View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

INFLATION CONTROL
EXTRACT FROM

HEARINGS
BEFORE THE

COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND CURRENCY
UNITED STATES SENATE
E I G H T I E T H CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION
ON

CONTROL OF INFLATION

INFLATION: DANGERS AND

REMEDIES

By L E O N H . K E Y S E R L I N G
Vice Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers
(Statement before Senate Committee on Banking and Currency
August 4, 1948)

79768




UNITED STATES
GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1948

INFLATION CONTROL
Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am particularly
appreciative of the opportunity to discuss with this committee some
current facts about our economy and some of the economic analyses
which may be applied to these facts, because this committee had
initial legislative responsibility for the Employment Act of 1946
under which I serve as Vice Chairman of the Council of Economic
Advisers. The high purpose of this act was that, while no men are
infallible and economics is not an exact science, men of good will
could be aided by the known and tested tools of economics in evaluating and deciding upon national policies in the national interest.
I am deeply conscious that my only function here is to lay before
you some of the facts and some of the methods of economic analysis
which may help you in evaluating proposed public policies. This
task of ultimate evaluation is yours, not mine, and if I should overstep this boundary it will not be intentional.
For almost 2 years, the members and staff of the Council of Economic Advisers have been devoting constant study to the tasks and
trials of our complex and tremendous economy during a period of
postwar transition characterized for the most part by the central
problem of inflation.
I n the course of our studies, we have received additional evidence
that no economist will ever have a perfect answer to practical problems. But because we have assumed a public responsibility, these
imperfections have not turned us from seeking clearer understandings,
more workable answers, and a wider range of common agreement.
Considering the difficulty of our work, and the imponderables
involved, we have arrived at a surprising degree of agreement as to
what the facts say, what they mean, and what should be done about
them. That appears clearly from various publications issued by the
Council as a whole, such as its recent report on The Economic Situation at Midyear 1948. However, I ought to say that my statement
here today is my own in the sense that no two individuals in a field
such as economics ever use exactly the same process of reasoning or
stress exactly the same points in reaching results.
308




3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

I n the current economic situation, as I see it, there are compelling
reasons why inaction is fraught with danger, and why men must act
even if they cannot be absolutely certain of every step they take.
The material that I should like to bring before you classifies easily
into four main parts:
First, as an aid in the interpretation of specific data and problems,
I shall attempt to state a few general principles and uncover a few
current fallacies. Without this as a foundation, we all seem to be
confronted with a hopelessly baffling welter of facts, contentions, and
conflicting viewpoints;
Second, upon this foundation, I shall attempt to build a fair portrayal of some of the most serious maladjustments and disparities
which our economy is generating in the process of inflation, and to
indicate how these maladjustments and disparities are now imposing
genuine hardships upon millions of our people and how they threaten
all of our people if they are not corrected;
Third, I shall endeavor to show why the prospects for continuing
inflation are so substantial as not to justify the belief that relief will
come quickly, or come at all without involving even more serious
dangers, if this inflation is left to follow what might be called its
"normal" course;
Fourth, I shall try to apply some economic analysis toward an
evaluation of various proposals now before the committee for consideration, in terms of their relevance to the current and immediately
prospective economic situation.
BASIC PRINCIPLES A N D CURRENT FALLACIES

Generally speaking, we are now and for some time have been in an
era of rising prices, wages, and other incomes, accompanied by rising
costs. I n popular terms, this situation and the processes by which
it is unfolding are called inflation. I t is frequently stated that this
inflation is taking place because demand for goods is being exerted
in the market in excess of the supply of goods flowing into the market.
This demand for goods is made manifest by money exerted as spending power; and consequently it is said that inflation is taking place
because the money supply is unusually high in relation to the volume
of available goods.
The total money supply, which was 26.5 billion dollars in 1929,
rose to 37 billion in 1939, and to 115.1 billion in 1947. In June 1948,
it stood at 110.4 billion dollars. (See chart 1, p. 310.) Manifestly, the
money supply has increased much more than the volume of available
goods.
The proposition that the relationship between the money supply
and the available supply of goods has a basic influence upon the level
of prices and incomes of all kinds is obviously correct as a statement of
fact. But it does not in itself tell us much about causes and effects.
More important, it does not in itself tell us why the current inflation
is dangerous, or where the particular dangers lie, or why we need to
worry if nothing is done about these dangers, or what ought to be done
about them. Until this is firmly recognized, we are likely to be misled
by oversimplified or distorted solutions focusing attention upon the




3.12




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

money supply alone. This is true because it is not demonstrable that
a generally rising price level interacting with a generally rising money
supply is bad per se. We had a falling price level after 1929, and the
country was certainly not on the way to prosperity. We had a rising
price level after 1932, and yet the country was on the way to increasing
employment and production. We had a fairly stable price level in the
later twenties, and yet obviously something must have been wrong
with the economy in view of what ensued although everyone will not
agree as to just what was wrong. I n short, there is no arbitrarily
sound or even preferable price level or course of price movements—
such as those of 1926 or 1939 or 1946—as distinguished from some
other price level or course of price movements; and, therefore, there
is no arbitrarily sound or ideal relationship between the size of the
money supply and the available supply of goods.
To detect whether our economy is in a state of danger or safety, we
must concentrate foremost attention upon other things besides the
over-all levels or movements of prices and the money supply. I n a
period such as the present, when prices, wages and other incomes are
far above prewar levels, and when employment and production and
other indexes of useful business activity are also far above prewar
levels, the most important thing to be considered is the relationship
among these various factors in the economy rather than the absolute
magnitude or course of each factor viewed separately. This is
particularly true when the relationships among these separate factors,
as well as the absolute magnitudes of each of them, have been changing
substantially for some time and are changing rapidly now.

Since 1939 (see chart 2, p. 312) these relationships have changed
enormously, and they have been changing greatly during the accelerated inflationary process since the middle of 1946. To select a few
items, employment since 1939 to the middle of 1948 has increased
about 28 percent; consumers prices about 70 percent; wholesale prices
about 112 percent; weekly earnings in manufacturing about 118
percent; gross national product in current dollars about 173 percent;
manufacturing sales about 231 percent; and corporate profits after
taxes about 272 percent. The base year that I have chosen, 1939, is
used only to illustrate the point generally that relationships have
changed greatly. The use of this base year should not be taken as an
assertion that it is the best base year for all purposes of comparison or
analysis.
The

CHAIRMAN.

Where is your cost of living there?

Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . The cost of living is represented by the consumer price index; that has gone up 70 percent.
The C H A I R M A N . M a y I interrupt you? I am puzzled. Hold that
a second.
K i n d l y show me the relative difference between the cost of living
and the wage income.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . I w i l l show that in much greater detail, M r .
Chairman, in the further charts.




312




INFLATION

CONTROL

3.12

INFLATION

The

CHAIRMAN.

CONTROL

Thank you.

Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I n probing the significance of these changes in
relationships, there are two current fallacies to be avoided. First, it
is fallacious to assume that dangers or maladjustments have been
created in our economy simply because the indexes of various items
have moved upward, or that the cure lies simply in moving them downward. For example, it is certainly desirable that employment and
production are much higher now than in 1939. Likewise, it is to be
expected that both wages and profits should be higher now than in
1939. The second fallacy to be avoided is the idea that there is any
danger or maladjustment in the current situation simply because some
of these items have moved upward faster than others. In a changing
and growing economy, some items must move upward faster than
others. For example, wages should be expected to move upward
faster than consumer prices during a period when there have been
vast increases in production for civilian use. Profits should be expected to move upward faster than prices during a period which has
carried us from large-scale unemployment to full employment. Thus,
persons who attempt to prove that dangers or maladjustments exist
solely because some items have moved upward faster or more slowly
than others are simply misjudging the nature of our economy in
action.
The real problem we face now, in order to detect dangers and maladjustments, is to examine carefully and objectfully whether the relationships among various factors in the economy have changed and
are changing soundly or unsoundly by reasonably derived objective
tests; whether these changes are bringing us into a state of better
balance or worse balance throughout the economy; whether they are
curing discernible maladjustments or causing further discernible maladjustments; in short, whether they are moving us nearer to a zone
of safety or further and further into a zone of danger.
On the basis of these principles, we may t u r n to a more specific
examination of the relationships that are developing i n our current
economy during the continuing process of inflation. The evidence,
as I shall t r y fairly to present i t , is that the changes that have occurred
and are still occurring i n the process of inflation are progressively
creating dangerous maladjustments which now inflict hardship upon
millions of individuals; and also maladjustments among price relationships, wage relationships, and price-wage relationships which are
now interfering w i t h essential national objectives, and which are also
distorting the pattern of production, consumption, and national
income in ways that will eventuate in a general economic decline of
employment and production if they are not corrected promptly.
CURRENT MALADJUSTMENTS AND T H E DANGERS T H E Y PRESENT

The first serious maladjustment to which attention should be
turned involves the effect of the continuing rise i n consumers' prices
upon family standards of living.
The C H A I R M A N . I think i t is the most important.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . I t is extremely important, perhaps the most
important.
Since June 1939 (see chart 3, p. 314), the consumers' price index for
all items has risen 74 percent; for food i t has risen 129 percent. B y




