View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

RESPONSIBILITY FOR FEDERAL RESERVE POLICIES: 1927-1929
It has been stated that mistakes committed by the federal reserve system from 1927 to
1929 were due to the Federal Reserve Board. The 1927 easy money policy was initiated
by the New York reserve bank to encourage domestic business and strengthen European
exchanges. The policy was successful in achieving these objectives, but it gave a dangerous
impetus to stock market speculation. In the first half of 1928 the reserve banks took
vigorous action to restrain speculation with some success, but in the last half of the year
they relaxed their efforts and bought a large amount of acceptances. Early in 1929 the
Reserve Board took the lead and recommended "direct action" to restrict speculative loans.
The reserve banks then recommended rate increases. Differences were not as to aims but
as to methods. The lesson from this experience is that authority and responsibility for national credit policies should be concentrated in a single, independent, disinterested public
body having a national viewpoint.

The recent amendments to the Federal Reserve act gave rise before
their final enactment by Congress to pronounced differences of opinion
among observers of federal reserve policy and also among spokesmen of
various schools of banking and financial thought. More particularly, there
was an acute controversy with regard to the location of the responsibility for
the exercise of the open-market authority in the federal reserve system.
These discussions have sharpened interest in federal reserve history, and
especially in those episodes that throw light upon the wisdom with which
the system's open-market powers have been exercised in the past. The
greatest interest, as might naturally be expected, has been shown in the episode covering the period 1927-1929. Many commentators, reviewing the
policies of the federal reserve system during this period, have passed a
severe judgment upon them.
Not all these commentators, however, have confined themselves to
criticism of federal reserve policies. Some of them have undertaken in
addition to fix the responsibility for what has been variously characterized
as the "misdirected management" and the "unfortunate mistakes"1 of the
system during the period 1927-1929. Their tendency, in the main, has been
to ascribe the errors of judgment and faults of policy during that period
to the Federal Reserve Board; and the view has been frequently expressed
that, as between the federal reserve banks and the Federal Reserve Board,
the banks were right and the Board was wrong.
This view, as I shall undertake to show, is based upon partial and misleading information. The critics who condemn the Federal Reserve Board
and exculpate the federal reserve banks do so either through lack of
knowledge or in disregard of the following pertinent facts:
(1) That the Board's action in reducing the discount rate of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago in 1927 was in pursuance of a system policy initiated by
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and concurred in by all but one of the
federal reserve banks;
1
See, for example, page 52, The Great Depression, by Professor Lionel Robbins of
the University of London, and editorial, "Testimony on the Banking Bill" in the New
York Times of June 2, 1935.




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

443

(2) That the federal reserve banks took no action to check the growing tide
of speculation between July 13, 1928, and February 14, 1929; and
(3) That the first formal proposal for an increase in the discount rate from
5 to 6 per cent came to the Board on February 14, 1929, after the Federal Reserve
Board had sent to all federal reserve banks under date of February 2, 1929,
and had made public on February 7, 1929, a statement which undertook to curb
speculative excesses by a method which has come to be known as "direct action."
Let it be admitted at the outset that as a straight proposition of law, so
far as concerns the Federal Reserve Board, it must share the responsibility
for any action taken by a federal reserve bank, whether mistake or other-

PHYSICAL VOLUME OF INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

1925

1926

1927

CHART 1

wise, with respect to discount rates and open-market policies. Under the
terms of the Federal Reserve act, no change in discount rates proposed by
the federal reserve banks and no open-market policy proposed by the
Federal Open Market Committee can be put into effect until it has been approved by the Federal Reserve Board; but it is clear that action originates
with the federal reserve banks. The responsibility for initiative vests in
them. The primary responsibility is, therefore, theirs; the secondary and
ultimate responsibility is the Board's. This must be borne in mind in any
attempt to locate in any other than a formal and legal sense the actual




A. C. Miller

444

[September

responsibility for errors charged to the federal reserve system in the critical
period 1927 to 1929.
It is because of the bearing that a truer and fuller understanding of the
manner in which the federal reserve banks and the Federal Reserve Board
have discharged their respective responsibilities has upon pending banking
legislation that a clearing up of these misapprehensions takes on urgency3

