View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

HOUSING, INTEREST RATES
AND THE COST OF
LIFE INSURANCE

TESTIMONY OF MR. LEWIS W. DOUGLAS, PRESIDENT OF
THE MUTUAL LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY OF NEW
YORK, BEFORE THE SENATE BANKING

AND

CURRENCY COMMITTEE ON DECEMBER 17, 1945 ON
THE WAGNER-ELLENDER-TAFT BILL (No. S-1592)

Printed by the Life Insurance Investment Research
Committee, a joint undertaking of the American Life
Convention and the Life Insurance Association of America.




FOREWORD
Mr. Lewis W. Douglas, President of The Mutual Life Insurance Company of New York, recently
appeared at the hearing of the Senate Banking and Currency Committee, at the invitation of the
Life Insurance Investment Research Committee, on the Wagner-Ellender-Taft Bill. This bill proposes among its other provisions, a substantial reduction in the rate of interest on certain types of
mortgage loans as a means of stimulating new building.
Mr. Douglas took this occasion to explain to the Senate Committee the significance of the interest rate to the 71,000,000 policyholders, the 27,000,000 American families who have acquired
security through taking out life insurance. He showed how the precipitate fall in the rate of interest during the course of the last fourteen years had increased enormously the cost of life insurance.
He pointed out (1) that the bill was deficient in that it aggravated the consequences of the declining rate of interest to this large segment of the American public and, (2) that it was completely
indifferent to the fundamental problem of housing, namely, the cost of land, of construction, of
materials, and the unit cost of labor.
In preparing and presenting this testimony, Mr. Douglas has performed a real service in the
best interests of policyholders and the public. Because of the great importance of the questions
involved, the Life Insurance Investment Research Committee has obtained Mr. Douglas' permission to publish his testimony for the information of interested persons, governmental agencies and
financial institutions.
Mr. Douglas has asked me to thank all those who contributed so generously of time and material in the gathering of the data.




JOHN S. SINCLAIR, Chairman
Life Insurance Investment Research Committee

HOUSING, INTEREST RATES
AND
THE COST OF LIFE INSURANCE
I

M

AY I express my gratitude to the Committee for
inviting me to appear before it and to discuss,
candidly and frankly, certain phases of the housing
legislation which it is now considering.
It would require the most ingenious man to exaggerate the meaning of housing—its immediate and
future importance to the American people.
The immediate significance is, I think, now unmistakable. The returning servicemen and women
and their families, the war workers migrating to
places where peacetime factories are now beginning
to hum or will begin to hum, face a grave shortage of
housing facilities. Unless we deal promptly with this
critical situation, we will, I fear, experience, in some
measure at least, mounting prices of homes, rising
rentals and widespread inconvenience, if not privation. One of the alternatives to rising rent prices is to
clothe the Government with authority arbitrarily to
suppress prices and hold down rents. But this will
not cure the deficiency in housing accommodations.
It will not provide homes that do not exist.
Housing's Importance
Stretching out over the future years, housing, in
dramatic fashion, is of equal importance to the
American people. There is, I believe, a relationship
between the quality of the quarters in which men
and women live and the sense of responsibility they,
as citizens, possess.
It is certain that clean and sanitary housing facilities and a clean and wholesome environment tend
by themselves, though they are not by any manner
of means the only factors, to reduce the amount of
disease and the volume of crime, and to improve
health, and to create a more wholesome life.
During the last quarter of the last century, one of
the important events in our economic history which
resulted in a high level of industrial activity, accompanied on the whole by full employment, was
the construction of the railroad systems that were to




