the interest-rate equations, by allowing the nominal interest rate
to depend on an internal-rate-of-return construct, the other sources of
misspecification remain and help to explain why the Durbin-Watson statistics in table 6 are so poor. While specification problems may introduce
several sources of bias into table 6, one particular bias is suggested by the
discrepancy between the autoregressive and Livingston estimates of expected inflation in the 1950s. Imagine that the "true" expected inflation
rate in the 1950s was close to zero, rather than in the 2.5 percent range
estimated in table 4. Then the computer would not be forced to explain
the increase in the nominal interest rate between the 1950s and 1960s by
the rising MPIR variable (the MPIR33G and MPIR33N variants), and
would be able to raise the coefficient on expected inflation and reduce the
coefficient on MPIR. By this argument, the high MPIR coefficients for
equations 6-1 and 6-3 of table 6 are probably biased upward, and the
inflation coefficients are probably biased downward.
Two broader issues are suggested by the paper and deserve further discussion and research. Do savers really equate the after-tax real rate of
return on bonds ( and savings accounts) with the after-tax real return net
of risk premium on equities? In recent years both of these have been negative, if the paper's assumptions about risk premiums are correct. Yet Feldstein elsewhere has made the standard classical economic assumption that
"as a first approximation, everyone equates his rate of time discount to
the net of tax rate of return that he receives." Who are these savers who
currently have a negative rate of time discount? My own conjecture is that
savers are currently willing to hold assets bearing a negative real net-oftax return because unanticipated inflation has thrown their actual real
wealth out of balance with their desired reai wealth. In order to recover
the desired level of real wealth needed to smooth lifetime consumption,
wealth is still being accumulated. In fact, this positive response of saving
to unanticipated inflation may help to explain why the personal saving
rate was substantially higher in the first half of the 1970s than in the
1960s. And, since it is a disequilibrium phenomenon (which may persist
for some time if people choose to regain their desired wealth level gradually), it does not rule out the equality of the rate of time discount with
the net-of-tax real return as a condition of full steady-state equilibrium.
Finally, the nonneutrality of the tax system·with respect to inflation
points to crucial policy implications that go beyond the scope of the paper.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

234
Martin Feldstein.and Lawrence Summers

107

The United States is currently experiencing a steady inflation that is both
well anticipated and highly resistant to deceleration (by either recession
or jawboning). By failing to place any stress at all on tax reforms that
would eliminate the nonneutral features of the present system (particularly the taxation of nominal rather than real yields), the administration
is condemning the U.S. economy to continued distortion of investment
and saving decisions. The paper strongly implies ( even if it does not state
outright) that a substantial portion of fiscal dividends over the next decade
should be devoted to elimination of the overtaxation of the nominal yield
on investment projects.

General Discussion
A number of discussants expressed reservations about the simplifying
assumptions adopted by Feldstein and Summers. John Shoven was particularly concerned about the assumed fixity of the marginal debt-equity
ratio. The analysis in the paper itself showed that inflation raises the cost
of equity relative to debt; hence the proportion of debt :financing should
be expected to expand in an inflationary period.
Agreeing with Fellner's comments, Shoven also was critical of the assumption of a fixed risk premium between equity and debt securities.
Thomas Juster elaborated on this point, arguing that higher inflation rates
had increased variances, as people perceived them. The greater uncertainty led investors to pay a higher price not just for safety but for flexibility as well. Juster also cautioned R. J. Gordon to bear in mind that the
price expectations of the Livingston panel registered the views of professional economic forecasters-which might be quite different from the
inflation expectations of key investors.
Arthur Okun was concerned about the assumed constancy of the mix
between equipment and structures. The net effects of the tax system'.s "underdepreciation" and "overdeduction of interest" during inflation are
favorable for long-lived assets, as the analysis of the paper suggested.
Judging by that element alone, a shift toward structures should have been
expected in the seventies. In fact, corporate investment seems to have
shifted toward equipment and away from structures, perhaps because of
increased risk, an element ignored in the model in the paper.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

235
108

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1978

R. A. Gordon sought some disaggregation of the nonfinancial corporate sector. He thought it important to distinguish, for example, between
utilities, which rely primarily upon external debt financing, and manufacturing firms, which are financed principally by their retained earnings.
William Poole suggested that the careful analysis by the authors of
considerations affecting corporate demands for funds should be replicated
for the supply side. It would have to conside~ tax shelters, retirement saving, and the like. Benjamin Friedman elaborated on the need for a more
detailed supply-side analysis. The suppliers of long-term debt capital to
the corporate sector are primarily tax-exempt investors, such as pension
funds, nonprofit organizations, and the reserve accounts of life insurance
companies. The supply of equity finance, in contrast, comes from sources
that are subject to income taxation. George von Furstenberg noted that
the supply of funds to corporations depended on the interaction of taxation and inflation and on the returns to residential capital, consumer durables, and other noncorporate real assets.
Other comments focused on the econometric results in the latter sections of the paper. Christopher Sims insisted that the values near unity
of the coefficients on expected inflation in the interest-rate equations of
the second section should be considered descriptive, rather than structural. He considered it equally sensible to reverse the dependent and independent variables. He pointed to one equation in which such a reversal
led to a coefficient of expected inflation on nominal interest rates of 2
rather than 1; moreover, with a correction for serial correlation, the implied coefficient would be 4. In light of these illustrative calculations, Sims
saw a wide range of uncertainty surrounding this coefficient. He also
doubted the structural character of the equations in the final section that
included MPIR, since that variable might be endogenous.
Saul Hymans noted that the econometric analysis was conducted on
the implicit assumption that the rate of inflation was the only systematic
factor shifting the supply of funds to corporations. He regarded this as
implausible and inappropriate, even for a first approximation of coefficient values.
Robert Hall was unconvinced by the authors' rationale for not correcting for serial correlation. He was also critical of the use of the fitted values
from the regression equations on price expectations as variables in the
interest-rate equations; he noted that such a procedure understated the
standard errors.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

236
Martin Feldstein and Lawrence Summers

109

While the participants had many reservations about specific aspects
of the paper, several congratulated the authors for their pioneering efforts.
Von Furstenberg predicted that the article would become a standard entry
on the reading list of graduate courses in public finance. Okun felt that
the introduction of the debt-equity constraint on corporate financing
achieved an important qualitative improvement in the Fisherian analysis.
Feldstein responded to several issues raised in the discussion. In response to Fellner, he stressed that only under very special assumptionshistoric-cost depreciation and full debt financing-would the interest
rate be raised by twice the equivalent of the exp~cted inflation rate. Under
more realistic assumptions, as tables 2 and 3 demonstrated, inflation
would raise interest rates about point for point. In general, he noted that
the main flavor of the reservations expressed by participants was that the
model in the paper had too many simplifying assumptions-in effect,
it was not sufficiently complicated. He found this criticism somewhat
ironic, since the paper did introduce substantially more complexity into
the Fisherian framework by taking account of taxes in general and specific
provisions of the tax law, by distinguishing between debt and equity financing, and by allowing for risk premiums. He hoped that the paper provided
a framework for subsequent analysis and research to make the debt-equity
ratio and the debt-equity yield differentials endogenous, to disaggregate
demands by types of corporations and types of assets, and to deal with
the supply of funds in a more sophisticated way.
Summers joined Feldstein in explaining that they viewed the initial set
of simple regression equations relating the interest rate to expected inflation as a bridge from the traditional Fisherian equations to their more
serious, subsequent equations that include the MPIR variable. Summers
pointed out that survey data on inflationary expectations, such as those
from the Livingston panel, are confined to a one-year horizon and hence
cannot be used to explain the long-term interest rate. Thus the authors
had been forced to rely on an autoregressive specification of the formation
of price expectations, even though they recognized its severe limitations.
Responding to Sims, Summers defended the use of expected inflation as
an independent rather than dependent variable. He saw good theoretical
reasons for believing that inflationary expectations affected interest rates,
rather than vice versa. He also observed that a shift in the mix of investment toward equipment noted by Okun was probably the result of the
investment tax credit, which applies only to equipment.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