WHOLESALE PRICES

1922

1923

1924

1925

1926
CHART 2

1927

1928

1929

1930

at this time. And it is because of this that I here propose to recite as briefly
as I can the facts which are essential to an understanding of the course of
federal reserve policy during the period 1927 to 1929. I shall endeavor to do.
this in a way that will make it easy to distinguish statements of fact from any
comment I may offer on the facts.
To facilitate brevity of exposition and to focus attention more quickly
upon the material points I shall state and answer a series of questions.
(1) What was there in the economic and financial situation in 1927
that caused the adoption by the federal reserve system of an easy money
policy during that year?
The record shows that in the summer of 1927 there appeared a downward
tendency in industrial production (Chart 1) and that commodity prices
(Chart 2), which had been declining since the autumn of 1925, were at




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

445

the lowest level in five years. There was apprehension that this downturn
in business might foreshadow the coming of a depression. A marked decline
in production and employment in the durable goods industries did, in fact,
develop in the last half of the year.
In addition to disquieting domestic factors in the economic situation in
1927, the European monetary and financial situation, particularly as it

MEMBER BANK RESERVES,
RESERVE BANK CREDIT, AND GOLD

CHART 3

might affect the United States, was far from satisfactory. European currencies, and particularly sterling, were showing weakness. It was feared that
this would interfere with sales of our agricultural products in the autumn
months. Considerable concern was also felt regarding the position of the
gold standard in those European countries which had already restored it
and also regarding the prospects of its early and successful restoration in
others which had the matter under consideration.
(2) What were the objectives of the policy then developed?
It may be said that the objective of federal reserve policy in 1927 was
to set in motion such forces as the system could command to counteract the



446

A. C. Miller

[September

recessionary forces which were in evidence. To this end there was developed
and adopted a policy of easing both the domestic and the international
financial situation by purchasing securities in the open market and by reducing discount rates, thus cheapening the cost of credit to borrowing member
banks.
To relate the sequence of these open-market operations and discount
MONEY RATES IN NEW YORK CITY

CHART 4

rate changes, without going into too much detail, the following summary
will suffice:
The policy began in May, 1927, with purchases of United States government securities by federal reserve banks, which carried their holdings from
$300,000,000 in May to $600,000,000 in December. As a result of these operations member banks were able to meet gold withdrawals of $200,000,000
and to increase their reserve balances by over $100,000,000 without being under the necessity of increasing their borrowings from the reserve
banks (Chart 3). Discount rates at all the reserve banks were reduced from
4 to 3 1/2 per cent during the third quarter of the year.
Money rates in the open market soon declined (Chart 4), sterling exchange advanced, and in time there was a considerable outflow of gold
from the United States to other countries.
(3) Was the policy successful in achieving its objectives?
It was. The tide of business recession or depression, whichever it was,




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

447

was arrested toward the end of the year 1927. The production curve turned
sharply upward and, except for a halt of short duration in the spring of
1928, maintained a steady ascent until the summer of 1929 (Chart 1).
Prices of farm and related products showed a marked rise in the latter part of
1927 and in 1928 the general level of wholesale prices was characterized
by relative stability (Chart 2). The European currencies, notably sterling,
strengthened and, in general, tension in the European financial situation was
considerably relieved.
So far, then, as the policy of mid-summer 1927 was instrumental in resisting the forces of business depression, stimulating production, giving
stability to the price level, and strengthening foreign currencies, it must
be pronounced to have been successful. Were this all that there was to the
episode, it might be regarded, as many felt disposed to regard it at the time,
as a brilliant exploit in central bank policy and as a demonstration of the
reasonableness of the belief, which existed in the minds of many economists
and others at the time, that through well conceived and well timed monetary
policy the terrors of the business cycle could be largely if not wholly removed
and price stability and economic prosperity be insured under the operation
of the federal reserve system. It will not be forgotten that by many the
opening of the year 1928 was heralded as the beginning in these respects, as
well as in many others, of a "new era."
Unfortunately the 1927 policy of the federal reserve had other effects
beside those which were sought and intended. In the light of the longer
perspective in which we can now view these other and further effects they
stand out as the larger and more serious consequences of the policy then
initiated and pursued. But before leaving the year 1927 there is a further
question with reference to it which remains to be considered.
(4) Who proposed the policy pursued?
The policy above outlined was originated by the New York Federal
Reserve Bank, or more particularly by its distinguished governor, the late
Benjamin Strong. Brilliant of mind, engaging of personality, fertile of resource, strong of will, ambitious of spirit, he had extraordinary skill in impressing his views and purposes on his associates in the federal reserve system. His ideas began to develop in the spring of 1927, but his program was
not shaped until after conferences with representatives of the three great
European central banks, who visited the United States in the summer of
that year. This program was then presented to the federal reserve system
in informal conferences with federal reserve bank governors, proposed to
the Federal Reserve Board and approved by it, and participated in by the
federal reserve banks with dissent on the part of only one. The Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago was reluctant to fall in line with the reductions
of discount rates that were being made at the other reserve banks, and its
rate wasfinallyreduced by the Federal Reserve Board.