span the continent. During the 1920's, the development of the automobile industry and the expansion
of the electrical generating and distributing systems
played a similar role.
It is not an exaggeration to say that housing, if
undertaken in an appropriate economic environment and under a legislative mantle of encouragement, can play the same role during the next decade,
perhaps even during the next quarter of a century,
that the construction of the railroads, the development of the automobile industry, and the expansion
of the public utilities have played in the past. Hence,
any legislation which deals with the problem of
housing is of pressing significance, now and in the
future.
Life Insurance and Housing
Life insurance companies, as you know, are deeply
concerned with the general health of the people of
the country. They realize the relationship between living conditions and disease, or the absence of disease.
They realize the part that housing, if undertaken in
an appropriate environment, can play in providing,
or going far toward providing, full employment and
full production during the coming year, and they
realize that housing has been throughout the years,
and should continue to be, in one form or another, a
very appropriate and legitimate outlet for the investment of the funds which have been placed in their
hands as custodians by 60 to 70 million policyholders.
I do not want to bore you with a carefully documented statement which would demonstrate beyond
doubt that life insurance companies have in the past
looked upon housing as an appropriate and prudent
field for the investment of funds. Perhaps, however, you will be interested to know that at the
end of last year the insurance companies held
approximately one-third of all the FHA mortgages insured under Title II, Section 203. This
amounted to about one billion dollars. They held

BY REGIONS
90-

BY SIZE
OF PLACE

BY INCOME CLASS

8070605040302010-

0
uj

d

x

o

z

EXHIBIT I

PROPORTION OF TOTAL FAMILIES
PAYING LIFE INSURANCE PREMIUMS - 1935-1936
% CHANGES IN COST OF INSURANCE.

% CHANGE 1930 - 1944
2 0 YEAR ENDOWMENT

% CHANGE 1921-1944
2 0 YEAR
ENDOWMENT

iNCREASE IF
RATE FALLS
DDITIONAL 1%

27.2%

WHOLE LIFE

INCREASE IF
RATE FALLS
DDITIONAL 1%

NCREASE IF RATE
EARNED ON
.SETS FALLS TO
EW INVESTMENT
RATE

ACTUAL
INCREASE
1930-1944
2.5%*|

25

35

45

25

35 45

25

35 45

25

35

45

AGE AT ISSUE
IN FORCE 10 YEARS
• N E T EFFECT OF 2.1% DECREASE 1921-1944 AND POTENTIAL
4.6% INCREASE DUE TO CURRENT INVESTMENT RATE




NOTE: Mortality improved'markedly between 1921
and 1930 while interest remained stable; conversely,
from 1930 to 1944 the mortality factor in dividends
was fairly stable and interest fell precipitately.

EXHIBIT II
PER CENT CHANGES IN COST OF INSURANCE

GROSS RATE ON TOTAL ASSETS

CROSS INCURREC RATE ( 1 0 0 COMPANIES SINCE I S O ' .
SMAUCH SAMHC OF COMPANIES fOR EARIIER YEARS)

NET RATE ON TOTAL ASSETS (\\
INCURAEO RATE AFTEA DEDUCTION Of

"^

*•••«,

VESTMENT EXPENSE »UT MITHOUT ALLOWANCE to*
INVESTMENT CAINS OH LOSSES
( ' 0 UM6EST l i f t INSURANCE COMPANIES)

1950

EXHIBIT III
INTEREST RATE EARNED BY U. S. LIFE INSURANCE COMPANIES SINCE 1875

$ 270
LUIND

24a

IKTCRIST RATt OM KlIkK 0C«T

-

.A,

i8a

PUBLIC DEBT (DIRECT ANO GUARANTEED)

_ _ „

TOTAL BANK DEPOSITS

4.0

AVERAGE MARKET YIELD ON LONG TERM PARTIALLY TAJ EtEMPT G6VT&

*">•

2K>

_ _ _

:

""V^ A

.......

AVERAGE MARKET YIELD ON TAXABLE LONG TERM GOVTi

_ . _ .