237
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you, Professor Feldstein.
Mr. Fromm, would you proceed with your statement, please.
STATEMENT OF GARY FROMM, DIRECTOR, SRI INTERNATIONAL 1
Mr. FROMM. Thank you, Senator.
Lfke Mr. Feldstein, I would also like to comment on the previous
testimony. It appears to me that some of the statements made, while
they could be supported from one line of argument, could seriously be
questioned from other avenues.
Just to cite one example before I enter into the body of my testimony, Mr. Feldstein makes the point that many individuals who
realize capital gains in fact are making real capital losses in terms of
their investments.
That applies not only to the area of capital gains, but it also extends
to such mundane investments as putting money into commercial bank
savings deposits. Under regulation Q, for example, at the moment, the
maximum rate that commercial banks can pay on passbook savings is
between 5 and 6 percent. Yet the rate of inflation is greater than that.
So, eve.n before taxes, individuals are realizing capital losses on current savings.
Senator BENTSEN. I think he made that same point.
Mr. FROMM. Yes; that is the same point.
So one should not focus entirely on capital gains as if there were
some aberration in the tax code. The difficulty extends across the board.
The problem is that inflation is taking place and is eroding real capital
values which then, as has already been indicated, makes matters worse
because nominal gains already are taxed. So, instead of looking only at
the taxation of gains, this is a situation that should be examined more
broadly.
Let me now turn to the body of my prepared statement.
As always, it is a privilege and pleasure to appear before this committee to participate in a discussion of problems confronting the U.S.
economy and particularly this morning, that of ca.pita! formation.
It seems likely that other panelists will cite the relatively weak performance of business fixed investment during the recovery from the
1974-75 recession and the significant probability that another recession will occur beginning late this or early next year. Notwithstanding
strong second quarter 1978 growth, current stringent monetary conditions coupled with high inflation could lead to marked erosion in real
spending and an inventory decumulation reaction.
Senator BENTSEN. Pardon me, Mr. Fromm. There are people in the
audience who I am sure want to hear what you have to say.
Can you hear back there? [The audience responds in the negative.]
I didn't think so. Is the speaker system working?
I think, then, if you would move your microphone closer to you, Mr.
Fromm, it would be helpful.
Mr. FROMM. Thank you.
Both this and the less-than-ideal U.S. foreign trade and exchange
situation are subjects that deserve extensive exploration by this com' The views expressed herein ar<> those of the author and dn not necessarily reflect those
of officers, directors, or other Rtaft' memhers of SRT International (formerlv Stanford ReRearcq Institute. Research underlying this statement was, In part, supported by the National Science Foundation.


35-570 0 • 79 • 16
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

238
mittee. The causes are complex and the cures will not be easy. A wide
variety of measures is indicated.
One s~t of th_?se, and the _subject on which I was requested to comment this mornmg, are specific measures that might be adopted by the
Federal. Governme~t to spur a hig~er level of capital spending. Increased m~estment m plant and eqmpment not only would contribute
to economic growth, but should help to increase productivity, lower
~nflation_, and raise the competitiveness of the U.S. economy within the
mternational arena.
As is well and widely recognized, the greatest Government-induced
spur to capital spending would come from the pursuit of policies that
~oul~ create conditions conducive to high and stable growth without
mflabon. No single measure can be effective in that regard. It requires
complementary fiscal and monetary policies together with other policies which largely impinge on the supply side. The latter include
policies targeted to increase labor skills and reduce structural unemployment, policies directed toward relieving bottlenecks in critical nonlabor inputs-selected materials, services, and energy-regulatory
and other policies.
Unfortunately, while pursuit of goals of enhanced environmental
protection, greater occupational safety and health, and lower discrimination in employment is laudable, the degree of regulation of business appears to be rising daily. In some fields regulation already appears excessively to be limiting replacement of outmoded facilities
and inhibiting expansion of productive capacity. No matter how favorable are the general economic conditions and climate for investment
that might be created by sound fiscal and monetary policies, specific
regulatory constraints and overall regulatory deterrents could prevent
their realization. Substitution of general for specific regulations,
greater use of performance incentives, including Government procurement from suppliers who more nearly satisfy national goals, and
more reliance on competition than price-quantity regulation could all
be favorable for higher levels of capital spending.
Such spending, too, would clearly be enhanced by measures that
raise after tax rates of return and funds available for investment.
During 1976 and 1977, subcommittees of the U.S. Senate Committee on
Finance held hearings on incentives for economic growth and capital
:formation effects of tax policy. In my testimony of June of last year
in those hearings, I summarized results of predictions of 1978-85
growth by 22 forecasters, implications for savings and investment, and
the revenue and fixed investment impacts of selected Federal tax revisions. The conclusions, I believe, are still valid.
One, the economy has the ability to generate sufficient savings to
meet investment needs of the next decade, including increased outlays
for energy conversion, polJution abatement, and capacity expansion.
Two, to make this possible, Federal expenditures should be. restrained so that current high deficits are reduced and Government saving is raised.
Three, individual income tax cuts will be needed to offset a progressive tax rate schedule and limit reductions in real consumer purchasing- power arising from inflation.
Four, monetary policy should be accommodating and should not
foster but seek to prevent episodes of highly restrictive credit availability.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

239
Five, the principal problem is financing increased investment in a
highly uncertain inflationary setting when business exposure to working capital needs are swollen, historical depreciation falls ::;hort of replacement costs, growth in nominal retained earnings is insufficient to
fund much higher capital outlays, and relative rates of return are too
low and risk too high to attract much greater equity funding.
Various proposals have been made during the past few years to
modify the Federal Tax Code so as to reduce tax burdens, stimulate
the economy, inject a degree of reform in selected inequities and inefficiencies-such as "double taxation" of gross income from corporate business-and to stimulate investment outlays. While virtually
any tax reduction would tend to increase investment to some extent,
there are large disparities in impacts on capital spending of different
alternatives.
Per dollar of lost Federal revenue-and here I clearly disagree with
Mr. Evans-the most effective investment stimulus, assuming the
economy is not at full employment, is the investment tax credit. Next
in effectiveness are revisions in depreciation provisions. This is hardly
surprising since both measures are tied directly to capital outlays.
Given the structure of the present Tax Code, lesser impacts on investment result from various schemes to integrate corporate and individual taxes, reduce. corporate profits taxes, or lower capital gains
tax rates. If investment stimulus is the -only goal, preference for
changes in the tax structure is roughly as shown in the table I provided for the record.
[The table referred to follows:]
Relative
Buperiority

1. Increase investment tax credit or liberalize depreciation allowances__
2. Lower corporate taxes via rate reductions, dividend deductions, surtax exemptions_________________________________________________
3. Lower personal taxes via dividend integration, capital gains tax reduction ----------------------------------------------------------4. Special
provisions, increase percentage depletion, DISC, etc__________

10
5
41

Mr. FROMM. In that table the investment tax credit is preferred by
2 to 1 over other reductions of tax liabilities. The reason for this is
that, when taxes are reduced for corporations in general, or for individuals, part of the proceeds on the corporate side are.used for dividends, which in turn creates a leakage, because individuals use some
of the revenues reviewed as dividends for consumption.
The same effects would occur if capital gains taxes were lowered.
Reduced general corporate and individual tax levies may still be
preferred for other, including relative equity, reasons, but then the
principal justification should not be the effectiveness of such policy
changes in stimulating investment.
There are other possibilities for tax code revisions that would stimulate savings and investment. Incentives for broadening and deepening equity ownership by individuals in small and large business probably would lead to greater capital and output growth. Another measure that should be considered is a basic overhaul of accounting practices together with fundamental changes in the tax treatment of capital gains and losses and depreciation allowances. This is especially important in an inflationary setting when historical cost accounting, the
present standard for corporate reporting to the IRS and SEC, yields
biased and inconsistent conclusions about profitability and returns on