448

A. C. Miller

[September

The general policy adopted at the time, therefore, was a system policy,
conceived and initiated by the governor of the New York Reserve Bank,
but approved at a meeting in July participated in by the Open Market Committee, which consisted of five reserve bank governors, by members of the

BROKERS LOANS
MADE BY REPORTING MEMBER BANKS IN N.Y. CITY

CHART 5

Federal Reserve Board, and by two governors and one chairman of midwestern reserve banks. It was not, as might be inferred from the Times
editorial, a policy either developed or imposed by the Board on the reserve
banks against their will. It was distinctly a reserve bank policy.




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

449

The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City reduced its rate from 4 to
per cent on July 29; other federal reserve banks reduced their rates in quick
succession, St. Louis on August 4; Boston and New York on August 5;
Cleveland on August 6; Dallas on August 12; Atlanta on August 13; and
Richmond on August 16. The directors of the Chicago bank, the second
largest bank in the system, delayed action until the Federal Reserve Board
reduced its rate on September 7, in accordance with the system policy.
Thereafter, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia reduced its rate on
September 8; San Francisco on September 10; and Minneapolis on September 13.
The reductions in discount rates, except in the case of Chicago were
authorized by the boards of directors of the respective federal reserve banks
and approved by the Federal Reserve Board. The action of the Board in
reducing the rate at Chicago was taken after funds began to move away
from districts in which rates had been lowered, a development which appeared to jeopardize the achievement of the general objective of the system's
policy, a necessary part of which was the maintenance of easy conditions in
the New York money market.
(5) What further results ensued?
Effects of cheap and abundant credit during the autumn of 1927 were
not limited to stimulating business and production and to sustaining the
price level and the European exchanges. Cheap credit gave a further great
and dangerous impetus to an already overexpanded credit situation, notably
to the volume of credit used on the stock exchanges (Chart 5), and to a
further rapid upward flight of security prices (Chart 6). In consequence, the
federal reserve system was confronted toward the end of the year 1927 with
the problem of getting control of the fund of credit which it had been instrumental in placing in the market and keeping it within the bounds of
safety lest an uncontrollable and disastrous speculative situation should
develop. In consonance with this attitude the federal reserve system abandoned the policy it had been pursuing of offsetting exports of gold by the
restoration of a similar volume of credit to the money market through the
purchase of United States government securities, and allowed exportations
of gold to exert their tightening effect on the money market. The effect,
however, in the situation then existing was not very considerable. The stock
market expansion had acquired too much momentum. It was evident that
its pull was too strong to be counteracted by gold withdrawals.
An added factor of adverse character arose out of the exigencies in connection with the conversion of the Second Liberty Loan. The Treasury
found that actual cash outgo for redemptions in connection with its refinancing program outran its current cash intake and was, therefore, carried
by the federal reserve banks for a period of about a month on overdraft in




450

A. C. Miller

[September

varying amounts up to as much as $200,000,000, with an average during
the period of about $70,000,000, thus neutralizing to that extent the policy
of the reserve banks.
Total loans and investments of member banks during the second half
of the year 1927 showed a pronounced upward movement. There was an
active demand for funds in security markets, both in connection with specuSTOCK PRICES
PER CENT

421 COMMON STOCKS
INDEX OF STANDARD STATISTICS CO., 1926=100

PER CENT

CHART 6

lative trading and with the issuance of new securities. There being an
abundance of loanable funds, with no considerable demand for loans from
business, the funds held by the banks went into investments and loans on
securities. Bank loans to security brokers in New York increased during
1927 by about $600,000,000 (Chart 5).