INTEREST RATE 0» PUBLIC DEBT

35

/

*vm»U>O« MAHHST Y1BID ©N
LONS TWM MUVTUOI.Y m i >XC»M
OOVMNMCMm

3.0

ZI6O

15

o
IJ

a
2.0 UJ

120

15

CO 90

s^-—

1OTA4 W M N 0«»O»T»

6030
puauc O U T

IJO

.5

o

O

1928

'29

'30

'31

'32

'33

34

'35

'36

'37

*38

'39

I94O

"41

'42

'43

'44

1945

EXHIBIT IV
RATES ON GOVT. SECURITIES, PUBLIC DEBT AND TOTAL BANK DEPOSITS




non-farm mortgage loans in the total amount of
about $5.6 billions. Many millions were secured by
single family residences which were not insured under the FHA. Many millions were on apartment
houses of various kinds.
The sum of all the non-farm mortgages represented about 14% of all the funds which the life
insurance companies held in custody for their policyholders, and accounted for over 18% of all the
non-farm mortgage debt.
Effect on Public Welfare
The life insurance companies are, I believe, as
enthusiastic about the possibilities of providing
homes for the American people as is any group
in the country, for housing offers a much needed
outlet for the investment of the funds of its policyholders; it is related to the general health of
the public which is of such a vital concern to life
insurance; and it is irrevocably linked with a
high level of industrial activity and the general
public welfare.
In a broad sense, certain provisions of the bill under consideration affect the public interest. In a
somewhat narrower sense they have important implications and consequences for those who have,
through life insurance, acquired security for their old
age or an estate for their heirs.
This is not a small group. It is not a wealthy group.
It is a group consisting principally of middle and
lower income people — the frugal, the industrious
and the diligent people of the country. I have had a
series of charts prepared which I hope, graphically
and more clearly than would otherwise be the case,
present many of the considerations I would like to
lay before you.
Life Insurance Widely Held
The first chart (Exhibit I, page 5) is an analysis
of the group, the exceedingly large group, affected
by certain of the provisions of this bill. The study of
consumer incomes and expenditures made by
the National Resources Committee, the Bureau
of Labor Statistics and the Bureau of Agricultural Economics reveals that in 1935-1936, 74%
of all the families in the United States held life
insurance and that 86% of the families paying
premiums for life insurance received incomes of
$3,000 a year or less. Chart No. 1, which is reconstructed from the study to which I referred, discloses




that even in the lowest income brackets of our population, that is to say, with annual incomes ranging
from $500 to $750, more than one-half of all the
families carry life insurance; in the $1,500 to
$1,750 income bracket nearly 80% of the families
are paying for life insurance protection. You will
observe from the chart that the percentage of families owning life insurance rises very rapidly from
52% in the $5OO-$75O income bracket to 85% in
the $2,000 to $2,250 income bracket and that the
trend thereafter to the bracket embracing the $10,000 group rises slowly from 85% to approximately
93% of all the families. This entire group is, therefore, an exceedingly large one and represents a very
preponderant and dominant part of the families of
the country. Only an exceedingly small percentage
of the families of the country are not represented in
this group.
The geographical distribution of families carrying
life insurance indicates likewise a broad distribution,
ranging from about 60% of all the families in the
Mountain States to more than 80% in the New England States. As between small and large communities, the coverage is likewise startlingly broad. For
example, the chart reveals that in the metropolitan
areas nearly 90% of all the families have life insurance and that the percentage declines to about 60%
in the rural districts. Thus, in terms of percentage of
the family population, in terms of geographical distribution and in terms of distribution in various
sized communities, the group of which I am speaking and which is affected by certain provisions of
this bill is a singularly significant and important one
in American life.
Cost of Security
A review of the cost of security obtained through
life insurance during the course of the last quarter of
a century discloses clearly that it has, for the average
American family, risen markedly, principally during
the course of the last 14 or 15 years. This is particularly true of policies in which the interest element or
investment factor predominates. The cost of endowments and annuities, which represent a type of policy
purchased or carried by those who wish to provide a
nest egg for their later years, has risen exceptionally.
Chart No. 2 (Exhibit II, page 5) represents the
combined performance of 11 mutual companies
that account for 13*4% of the total insurance in
force. [This experience is characteristic of the busi-