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

investment. LIFO has long been accepted by the Congress as appropriate for inventory accounting and revenue determination for income
tax purposes. Similar current value accounting principles ought to be
extended to returns from use and sales of fixed assets, with appropiate changes in the Federal income tax code.
Here Mr. Feldstein and I are clearly in agreement. This is a longneglected area, one that the Congress should have turned to some time
ago.
Unfortunately, research on taxation under inflationary conditions,
on the impact of tax incentives on savings and investment, and on many
other related economic stabilization and growth issues, has been extremely limited.
Estimate_s, such as those presented here, are highly tentative and subject to large error. This committee is to be commended for holding
these hearings and for its interest in the subject. However, it should
also be urged to examine the adequacy of ~esearch funding in this area
and to exert efforts to assure more substantial support.
Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much, Mr. Fromm.
Next, we will hear from Mr. Charles D. Kuehner, director of security analysis and investor relations, American Telephone & Telegraph.
STATEMENT OF CHi\RLES D. KUEHNER, DIRECTOR, SECURITY
ANALYSIS AND INVESTOR RELATIONS, AMERICAN TELE:PHONE
& TELEGRA:PH CO.
Mr. KUEHNER. Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
It is an honor to accept this committee's invitation to state my views
on capital formation-with special emphasis as to how it relates to
reducmg inflation and creating new jobs. The views I express are my
own as an economist. and editor of a recent book, "Capital and Job Formation : Our Nation's Third Century Challenge," which presented
essays on many facets of the subject by 23 business, academic, and Government leaders.
Capital formation, as I use the term, means the process of stimulating savings and converting them into new plant and equipment.
The American people seem particularly concerned at this time with
continuing inflation, disturbing unemployment levels, and ongoing
Government policies to alleviate them.
As I will endeavor to show today, increased capital formation can
serve to do three things :
One, reduce inflation.
Two, expand job opportunities.
Three', reduce the burden carried by the American taxpayer.
In my view, the process of capital formation ranks as America's
most unrecognized and misunderstood problem. It is a national need
neglected.
Public awareness of capital formation as a national problem, unfortunately, is similar to awareness of high blood pressure as a personal
problem: Both involve millions of people who don't know they are
affected.
If high blood pressure goes undiagnosed, its debilitating effects
weaken other parts of the body, heart, liver, kidneys, and so on.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

241

Likewise, if capital formation disease is not recognized as a threat
to our Nation's economic health-then the impact spreads throughout
the economy in a regressive chain of events, of people becoming unemployed or underemployed relative to their training and skills. Demands are then made for greater Government spending, and without a
corresponding expansion in priva.te industry, inflation weakens the
economy as we have seen in recent years.
American industry also loses ground in domestic and world markets
as inflation weakens the dollar and saps our ability to compete.
A weakened industrial base triggers less spending for research, and
development and technology lags. Industry then suffers from a slowdown in productivity and is able to offer fewer choices of products and
services to consumers.
Industry also becomes less able to solve such basic problems as energy and pollution.
At the end of the line, the. consumer sees the cost of living moving up
still higher and deniands still more Government intervention, controls
and spending. Also .at a disadvantage are women and minority
groups-especially recent gradua.tes of high school and college-who
are penalized douply; that is, poth as consumers and as seekers of
nonexistent job opportunities.
I have included in my prepared statement a number of charts that I
would like to turn to.
Chart 1 shows that from 1970 to 1976 capital formation was a.bout 17
percent of the gross national product in the United States, almost 24
percent of the GNP in West Germany, and 33 percent in Japan.
Looking only at individual savers, some economists in the United
States get quite concerned when our citizens ·save more than 6 percent
of their disposable personal income, but we find that individuals save
and invest 15 percent of their disposable personal income in West Germany and 25 percent in Japan.
As to the average annual growth in productivity, chart 2 shows that
in the 1970's the .1970-77 period, the United States has been able to
average only a 1-percent increase in productivity~ while in West Germany the increase has been almoet 4 percent, and in Japan over 3
percent.
The impact of increasing productivitv in reducing inflation is
pointed up in chart 3, which shows the trend of inflation in the United
States, West Germany, and ,Tapan. Despite their almost total reliance
on high-cost imported oil, the Japanese-and the -West Germans, as
well-have been reducing inflation. Both natiOllls are expected to end
1978 with inflation significantly below that of the United States.
By doing a better job of increasing productivity, the West ~rmans
and ,Japanese have both been ahle to reverse the upward climb of
inflation.
I might add, Mr. Vice Chairman, that I just checked on Friday,
with Mr. Lawrence Veit, international economist of Brown Bros.,
Harriman & Co., who is responsible for the forecasts shown in chart
4. His most recent thinking is that the Japanese infla.tion rate will in
1978 be somewhat lower than that shown on chart No. 3, and he also
expects a slight decline in inflation in West Germany-below that
shown on chart 3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

242
I:f the United States-with only about a 1-percent gain in productivity-could match the Japanese 5-percent average rate, we would
have inflation far below the 7 perceht envisioned recently for 1978 by
'
Chairman Miller of the Federal Reserve Board.
Comparing the uneml)loyment rat~ of these three nations, that is
shown in chart 5, which links up the earlier charts and reflects the
end result in human terms.
After all, we are really talking about people. The countries which
invest more in plrunt and equipment, and which have been improving
productivity the mrn~t, have the lowest unemployment.
From 1970 to 1977, the U.S. unemployment rate averaged 6.3 percent. In West Germitny, it was 2 percent, and in Japan only 1.6 percent.
.
In the final analysis, unemployment and inflation are human problems.
A citizenry beset by these problems is readv to try almost any solution offered. All too often the proposed "solution" is, "Let's spend
our way to prosperity." But that has been tried and not worked. As
James Callahan, Labor Party Prime Minister of Great Britain, said:
We used to think you could just spend your way out of a recession and increase employment by cutting taxes and boosting Government spending. I tell
you in all candor that that option no longer exists and that insofar as it ever
did exist, it worked by injecting inflation into the economy. The long-term cure
for unemployment is to create a healthy manufacturing industry that can hold
its own overseas and in doing so will be able to hold its own in the domestic
market.

Please look for a moment at chart 6.
Chart 6 suggests strong linkage between capital formation and job
g-rowth. The 10 companies in the Dow Jones 30 Industrial Index with
the highest rates of capital formations had some 895,000 employees in
1960. They increased their employment by 836,000 jobs in the period.
This was an amazing 93-percent increase!
Conversely, the 10 companies with the lowest rate of capital formation had 898,000 employees in 1960, but they added oinly 29,000 new
jobs since then. This was only a 3-percent increase in employment. At
this point I would like to correct a typo in the prepared statement. A
sentence was omitted after the words "the 3-percent increase in employment." The omission was, "but 6 of those 10 compainies actually
reduced employment. They had fewer workers on the payroll at the
end of the period than they did in 1960."
In my view, another important impediment to capital formation is
the U.S. tax structure.
In all candor, it can only be described as a system that discourages
investment. As noted in chart 1, in West Germany and Japan there
is investment of a gre1tter percentage of their GNP in new plant and
equipment. Chart 9 suggests why.
As to the tax burden on individual investors. there are wide differences between the United States, Japan, and West Germany. As the
chart shows, dividends in the United States are taxed up to 70 percent, while Japan's rate in the very top bracket is just half as much,
35 percent. As to taxes on capital gains, the U.S. tax rate goes up to
49.9 percent, including preference items. There are no capital gains
taxes in West Germany, and for all practical purposes, there are no