Restrictive Policy in First Half of 1928
In the first half of 1928 the reserve system took successive measures to
check the further expansion of bank credit. Approximately $400,000,000
of United States government securities were sold from the system's holdings. Discount rates were raised from 31/2per cent to 4 per cent by all federal
reserve banks between January 25 and March 1, to41/2per cent between
April 20 and June 7, and to 5 per cent by 8 banks in July. Sales of securities




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

451

by the reserve banks and further loss of gold, amounting to $250,000,000,
forced member banks to borrow at the reserve banks. Bills discounted rose
to over $1,000,000,000 for the first time since 1921 (Chart 3). Call loan
rates rose to over 6 per cent by the middle of the year. The increase in brokers' loans by banks was definitely checked (Chart 5). Those by New York
City banks for their own account declined considerably. Brokers' loans by
non-banking lenders, however, attracted by high rates, increased more rapidly than before. The rise in stock prices was interrupted early in the year
and again in mid-summer, but these were but brief interruptions (Chart 6).
Thereafter evidence was accumulating that the speculative boom had become so intrenched and was exercising such a pull that an increase in the
cost of bank funds appeared to be no longer sufficient to check it and more
extraordinary forms of control had to be considered.
Under conditions existing in previous stock market booms the measures
adopted by the reserve system might have been sufficient to check the speculative expansion, but this was a new situation. In the first place, the astonishing increase in the earnings of large corporations and the extremely low
rates of interest at which money could be borrowed appeared to supply a
basis for the high prices that were being paid for stocks of companies
whose earnings were rising and whose dividend disbursements, not only
through extra dividends but through regular dividends, were far above the
going price of money. To put the matter bluntly, the market was actively
engaged in recapitalizing the values of securities on the basis of exceptional
earnings and artificially low interest rates for money. Second, the fact that
banks could in an emergency rediscount, as was not the case in stock market
booms of the pre-federal reserve period, inclined the banks to feel that they
could expand in the assurance that in case of need they could turn to the
reserve banks for assistance; and third, the supply of non-banking funds
available for "street loans" was larger than on any previous occasion. Consequently, whereas in earlier periods call money rates in a crisis rose to 20,
40, and even 100 per cent, in the first half of 1928 the rate did not rise
above 8 per cent. Higher levels were reached later, but never over 20 per
cent, and that for only a few hours.
Passive Policy in the Last Half of 1928
No further measures of restraint were adopted by the federal reserve system in the latter half of 1928. This was due in part to the expectation, based
on previous experience, that the seasonal demands for funds in themselves
would act as a tightening and restraining influence. There was also some fear
that with money rates at the prevailing high levels crop-moving and other
business activities might be severely handicapped.
These expectations were not realized owing to developments in the acceptance market. The reserve bank buying rate for bankers' acceptances had



452

A. C. Miller

[September

been advanced, but at41/2per cent was still below the discount rate. There
was a heavy demand for acceptance credits at the time, and metropolitan
banks were able to obtain reserve bank funds at rates below the discount
rate through the creation of acceptances and their sale to the reserve banks.
The banks, therefore, were able to expand their security loans without going
further into debt at the reserve banks. In fact, the purchase by the reserve
banks in the New York money market of acceptances in large volume
enabled the member banks actually to reduce their indebtedness to the reserve banks at the very period when restraint of speculation should have
continued to be reserve bank policy (Chart 3). Brokers' loans by both banks
and others increased rapidly (Chart 5) and bank loans on securities to others
than brokers also increased. Stock prices rose rapidly (Chart 6). Money
rates on acceptances and commercial paper did not rise in this period but
rates for "street loans" rose sharply, reflecting the intensity of the demand
for such loans (Chart 4).
In the face of these developments, the federal reserve system failed to
pursue affirmatively the policy of restraint adopted in the early part of
1928. Taking the period from mid-summer of 1928 until the early days
of February, 1929, the policy pursued by the federal reserve system may
be characterized in the light of all that is known now, and much of which
was visibly in process then, as a policy lacking in strong conviction with regard to current developments profoundly affecting the federal reserve system, the banking system, and the economic and financial condition of the
country.
In attempting to locate and assess responsibility for the delay and inactivity of the federal reserve system during the second half of the year 1928,
the incontrovertible fact is that during this period as well as during the
preceding year the leadership of the federal reserve system rested with the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. There is no attempt here to deny the
responsibility of the Federal Reserve Board, without whose sanction no steps
could be undertaken. But the responsibility of the Board was secondary.
Its mistake was in waiting too long before assuming active leadership in
firm intervention in the situation. A partial explanation for the hesitancy on
the part of the Board at this time, in the absence of proposals for action from
the reserve banks, may be found in the Federal Reserve act itself and in the
tradition that had grown up in the system. This tradition was that initiative
in credit policy should originate with the federal reserve banks, and that
the Board's function ordinarily should be to approve or disapprove proposals brought forward by the banks.
In the critical situation which developed in the second half of the year
1928 the Board followed the course of waiting for proposals by the reserve
banks to be submitted to it for review. No such proposals were made. It is
true that on some occasions the Board had assumed a more positive attitude