314




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

3.12

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

far the most rapid increases took place immediately after June 1946;
since then, the increase has been 29 percent for all items and 47 percent
for food. The increases since June 1947 have been 9 percent for all
items and 12 percent for food. While the net increases during the
past year have not been as rapid as in the preceding year, they have, of
course, come on top of earlier increases. Furthermore (see chart 4,
p. 317), the net increases during 1948 have been reduced by the downswing which followed the commodity break near the beginning of the
year; but since the middle of March the index for all cost-of-living
items, and particularly for food, has been rising very sharply. In the
second quarter of 1948, the food index rose at the rate of about 2 percent a month. I n recent months, the cost-of-living index has been
reaching new peaks.
The C H A I R M A N . Before you take that chart away, the lower strata
there gives some evidence that rent control, although it is much
maligned and created some injustice, has been effective in keeping
costs down?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . There is no doubt about that. You will notice
in this connection, Mr. Chairman, the beginning of the rise in rent
after the mid-1947 period.
The impact of the rising cost of living, in terms of hardship, is
necessarily associated with the distribution of family income. According to the most recent comprehensive studies covering 1947 (see chart
5, p. 318), about 50 percent of all families had incomes below the $3,200
a year estimated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics to be necessary to
maintain an urban family of four at a reasonably satisfactory standard of living. Between a quarter and a third of all families had incomes of less than $2,000 a year, and more than 10 percent had
incomes of less than $1,000 a year. Even allowing for the fact that
many of the families included in these statistics were of smaller size
than four, and that many of them were rural families where the cost
of living is somewhat less, it is nonetheless a palpable fact that a large
proportion of our population is being literally submerged by the high
cost of living.
I t may be said, of course, that "the poor are always with us"; that
millions of families were submerged even before the war and before
inflation; and that, relatively speaking, low-income families are better
off now than they were during prewar periods. If we take the whole
span of years since 1939 into account, these assertions are undoubtedly
true, because our total national output has gone up so much since
1939 that practically everyone has benefited to a degree. But this
would not be true since 1946, when postwar inflation got started in
earnest; since then, families of low income and moderately low income
have undoubtedly lost ground in the race with living costs. And 1946
if a fairer base of comparison than 1939 for this purpose, because our
national output now is quite similar to 1946 but far and away above
1939.
The C H A I R M A N . I n view of that situation shown by the crossed lines
under $3,200, in view of the price level and cost of living, it might not
be an overstatement to say that within the scope of those crossed lines
is a very definite, concentrated section of human beings in misery.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . There is no question about that.
Moreover, as a study of developments in 1946 and 1947 indicates
(chart 6, p. 319), while a majority of the families in the middle income
802626—48




2

3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

and upper income brackets have received increases in income as the
cost of living has advanced, a majority of those in the lowest income
brackets have either received no increases in income or have actually
suffered decreases in income. Among families with incomes under
$2,000, a full quarter suffered actual decreases of income during this
period, and an additional 40 percent of these families received no
increases in income. Thus, the families who have been the worst
victims of the advancing cost of living because their incomes are low
are also the families who have been least able even to hold their
ground during the process of inflation.
The sheer physical problem of being unable to maintain a satisfactory standard of living has been compounded by the psychological
problem of going deeper into debt. I n 1947 (see chart 7, p. 320),
about 57 percent of the families with incomes below $1,000 and about
41 percent of the families with incomes between $1,000 and $2,000
either spent more than they earned or barely broke even. By early
1948 (see chart 8, p. 321),.about 27 percent of all spending units had
no liquid assets, while another 15 percent had liquid assets of less than
$200, and still another 13 percent had liquid assets between $200 and
$500. Cumulative, about 55 percent of all spending units had liquid
assets of less than $500.
These hard facts illustrate one of the clearest and most undebatable
evils of spiraling inflation. There can be no disputing the truth that
inflation is imposing an intolerable and ever-increasing burden upon
millions of families. While it is hard to draw the line between matters
of social and economic significance, it is obvious that a social maladjustment so extensive in its range must have great economic significance in a nation of people who believe rightly that the ultimate
objective of their economic system is to promote the welfare and
security of its citizens as a whole.
The C H A I R M A N . We will recess at this point. I do not think we
will be gone more than 10 or 15 minutes, and we will extend your time.
(Brief recess.)
The

CHAIRMAN.

Come to order, please.

You may proceed, Mr. Keyserling.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Mr. Chairman, the main concern I have is that
these factual matters which I am presenting to you are the basis for
a brief discussion of how the various measures now before your
committee tie into this analysis.
I don't want
The C H A I R M A N . That brings us nearer and nearer to the $64
question of what we are going to do with it.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I don't want to burden you with the facts to the
extent of not getting to the very point and purpose of how I think
I can be helpful in the evaluation of measures, but I do think that
the facts are important.
Having covered the question of the effect of the price structure
upon people as individuals and families, I now turn to the wholesale
price situation, and will use this as a basis for what might be called
the economic as distinguished from the predominantly social question.
A second area in which the inflationary and uneven march of prices
is aggravating present maladjustments and storing up dangers for the
future is revealed by an analysis of wholesale price trends and relationships.



I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

TH

H
tf
<
w
o




317

318




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

CD
EH

«

<
W
o




319

320

i>
H
tf
W
o




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

3.12 INFLATION CONTROL

H
«

W
o




3.12

INFLATION CONTROL

Since June 1939 (see chart 9 below), the wholesale price index for
all commodities has increased 120 percent; for f a r m products, the i n crease has been 214 percent; for foods, 168 percent; and for products
other t h a n f a r m and foods, 86 percent. As i n the case of r e t a i l prices,
CHART

9

the sharpest increases have come since the middle of 1946. T h e significance of these trends i n wholesale prices m a y be appraised b y examining (a) the relative trends of a g r i c u l t u r a l a n d i n d u s t r i a l prices,
(6) the trends of a few specific i n d u s t r i a l prices w i t h p a r t i c u l a r stress
upon events of this year, and (c) the more general trends of prices as
they affect the relationship between funds available for business
investment and funds available for consumer use.




3.12

INFLATION CONTROL

The relative trends of agricultural and industrial prices may be evaluated by the test of equity, and also by the test of their implications
for the maintenance of economic stability at maximum levels of employment and production. By the test of equity, I do not share the
viewpoint of those who have belabored the proposition that agricultural prices have increased more than industrial prices since 1939 or
since some other base period. I n the main, I think it can be demonstated that the relatively greater gains in agricultural prices and
incomes have tended to redress the unfairly disparate position in which
farmers and farm families found themselves before the war in a predominantly industrial economy.
"While farm prices may well have climbed a bit too high at their
postwar peaks, in broader perspective the changes that have taken
place since 1939 for the most part not only represent an equitable
gain, but also represent a relationship between farm income and
other incomes that will maintain our whole economy in better balance
if it can be substantially retained. Moreover, by tMs vital test of
effect upon general economic stability, the quick adaptability of farm
prices to changes in the supp]y-and-demand situation gives reasonable
assurance that a substantial break in general levels of employment and
production will not be engendered by inflexibility or stickiness on the
part of farm prices. I n fact, experience thus far in 1948 (see chart
10, p. 324) illustrates quite clearly the almost unique sensitivity and
responsiveness of agricultural prices to the market situation and
outlook, compared with the fairly sustained pulse of rising industrial
prices. Thus the most recent experience tends to corroborate the
comments that I have just made with respect to the problems of
agricultural prices and industrial prices over the longer period since
1939. I venture the prediction, and it is one of the very few that I
shall make, that in the ensuing months and years the problem of
preventing agricultural prices and incomes from getting too high will
be less pertinent and less difficult than the problem of preventing
agricultural prices and incomes from falling so low in relation to other
prices and incomes as to jeopardize balanced national growth. This
balanced growth, as we have learned from experience, depends in
large measure upon such parity between agriculture and industry as
assures a high demand on the part of our farm population for the
products of our factories and city workers.
On the other hand, the fairly steady upward march of industrial
prices since 1939, which has been maintained thus far in this year
1948 (see again chart 10), is a cause of genuine concern. The reason
for this is that these prices are in large part administered or at least
partially administered prices, which we know from repeated experience do not respond so rapidly or so sensitively as farm prices to
changes in the composition of demand. If industrial prices go
beyond levels at which they can be permanently maintained, and this
they would seem already to have done, the necessary reductions in
such prices particularly if they are allowed to advance still further
along lines indicated by current trends will not be accomplished quickly
enough without being preceded by wide-scale unemployment and large
cut-backs in production. I t follows that, although farm prices happen now to have reached higher levels in relation to a prewar base,
there is a large margin of error in the oft-repeated proposition that
the problem of restraining industrial prices is less serious than the
802626—48




3

3.12




INFLATION CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

325

problem of restraining farm prices. There will be something further
to say about the trends in industrial prices, in connection with further
analysis of current dangers and maladjustments from the more general
perspective of price-income relationships throughout the economy.
The C H A I R M A N . What is that line, may I ask? Farm products?
That sharp digression downward back in July 1948. What are those
products that went down like that?
Mr. K E Y E R S L I N G . I would have to furnish you with a break-down
of that.
The C H A I R M A N . I think that is interesting.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I t is partly grains, but I would have to give you
a break-down.
The dangers in advancing industrial prices are further revealed by
examining some specific price trends in the industrial field (see chart
11, p. 326). During 1948 sustained and substantial industrial price
advances in highly significant areas have been occurring for metals
and metal products and for building materials, as well as for fuels
and lighting products. This continued upswing is taking place in
fields where the postwar demand thus far is extraordinarily high, in
view of the business reconversion and equipment boom, the cumulative shortage of housing, and the special demands of the preparedness program and the foreign aid program. True, if our economy is
maintained at full employment, it may continue to need an output
of metals and building materials as large or even larger than the present output. But it is extremely doubtful whether a demand sufficient
to absorb an output of this size can be maintained at current price
levels when the special temporary factors in demand just cited have
spent their main force.
For example, the country needs for at least 10 years an annual
volume of housing output as large, or even considerably larger, than
the current high level of house construction. But when the relatively
thin market of those who can buy high-priced or luxury housing is
saturated, and when the residential construction industry is faced
with the task of supplying the mass market of those who need far
more moderately priced housing, there is certain to be a collapse in
the postwar building boom, analogous to that which took place after
1925, unless prices are drastically lowered. M y personal belief is
that the postwar building boom at current prices cannot be sustained
for as many years as it was after the First World War. This forces
upon us tlie unpalatable conclusion that the rigidity and stickiness
of industrial prices in crucial fields will lead to serious unemployment
and cut-backs in production if the price level is permitted to move
further and further above levels that can be permanently maintained.
The continued upward surge of these industrial prices is also of
great significance in its effect upon the foreign-aid and preparedness
programs. This upsurge of prices confronts us w i t h the unhappy
choice either of carrying these programs forward at a slower pace
than our national interests require, or of serving these interests lully
at the cost of greater damage to the civilian distribution of the commodities involved than would result if a more restrained price policy
were pursued.
I n connection w i t h this phase of the industrial price situation, there
is to be considered the price-wage spiral. The movement for higher
wages through collective bargaining is not responsive solely to changes