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

243
capital gains taxes in Japan; that is, it begins only after you sell over
200,000 shares of stock in a given year.
In fact, just 3 months ago, the Japanese took another quantum leap
to ci:tcourage still more capital formation. Effective April 1, 1978, the
Japanese eliminated all income tax on the first $60,000-assuming a
family of four-of capital invested in yen-denominated bonds or notes.
Let's turn now to our Nation's future need for new capital investment.
Since 1960, there has been a sharp increase in plant and equipment
per worker.
_
Senator BENTSEN. I have to ask you to summarize, because we have
to vote at 11 :30. If you could summarize, we will include your entire
prepared statement in the record.
Mr. KUEHNER. Yes, sir.
I would like to close with chart 10. I try to show that greater capital
formation would benefit every American citizen through more and
better jobs, less inflation, and a higher standard of living. I have summarized on chart 12 mme of tihe arguments and my reaction to them in
my prepared statement. I won't go into them in detail, except to touch
on the very last argument, which we have numbered No. 9:
"You're right but we can't stand the revenue loss." This argument
has been heard as long as I can remember, and it was usually heard
when all others fail. The short answer is that our Nation can't stand
the consequences of neglectinp: capital formation.
The crisis is here and it is buildin~. Let's not forget that President
Kennedy, for one, recognized that reduced taxes on American industry
and investors would create more jobs, and history has proven him
correct.
Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Kuehner follows:]
PREPARED STATEMENT OF CHARLES D. KUEHNER

OapitaZFormation-Inf(ation and Jobs

It is an honor to accept the Committee's invitation to state my views on capital
forma,tion-with special emphasis as to how it relates to reducing inflation and
creating new jobs. The views I express are my own ·as an economist and editor
of a recent book, "Capital and Job Formation: Our Nation's 3rd Century Challenge," which presented essays on many facets of the subject by 23 business,
academic and government leaders.
The Joint Economic Committee's current focus on this vital issue is most timely,
indeed. There are numerous signs that the American people-perhaps looking
toward the November elections-are becoming increasingly dissatisfied with the
cur.rent economic environment. They seem particularly concerned with continuing
inflation, disturbing unemployment levels and on-going government policies to
alleviate them. As I will endeavor to show today, increased capital formation
can serve to :
1. Reduce inflation.
2. Expand job opportunities.
3. Reduce the burden carried by the American taxpayer.
Capital formation: America's most unrecognized and ·misunderstood problem

Of all important public concerns, none is more basic to the well-being of
Americans than how we can best continue to build the productive capacity of
our nation. It seems obvious tbat only a productive and growing economy can
finance the costs of finding enduring solutions to the multitude of other social
concerns-ranging from shortfalls in employment and ~nergy to excesses in
environmental pollution, inflation, crime and so on.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

But as clear as the need for a solid economic foundation may be in our drive
to achieve such high-priority national goals, the fact remains that increased
economic growth depends absolutely on the sufficiency of capital investment. And
that, the record shows, is too often viewed as· a corporate concern rather than
as a public interest problem of national scope.
·
In my view, the process of capital formation ranks as America's most unrecognized and misunderstood problem. It is a national need neglected. However, as
former Federal Reserve Board Chairman Arthur Burns said earlier this year 1
about the capital formation challenge: "If we have the good sense to create hospitable conditions for savings and investing, I truly believe ours could become an
age of sustained progress in employment and well-being."
As an economist entirely in agreement with Dr. Burns' comment, I might add
that public awareness of capital formation as a national problem, unfortunately,
is similar to awareness of high blood pressure as a personal problem: both involve millions of people who don't know they are affected.
If high blood pressure goes undiagnosed, its debilitating effects weaken other
parts of the body: heart, liver, kidneys, and so on. Likewise, if t'he capital formation disease is not recognized as a threat to our nation's economic health-and
treatment is limited to some of the observed effects-then the impact spreads
throughout the economy in a regressive chain of events:
Inadequate capital formation leads to large numbers of people becoming unemployed, or underemployed relative to their training and skills. This occurs first
in the construction and capital goods industries and then in consumer goods and
services.
Demands are then made for greater government intervention and spending "to
create jobs and income."
With increased government spending-based on a large budget deficit-and
without a corresponding expansion in private industry, inflation weakens the
economy as we have seen in recent years.
American industry also loses ground in domestic and world markets as inflation weakens the dollJtr and saps our ability to compete.
A weakened. industrial base triggers less spending for Research & Development
and technology lags.
Industry suffers from a slowdown in productivity and is able to offer :fewer
choices of products and services to consumers; industry also becomes less able to
solve such basic problems as energy and pollution.
At the end of the line, the consumer sees the cost of living moving up still
higher and demands still more government intervention, controls and spending.
Also at a disadvantage are women and minority groups-especially recent graduates of high school and college-who are penalized doubly, that is, both as
consumers and as seekers of nonexistent job opportunities.
In short, I believe capital formation is the crucial economic problem facil!g
our nation today because'it has been too long a victim of public neglect.
Neglect of capital formation

Neglect is obvious in a number of areas.
News meclia.-Neglect of this subject by the nation's news media has been

almost total. Of the thousands of articles published during 1977 by the nation's
leading magazines and newspapers, only seventeen• dealt with the subject of
"Capital Formation." (Although it is getting a bit more press recently ... thanks
to discussions such as this.)
However, while there were only seventeen articles published on "Capital Formation," there· were over ninety· articles published on "Unemployment" and
"Public Welfare". I would suggest that this is a classic case of paying heed to
symptoms of the disease, rather than the basic disease itself.
Labor leaclers.-At the local level, labor leaders seem most concerned with
seeking the largest possible increase in wages and fringe benefits for union
members. Consequently, there appears to be little concern for the long-run impact
of wage agreements on corporate earnings and how this may impinge on capital
and job formation. At the national level, AFL-CIO President George Meany was
recently reported to strongly support capital formation as essential for job
formation.•
1 National Press Club, January 30, 1978.
• "Reader'R Guide to Periodical Literature," New York: The H. W. Wilson Co. JanuaryDecember 1977.
• Tillie magazine, June 12, 1978. p. 74.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

245
PoUtioaZ Zeaders.-Opinion surveys show that, until recently at least, most
political leaders and their staffs do not regard capital formation as a high
priority item. But they have long been concerned about the problem of unemployment. In my view, this indicates a failure to recognize that capital formation
is needed to create new jobs and improve income in real terms.
Regulatory agencies.-Under political pressure to keep rates low, public utility
regulatory agencies have largely neglected capital formation. Under the doctrine
of "Deference," the courts have been reluctant to override regulatory decisions
on required equity earnings, capital structure and the like. They have tended
to defer to the agencies' "expertise." As a result, many regulated utilities have
had their credit ratings downgraded and have been forced to sell new common
stock below the nominal book value per share-and far below the actual value
of the assets per share in dollars of constant purchasing power. Equally important, many utilities-unable to sell common stock-have been forced to
excessive debt levels. This has triggered higher interest costs and a higher burden
on consumers.
Business schooZB.-Even the nation's graduate schools of business have virtually ignored capital formation in their course offerings. This may explain the
findings of a recent survey of :MBA's who failed to mention capital formation
as one of America's most important problems. This seems to reflect the Keynesian orientation of the business school curriculum : There was no shortage of
capital back in the 1930's. Hence, in the Keynesian System, it is assumed that
capital will always be readily available. Unfortunately, however, there has been
a shortage of investment capital for many years.
At this point, I would like to review a few charts which may help to sharpen
up the scope of the problem.
Percent of GNP saved and invested

Chart 1 shows capital formation as a percent of Gross National Product in
U.S., West Germany and Japan.
Admittedly, we are focusing on three different societies with three different
life-styles. I would not assert that West Germany and Japan are exact models
for the United States to emulate. They are both more disciplined societies.
I think it fair to say that most Germans are "scared to death" of inflation.
This stems from the German inflationary disaster of the 1920's. An extreme fear
of inflation has been built. into the national psyche. Dr. Ottmar Emminger,
Chairman of the Bundeshank, the German Federal ReserYe, discussed that point
in a speech in Chicago. He has said-only partly in jest-that the government
controls TV and-to heighten the citizens' ·awareness of inflation-each evening
on the 7 :00 P.M. news, the first ten minutes are devoted to scenes of labor strife
and inflation occurring that day in England.
·
In Japan, most people are educated to appreciate the importance of being more
efficient producers of goods : their jobs depend on it. And they invest over one
third of the GNP in capital goods. I'm sure you all heard the story that every
school boy and school girl has a plaque over the bed with the admonition "The
survival of Japan as a nation depends on capital formation and excellence in
technology---especially electronics."
Looking only at individual savers, some U.S. economists get quite concerned
when American citizens save more than 6 percent of their disposable personal
income. But we find that individuals save and invest 15 percent of their disposable personal income in West Germany and 25 percent in .Japan. This naturally gives a strong push to capital formation in those countries.
Average annuaZ growth in productivity