ness.] It shows how the costs of ordinary life policies
issued at specific ages and endowment policies issued
at the same ages have risen since 1921 and, thus, adversely affected the economic status of the large
number of people to whom reference has been made.
[The charts shown at the hearings displayed changes
only from 1921 to 1944. Mr. Douglas emphasized
before the Committee that if the period 1930-1944
were taken, the increase in cost would be very much
greater. This is shown by the charts herein which display changes both from 1921 to 1944 and from
1930 to 1944.] It reveals that the actual increase in
the annual cost of life insurance has ranged from
1.8% on an ordinary life policy issued at age 35 and
in force 10 years, to 9.9% in the case of an endowment policy issued at age 45 and in force 10 years.
But this is not a full reflection of the rise in costs.
Old Investments a Buffer
As old investments made at much higher rates
than presently prevailing ones pass out of the
portfolios, and are replaced by investments
yielding current rates — a process which is progressing with alarming speed — the cost rises. If
and when all old investments have been replaced, the cost as compared with 1921 figures,
increases 6.8% on an ordinary life policy issued
at age 35 and in force 10 years, and 16.5% in the
case of an endowment policy issued at age 45,
and in force 10 years.
And if and when the rate on new investments falls
another 1%—a movement which is now under way
and to which this bill would add momentum—then
the increase in cost of the ordinary life policy would
be more than 14% and of the endowment policy
over 25%. [This illustration presumes that the mortality factor and the operating ratio remain constant.]
If single premium policies were taken as examples, the increase in cost would be substantially
greater. But because single premium policies do not
constitute a predominant part of the total amount of
life insurance in force, it would be unfair and misleading to use them as examples.
By themselves and standing alone, while these
trends of costs are very disturbing, they fail to represent the real and singular significance of the interest
rate to insurance. When viewed in their context and
in the light of the full importance of interest to insurance, they reflect a serious condition.




Rising Cost of Insurance
The decline in the rate of interest, continuous
and steady and the precipitant fall in the rate
during the course of the last 14 years, is the sole
and exclusive explanation of the striking rise in
the cost of insurance.
At this point, let me call your attention to Chart
No. 3 (Exhibit III, page 6) which shows the gross
interest rate earned by life insurance companies
since 1875. You will observe that throughout the
Twenties the rate remained approximately steady,
but that beginning in 1930 the rate earned plummeted downward. This was not due entirely to a decline in the rate of interest, for during the first 3 or 4
years of the Thirties the decline in the rate of interest
earned, was aggravated by the default in interest
payments on many securities, bonds and mortgages.
On the other hand, during 1942 and 1943 the decline in the rate of interest earned, was retarded by
the payment of accumulated interest on securities
that had theretofore been in default. Nevertheless,
the chart is a reasonably fair representation of the effect of the decline of the interest rate on investment
earnings of insurance companies.
Interest Rate Trends
Chart 4 (Exhibit IV, page 6) shows the actual
interest rate on the public debt and on long-term
governments since 1928. This is perhaps a truer reflection of the decline in the interest rate than almost
any other chart which I could introduce, except possibly a chart on corporate issues which, as you would
expect, parallels generally the trend of the yield on
long-term governments. You will observe in Charts
No. 3 and 4 that the gross rate earned by life insurance companies since 1930 has fallen from 5.3% to
approximately 3.6%; while the rate on governments
has fallen from approximately 3.2% to somewhere
in the vicinity of 2%. (I say somewhere in the vicinity of 2% because an adjustment must be made
between yield and tax-exempt governments still outstanding in 1945 and the taxable governments outstanding at the same time. You will recollect that
generally government bonds were not taxable in
1930 and that new issues became taxable in 1941.)
Accordingly, it is, I think, beyond the area of debate to say that the decline in the interest rate and,
as a result, the shrinkage of earned income of life insurance companies have been marked and profound.
While speaking of interest rates, may I remind