326




INFLATION

CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

327

in the cost of living, although, most of the attention has focused upon
this aspect since the war. The demand for higher wages rests also
in large degree upon the price-profit picture in the industries that
pay the wages. Even if the cost of living should be leveled off or
reduced, no one familiar with the realities would predict that the
price-wage spiral can be stopped so long as industrial prices are moving
upward and resulting in such large net returns as now seem both
present and prospective.
This brings us to an examination of price trends in terms of their
effect upon the flow and use of national income. Particular emphasis
should be placed upon the key problem of maintaining a workable
balance between productive capacity and consumer buying power.
There is a general tendency to overlook this venerable problem in
the midst of inflation, although one of the main dangers of inflation
is that it stealthily creates conditions which will ultimately throw
this problem at us with stunning impact.
The CHAIRMAN. W h i c h is coincident w i t h deflation.
M r . KEYSERLING. W h i c h is coincident w i t h deflation, and this
is the real central danger of inflation, f r o m the economic point of
view. The paradoxical t h i n g about i t is t h a t inflation masks this
danger to the point t h a t i t is hard to see i t while the inflationary period
lasts, b u t i t is there, nonetheless.

The growing maladjustments taking place, during the process of
inflation, in the relationship between income available to stimulate
and finance production and income available for consumer use, may
best be revealed by examining trends in the gross national product and
in its composition.
Since 1929, there have been enormous changes in the gross national
product measured by current dollars, and very great changes in real
output are evidenced when the current dollar figures are deflated to
take account of price changes. (See chart 12, p. 329.) Our real
national output is about 72 percent higher now than in 1929, reflecting
a profound and presumably permanent change in the national economy. The gross national product in real terms was only very slightly
lower in 1947 than it was in 1946, when it still reflected conditions
carried over from the war. During the first half of 1948, the product
has been running at about the same annual rate as during 1947 as a
whole. The slight variations since 1946 are not very significant,
because of changes in the composition of the product which makes
available measurements inexact. I t is significant, however, that
total output since 1946 has not increased as might have been expected
in view of the volume of employment and the improved quality of
plant and equipment.
The gross national product may be translated into receipts and
expenditures by consumers, Government, business, and in the form
of net foreign investment. (See chart 13, p. 330.) For the purpose of
appraising trends in the composition of demand, the expenditures
figures are relevant. The expenditures of consumers, which may be
taken to represent the pull of consumers upon the total supply of goods
and services, dropped from 71.1 percent of the total gross national
product figure in 1939 to 65.2 percent in the first half of 1948. Contrasting tne same two periods, the expenditures of Government rose
from 18.5 percent of the total to 19.4 percent; net foreign investment
rose from 1 percent to 1.5 percent; and business investment rose from
9.5 percent to 13.9 percent. Thus, the most significant changes in the



3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

composition of demand since the last prewar year have been the sharp
downturn in the relative size of consumer expenditures, compensated
for mainly by the sharp upturn in the relative size of business investment. This reflects industry's postwar reconversion boom and does
not in itself reveal anything undesirable.
However, the present composition of expenditures or demand cannot be expected to maintain as we move to a more characteristically
peacetime economy. To preserve a workable balance between productive capacity and ultimate consumption, consumer expenditures
or demand will need to assume a relatively larger role, not only
because business will be through the reconversion and re-equipment
period but also because the relative role exerted by Government expenditures and net foreign investment must be expected to decline
with the advent of a more normal international situation. Yet, when
we examine the income relationships being developed in the current
inflationary process and remember that income is the foundation for
expenditures or demand, we find that these developing income relationships threaten to militate against, rather than to facilitate, the
necessary adjustments.
This conclusion rests on national-income analysis. The total of
national income, rising with the total gross national product, has increased in real terms by about 80 percent since 1929 and has not
changed significantly since 1946. (See chart 14, p. 331.) Upon
examining the composition of national income (see chart 15, p. 332), it
appears that the following developments have taken place: Compensation of employees has dropped from 65.9 percent of the national
income total in 1929 to 63 percent in 1947 and to 62 percent in the first
half of 1948. During the same three respective periods, business and
professional income has increased from 9.4 percent to 11.5 percent to
11.8 percent. Farm income has increased from 6.5 percent to 7.8 percent to 8.4 percent. Corporate profits and inventory valuation
adjustments have increased from 8 percent to 12.2 percent to 12.3
percent. Interest and rents dropped from 10.6 percent in 193-9 to
5.6 percent in 1947 and remained at the latter level during the first
half of 1948. The most important changes have been the increase in
the farmers' share, the significance of which I have already discussed;
the decrease in the share represented by compensation of employees;
and the very substantial increase in the share represented by corporate profits and inventory valuation adjustments, accompanied by
a lesser increase in the share represented by business and professional
income.
The C H A I R M A N . I S it correct, sir—do I interpret that chart aright—
that compensation to employees has been practically at parity from
'47 to '48?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . That is substantially correct, as a percentage of
the total national income, contrasting 1947 as a whole with the
annual rate during the first half of 1948. There has been a slight
downward movement of compensation to employees, from 63 to 62
percent.
The C H A I R M A N . H O W about corporate profit?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . There was a slight change upward, hardly discernible on the chart, from 12.2 percent to 12.3 percent, between 1947
and the first half of 1948. The great change in the corporate profits
percentage of total national income was from 8 percent in 1939 to
more than 12 percent in 1947 and in the first half of 1948.






I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

329

3.12




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

802626—48




4

331

3.12




INFLATION CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

333

The C H A I R M A N . That cannot be right; compensation to employees
in 1939 is 72 billion.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . N O ; that is the total figure for the whole bar,
representing total national income.
Senator S P A R K M A N . Y O U seem to have one element in the 1939
column that is not in the column to the right. I guess it is. Is that
business and professional income?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Yes; they are all in.
Senator S P A R K M A N . I t seems a little lighter on this side.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I t is the same. The width of the bars, rather
than the height of the bars, indicates the change in the total size of
the national income (deflated), which was 72.5 billion in 1939, rising
to 126.4 in 1947, and to an annual rate of 127.1 for the first half of
1948. •
The C H A I R M A N . For the sake of ordinary minds like ours, you
could elucidate that a little better in your chart to make that distinction.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I would like to try to do that.
Senator S P A R K M A N . Let me see if I understand. You have a percentage bar running up and down on both sides.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . The percentage bar indicates the percent of the
total that is taken by these various factors.
Senator S P A R K M A N . The percentage of the total which the compensation of employees bears in 1939 is not greatly out of line with
1947 and 1948, the percentage, not the quantity.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I t depends on what you mean by greatly. The
change has been from 6$. 9 percent, Senator, to 62 percent. When
you are dealing with large compounds, that is quite a substantial
change.
Senator S P A R K M A N . I t looks slight there.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I t is a substantial change.
These relative trends in the main types of income would not seem
to correlate at all well with the composition of expenditure or demand
that will be needed in a balanced economy at maximum employment
and production as we mbve toward workable peacetime relationships.
But before embracing this conclusion, it is necessary to examine the
trends in corporate profits and in consumer incomes a bit more specifically. Looking first at the corporate profits picture (see chart 16,
p. 334), these profits when measured as a percentage of sales were 5.4
percent in 1929; 3.9 percent in 1939; 4.6 percent in 1946; 5.2 percent
in 1947; and 5.2 percent in the first quarter of 1948 according to the
best available estimates. Measured as a percentage of investment,
these corporate profits were 5.1 percent in 1929; 3.5 percent in 1939;
7.4 percent in 1946; and 9.6-percent in 1947. Details for 1948 are
not yet available. Together with thesefigures,it is noteworthy that,
during the first half of 1948, retained net earnings and depreciation
reserves continued to supply* the major part of corporate financial
requirements (see chart 17, p. 335). I t appears from the available
data that business income is on the high side in relation to the amounts
required to sustain the volume of business investment compatible
with peacetime economic balance. At the same time, consumer incomes, of which the compensation of employees forms the major part,
have been reflecting a decreasing share of national income. Furthermore, total real per capita personal income after taxes is now lower



334

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

than during 1946, although it has been fairly constant since the second
half of 1947 (see chart 18, p. 336).
The foregoing analyses strongly presage the emergence of an inadequacy of consumer income when production mounts, when reservoirs
Of wartime savings have been further depleted, when those expenditures of Government which reflect the tense international situation

decrease, and when business investment comes to assume a relationship to total economic activity more nearly in line with peacetime
experience. I t may be said, in dissent from this conclusion, that
total consumer income is now adequate, or more than adequate, to



I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

335

take the supply of goods now available for consumer use, as evidenced
by the fact that prices are still being pushed upward. This would
be a comforting conclusion if we could but ignore the lesson of experience. For experience during past periods of adjustment leaves
little room for belief that wages would be increased voluntarily or
prices decreased systematically at the very time when the business
outlook might be dampened by a decline in Government-created demand for foreign aid and preparedness. Experience indicates, rather,
that the delay of adjustment until that time would result in curtailment of employment and production, followed by disorderly price
breaks and a general economic decline—the spiral of depression.
I t would be far safer if real consumer incomes were now kept more
nearly abreast of increases in domestic output. If compelling reasons
of national policy require for a time that an extraordinary part of
this output be diverted away from domestic consumers, the worst

way to deal with the situation is by price increases that ration goods
unfairly and enormously magnify the coming problem of peacetime
adjustment. A more prudent approach, for the time being, would be
to keep income relationships in sounder balance by a restrained price
policy, and to cut consumer spending rather than consumer incomes
by voluntary savings and high taxes. We should then have a better
chance to maintain a full economy by not cumulating maladjustments
against the day of reckoning.
The C H A I R M A N . Are all those charts in this booklet?
M r , KEYSERLING. Y e s .