One impact of greater plant and equipment spending on productivity is shown
in Chart 2. In the 1970-77 period. the U.S. has been able to average only 1 percent annual increase in productivity, while in West Germany the increase has
been almost 4 percent and in Japan over 5 percent.
And our country's situation is not improving : in the first quarter of 1978,
U.S. productivity actually dropped. This was in part attributable to the coal
strike and to the weather. But it was also attributable to the generally low
level of productivity in the U.S. We are too close to the zero line. Hence, we
have no "cushion" to absorb a slowdown, such as that caused by the strike and
bad weather.
Studies indicate that some two-thirds of U.S. industrial cap,icity is over ten
years old. This helps explain why so many goods produced in the U.S. have

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

246
trouble competing both in the domestic market and in the world market. As a
result, instead of exporting goods, the U.S. has been exporting jobs.
Let's remind ourselves that, in looking at the economic growth rate in West
Germany and Japan, we are not talking about undeveloped nations starting from
ground zero. We are focusing on the leading economic nations in the free world.
The impact of increasing productivity to reduce inflation is pointed up by
Chart 3 showing the trend of inflation in the United States, West Germany and
Japan.
Despite their almost total reliance on high cost imported oil, both the Japanese-and the West Germans as well-have been reducing inflation. Both nations
are expected to end 1978 with inflation significantly below that of the United
States. By doing a better job of increasing productivity, the Japanese and West
Germans have both been able to reverse the upward climb of inflation.
The problem in the United States is shown in Chart 4. Productivity, as reflected by output per hour, is far below the cost as measured by compensation
per hour. The increasing gap between output and compensation is the inflationary
impact. Let me stress that higher compensation is not the sole cause of inflation.
However, at the present time it seems to be making the task of reducing inflation
substantially more difficult.
If the U.S.-with only about 1 percent productivity gain-could match Japan's
5 percent average rate, we would have inflation far below the 7 percent envisioned
recently for 1978 by Chairman l\filler of the Federal Reserve Board.
Unemployment rate

Chart 5 links up Charts 1 and 2 and reflects the end result in human terms.
After all, we are really talking about people. The countries which invest more in
plant and equipment, and which are improving productivity the most, have the
lowest unemployment.
.
In the final analysis, unemployment and inflation are human problems. A
citizenry beset by these problems is ready to try almost any solution offered. And
too often the proposed "solution" is "let's spend our way to prosperity." But that
has been tried and has not worked. As James Callaghan, Labour Party Prime
Minister of Great Britain, has said:
"We used to think that you could just spend your way out of a recession and
increase employment by cutting taxes and boosting government spending. I tell
you in all candor that that option no longer exists-and that insofar as it ever
did exist, it worked by injecting inflation into the economy ... The long-term
cure for unemployment is to create a healthy manufacturing industry that can
hold its own overseas and in doing so will certainly be able to hold its own in the
domestic market."
Does government spending really lead to less unemployment? In recent years
there has been growing disenchantment with that point of view.
Let's spiral back to the bottom of the depression, when John Maynard Keynesperhaps the most brilliant and certainly the most influential economist in this
century-began to write his thesis calling for more government spending.
What was the economic and social milieu in 1933?
Unemployment was in the 20 percent range.
Some industries, such as steel or autos, were almost entirely shut down.
Housing start!!' were minimal.
Deflation, not inflation, was a major problem.
Farmers were selling corn in Iowa for 10 cents a bushel.
Above all else, total government spending-federal, state and local-was only
$10 billion or about the same as it was in 1929, the year of the crash. At that time,
government spending was only 10 percent of the G.N.P. ·
In this environment, Keynes rightly saw increased government spending as a
substitute for almost non-existent private spending. He clearly did not envision
goevrnment "crowding out" private spending. When Keynes wrote his general
theory, government spending was merely putting to work idle dollars lying in
banks and earning only 1 or 1½ percent interest. That is not true today. Today
government spending is drawing dollars away from the productive private sector,
that is, "crowding out."
Capital formation and jobs

Chart 6 suggests the strong linkage between capital formation and job growth.
The 10 companies in the Dow Jones 30 Industrial Index with the highest rate
of capital formation had some 895,000 employees in 1960. They increased their

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

247
employment by 836,000 jobs in the 1960-76 period. This was an amazing 93 percent
increase!
Conversely, the 10 companies with the lowest rate of capital formation had
898,000 employees in 1960. But they added only 29,000 new jobs since then. This
was only a 3 percent increase in employment.
From this data we can only conclude that if we want more jobs, we've got to
have more capital formation.
Chart 7 reflects government spending as a percentage of the GNP. As I said,
back in 1929 government consumed about 10 percent of the GNP. By 1950, while
fighting a war in Korea, government spending accounted for 21 percent of the
GNP. By 1977, government spending had zoomed up to 33 percent of the Gross
National Product. As you know, these data include all transfer payments, such
as unemployment payments, and interest on the public debt.
As a one time Keynesian, I find it interesting that a growing number of people
in the productive private sector of the economy-as well as in the academic
world-are coming to the view that government spending is "part of the problem"-not "part of the solution."
Perhaps this was what Lord Keynes had in mind when, in his final days, he
expressed the hope that his followers would not blindly apply his theory in times
when it was no longer applicable.
It would appear that with government spending 33 percent of the Gross National Product, we have a choice of two evils:
1. One evil is that government can run at a deficit, issue government bonds,
and thus "crowd out" private enterprises from the securities markets. For example, Chart 8 shows that of all bonds issued in the past four years, 47 percent
were government: Federal, state and local. By way of contrast, in the early
1960's, government took less than 20 percent of the total supply of credit. A basic
danger of government borrowing is that it is largely used to finance current
consumption. It is not spent for plant and equipment needed to produce goods or
services for the consumer on a more efficient basis.
2. The second evil is that goevrnment can raise taxes to balance the budget.
But this places an even heavier burden on industry and consumers. Milton Friedman, for one, has stated that the advocates of a balanced budget via higher taxes
have contributed to the problem. In his view, they should have called for less
government spending.
The debate on taxation has concentrated heavily on who should pay taxes.
Only rarely does the debate center on the basic question "Is our level of spending
absolutely necessary?"
Taxes on capital

In my view, another important impediment to capital formation is the U.S. tax
structure. In all candor, it can only be described as a system that discourages
investment. Let's look briefly at the incentive, or lack of it, to invest in modern,
highly productive plant and equipment in the free world's three leading nations.
As noted in Chart 1, West Germany and Japan are investing a greater percentage of their Gross National Product in new plant and equipment and Chart
9 suggests why.
First, we should note that taxes on corporate earnings in all three nations
are about the same. But in light of our nation's lagging economic progress in
recent years, a good case can be made for reducing U.S. corporate taxes below
either West Germany or Japan.
As to the tax burden on individual investors, there are wide differences.
Dividends in the U.S. are taxed up to 70 percent-while Japan's rate in the
very top bracket is just half as much, 35 percent.
As to taxes on capital gains, the U.S. tax rate goes up to 49.9 percent including preference ftems. There is no capital gains tax in West Germany. And, for
all practical purposes, there is no capital gains tax in Japan; that is, it begins
only after you sell over 200,000 shares of stock per year.
In fact. just three months ago the Japanese took another quantum leap to encourage still more capital formation. Effective April 1, 1978 they eliminated all
income tax on the first $60,000 (assuming a family of four) of capital invested in
Yen denominated bonds or notes.
In light of our nation's capital formation needs, it's bad enough that U.S. capital gains are taxed at all. It's doubly so when you realize that much, or all, of
the gain is illusory-merely reflecting inflation and capital "gains" from the sale