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

453

in the matter of the determination of discount rates, but on the last occasion
on which it had aggressively intervened (the reduction of the Chicago rate
in 1927) the reaction, both in public and governmental circles, had been
generally unfavorable.
That the responsibility of the Federal Reserve Board was great, I should
be the last to deny. But it erred chiefly in following the more customary
course indicated by the law and by practice rather than adopting a bolder
course which might have been possible under the law but was not clearly
made the Board's responsibility.
Looking at the matter in a practical way, it will be recognized, and it
should not be overlooked in this connection, that the unfavorable public
reaction to the assumption by the Board in the Chicago rate controversy in
1927 of authority to force rate action by federal reserve banks was not calculated to stimulate its sense of responsibility for appropriate and timely
federal reserve policy. There is a great difference between the power to
initiate action and the authority to review proposals after they have been
made.
No one can tell whether the policies of the federal reserve system in
1927 and 1928 would have been different had the Board had full responsibility for action. But it is abundantly clear that acceptance by the Board
of aggressive easing action proposed by the New York Federal Reserve
Bank in 1927 and of complete abandonment of restraining action in the
second half of 1928 proves that the Board, under the established tradition,
was first too quick to fall in with a daring and dangerous proposal and later
too slow to assume the leadership which was needed and was lacking at a
most critical time. It is my belief that, if the Board had had full responsibility
in the matter, it would not have adopted so readily the easing program of
1927 and would have acted more promptly in assuming leadership after
July, 1928.
But be this as it may, as things then were in the second half of 1928 the
Board looked to the federal reserve banks for the initiation of further
measures of restraint and the banks, in turn, depended on the leadership of
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. And New York's leadership
proved to be unequal to the situation.
An inquiry why federal reserve bank leadership erred during this period
would make an illuminating and most instructive contribution to the problem of how to secure a more continuously effective leadership and responsibility in federal reserve administration. One observation may be made and
that is that the supercharged atmosphere of the country's great financial
and speculative center is not one which can be said to be conducive to sustained detachment of mind and interest or to a clear perspective with regard
to current developments and their implications when the tempo is as swift
as it was in this period of optimism gone wild and cupidity gone drunk.



454

A. C. Miller

[September

However this may be, it is a fact that while the attitude of the federal reserve banks was one of tolerance and temporizing and the federal reserve
system as a whole was, as I have elsewhere stated, "drifting" in the midst
of a perilous situation that called for intervention, the Federal Reserve
Board was growing more and more anxious at the course of developments.
Ultimately its anxiety reached a point where it felt that it must itself assume the responsibility of intervening in the dangerously expanded and
expanding speculative situation menacing the welfare of the country. This
it did early in February, 1929.
Board's Direct Action Policy in 1929
On February 2 the Board directed a letter to the federal reserve banks
and on February 7 it issued a statement to the public carrying the substance
of the letter previously addressed to the banks, in which, after expressing
its anxiety with regard to current developments, it laid down an interpretation of the Federal Reserve act under which it was stated:
The Federal Reserve Board neither assumes the right nor has it any disposition to set itself up as an arbiter of security speculation or values. It is, however,
its business to see to it that the federal reserve banks function as effectively as conditions will permit. When itfindsthat conditions are arising which obstruct federal
reserve banks in the effective discharge of their function of so managing the
credit facilities of the federal reserve system as to accommodate commerce and
business, it is its duty to inquire into them and to take such measures as may be
deemed suitable and effective in the circumstances to correct them; which, in the
immediate situation, means to restrain the use, either directly or indirectly, of
federal reserve credit facilities in aid of the growth of speculative credit.
This interpretation was the basis of what soon came to be known as the
policy of "direct pressure." It was, in brief, a method of exercising restraint
upon the speculative credit expansion then in process by restricting the borrowings from the federal reserve banks by those member banks which were
increasingly disposed to lend funds for speculative purposes.
It should be particularly emphasized and noted that not until the Board
thus declared its own attitude and the position which it deemed appropriate for the federal reserve system as a whole did the federal reserve banks
come forward with proposals for discount rate action looking to restraint
of credit. It was on February 14, twelve days after the Board's warning
letter, that the Federal Reserve Bank of New York submitted to the Federal
Reserve Board its recommendation that its discount rate be raised to 6 per
cent. This was the first proposal for an advance in discount rates to reach
the Board after the 5 per cent rate was established in July of the preceding
year.
Thereupon an acute controversy extending over a period of months developed between the federal reserve banks and the Federal Reserve Board