336




INFLATION

CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

337

Senator SPARKMAN. What number will be the one that you are
about to put up?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Chart 19 is coming up. This chart shows the
final type of maladjustment which I shall discuss, now appearing in
the process of inflation, which is a consequence of unequal trends in
the real earnings of individuals. For all wage earners (see chart 19,
p. 338), the index of real earnings has declined about 10 percent since
June 1946, and this is to be regarded as an unfavorable development
for reasons already stated. But more significant than this, in some
ways, is the much greater decline in real earnings suffered by such
groups as clerical and professional workers. This group has been
thrown for a loss of about 15 percent during the same period. Meanwhile, a few groups have fared much better than the average.
The C H A I R M A N . I confess I am surprised at that, sir. I had supposed that the wage scale was fully as high today as it was then.
Mr. KEYSERLING. Not in relation to the price level.
Senator SPARKMAN. This is the real wage?
Mr. KEYSERLING. The real wage, in relation to the price level.
This is made more realistic by adjusting i t to the price level.
Quite aside from the inequities involved, these widely disparate
changes in the wage and salary structure are not a basis either for
social contentment or for uniformly calm industrial relations. Moreover, in the extremely tight labor market of full employment, these
disparities do not result in the distribution of required manpower
along lines consistent with the best national interest by any reasonable
test. An outstanding example of this, of course, is the situation of
the teaching profession, where the shortage of teachers is growing
while the number of school-age children is increasing rapidly.
Due to historic and other reasons, disparities in wages and salaries
among groups where most people would not say that the differentials
in training or skill justified the differentials in pay, is to a degree
normal even if not entirely fortunate in a complex economy. But
disparities as great as those that have been developing in the process
of inflation are neither normal nor desirable. They constitute some
of the worst manifestations of the inflationary process. These disparities also indicate the superficiality of the argument that an effective anti-inflationary program must "hurt everybody a little bit,"
when in fact the essence of an effective anti-inflationary program is
that it be selective enough to help those who have already been hurt
too much, while it restrains those who have been going too far.
We may now summarize briefly the dangers and maladjustments
which have been and still are being generated in the inflationary
process.
First, the inflationary process is working untold hardships upon
millions of families. Not only have these families failed to participate
in the rising standards of living that have been made available to
others as the end of the war has released more goods for civilian use.
More than that, these millions of families are now losing ground in
absolute as well as relative terms. Their money incomes are going
down; their real incomes are going down; their accumulated savings
are disappearing or have already disappeared; they are spending more
than they earn; their debts are increasing. Whether one calls this a
social or an economic problem—and it is certainly a mixture of both—
it is a problem that no great nation can discount or ignore without



338




INFLATION

CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

339

facing the prospect of mounting discontent, friction, envy, and suspicion, at a time when there is desperate need for unity of endeavor.
Under such circumstances, wily or misguided agents can more easily
show the seeds of trouble in the field of discontent.
The C H A I R M A N . I t has some religious aspects, too.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think it is fundamentally a moral question.
The C H A I R M A N . I think so.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . A S many economic questions are ultimately.
Second, the inflationary process is creating price and income and
production maladjustments of increasing size throughout the economy.
I t is threatening, though few as yet perceive it, to revive the postTV orld "War I problem of disparity between agricultural income and
industrial income and thus to complicate the problem of price supports.
I t is pushing specific industrial prices, such as those in metals and
building materials, to the point where output cannot permanently be
disposed of at these price levels, while if the threatened further rise of
these prices occurs it will make readjustment of these prices to maintainable levels almost impossible without being preceded by large
cutbacks in employment and production. The inflation is creating
enormous disparities in the wage structure which are indefensible on
equitable grounds, and which are inconsistent with the availability
of an adequate supply of workers for some of our most vital national
needs such as primary and secondary education. The inflation is so
distorting the composition of national income that the old danger of
inadequate consumer buying power to provide a market for the
maximum output of industry and agriculture at full employment is
threatening to reappear; and this danger should not be overlooked
because inflation by its very nature tends to conceal the danger until
it suddenly descends upon the economy in full force. There is stewing
in the boiler of inflation the main ingredients for an economic explosion,
and we cannot afford to wait until these ingredients fuse themselves
into the combination that will touch off that explosion.
Third, even if in the process of inflation many of the changes in the
price-income-production structure were not moving in the direction
of further maladjustment, which in fact they are, we could still be
certain that the speed with which these changes are taking place
prevents any responsible factor in the economy from getting its true
bearings. By keeping everyone off balance, inflation is profoundly
unsettling everyone. This is best illustrated by the price-wage spiral
(see chart 20, p. 340). Quite independently of whether prices are
outrunning wages or wages are outrunning prices, quite independently
of who is blameworthy or blameless in this process, the very fact that
prices and wages are chasing each other at such a mad speed around
so many dark corners means that serious collisions are bound to take
place unless both management and labor can slow down for a while
and get their bearings.
The C H A I R M A N . When Mr. Ben Fairless came before the Joint
Economic Committee last spring, I happened to be present, and in
the course of his prepared statement he made this statement; I think
I report it verbatim:
"Under no circumstances should demands for increased wages follow
increased profits."
I wrote it down. When he got through I asked him the question
and he said he did say that.



340

INFLATION

CONTROL

M y question was, Suppose he wasn't Ben Fairless, president of the
steel corporation, but Ben Fairless, one of the open-hearth operators
in Pittsburgh, and he is intelligent as most men are who are in labor
today, and he thought the steel corporation was making large earnings of $11.70 on a share after taxes and reserves and $120,000,000
net profit, when would Ben Fairless, now John Smith, hearth worker,
feel that he was entitled to increased wages when the concern he represented was making the largest earnings in the history of the country?
He didn't like the question. I was thinking in terms of when the
reverse happens. Then they close the plants and John Smith goes
out on his ear, and his income is lost, and his family is in distress.




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

341

I am asking you on this theory about labor and the demand for
wages and all, when would they expect to get increased wages if it
wasn't at a time when profits were being paid and made from products
which they produced.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think what you say, broadly speaking, is correct, Mr. Chairman. I would say that I have tried to approach this
subject objectively, and as-I said near the beginning of my statement
it doesn't always follow that wages and profits should increase at the
same rate.
There are periods when profits should increase faster than wages,
because the profit structure is more volatile. When the economy is
going downhill, when it is running into a period of large-scale unemployment, profits sometimes fall below the zero point, and manifestly
we couldn't allow wages to fall below the zero point. And likewise,
profits have to increase faster than wages at times to make up for the
times when they have decreased faster.
At other times, wages should increase faster than profits. I think
this second formula is closer to the correct formula for a well-balanced,
healthy, maximum employment and maximum production economy.
What has been happening at the present time is partly illustrated
by this chart 20 showing the relative movements in prices and wages
from June 1946 to June 1948. The line moving upward is the price
line. The line moving sideward is the wage line. The dates on the
lines indicate the points at which particular spurts occurred, and they
are important for the purpose of showing you how you have had a
sequence of a price jump and a wage jump and a price jump and a
wage jump. That is the spiral. The line, of course, does show that
the prices have moved forward more rapidly than the wages.
The C H A I R M A N . I S it possible in your judgment as an economist
for the mind of man to devise some scheme whereby the dollar may
be tied into the values and factors that make up the cost of living
something along the line of a commodity dollar, whereby that dollar
would reflect in the exchanges which a man receives for his wages and
go along in juxtaposition with changing conditions?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Irving Fisher had an idea something like that and
worked for many years on it. I t wasn't very widely accepted for a
variety of reasons. I t may have some merit, but it still would leave
you with the real problem, Senator Tobey, which is the fundamental
problem of the distribution of the product, because you cannot simply
say that the wage at all periods should change simply comparably to
the cost of living. If it did that, you would have a constant standard
of living although production might be increasing. I f you are in a
period when production increasing, you should have an increase in
the real wage. This is a generally accepted proposition. The real
question is how much of an increase? The real question is how much
of that increased production should take the form of further capital
expansion financed or stimulated in part by profits, and how much
should go immediately to increased consumption. This is the problem
at its core.
As an economist, I would say that in one form or another we are
always going to have this problem with us in the free society we want
to maintain. But we can, I believe, reduce this problem by developing some economic judgments to promote a better balance in the




3.12

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

economy than is generated by the unrestrained price-wage spiral
during inflation.
Senator SPARKMAN. Before you get away from that, may I ask
you this question?
I think the whole country has been interested in the recent price
and wage increase in steel. I am just wondering if you and your
group of analyists have analyzed that situation. I don't vouch for
the accuracy of these figures, but I have heard something like this:
The increase in the wage amounted to somewhere—nearly $5 a
ton—$4.70 or something like that; but United States Steel "almost
immediately announced an increase in its product of nearly $10 a
ton; $9.94, I believe.
I also saw somewhere that the profit they were already making
after taxes was something over $12 a ton. As I said, I don't vouch
for the accuracy of those figures; I wonder if you have analyzed that
situation so as to be able to say whether or not there was any justification of this in such a price increase, on steel, following that wage
increase, and particularly in view of the already existing high corporate earnings?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Senator Sparkman, I don't have the detailed
figures before me now, and a generalization in a matter of this kind
is always difficult. I am prepared to say, however, directly in answer
to your question, that it has seemed that the price advances which
have taken place in certain key industries, steel being one, have
been more than were desirable or necessary in view of the whole
economic situation. I n other words, in such cases the level of profits
after taxes has afforded a higher rate of return than has been necessary amply to stimulate and support the level of investment and
production required to keep a fully employed labor force and plant
at work and to use the resources that should at this time or shortly
be turned to production purposes. This conclusion is generally
implicit in my analysis of the production picture, and it was developed
a little more specifically in the charts and figures which I have submitted on the profit picture in general.
Senator SPARKMAN. Are they in the report?
M r . KEYSERLING.