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

248
of stock in dollars of far less purchasing power. Thus, the capital "gains" tax
is really a tax on capital-it is not a tax on gain.s.
This is reflected in Harvard Professor Martin Feldstein's recent ·study which
showed that individual U.S. tax payers paid taxes of $1 billion on "phantom"
capital gains of $4½ billion a year. But when the "gains" are adjusted for the
declining value of the dollar, these investors really suffered a capital loss of about
$1 billion.
In short, they paid $1 billion of Federal income taxes on a $1 billion loss.
Plant and equipment per worker

So much for the general environment of capital formation in the U.S. and our
chief industrial competitors, West Germany and Japan. Let's now turn to our
nation's future meed for new capital investment.
Chart 10 shows the sharp increase in plant and equipment per worker since
1960. Judging from the obsolescence of America's existing plant and equipment,
even these numbers obviously understate the problem. If, over the years, American industry had been able to build the kind of modern facilities really needed
to compete effectively in world markets, the investment per worker clearly would
be higher.
For example, in the paper industry the average investment per worker is now
about $42,000. However, it would require an investment of about $81,000 per
worker on the basis of today's cost. The airline industry affords another exaII11Ple.
Airlines require an investment of $90,000 per seat in existing jet airplines. Looking to the next decade and the new generation of jets, industry experts estimate
that the investment per seat wlll soar to $200,000. The unanswered question is:
"Where is all the money coming from?"
Growth in population by age groups

Let's turn now to the supply of capital available.
Chart 11 shows the growth in population by age groups in the current decade.
In general, people over 65 years of age are not major contributors to the nation's
supply of savings. Rather they are primarily concerned wilth spending the savings of a lifetime.
The largest group of savers are people in the 50--64 year-old group. They are
in the years of peak earning power. Their children have generally been educated
and the parents are in a position to devote substantial amounts of their current
income to investment. The bad news is that the 50--64 year age group will be increasing only 600,000 people in the current decade. More bad news : the biggest
increase is in the 20-34 year old age group. Unfortunately, these people are what
economists call "net dissavers." They look to other people to provide savings for
their house and their job.
It is quite clear that population trends will aggravate the problem of capital
formation in the years ahead. This, too, suggests extraordinary efforts must be
made to turn the situation around.
Arguments against increased capital formation

I have tried to show bow greater capital formation would benefit every American citizen through more and better jobs, less inflation, and a higher standard
of living. But, to be fair, I should tell you that this view is not unanimous. There
have been some differences of opinion about increased capital formation. Chart
12 summarizes some of these arguments which we might briefly review.
1. Supply must be identical to demand.-This argument holds that "by definition supply must be identical to demand." On a theoretical basis this is true;
that is, at the end of each year the supply of capital made available was identically equal to the demand that was actually satisfied.
But the short answer to this argument is that it's like saying "Last year the
supply of food in India was identically equal to the demand for food-but unfortunately 10 million people starved to death."
i. Stimulate consumption fl,rst.-As noted earlier, this theory stems from economic thinking of the depression years. As Prime Minister Callaghan noted, this
approach has ·been tried but it failed in Great Britain, the land where the theory
originated.
The short answer is that this argument neglects the supply side of t,be p1cture
which, as we've seen in the charts, is why we're in the situation we're in today.
West Germany and Japan, which have strongly encouraged capital investment,
enjoy both more supply and more demand.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

249
3. Free market wiZZ allocate resources ebloiently".-This argument, advanced
by such leading economists as Paul Samuelson, asserts that a "free market" will
ration capital efficiently among the many demanders of capital.
The short answer, in my view, is that this free market theory isn't based on
fact. We do not have a free market for capital in the U.S. Rather, we have a
market where capital investment is penalized by heavy corporate taxes, by
double taxes on dividends, as well as by taxes on capital gains which are often
not true gains at all. Investment also is discouraged by burdensome government
regulations.
4. Plant is now operating below capaoity.-This argument notes correctly that
U.S. industrial plant is operating at about 82 percent of capacity. It therefore
asserts that there is no need for more investment.
The short answer is "look at England." The British steel industry, for example, is operating at only 67 percent of capacity because it is even more antiquated than the American steel industry. Much of America's idle plant in many
industries is simply too old to produce efficiently for world markets.
5. U.S. is bec01ning a service economy, i.e., industry is deolining.-This argument holds that industry has been declining and that service businesses are
becoming a bigger part of the total American economic picture.
The short answer is th3rt, despite the growth of service industries, the investment per worker has increased sharply. Let's not forget that even service industries require substantial increases in investment. The clerk with a 10 cent pencil has been replaced by a $6 million computer. Equally important, if today we
had more productive plant and equipment, the investment per worker would
be still higher.
6. Other factors, such as health, education and R . .'.E D. are itmvortant.-The
short answer is that even if we had the best educated workers in the world
all in perfect health and with the best R. & D., but still didn't have the tools, we
would not have the output of goods and services our citizens require. I should
note, however, that there are warning signs on the horizon. For example, research and development expenditures in the U.S. have been falling behind just
as has our American plant and equipment spending.
7. Brookings Institution model (1975) forecast no shortage.-As you may recall, the Brookings M.-idel was widely accepted in academic and in some government circles as "proof'' that we had no capital formation problem in the U.S.
T-he short answer is that the Brookings Model was based on certain crucial
assumptions. Today, these assumptions have been proven incorrect in light of
what ha8 happened since 1975. For example, Brookings assumed that: (1) inflation would subside-they did not expect the double digit inflation that we've
seen recently, (2) government would balance its budget-they did not contemplate the $60 billion deficit the Federal government has been running recently,
(3) corporate profits would rise and permit increased reinvestment of corporate
earnings to build new plant and equipment-they did not contemplate the drop
in re,al corporate earnings of the last few years.
8. You're right ... but a tam cut for inv-~stors is not politically palatable.The short answer is that medicine doesn't always taste good. The facts somehow
must ·be made politically palatable. I don't subscribe to the notion that the American people want to live in a dream world. Rather, I sincerely believe that
given the facts, the American people and their leaders will recognize that capital formation must become a top national priority.
9. You're right ... but we oan't stand the revenue lo8'8.-This argument has
been heard as long as I can remember and is usually heard when all others fail.
The short answer is that our nation can't stand the consequences of continuing neglect of capital formation. The crisis is here and is building. Let's not
forget that President Kennedy, for one, recognized that reduced taxes on American industry and investors would lead to more jobs-and history has proven
him correct.
Conclusion
I have reviewed the nature of the capital formation problem and I understand
that others will focus on possible solutions. Hence, I'll touch only lightly on
the four possible remedies listed on Chart 13.
1. Get 0. F. out of the closet.-Substantially more capital formation is crucial to our national well-being. It needs to be discussed and debated in more public forums such as this.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

250
All of us-we in the private sector and you in government-face a real challenge to bring the capital formation message to all the nation's thought leaders.
Especially, we face the real challenge of encouraging the media to focus attention on this issue. Until recently, it has been virtually ignored, as was New
York City's impending financial crisis a few years ago.
How do we do it? Perhaps we might abbreviate "Capital Formation" to "O.F."
and make it a household word. Look what happened when "Transcendental
Meditation" was ahbreviated to T.M.: It was put in paperback and sold millions
of copies!
2. Rethink national priorities.-Everyone agrees that the priorities prevailing during our nation's first century were inadequate for uur nation's second
century. Are the national priorities for our nation's second century adequate
today as we move into the third century? The facts say "No."
Perhaps what is needed is a statement of national policy on capital formation
similar to "The Employment Act of 1946." How about "The Capital Formation
Act of 1978?" It could do-through private enterprise-what others would try
to do by more government spending.
3. Rethink Government spending and, intiation.-In recent weeks several authorities, including Chairman Miller of the Federal Reserve Board, have called
for less government spending, pointing to the inflationary impact of our present
course.
Many astute observers of the political scene have concluded that the landslide
victory of "Proposition 13" in California indicates that the American people
are ready "to march to a ditrerent drummer." In my view, capital formation
can be that drummer. It is "the economic Moses" to lead the American people
out of the wilderness of high inflation and unemployment. With stepped-up
capital formation, greater economic growth would materially reduce demands
for more government spending.
4. Encourage investment.-Also on that same score, I would opine that
present taxation of investment, as well as government regulatory policies in
many industries, serves to retard capital formation. And with it, of course, economic growth-including the creation of new jobs and the battle against inflation-is retarded.
It might be a good idea to follow the lead of the environmentalists. Perhaps
each new legislative proposal should be accompanied by a "Capital FormationInflation and Jobs Impact Statement".