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

455

with reference to the respective merits of the policies of control through
discount rate advances and through "direct pressure" It is the theory of
discount rate advances that they increase the cost of credit to borrowing
member banks and thus tend to restrain borrowings. In ordinary circumstances, and especially when the discount rate of a reserve bank is abreast of
or above going money rates in the market, the method of controlling an expanding situation through discount rate increase has frequently proved
efficacious. But in such a situation as existed in the opening months of 1929
with the rate for call money fluctuating between 6 and 20 per cent, it
would have been necessary to step up federal reserve bank rates to unprecedented levels in order to catch up with the rapid ascent of rates in
the open-money market. To have done that would have involved damaging
disorganization of the whole structure of commercial money rates, with
economic consequences that could not be accurately foretold and might
easily in the then existing situation have proved disastrous. A prompt and
energetic stepping up of the discount rate in the earlier stages of a pronounced credit and speculative expansion might have been relied upon to
exercise an effective restraining and corrective influence, but when the rate
of speculative expansion had attained such speed and the thirst for credit
had attained such intensity as was the case at the beginning of the year
1929 and earlier, control through discount rate increase, to put the matter
mildly, is at best to be regarded as a frail reliance and a dubious expedient.
In the circumstances which existed at the time when the Board made its
announcement with regard to "direct pressure," the speculator did not ask
what was the cost of money but whether he could get it at any price. The
increase of rate might even have been a relief to the speculative market inasmuch as it would have carried the suggestion, whether so intended or not,
that money would be forthcoming from the federal reserve banks so long
as the stipulated price for it was paid. "Direct pressure," on the other
hand, works as the name indicates, by direct control of member banks instead of indirectly through money rates. As applied in 1929, it put the
member bank, which was seeking federal reserve credit facilities in order
to support or increase its extensions of credit for speculative uses, under
pressure by obliging it to show that it was entitled to accommodation, and
leaving undisturbed such member banks as were borrowing in the usual
course from their federal reserve banks for meeting commercial requirements. It was, in brief, a method of exercising a discriminating control over
the extension of federal reserve credit such as the purely technical and impersonal method of bank rate could not do. "Direct pressure," furthermore,
is a more flexible method of control, capable of easy adjustment, if circumstances should demand. By comparison, the discount rate is a more formal
device, and one that in a rapidly shifting scene is rigid and clumsy. Pressure can easily be increased or diminished through direct action. Change