Yes.

Senator SPARKMAN. I do not recall whether or not in this midyear
economic report to the President, which the President in turn transmitted to Congress, you and your associated economists called attention to the effectiveness of an excess-profits tax in drying up those
high-level corporate earnings.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I shall touch on that question as I come to an
evaluation of specific proposals.
Mr. Chairman, I have cited three of the dangers and maladjustments
occurring in the current inflation. I should now like to cite two others.
Fourth, the pace of the inflationary process is breeding a psychological uneasiness throughout the economy. This psychology is based
upon the observation that booms in the past have ended up in busts;
and the question of whether history must repeat itself becomes irrelevant in view of the fact that history will repeat itself if enough people
think that it is going to.
Fifth, the inflationary process is jeopardizing our whole program of
aid to the free countries of western Europe, along with all of our objectives for the restoration of better international economic relations as a



I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

343

foundation for permanent world peace. The inflation is confusing
many of our own people into the mistaken belief that the foreign-aid
program is primarily responsible for the hardships they are suffering
under inflation, and thus is tempting them toward the relinquishment
or abatement of an imperative undertaking of policy. The inflation is
reducing the value of the financial aid that we are extending to other
countries, planting in their minds legitimate concern that America may
be heading for another depression, and therefore militating against
their cooperation with us on the fall and trustful basis which the world
situation demands. The inflation is affording a talking point for such
enemies of our foreign policy within our own gates as look elsewhere
than to America's best interests for their guidance or command.
T H E OUTLOOK FOR I N F L A T I O N I F L E F T U N C H E C K E D

If these be the dangers of inflation, what are the prospects that
these dangers will disappear of their own accord, except through a
process of deflation and depression which would mean infinitely
larger dangers?
There is little need at this point to enter into an extended demonstration of the fact that inflation is still on the march. Prices are
still going up, and reaching new peaks. The price-wage spiral is
augmenting. The suffering of the primary victims of inflation is
increasing. While a year ago, or 6 months ago, there was division
of opinion as to whether the forces of inflation were nearly spent, there
is little division now. Business journals and business economists
join with others in appraising the current situation as highly inflationary. The proponents and opponents of the anti-inflationary program
now before the Congress are not divided in this appraisal. The overwhelming majority of them seem to agree that inflation is still very
much with us; their division of opinion is limited to what are the main
causes of inflation and what are the main remedies to be applied.
Some favor the proposals that have been advanced on the ground that
they will help remedy the inflation, while others oppose the very
same proposals on the ground that they would aggravate the inflation;
but almost all agree that the inflationary problem has become more
acute. Under such circumstances, to bring before this informed
committee the accumulated evidence that the danger of inflation is
still here, beyond the evidence contained in the various charts and
figures already referred to, would be carrying coals to Newcastle.
The question is no longer what the factual situation is, but rather
what to do about it.
The only prospect now being held out for relief from the dangers
of inflation in our strained economy, without benefit of an affirmative
program, is that there will be a general softening of demand which will
reduce prices. This is nothing more than a sugar coating of the bitter
pill that inflation of course will be over when unemployment mounts
and when the economy passes from a sellers' to a buyers' market.
There is nothing new about that kind of relief for inflation, and by the
same token there is nothing desirable about it. There is no assurance
that an adjustment along such lines would afford succor to the millions
of families who are the primary victims of inflation; on the contrary,
we know full well that rising unemployment and a slackening of
industrial activity would put these families in an even worse position




3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

than they are now. Nor is there any assurance that such an adjustment, even if tolerable, would stop at some nice and convenient point
between what is called inflation and what is called deflation. The
prospect is all too real to be overlooked that our highly sensitive
economy cannot start rolling down this kind of hill without rolling
into the valley.
I n essence, the bad thing about inflation is not the high price level
in itself, but rather that the maladjustments and disparities which
are occurring in the process of inflation victimize countless individuals
and threaten the maintenance of maximum employment and the
achievement of maximum production. The main reason for wanting
to combat inflation is that it jeopardizes prosperity. We cannot wait
for or solicit the kind of cure that kills the patient.
The C H A I R M A N . Y O U are pretty nearly through; are you?
M r . KEYSERLING. Yes.
The C H A I R M A N . May I

ask you a question? Here is a committee,
sitting here. We are charged with the responsibility of doing something. You, I assume, can testify you were consulted in drawing up
the administration bill; is that correct?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I n drawing up the administration bill?
T h e CHAIRMAN.

Yes.

Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Not as a technician on the details.
The C H A I R M A N . Y O U are familiar with the bill?
M r . KEYSERLING. Yes.
The C H A I R M A N . Y O U know

how important price control is to most

of us?
M r . KEYSERLING. Yes.
The C H A I R M A N . Here we

are in a tropical sea in here, and this inflation is going on. We have Mr. Eccles' thesis that we are going to
have a bust. When, as, and if is the question.
Forgetting the political side of this entirely, what do you think we
ought to do?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . That is what I want to come to now. M y statement thus far has attempted to provide the factual and analytic
foundation for evaluating proposed measures. I want to take these
few remaining minutes that you may give me—and I am terribly
sorry if I am delaying the Secretary of Commerce, but I got started
about an hour after I was scheduled.
The C H A I R M A N . He is getting an education, too.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . On this foundation, we may make a general
appraisal of the relative weight and significance of some of the explanations advanced as to the causes of inflation and some of the economic proposals made to combat the dangers and maladjustments of
inflation.
T H E E C O N O M I C S I G N I F I C A N C E OF PROPOSED R E M E D I E S FOR
INFLATION
I N F L A T I O N AND FOREIGN A I D

The very first point to be made involves firm, unalterable recognition that we must conquer inflation while meeting our essential
obligations as a nation, and not by avoiding these obligations.
Sufficient examples of this are the foreign-aid and preparedness pro-




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

345

grams. Even if these programs were complicating the inflation
problem far more than they in fact are, we would have to carry these
programs forward nonetheless. To be sure, if we abandoned foreign
aid, and preparedness, and agricultural price supports, and the good
living standards that come with good wages, and the goal of maintaining maximum employment and production, and many other things
that make our Nation what it is, we would then have no problem of
inflation. But we would lose infinitely more shan we would gain.
I t is true that if we decide to divert more of our resources to a particular purpose, such as foreign aid or preparedness, we will for the
time being not have those same resources available for other purposes.
But there is no good reason why a decision on grounds of national
policy to divert manpower and other productive resources to one
purpose rather than to another should present us from dealing more
equitably with our people at home or from checking the economic
maladjustments which are now under way. During the war, we
diverted about half of our output to noncivilian use, and yet through
affirmative economic policies we actually raised civilian standards of
living and ended the war on a fairly promising footing for lasting
economic prosperity. Growing maladjustments have developed
since then, not because we have undertaken certain essential programs,
such as foreign aid and preparedness, but because we have done so
little to deal with the disruptive forces which have been released by
the actions of men and can likewise be contained by the actions of
men.
INFLATION AND INCREASING

PRODUCTION

The second point in evaluating measures to combat inflation is that
increased production alone is not a feasible solution. I n the first
place, with full employment (see chart 21, p. 346), shortages of materials, and almost full utilization of our resources, we cannot increase
production very much in the short run and must live with that fact.
Certainly, price inflation is not driving production upward (see
chart 22, p. 347). In the second place, mere increase in production
will not by itself correct the maladjustments already indicated in the
price-income structure; taken alone, it might even accentuate some
of these maladjustments, particularly the general balance between
production and consumption. If this were not true, no one would
be able to understand how a business upswing ever turns into a business downswing. The truth is that our immediately soluble problem
is less one of total production than of the composition of production and the distribution of the product. Prices under unrestrained
inflation are operating to induce the production of too much of
some things and not enough of others at a rather fixed level of total
production. Some lines are expanding relatively too fast, and others
relatively not fast enough, to serve national needs or to avoid eventual
disruption of production generally. I n short, while the problem is
partly to relieve inflation by more production as fast as we can, the
bigger problem is that inflation is impairing production in detail and
in the long run will impair it in general. If we can deal vigorously
with inflation, production for the most part will take care of itself.




3.12




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL




INFLATION

CONTROL

347

3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

I N F L A T I O N A N D D E C R E A S E G DEMAND

The third point in evaluating anti-inflation measures is that reducing
total demand is by no means a full solution, although it is frequently
hailed as such. Demand means spending power in the market. If all
demand throughout the economy were reduced pro tanto, we would
indeed have a lower price level, but price-income relationships and the
distribution of goods and services would remain approximately the
same as they are now. The submerged families who are not now
getting enough goods would still not be getting enough goods; and
some others who are getting relatively too much would still be getting
relatively too much. On the demand side, as on the supply side, the
immediate problem is mainly one of relationships rather than of
totals. Some types of demand need to be curbed, while other types
need to be made more effective. Effective demand in the market
determines the kind of work that people do, the kinds of goods that are
produced, and how these goods are distributed. When we are faced
with trouble on the demand side in a full employment economy, the
real task is not to reduce all demand but rather to readjust relative
demands either for reasons of equity or national policy or in the
interests of general economic stability. We need to do this now for
all three reasons.
I N F L A T I O N A N D HOUSING