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

251
Chart 1

FIXED CAPITAL FORMATION
AS A PERCENT OF G.N.P.
1970-1976

Percent
40 -

30 -

20 -

10 -

0

u. s.
Source: United Nations


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

West
Germany

Japan

252
Chart 2

AVERAGE ANNUAL GROWTH
IN PRODUCTIVITY

5.4"'~

1970 - 1977

Percent
5 -

0
U.S.

West
Germany

Source: U.S. Dept. Of Labor, Bureau Of Labor Statistics


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Japan

253
Chart 3

INFLATION RATE
Percent

25 . - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

20 -

15

10

5
Germany

01970
---------------------'72
'74
'76- - - - - - -1978
(EST.)

Source: International Monetary Fund
Organization For Economic Cooperation & Development
Brown Brothers Harriman & Co.

35-570 0 - 79 - 17

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

254

Chart 4

COMPENSATION VS. OUTPUT PER HOUR
Index

300 ~ - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

200

'65

'70

'75

1977

CONSUMER PRICE INDEX
Index

200 , - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - ~

150

'65

'70

Source: Ecor,omic Report Of The President, 1978


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

'75

1977

255
Chart 5

UNEMPLOYMENT RATE
AVERAGE, 1970 - 1977

Percent
10 -

6.3%

5 -

1.6%

0

U.S.
Source: Monthly Labor Review


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

West
Germany

Japan

256
Chart 6

NEW JOBS AND CAPITAL FORMATION
DOW JONES INDUSTRIALS
Percent Increase In Jobs
100 8:?6,000 New Jobs

1960-1976

80 -

60 -

40 -

20 29,000 New Jobs
10 Companies
With Highest
Rate Of Capital
Formation
Source: Standard & Poor's Compustat Service


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

10 Companies
With Lowest
Rate Of Capital
Formation

257

Chart 7

TOTAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES AS A
PERCENT OF GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
Percent

35 30

:,o

10 -

1929

1950

Source: Economic Report Of The President, 1978


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1977

258
Chart 8

"CROWDING OUT"
TOT AL SUPPLY OF CREDIT
(Excluding Refundings)

1975-1978 Average
Source: "Supply & Demand For Credit In 1978", Salomon Bros.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

259
Chart 9

TAXES ON INDIVIDUAL INVESTORS
(MAXIMUM)

Dividends

U.S.

70%

W. Germany
Japan

56
35

Capital
Gains
49.9%·
0
0

• Includes 15% Minimum On Tax Preference Items
Source: Coopers & Lybrand


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

260
Chart 10

PLANT & EQUIPMENT PER WORKER
Thousands

(1977 $)
38.7

40 33.7

20 -

0

1980
Source: Survey Of Current Business


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1970

1976

261
Chart 11

GROWTH IN POPULATION BY AGE GROUPS
1975-1985

Millions
15 -

10.2

10 -

5 -

4.3

.6
0
-2.8
-5
Under 20

20-34

35-49
Age Groups

Source: U.S. Dept. Of Commerce, Bureau Of The Census


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

50-64

65+

262
Chart 12

ARGUMENTS AGAINST INCREASED
CAPITAL FORMATION
1. "Supp:y must be identical to demand"
2. "Stimulate consumption first"
3. "Free market will allocate resources efficiently"
4. "Plant Is now operating below capacity"
5. "U.S. Is becoming a service economy, i.e., Industry
is declining"
6. "Other factors, such as health, education,and R&D are
more Important"
7. "Brookings Institution model ( 197 5} forecast no
shortage"
8. "You're right •.. but a tax cut for investors
is not politically palatable"
9. "You're right ... but we can't stand the
revenue loss"


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

263
Cnart 13

FOUR POSSIBLE REMEDIES
TO THE
CAPITAL FORMATION PROBLEM
1.
2.
3.
4.

Get C.F. Out Of The Closet.
Rethink National Priorities.
Rethink Government Spending And Inflation.
Encourage Investment.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

264
Senator BENTSEN. Thank you very much.
A comment was made on public relations. The problem we run into
is that we have competing objectives. We want to clean up the water
and the air, and sometimPs we do it at any price.
Now we understand that that adds to inflation, and makes us less
competitive. ,ve have to have some cost-benefit ratios involved. There
was a story yesterday in the Washington Star on the point some of
you made. A memorandum from Barry Bosworth said that in the next
i2 to 18 months regulatory agencies will make regulatory decisions
which will increase compliance costs to the private sector by $35
billion annually. That is very much along the point that you are
speaking to.
I would ]ike to hear a little more about why Mr. Evans thinks that
the investment tax credit is the last of the priorities in accomplishing
these objectives and why Mr. Fromm thinks it is first.
I would like to· get a little bit of practical decisionmaking-how
much you fellows have actually talked to people who make decisions
on whether they will go ahead and buy a piece of machinery or make
an investment, because the investment· tax credit was factored into
the return they will receive.
I understand all businessmen want all business tax credits, and all
want them at ]east doubled. e will start with that premise. I want
to see how much you know and how much this has influenced decisions.
Mr. EvANs. My answer may surprise you a little bit. I have talked
to 100 businessmen. I would say 2 percent have made investments
because of investment tax credits.
Senator BENTSEN. About 2 percent i
Mr. EVANS. Yes. They don't consider that in their planning. They
try to figure out what the rate of return is, and they try to determine
whether it wi11 be a useful investment, but they don't consider the
investment tax credit to be very important.
Mr. FROMM. That is clearly the case. It is not the sole dete,rmining
factor, whether an investment is made or not, but it must enter into
the calculation of the rate of return, just as the tax rates must enter
into that computation as well.
If you ask a businessman, "Does the difference between a 48- and a
45-percent corporate tax rate enter importantly into whether a particular decision is made or not," of course he is going to say "no."
That is a small change.
Businessmen must consider the entire complex of factors that influence the rate of return. But, the most important one is the state of
demand for the products or services that will be produced with the
investment.
Senator BENTSEN. I had an argument with a banker once. I was
arguing on half of 1 percent interest on the loan. He finally said. "It
either is a good de11l or it isn't, and what you are really arv.-uing about
now is your pride." I am not sure I buy that. [Laughter.] Go ahead,
Mr.Evans.
Mr. EVANS. I used to think the investment tax credit was more
important. as a matter of fact, and when I first started asking this
question, I was surprised at the answer I got. I used to argue back
with them. But I found this was a very large maiority of people who