MILLIONS
OF $
EXCESS INTEREST

MILUONS
OF $

BILLIONS
OF $

PREMIUMS

90-

9-

80-

8

70-

7-

60-

6-

50-

5-

40-

4-

30-

3-

20-

2-

10-

1-

1921 1930 1944

1921

NOTE: Excess interest is the amount which with
gains from other sources constitutes the sum which
may be paid to policyholders in the form of dividends.

0 1944

ASSETS

1921 1930 1944

BILLIONS
OF $

INS. IN FORCE

1921 1930 1944

EXHIBIT V

11 COMPANIES, REPRESENTING 13V4% OF TOTAL INSURANCE IN FORCE
AND 20% OF TOTAL ASSETS

MILLIONS
OF $
EXCESS

INTEREST

1921 1930 1944

EXCESS INT AS %
OF PREMIUMS

1921 1930 1944

NOTE: Excess interest is the amount which with
gains from other sources constitutes the sum which
may be paid to polloyholders in the form of dividends.




EXCESS INT AS
OF ASSETS

1921 1930 1944

EXCESS INT AS %
OF INS. IN FORCE

1921 1930 1944

EXHIBIT VI

11 COMPANIES, REPRESENTING 13V4% OF TOTAL INSURANCE IN FORCE
AND 20% OF TOTAL ASSETS

CHANGES 1930-1944

CHANGES 1921-1944
% CHANGE

% CHANGE

A 95.9% INCREASE IN PQLICYHOLDERS FUNDS
PRODUCED A 70% DECREASE IN EXCESS INTEREST

A 268.5% INCREASE IN .POJJCYHOLDERS FUNDS
PRODUCED A 46.8% DECREASE IN EXCESS INTEREST

INS. IN FORCE 4.6% LARGER - SHARED IN 7 0 %
LESS EXCESS*INTEREST

•300-

•300 -

•200-

• 200 PREMIUMS
EXCESS
INTEREST——-

1NS

-

1N

+ 100 -

•100-

-100.

-100-

NOTE: Excess interest is the amount which with
gains from other sources constitutes the sum which
may be paid to policyholders in the form of dividends.




EXCESS
INTEREST

EXCESS
INTEREST

F0RCE

PREMIUMS

EXHIBIT VII

CHANGES 1921 TO 1944 AND 1930 TO 1944

ADDITIONAL DIVIDENDS FROM 1%

$76,100,000

INTEREST INCREASE

1945 DIVIDEND

ALLOTMENT

TOTAL 1945 DIVIDENDS ALL COMPANIES $430,000,000.
1% additional interest would mean $323,000,000
more dividends if the increase were in the
same proportion as for the 11 companies.

EXHIBIT VIII
EFFECT OF INTEREST CHANGE ON DIVIDENDS
(Eleven Companies)

10

you of a fundamental distinction between a life insurance company and a bank. The earnings of a bank
need not be seriously or adversely affected by a decline in the interest rate, if at the same time the decline in the rate is accompanied by an increase, or a
corresponding increase, in deposits, for the bank
need not put up additional capital. A life insurance
company, however, and the amount of its investment
income available for refund to policyholders, is very
seriously affected by a decline in the interest rate. For
a life insurance company must each year add to its
capital in the form of additions to its policy reserves.
If these increments were not made, the life insurance
company would be unable to meet the death claims
of its policyholders when they fall due. It is only by
making additions to reserves out of premiums and
investment income, and the interest compounded
upon those reserves each year, that a life insurance
company is able to discharge its obligations, and pay
its claims when they are presented to it. It is because
of this characteristic of the life insurance institutions
that a decline in the interest rate affects it and its
policyholders so violently.