A good example of the demand problem is in the field of housing.
The point has been made that the Taft-Ellender-Wagner housing bill
is inconsistent with an anti-inflation program because it would add to
demand.
This point is not well-founded. If there is a shortage of housing,
and if this is contributing to excessive housing costs in the same way
that a shortage of food would contribute to excessive food costs, then
the production of more housing is anti-inflationary in the same sense
that the production of more food would be anti-inflationary. I t may
well be that, for a time, we cannot divert much more labor and materials to the total production of housing in view of other competing
national needs. But let us make sure that they are competing national needs, and not competing nonessentials. And even then, there
would still remain the question of the coritposition of the housing
that is being produced. I t would still be sound and desirable to
produce relatively more low-rent housing for veterans and others of
modest means, and relatively less high-priced housing for families
who can get along very nicely for a while with what they already
have. The Taft-Ellender-Wagner bill is designed basically for this
purpose, although this is not true of the "title V I " provisions contained
in the bill. Thus, under present circumstances, talk about damping
down the demand for housing is undiscriminating and mistaken until
one breaks the demand down into various types. Some types of
housing should be expanded, other types should be contracted.
I N F L A T I O N A N D GOVERNMENT PROGRAMS

What is true of housing is equally true of other expenditures, including expenditures under Government programs. Some types of
expenditures, of course, should be held low or reduced. Those types




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

349

of expenditures which represent essential national purposes, or serve
essential individual needs, cannot be reduced below the point of
safety or basic welfare. Some of them, for example educational outlays, need to be increased. The problem is to translate the more
necessary expenditures into effective goods and services, and this can
be done only by reducing, on a selective basis, other types of expenditures which are drawing goods and services away for less-essential
purposes. The problem here again is one of the composition of
expenditures and their relationships one to another.
I N F L A T I O N A N D PRICE-WAGE-PROFIT

POLICIES

The price-wage-profit problem in the current stage of inflation
cannot be met by deciding arbitrarily that all prices should be held
where they are now, or *hat all wages should be held where they are
now, or that all profits should be held where they are now. Some
items are relatively too high, and others are relatively too low, both on
grounds of equity and on grounds of economic stability. A program
which sought to hold everything just as it is now, even if it could be
successful, would merely freeze current maladjustments where these
exist; and if current maladjustments did not exist there would be no
crying need for the program at all. The fact is that some items need
to be raised, and others need to be lowered, in relation to the general
structure of prices, wages, and profits.
I N F L A T I O N A N D PRICE OR W A G E SUPPORTS

As a further example of this point, there is nothing intrinsically
inconsistent between proposals on the one hand to maintain agricultural price supports, and proposals on the other hand to check such
prices as are found to be rising too fast. Preventing some prices from
falling to levels that are relatively too low is just as much a part of a
sound economic program as preventing other prices from reaching
levels that are relatively too high. Likewise, there is no inconsistency between raising minimum wages, or seeking to improve the
real earnings of those who are discriminated against in the current
price-income structure, while at the same time seeking to restrain
such wage increases as would break through necessary price ceilings.
TREATMENT OF I N F L A T I O N SHOULD B E S E L E C T I V E A N D NOT
INDISCRIMINATE

For these reasons, there is little merit in the high-sounding notion
that a genuine anti-inflationary program should get equally tough on
everybody, and that a program which gets tough at some points and
not at others is unsound or disingenuous. For example, inflation
cannot be remedied by getting tough on those who are already its
chief victims. The very essence of a corrective program is that it
increases pressure at some points and relieves pressure at other points
so as to get things into better balance. The only kind of economic
development that gets tough on everybody is a depression.
An effective anti-inflationary program must be both comprehensive
and selective. I t must embrace a variety of measures because the
problem is complex, and it must treat each of these problems carefully




3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

and not with a meat ax. Maladjustments can be cured only by
treating everybody fairly, not by treating everybody the same.
In the light of these standards, it becomes easier to evaluate the
main proposals now before the committee, relating to credit controls,
materials allocations, and selective price control.
CONSUMER CREDIT CONTROL

The control of consumer credit has an appropriate place in a rounded
anti-inflation program, because it can be used to curb the effective
demand for goods on the part of those who are now securing too
many goods in relation to what the economy at current levels of
production can make available. But manifestly, consumer credit controls cannot and should not be used to decrease the amount of goods
made available to those who are already receiving relatively too Tittle.
In short, consumer credit controls by themselves cannot do much for
the primary victims of inflation, and for this reason, as well as others,
they need to be combined with other measures.
Let me illustrate that a bit more specifically, Mr. Chairman. If
consumer credit controls were to be directed primarily against those
whom I call the primary victims of inflation, in other words, those
at the bottom of the structure, isn't the manifest truth that it would
operate to lower their living standards much more rapidly than i t
would operate to lower the whole price-wage structure to the point
where they might be among the beneficiaries of that general lowering?
The C H A I R M A N . Of course, because they haven't the fat.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Certainly. I n other words, consumer credit
control is a selective device that can be used effectively in connection
with other measures; taken alone, it would be a puny device indeed.
The C H A I R M A N . Y O U understand what the committee is charged
with in the next few minutes, is to put you on the spot in view of
your background. Tell us what you, Leon Keyserling, would do if
you were charged with full authority—carte blanche—to go ahead
and remove the danger of inflation.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I am certainly relieved not to have that responsibility. I t is my responsibility to put before you, as the makers of
policy, as objectively as I can, the facts and some of the results ol
analysis. I t is up to you to decide basic policy.
I think I have sufficiently discussed consumer credit controls. The
next proposal relates to bank credit.
RESTRAINT ON INFLATIONARY BANK

CREDIT

This proposal has great merit as a part of a rounded program, b u t
I don't think that it should be ridden to the point where anyone would
regard it as a sufficient remedy by itself.
The C H A I R M A N . Would you also agree with me in a remark made
last night in the committee that by no circumstances would the common people be justified in feeling that relief from this burden of high
prices would accrue to them from regulation of bank credit?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Taken alone, it is not nearly enough, in my
j udgment.
The control of inflationary bank credit, by whatever devices may be
used, has fruitful usages and is subject to obvious limitations in the




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

351

kind of inflation we now have. If such controls are used selectively
to abate the types of business enterprises which should not be undertaken at this time, they can be useful. But if they were to be used
in a blunderbuss fashion to contract the total volume of business
activity, they would be utterly inconsistent with the sound idea of
striving to increase total production, and would be consistent only with
the fallacious and dangerous notion that inflation can be cured by
bringing on a "mild" recession in the general level of employment and
business activity. Such controls, moreover, have other inherent shortcomings which prevent them from being the whole answer or even
enough of a answer to the current inflationary problem. Some of the
lines of enterprise and expansion which ought to be relatively reduced
under present circumstances are not dependent upon outside credit to
an extent that they would be affected perceptibility of these controls.
Conversely, some of the types of production that should be relatively
stimulated under present conditions would not be helped by such controls and might be impaired by them. And, manifestly, these controls
would not reach into the crucial problem of the price-wage spiral generally unless they were applied so extremely and so unwisely that they
brought about a serious contraction in Nation-wide levels of business
activity—which is just the reverse of what we should want to do.
Therefore, neither by the test of relieving the primary victims of
inflation, nor by the test of curing the maladjustments in the economic
structure which are the central danger of inflation, do credit controls
afford more than a part, albeit a necessary and essential part, of a workable program for checking inflation.
So, without laboring the point too much, and I will carry it further
if you have any additional questions, it seems clear that consumer
credit controls and bank reserve controls taken together are highly
selective measures to be judicially employed for limited purposes,
but they hardly touch some of the most strategic elements of danger
in the current inflationary situation.
The C H A I R M A N . What are they?
Mr. KEYSERLING. First, the hardships inflicted on the primary
victims of inflation. Second, the question of the allocation of materials and productive effort to necessary uses in the short run, and to
uses that will build up the most favorable conditions for sustained
maximum employment and production.
The C H A I R M A N . And the lever there would be to have some power
of allocation over these things.
Mr. KEYSERLING. That is right. This brings me to the subject of
allocations.
ALLOCATIONS

Because it is neither desirable to contract the total level of economic
activity nor feasible in the short run to expand it very much, the real
problem is to weigh the composition of this activity in favor of our
most urgent national needs. This means that a vigorous and fully
implemented program of allocation of basic commodities in relatively
short supply ranks high on the list of effective measures from the
viewpoint of general economic analysis. So long as there is not
enough steel for everyone to get as much as he wants or has the money
to try to buy, it is imperative that a program such as the preparedness
program not be jeopardized because too much steel is being drained off



3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

in other directions. I t is likewise important, even to the extent that
effective measures exist for getting steel for the preparedness program,
that the amount of steel which this program leaves available for general civilian use is wisely directed and sanely used. The same principle
applies to other basic commodities in relatively short supply, whether
because of domestic conditions or because of a combination of domestic conditions and the foreign aid or preparedness program. We
should not want to reduce the total production or the total use of these
basic commodities through general contracting measures which would
both impoverish the country and create unemployment; the jproblem
is rather to channel them to the most effective use. And in appraising
what is the most effective use, we need to take into account not only
short-run urgency but also the longer-range problem of the balanced
development of interrelated facilities. The worst danger of relative
shortages is the distortions which they create.
Senator S P A R K M A N . I suppose every Member of the Senate received
just a few days ago from Mr. R. R. Young, president of the Chesapeake
& Ohio Railroad, a letter and an article that had been published in
some railway publication dealing with the unavailability of steel with
which to build needed railroad cars, whereas trucks and automobiles
apparently were getting all they needed.
I don't recall the figure, definitely. I believe he said they were
having a shortage this year of 28,000 railroad cars.
He pointed to the fact that when the time comes for transporting
the great fruit crops of this year, the grain crops, we were going to feel
that. Is that when you mean by taking care of the more essential
needs?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Very definitely.
Senator S P A R K M A N . At the expense of the less essential.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Very definitely. There are illustrations of this
problem at numerous key points in the economy. Some of the
specialized agencies working in the various commodity fields would be
able to illustrate this better than I.
This brings us to what the chairman calls the $64 question—price
control.
SELECTIVE PRICE CONTROL

I very genuinely feel, as I know every member of the committee
does, that there is involved here a question of balance. On the one
hand, there is to be weighed the inconveniences, the black market
possibilities, and the administrative difficulties, of imposing this kind
of restraint. On the other hand, there is the fact that unrestrained
prices have become immensely dangerous.
I n weighing this issue, we cannot say that price control is basically
inconsistent with our form of government or our basic freedoms,
because we have used it before without endangering these precious
values. Nor can we set the proposal for price control aside on the
ground that it won't work at all, because we know that despite the
black markets and inconveniences and aberrations it did work to hold
a fairly stable level of prices and that it did bring us out of the war on
a much sounder economic footing for postwar prosperity than we now
have, because of the maladjustments which have crept up particularly
since mid-1946.
If price control is going to be excluded from the tools made available to fight inflation, this can reasonably be done only on the ground



I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

353

that its inconveniences outweigh the need for meeting the great
dangers and hardships in the existing economic situation, or on the
ground that other proposals than price control are in themselves
sufficient without price control.
I have indicated my reasons for believing—and I most reluctantly
reach this conclusion—that the other proposals taken alone would be
insufficient; that the other proposals taken alone would seem even to
be inequitable; that the other proposals taken alone would seem to
have an even greater shortcoming—they would seem to impose upon
our people the belief that their Government had taken adequate
steps to cure the situation when i n fact i t hadn't, which I think as an
economist should be a cause for great concern.