456

A. C. Miller

[September

of discount rate, because it is a more formal and public proceeding, takes
on the aspect of a signal indicating change of direction or change of policy,
and therefore is less likely to be invoked promptly as soon as indications of
changes in the situation become discernible. To put it bluntly, though not
elegantly, control by rate action in a speculative gale of such fury as swept
the United States in 1929 is a good deal like spitting against the wind.
The Board's opinion that "direct pressure" would afford not only a
method more appropriate in the circumstances than a discount rate increase but also one likely to prove highly successful in putting an effective
pressure upon the hitherto expanding volume of speculative credit was
vindicated by the influence this policy exerted shortly after the beginning of
its application.
From the beginning of February until the end of May brokers' loans
by reporting member banks declined by about $650,000,000; and although
brokers' "loans by others" continued to increase, the total of brokers' loans
showed a net decline in this period (Chart 5). Money rates increased
sharply (Chart 4 ) . Stock prices, which had been rising rapidly, fluctuated
within a comparatively narrow range (Chart 6).
By the middle of June it became apparent that in the then existing psychological and economic situation continuance of unremitting pressure on
the market, particularly with the known heavy financial requirements of
many leading industrial undertakings at the approaching end of the fiscal
year, might precipitate a catastrophe. The Board, after a conference with a
delegation of New York reserve bank directors, decided to relax for the
time being but not to abandon its "direct pressure." It was moreover then
becoming evident that the stock market was reaching a point where it would
collapse of its own weight, and that the principal concern of the federal
reserve system should be to prepare itself to help the banks and the country
to absorb the imminent shock as soon as it occurred.
It is not without signficance in current discussions as to the proper distribution of authority between the banks and the Board, that during the
tension occasioned by the acute differences over the leadership of the federal
reserve system in the six months following the Board's declaration of its
position of February 2, 1929, the five members of the Board who took the
responsibility of formulating the attitude and policy for the federal reserve
system were opposed by a minority of their own membership, including the
Secretary of the Treasury, the governor and the vice-governor, by the twelve
federal reserve banks and, finally, by the Federal Advisory Council and
many, but by no means all, of the largest member banks. This was a formidable opposition. Nevertheless the Board adhered to its position, firm in its
conviction that it was pursuing the only proper and effective course of action,
belated though it was, which was open to the federal reserve system at the
time. That it did not err in its judgment from a public point of view seems




1935]

Federal Reserve Policies: 1927-1929

457

sufficiently established by the fact that several of the most important amendments written into the Banking act of 1933 with regard to the federal reserve system were based upon the attitude of the board as expressed in 1929
and the procedures then developed. This was a ratification by the Congress
of the United States of what had been undertaken by the Board in the early
months of 1929 in the face of determined resistance.
The Lessons of This Experience
Looking at the record of this period 1927-1929, as thus briefly recited,
certain conclusions, I believe, will suggest themselves to anyone who is seriously interested in drawing from this chapter of federal reserve experience
lessons which are pertinent to any future discussion of the modification of
the federal reserve system brought about by the Banking act of 1935. More
particularly, these lessons have a bearing on that phase of the new legislation
which would provide a more definite concentration of authority over the
open-market policy of the federal reserve system.
The first of these lessons clearly points to the inadvisability of a division
of responsibility in a matter of such vital national moment. Whatever might
be said for the former system theoretically, it did not, in its actual working,
produce a satisfactory result, as the 1927-1929 experience appears clearly
to demonstrate; and it did not do it, in my opinion, because the responsibility
was divided.
Unity of responsibility, my experience with the federal reserve system
has convinced me, is essential to the ceaseless concern and vigilance which
are necessary for timely and vigorous action in matters of central banking
policy and administration. I would put the matter this way:
(1) The authority to initiate policies carries with it the opportunity to
exercise leadership and involves a far greater degree of responsibility than
the mere authority to approve or disapprove policies initiated by others.
(2) The body which initiates a policy should be under obligation to
watch its consequences and to inaugurate a change whenever circumstances
make it advisable. In other words, responsibility should be continuous.
(3) The judgment of the bankers or of officers of federal reserve banks
regarding national credit policies has proved itself not to be infallible, and
they cannot always be trusted to reverse their policies promptly when the
public interest requires such action.
(4) The authority to initiate national credit policies should be concentrated in a single body which should have definite responsibility to the public not only for the initiation of policies but also for following them through,
watching their effect and initiating changes or modifications when the public interest requires.
This brings us, in conclusion, to the question in what body should such
authority and responsibility be concentrated.




458

A. C. Miller

[September

It is my conviction that it should be lodged in a body, no matter how
constituted, having a national viewpoint and owing undivided allegiance
to the general public interest. Its judgment should not be warped by the
viewpoint of any particular section of the country or by the special interests
of any particular group. It should be an impartial, independent body with
a keen and continuous sense of public duty and a point of view sufficiently
detached to avoid having its judgment as to long-time policies swayed by
the popular clamor of the moment.
A. C. MILLER

Federal Reserve Board