9) .* Excess interest represented a return of 1.8% on
admitted assets in 1921; in 1944 it was only 0.3%, a
decline of about 83%. In 1921, excess interest was
equal to 0.4% of the insurance in force; in 1944 the
percent was only a quarter as large. Similarly, excess
interest as a percent of premiums dropped from
11.8% to 2.9%—a fall of 75 %.
(See Chart 7, Exhibit VII, page 10).* A 268.5%
increase in policyholders' funds produced a 46.8%
decrease in excess or refundable interest. A volume
of insurance in force 98.5% larger was accompanied
by a 46.8% smaller amount of excess interest.
This trend of course, does not imply impending insolvency. The striking decline in interest
earnings does mean, however, an increase in the
cost of security to the large group that owns life
insurance. The increase applies both to new and existing business. (See Chart 8, Exhibit VIII, page 10.)
If the net interest rate earned by these companies in
1944 had been 1% higher than it was, their dividend
allotment [to policyholders] would have been increased from $102 millions to $178 millions, or by
75%. If this ratio holds for all companies, it would
mean that 1945 dividends [to policyholders] of
$430,000,000 could be increased by $323,000,000.
This is a model of extreme understatement. For if
the interest rate were 1% higher, the many, many
millions of dollars that are being set aside annually
to strengthen reserves in efforts to compensate for
the fall in interest rates, would be available for refund to the policyholders.
Therefore, if the interest were 1% higher, the
amount of dividends paid to policyholders would be
increased probably by as much as, if not more than,
100%—or for all companies by as much as $430,000,000, and the cost of security would be reduced
by that much.

Decline of Insurance Earnings
Chart 5 (Exhibit V,page 9) .* In 1921 when these
same eleven companies had $9.9 billions of insurance in force and $2.2 billions in assets, their funds
earned $40 millions over and above the minimum
amounts required to maintain reserves. [This
amount is known as excess interest and with gains
from other sources constitutes the sum which may
be paid to policyholders in the form of dividends.]
In 1944, with about double the volume of insurance
in force, and assets over three and a half times as
large, the companies had only $21 millions above
their requirements. (See Chart 6, Exhibit VI, page

II
Long Term Nature
of Life Insurance Commitments
tions. Life companies' contracts extend far into
the future — in many cases for more than threequarters of a century, and the reserves held

/-pi HE decline in the interest rate is not a mere
[_ temporary and passing phenomenon of immediate significance without future implica-

• Charts 5, 6 and 7 as presented at the hearings showed only 1921 and 1944, but it was stated that more significant changes had occurred
between 1930 and 1944. The charts herein show all three years.




11

ing good quality housing at reasonable prices by the
further reduction of the interest rate which this bill
contemplates.
The housing problem consists of two parts. There
is the immediate one of the next year or two, when
housing shortages in many areas, suitable or appropriate to the income of various groups, must be
diminished. The demand is very great, the supply is
now very short. New housing construction is the
only answer to this part of the problem.

against them remain equally as long. These commitments made in the past will continue for a long
time to represent the major portion of the life companies' obligations. Because of the fact that beneficiaries under existing policies usually have the right to
take the proceeds in the form of an annuity, or to
leave funds on deposit at guaranteed rates of interest,
these obligations will extend well into the twentyfirst century.
Life companies, accordingly, make long term investments on which prevailing low rates will be projected forward for a protracted period of time. In the
company of which I am president, there will still be
funds requiring interest in the year 2000, resulting
from insurance in force outstanding at the present
time. Chart No. 9 (Exhibit IX, page 13) clearly reveals this.
One more word on interest as it affects a life insurance company. It is important to understand that
there is a wide difference between the gross rate and
the net rate after investment expenses. If net rates
are considered, the figure for net investment return
on all assets has fallen from about 5.10% in the early
1920's to about 3.10% at the present time.
If you will turn back to Chart No. 3 you will observe the wide difference between net rate and gross
rate.