Senator H A W K E S . Might
your committee.

I

ask a question there?

I

am not on

The C H A I R M A N . D O you want to wait u n t i l he gets through? We
will question him when he gets through.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . Y O U are the chairman. I t is up to you.
The C H A I R M A N . We will wait until you get through.
Go ahead.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . Then we come to another question which has
been raised, and this is whether selective controls can be effective.
The argument has been made that selective controls must necessarily
move to all-pervasive controls.
Purely as an economist, I think that this argument proves too
much. I t proves too much because i t seems to r u n to the conclusion
that a nation cannot take moderate measures to deal w i t h — I won't
say a moderate situation, but a developing situation—but must wait
until you have a total situation and then take all-out measures.

I t seems to me that such an approach is inconsistent with prudence,
and inconsistent certainly with the "stitch in time saves nine" idea
that this committee and the Congress approved by a great majority
in the Employment Act of 1946 under which I serve.
The reason that we moved from selective controls to all-pervasive
controls earlier in this decade was not by any inexorable law of logic
that if you do something you have to do everything. I t was rather
because of the, fact that we moved from a defense period which presented a relatively lesser strain to a war period which had a terriffic
impact on our economy.
During the war, we were devoting about 50 percent of our total
resources to noncivilian use, and at the same time, because we were
financing the war mainly through borrowing rather than by taxation—and I am not criticizing that policy—the volume of purchasing
power in the economy went up as fast or faster than production went
up, but the production was not going to civilians although civilians
were getting the income. Thus there was a perfectly terrific spread
between purchasing power and goods. I n that situation, of course,
we needed all-out measures. We needed all-out rationing, we needed
all-out price control, we needed all-out compulsory savings, and
other extraordinary things besides.
We haven't that kind of all-out situation now. A comparable
emergency in peacetime would be a large-scale depression, which
would be as great a danger to our economy as a war, or nearly as
great. If we now waited until we arrived at such a critical situation,




3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

we would need all-out measures, though different from wartime measures. But there is no reason, as I have said, why the application of
certain limited measures to the limited dangers of today should lead
to all-pervasive measures unless we neglect the situation until a crisis
is at hand. I don't want to burden the committee with detail, but
I think the Canadian experience with selective controls has worked
fairly well, if you measure it by the test of holding down the cost of
living. I think it can be done.
The point I want to stress again is that this is not the kind of
situation where it would be safe to compound a series of remedies
which fairly clearly cannot do the job. Anyone would be pretentious
who said—and I am not prepared to say—that any series of remedies
offer sure-fire 100-percent proof, in advance, of their perfection.
The real test before us is to select those proposals which, looking at
the situation as a whole, we think are most likely to do the job with
reasonable safety and dispatch.
If this covers the questions raised sufficiently, I can turn to the
excess-profits tax matter.
The C H A I R M A N . G O ahead.
T H E EXCESS-PROFITS T A X

Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Y O U asked me to discuss the excess-profits tax
proposal. That is not before this committee. Nonetheless, this
committeee has to consider that the whole range of anti-inflation
proposals are interrelated.
I think that, in the present economic situation, there is merit in
the proposal for the excess-profits tax.
First, by definition the tax does not apply to restrain either normal
or legitimate levels of profits. I am not using the word "legitimate"
in the legal sense. I am using it in the popular sense.
Second, in the current economy, as was indicated by my general
analysis and further brought out by one of Senator Sparkman's
questions, there clearly are important instances where the level of
profits after taxes is lugher than needed to provide adequate incentives and funds for the highest rate of present and prospective investment that our resources can sustain.
Third, I think that the excess-profits tax would help to moderate
the price-wage spiral for this reason: Although wage negotiations
recently have concentrated largely upon the question of the cost of
living, it is only realistic to recognize that the cost of living is not the
only question or rationale underlying collective bargaining. Even
if the cost of living should be held at its present levels, there is a general philosophy which we cannot set aside that there should be some
relationship between the earnings of a business and what those who
work therein receive. There is a philosophy which we cannot set
aside that, at a stable cost of living or a stable price index, wages
should go up as productivity increases to reflect increasing standards
of living. Because these issues enter into collective bargaining, I
think that a restraint upon excess profits would relieve tension and
help to moderate the rate of wage increases. This does not claim
that it would be a panacea, but it would help.




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

355

The fourth point I would make relates to the argument that an
excess-profits tax would operate actually to raise prices because, since
the return after taxes would be lower with the excess-profits tax than
without it, even higher prices would be charged in order to keep the
return stable. Putting aside entirely the fact that this argument is
directly contrary to accepted principles of economics, there still
remains the fact that the repeal of the excess-profits tax when it was
repealed had no restraining effect upon prices. The price-wage spiral
continued.
I n the present inflationary situation, in those administered price
areas where businessmen make conscious judgments as to prices,
the price does not necessarily represent the highest price that can
be charged at any given moment. I think that there has been
some restraint in this respect. But it does represent what some
businessmen regard as the highest price that it is wise to charge, and
their judgment may sometimes be wrong, although the principle of
seeking the optimum price is right and proper in the profit system
which we all want to retain and support. I think that, where there
are excess profits, the judgment is wrong from the point of view of
the interests of the whole economy. For these reasons, in an inflationary economy operating at full employment and very high demand,
I do not believe that an excess-profits tax would operate to drive
administered prices higher, because in any event they tend during
inflation to come near to the highest level that those who administer
prices think they can safely charge. I think that the spiral of inflation will take prices still higher, if firm measures are not applied.
The C H A I R M A N . Y O U do not contend that you can increase production by price-control measures?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I would make two points. I would say, first,
that it has been clearly demonstrated from chart 22 which I have
already discussed, that spiraling prices do not increase production.
Second, while I would admit that price control in itself does not
directly and immediately increase production, we have learned from
experience that production can be increased greatly while price control
is in effect, if the manpower and resources are available to increase
it. Moreover, by helping to check inflation, price control would help
to remove one of the main dangers to both employment and production. The maladjustments that are developing in the course of
inflation will turn us down hill if they are neglected. I f we can stop
inflation, without a recession or depression, production will be quite
satisfactory.
The C H A I R M A N . If wage controls are necessary, in your judgement,
is not the pending legislation deficient in that respect?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that the formula in the pending legislation
relating to the relationship between price control and wage control is a
sound formula. I think that if we look at the situation in the main,
Senator Tobey, on the factual side, economic analysis will not support
the proposition that the total level of wages has risen relatively too
fast in the relation to the whole complex of the national economy.
Wages, since inflation got started in earnest, have been trying—and
not with complete success*—to keep up with the cost of living. Nor
has the total of compensation to employees been too high in relation
to other distributive shares of national income, as my earlier remarks
have indicated in more detail. The outrunning has been mostly in



3.12

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

parts of the price structure and in certain levels of profits. For these
reasons, I do not think that there would be an acute problem on the
wage side if the cost of living could be held measurably i n line, and if
the exacerbating factor of some excessive profits could be dealt with.
The formula i n the bill, however, does not sidestep the wage problem.
I t says simply and directly that in those cases where i t is necessary to
impose a price ceiling because of the price structure, the Government
should have authority to prevent those types of wage increases which
would break through the price ceiling, except where necessary to
relieve hardship or maintain living standards or correct inequities or
maladjustments. Wage increases based on productivity or payable
out of margins without breaking through a price ceiling should not be
interfered with.
The C H A I R M A N . There are those who do not think that strong
enough.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . There are those who don't think i t strong enough,
and there are those who think i t too strong. I disagree w i t h both. I t
is a middle approach.
The C H A I R M A N . I want to give my colleagues the privilege of asking
questions. Senator Buck?
Senator B U C K . I have no questions.
The C H A I R M A N . Senator Cain?
Senator C A I N . N O questions.
The C H A I R M A N . Senator Fulbright?
Senator F U L B R I G H T . M r . Keyserling, would you say the imposition
of credit controls alone would be worth while if the whole program is
not undertaken.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . I find i t hard to answer that question, Senator,
although I don't want to duck it.
M r . Chairman, the question asked me was whether I would say that
the imposition of credit controls alone would be undesirable if the whole
program were not undertaken. I did not intend to say that, and I do
not think that I said i t .
Senator F U L B R I G H T . Y O U didn't put i t that way.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . I said that I did not think that credit controls
alone would be nearly adequate to deal with the current inflation.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . I was trying to clarify what you meant. I
realize you did not use the words I used, but I was trying to get at
your meaning, because all of your remarks were i n the background
of an over-all program, including several things. I don't think as a
practical matter the whole program is going to be given serious consideration. I t is generally thought in the Senate that this credit
control, particularly bank credit and consumer credit, is the only
feature of this program that may be given consideration. As a
Member of the Senate, I am intensely interested i n whether or not
that alone is worth while.
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . Senator Fulbright, I think we are talking in an
area where i t is important for me to distinguish between the functions
of the economist and the functions of the legislator. I don't want to
step over the line. I understand your question, and i t is reasonable,
but i t is a very hard question for me to answer. About as far as I
can go is to say that i t seems clear to me that a rounded and sufficient
program to deal w i t h the inflationary situation requires the range
of measures that I have discussed, and that anything short of this