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

,v

265
said that o:f all the :factors, the tax :factors they considered, the investment tax credit really had less o:f an effect.
.
.
A:fter that, then I went back and tried to estimate on an econometric
basis which o:f the five :factors that I have listed there were important,
and what the order o:f importance was, and on an empirical basis I
also :found the investment tax credit came out last. So there appears to
be some correlation between what businessmen were telling me and
what I :found out in my own research.
So I think that the businessmen have viewed the investment tax
credit as a toy o:f Congress. It comes on one year and come off another
year. I think in the business community it has received negative connotations as sort of a plaything instead o:f a long-term commitment
to increase capital :formation.
Senator BENTSEN. Mr. Evans, do you argue that capital investments
will be reduced by companies when the stock market is down, when
stock prices are down?
Mr. EVANS. Yes.
Senator BENTSEN. I suppose, then, you also argue, i:f I recall, that
when stock prices are down, they will buy small companies, and they
buy them :for cash.
Mr. EvANS. Yes.
Senator BENTSEN. But when their stock prices are up, they either
sell equity or they use their high multiples to try to buy companies at
lower multiples and end up with an increased rate o:f return?
Mr. EVANS. Yes. Over the years there has been a strong negative
correlation between stock prices and mergers and acquisition activities.
In the last six quarters, mergers and acquisitions have been extremely
high. ·when the stock market takes off, you see acquisitions and mergers
drop off. The spirit is still there, but it is not intensive.
Senator BENTSEN. Senator Hatch, why don't you use the next 7
minutes?
Senator HATCH. Thank you, Senator Bentsen.
It is my understanding that i:f we cut the corporate rate by, say,
$10 billion, which is about the cost o:f the investment tax credit, it
would raise the return on investments more than the investment tax
credit because we, under those circumstances, could lower the corporate rate down to 39 percent and be better off.
Would you agree or disagree with that?
Mr. EvANS. I basically ,agree with that.
Senator HATCH. Mr. Evans, one of the hot economic proposals is
the Roth-Kemp bill, which would, among other thi.ngs, reduce individual income taxes 'by about 33 percent. One of the big questions concerning the bill is the size of the deficits that may occur and the effect
of these possible deficits on inflation. Have you put the Roth-Kemp
bill through the Chase models, and what were vour resuks concerning
the deficits and inflation?
•
Mr. EvANS. I did make a number of runs like that. If you take the
R6th-Kemp bill at :face value, it does increase the deficit and does increase inflation. I made two modificat,ions to it in the computer run:::.
and one thing that I did was to hold the rate of Government spending
constant in real terms. In other words, Government spending still increases, but only at the rate of inflation. There was no real increase.
Also, I lowered the corporate tax rate to 40 percent instead o:f 45

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

266
percent in order to provide more capital formation, and when I made
t~ose two modifications to Kemp-Roth, we found the budget deficit
disappeared over ,a 10-ye,ar period, and that the rate of inflation was
virtually the same as it would be without any of these changes.
So for what it was worth, our calculations showed that with these
two modifications, lower rate of spending growth and grea.ter cut in
?Orporwte tax rates, that the overall tone of the economy would be
improved rnuch more.
Senator HATCH. How much did saving increase in your model run i
Mr. EvANS. Personal savingsi
_
Senator HATCH. Yes. And how much of the deficit was covered by it?
Mr. EvANS. Let's see. We got rid of a $60 billion deficit. About twothirds was c~vered by personal savings and one-third by additional
corporate savmgs, more or less.
Senator HATCH. If it weren't for higher social security taxes, inflation's impact on our progressive tax system and proposed energy taxes,
would we need ,a general tax cut to stimulate the economy 1
Mr. EVANS. Yes, as long as inflation goes on, because it places people
into higher brackets.
There are really two problems, the fact that taxes keep increasing
in proportion to income, and the question of indexation. If we were to
go to an indexation scheme, I would say we would need a general tax
cut, but that doesn't seem to be likely at the present.
Senator HATCH. Does the Chase model, or ,any of the major models,
tak~ account of supply-side incentive. effects of tax cuts, and the resultmg tax revenue feedback 1
Mr. EvANS. Our model takes that into account a little bit. I think all
the econometric models I know ahout are seriously deficient in the
sense that they don't take into account supply-side effects.
Senator HATCH. Do the leading forecasting models lose any predictive power by leaving out the disincentive effects of higher marginal
tax rates on people's unwillingness to save and work?
Mr. EVANS. Well, we don't know for sure, but my opinion is that
they probably do, and we probably underestimate the effect of tax cuts.
As I said, we are trying to move in that direction.
Senator HATCH. I have a lot of questions for all of you, but we wre
running out of time. Let me ask Mr. Feldstein a couple of questions.
Would you recommend making savings into a tax deduction or
providing some form of tax credit for saving?
. Mr. FELDSTEIN. I do think savings should be increased. I think we
can't work just on the investment side of the equation. We can't simply
look to ways of stimulatin~ investment demand; We also have to find
ways of stimulating individuals to save more.
.
I think the idea of allowing deductions for savings seems radical
when you first think of it, but when you look at ouT tax system in detail,
it is clear we already do that to some extent. Most savings now is done
through the pension system where individuals don't pay tax on that
savings, or through individual retirement accounts, Keogh accounts,
or through accrued capital gains in which individuals don't pay taxes,
·
rolJovers on their own homes, et cetera.
We are fa,r along that route, but we have done it in a ha,nhazard way
rather than having a general policy of allowing people substantial reductions for savings, something other countries have done.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

267
The Canadians recently began a program of what in our terms would
be individual retirements accounts, but independent of whether people
were under corporate pensions, allowing p~ople to deduct that from
their taxable income.
Senator HATCH. How are savings, growth, and social security related? Can we pay the benefits we have promised without first providing a substantial increase in GNP?
Mr. FEWSTEIN. I am glad you asked that.
In my view, social security is a major force depressing savings in the
United States. For most American families now, social security has
become the major asset. A typical person who retires now, who has had
average earnings over his entire life, who has a dependent spouse, gets
benefits which replace 70 percent of his peak earnings on a pretax basis.
If you think about those as replacing aftertax dollars, that is about
85 percent. So there is really no incentive for people with middle incomes and below to do any private saving at all, given the current
social security system. I think the financial mess social security is in
provides an opportunity to rethink the growth of benefits that Congress enacted a few years ago, while mamtaining benefits for people
today and not cutting benefits at all in the future, reducing the rate of
growth of those benefits, causing individuals, theirefore., to depend
more upon private pensions and direct savings ap a way of accumulating for their retirement.
If we did that, we would have much more capital in our own
economy.
Senator BENTSEN. I am afraid that is it.
Thank you very much, gentlemen. We will stand in recess.
. [Whereupon, at 11 :40 a.m., the committee recessed, to reconvene at
9 :30 a.m., Wednesday, July 12, 1978.]
[The following information was subsequently supplied for the
record:]
AMERICAN TELEPHONE & TELEGRAPH Co.,
Ne·w York, N.Y., July 19, 1918.

Hon. RICHARD BOLLING,
House of Representatives,'
Rayburn House Office Bldg.,
Washington, D.O.

DEAR CHAIRMAN BOLLING: I appreciated the opportunity to testify at your invitation before The Joint Economic Committee on July 11th on the subject of
Capital Formation-Jobs and Inflation. The high priority you and your Committee have accorded to capital formation is most encouraging.
Time did not permit me to respond to a question Senator Bentsen asked at the
conclusion of the testimony. He asked whether the Investment Tax Credit, in fact,
influenced business decisions to make investments in new plant and equipment.
I believe it does. The Investment Tax Credit, also referred to as the Job Development Investment Credit, is a major consideration in making business investment decisions in the capital intensive industries that are at the heart of the
American economy. These include such industries as oil, steel, chemicals and
aluminum, and regulated industries such as the airlines, electric utilities and
telecommunications.
For example, in the telecommunications business, decisions to undertake and
imp1ement technological devE>lopment and to modernize facilities are to an important extent economic decisions. Assurance of the continued availability of
funds generated by the investment credit and by accelerated depreciation tax
deferrals is essential to business investment planning, especially in projects with
long lead times requiring substantial capital commitments. Loss of the Investment
Tax Credit would dramatically decrease demands upon the nation's capital


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

268
markets and serve to increase the cost of capital, risk slowing modernization projects and impede productivity, with the adverse effects on consumer prices and
employment which I described in my written and oral testimony before the
Committee.
I would also like to comment that the "off-again, on-again" use of the Investment Tax Credit (ITC) for "fine-tuning" that has occurred in the past has tended
to create uncertainty and that, to be effective, the ITC.must be made a permanent
feature of the tax law.
Because this issue is so important, I would appreciate it if this could be included in the Committee's record of the July 11th hearing as my response to Senator Bentsen's question.
Sincerely yours,
CHARLES D. KUEHNER, Ph. D.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

0