I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

357

xange of measures would be insufficient. That much I can say as an
•economist. When you go beyond that and ask me to advise whether
or not, if I were a Member of the Senate, I would vote for a partial
program, being unable to get a whole program, I think that this is a
practical question of legislation beyond my appropriate province.
Frankly, I don't know what I would do if I were in your place, but
I don't have to make that decision.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . D O you think the repeal of the excess-profits
tax in 1945 was a proper-measured move to take at that time?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think it was well-intentioned at the time, but
in view of subsequent events I think it would have been better not to
have taken such action.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . D O you think the decrease in income tax this
spring was a proper measure from the inflationary point of view?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that from the inflationary point of view
it was a mistake to do this at that particular time.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . We will assume for purposes of this question
that we do impose some credit controls, the ones proposed. Do you
think at the same time that we increase the availability of money for
the housing program that that would not have the effect of offsetting
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I am glad you asked that question, Senator
Fulbright. I t raises the whole point which I have labored throughout my statement to develop, namely, that in a situation like the
present it is impossible to get a formula which says: We are going to
fight inflation by clamping down on everything. Every expenditure is in a sense inflationary. Expenditures for production are in
that sense inflationary. Raising the wage of the fellow who is getting
$14 a week and who can't live under inflation is inflationary, in a
sense.
The C H A I R M A N . I t is a question of objectives, is it not, and of
human needs?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I t is a question of balance. On the housing program I would say this: If you look at it solely from the demand side,
obviously when you create more demand for housing it is inflationary.
I f you look at it on the production side, then a proposal to increase
the volume of housing because the inflationary situation in that area
is caused partly by a shortage is no more illogical than if we were proposing to increase the production of steel or to increase the production
of food because there were shortages in such areas. As I understand
it, the proposed housing program is primarily designed to increase the
production of housing. I t is quite different from something like consumer credit, which does not increase the production of anything.
Further, even if we have reached the point where for a while we
cannot increase the total volume of housing because of shortages of
manpower or resources or materials, we still have to be concerned
tremendously about the composition of the housing product. We
should have a combined program, which on the one hand cuts down
the amount of certain types of housing which are being built, like
luxury housing, high-priced housing, 12- to 15-thousand-dollar-a-unit
housing, while at the same time filing in the gap with a relatively
greater diversion of the product into low-rent housing which now
represents a much greater need on the part of veterans' families
and others with low and moderate income. I think that the Taft


3.12

INFLATION

CONTROL

Ellender-Wagner bill, which has been before this committee, is sound
at this time because its main immediate purpose is to deal with the
composition of the housing product. We are in a situation where at
any given level of housing production we should have relatively more
low-rent housing available at moderate charges for the kinds of families who now are suffering most from the housing shortage.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . A S I understand it, as a practical matter,
title V I is about the only feature that is receiving serious consideration.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that would be a most serious mistake, to
act on that feature alone.
Senator F U L B R I G H T , That is really what I meant by housing. I
am not sure about that because the agenda of the Congress is still
uncertain.
I t seemed to me that that alone would do the very thing which
you say should not be done.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Exactly, Senator Fulbright. Housing is the
best example of the point that what is needed is a well-rounded,
selective anti-inflation program. We can't just take an oversimplified solution and say that we want to cut down on everything, because
that would cut down on employment and production. We can't
say we want an over-all solution that will cut everybody's income,
because that would cut the income of the people at the bottom faster
than the income of anybody else. We can't say we want a program
that is just going to contract credit, for that would restrict necessary
production as well as unnecessary production. We need a selective
program in this kind of situation, and that is why I think a balanced
program of credit controls, allocations, selective price controls with
its attendant features, and fiscal measures, is the kind of program
adjusted to the kind of situation we are in.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . Just one other question. Why is it that the
control of bank credit by the increase of reserves is more appropriate
now than it was last January, when it was first proposed and apparently was not supported?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that this would have been a desirable
measure last January, and I recall that it was proposed.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . What?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that this would have been a desirable
measure last January, and I recall that it was proposed.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . Well, I understand the administration didn't
approve of it last January. I understood that; I thought there was
some change in the economic situation that might very well have
justified that difference of view.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I have tried throughout my statement here to
give you my objective views as I hold them, and not to defend
Senator F U L B R I G H T . I understand that.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Not to defend or disclaim.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . Unfortunately, we have to make that decision.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I have answered your question in the one
way that I can. You asked me about the control of bank credit
last January, and my answer is that I think it would have been a
good thing if i t had been done then.
Senator F U L B R I G H T . That was a mistake, then, not to have done
it then
M r . K E Y S E R L I N G . I do not know who made the mistake.



I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

359

Senator F U L B R I G H T . But it is proper to do it now.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Whoever may have been responsible for the
mistake, I think it was a mistake. As to who was responsible, that
is not within my province.
The C H A I R M A N . Carrying that out further, we are 8 months further
down the river, nearer the breakers.
Senator M Y E R S . I surmise that just the restriction of bank credit
last January would have been just as inadequate as the restriction
of bank credit alone today might be.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that is correct, Senator Myers.
Senator M Y E R S . And you needed a balanced program last January
in 1948 just as much as you need a balanced program today.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I think that is correct, except possibly that i t
is even more clearly needed today.
Senator H A W K E S . I was going to ask the gentleman, at the time
he said he didn't think we ought to hold out a plan that you know
will not work, did he say that? Did I understand that correctly?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I said that I , as an economist, had concern
about that.
Senator H A W K E S . I thought you said that you didn't think we
should hold out a plan that we know will not work. I want to ask
you whether you know that this plan you are suggesting will work?
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Well, no; I cannot be certain of the future. I
have said that very frankly. I said that
The C H A I R M A N . Y O U made a qualifying statement.
Senator H A W K E S . I W&S not here at the beginning.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I said that in the kind of world we live in, we
cannot get universal agreements, or absolute surety, even among
technicians.
Senator H A W K E S . That is correct; or legislators.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Also, we cannot be absolutely certain of every
step we take. However, that is generally true in dealing with practical
problems. But this does not mean that, where a situation is sufficiently critical and the pressure sufficiently acute, no steps should be
taken until they are as certain as a mathematical demonstration.
I t is necessary to make the best possible judgment as to whether, on
the basis of experience and analysis, the steps proposed seem like wise
or foolish steps.
I have tried to indicate, in response to questioning, what seemed to
me to be wise or foolish steps by the test of economic analysis. I
didn't intend in any way, Senator Hawkes, to have that carry over
into an expression of what I felt members of the committee or of the
Congress ought to do as they weigh from a somewhat different perspective the whole range of competing considerations.
Senator H A W K E S . The point I had in mind was to ask you this
question: if you can tell us a single nation that has gone to and stayed
with controls, price controls and allocations, the things that are
being asked, that has been successful in doing the thing we want to
do in the United States.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I don't think, Senator Hawkes, that I suggested
in any way that we should stay with price controls permanently.
They should be employed temporarily and selectively, and such is
the proposal before you.




3.12

I N F L A T I O N CONTROL

Senator H A W K E S . That is all right. We don't need to have so
much conversation. What I wanted to do is to get right down to the
point that if you get them on, these other countries, their leaders,
promised that they would not stay on, but they did stay on, and
habit is very strong, and when you get it going, it is very hard to
get it off.
We who got OPA off the backs of the American people happen to
know how hard it was to get it off. I t was a very difficult thing. The
countries who have adopted the plan that the President is recommending to us now, and that you are talking about, are all socialistic today,
and they are all in the junk pile, and we are sending millions of tons of
foodstuffs and things of that kind over to keep them from starving to
death.
I am not saying I am right, and you are wrong. I am saying that
this is a very debatable thing, and I think every serious-minded man
in the Congress and in the Senate realizes it is a debatable thing, and
we are trying to find out if there isn't some way to do this thing without
fastening controls again upon the American people and destroying
voluntary cooperation and incentive.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . I n conclusion, I want to say just a word about
timing.
T H E PROBLEM OF TIMING

Nobody can foretell just when the dangers and maladjustments of
inflation will culminate in a crash. But is it not a strange paradox
that those who believe that this ultimate calamity is some time off
should on that ground be skeptical of prompt remedial action? Is
it not more prudent to take remedial action while the common judgment is that there is still time for it to be effective? I think that
these questions pose one of the supreme issues of our generation,
which is a moral issue as well as an economic issue. Will our democracy make manifest its innate sense of justice, which rebels against
hardship for so many people even in the presence of prosperity? . Will
our democracy make manifest the strength and the unity to act before
the ultimate crisis appears, just as we have made manifest the strength
and the unity to act upon the event of crises—especially when we
know that some of these crises would never have appeared if we had
acted in time?
The C H A I R M A N . I would like to say, now that you have come to the
conclusion of your talk, and I sat all through it; that you have in a
more comprehensive way than any witness that has come before us in
my memory met this situation that you came to talk to us about.
Speaking from this chair and for myself only, and I do not doubt
very much reflecting the minds of some others here, you have shown
a grasp of the situation, you have shown a manifest fairness, you had
a lucidness of utterance of expression, you have not been dogmatic,
and you have impressed me with the fact that you realize how delicate the situation is; all of these things, after all, are experimentations,
but you have a reason for the faith that is within you.
I want to pay you a compliment, if I may, and say that as far as
this fellow is concerned, and I invite the committee to join me, 1 envy
the mental equipment that God has given you and that you use so
well. I thank you for being present.
Mr. K E Y S E R L I N G . Thank you very much.
o