Building supplies, labor in the factories that produce building supplies and, of much less importance,
construction organizations and site labor, are the factors which limit our ability to increase the supply of
suitable housing facilities. There are no other limiting factors. There is an ample supply of credit—indeed, there is an ample supply of everything else that
affects housing.
The reduction in the rate of interest is much more
likely to add a further restricting factor than it is to
add encouragement to housing. The same is true
about increasing the coverage of mortgages and extending the period of amortization.
Security, Housing Costs Higher
These financial devices; i.e., lower interest
rates and extended periods of amortization, will
produce two results, and I shall be surprised if
you wish to accomplish either one. The first is to
damage further the personal security in the
United States by making life insurance more
expensive and putting further and serious pressure on the institutions which provide it. Secondly, it will make housing more expensive for
the returning veterans and American people
generally and cause their financial burdens to
increase.

American Families Penalized
The further reduction in interest rates effected through certain provisions of the Bill you
are now considering, it seems to me, will be adding arbitrarily penalty upon penalty to a group
of about 27,000,000 American families, by increasing still further the cost of family security
to them.
I hope these graphic representations have revealed
the truth of this conclusion and the vital significance
of the interest rate to the extraordinarily large part
of the American population that has obtained,
through life insurance, security for their older years
and financial support for their family.
The question I lay before you is whether, as an offset to the serious consequences already having been
caused by the reduction in the interest rate for this
predominant part of the American population—and
in view of the more serious consequences that the
future holds for them—there will be made any contribution of significance to the objective of provid-




This latter results because, through making credit
easier, the bidding for limited supply of housing is
made more spirited. Prices of houses and rentals, already at a high level, will thus be driven higher.
Against these pressures, price controls, while they
may provide some relief, are not likely to be able to
hold the line. They will not provide homes.
But beyond this, these financial devices will impose a larger financial burden and a greater risk of
loss to the purchasers when supplies become less
tight. These are the two results that I believe will be

12

MILLIONS
OF $

MILLIONS
OF $

1,600-

-1,600

1,400-

-1,400

1,200-

-1,200

1,000-

-1,000

800-

-800

600-

-600

400-

-400

200-

-200

Q




1950

I960

1970

1980

1990

EXHIBIT IX
FUNDS WHICH MUST BE INVESTED AT INTEREST
(Existing Business — One Life Ins. Co.)

SAVINGS IN MONTHLY HOUSING COSTS
BY 2 0 % REDUCTION

INCREASE

INTEREST

IN

COST OF
TAXES

AMORTIZATION

MAINTENANCE

65%

HOUSE
a LAND

COST

DECREASE
IN
COST

44%

43%
56%

15.4%

EXHIBIT X
SAVINGS IN MONTHLY HOUSING COSTS

13

2000

achieved by the financial devices which the bill contemplates.

Much the same results apply to almost any type of
housing. The N.H.A. has itself prepared a chart,
which I have here, (Chart No. 11, Exhibit XI, page
15) and which confirms everything I have said as to
the significance and importance of the cost of materials, land, and so forth.

Different Approach Required
The conclusion seems to me to be inescapable
that financial devices alone will not add one
shingle to a roof, not one board to a floor, not

This is the heart, the bone, and the sinew of the
problem, and I doubt that housing will play the part
that you would like to see it play—and indeed that
every well-intentioned person would like to see it
play — unless the problem of costs is adequately,
appropriately, and wisely solved. This bill, I am confident, not only fails to solve it; I think it almost
completely ignores it.
May I make one final observation. I was one of
those who, as a member of the administration in the
early thirties, was deeply concerned about organization of the mortgage market as an instrument of
recovery and as an aid to housing, and in an unimportant and modest way played a part in advising on
the provisions of the housing legislation that led to
the FHA. Therefore, I can speak as one who is a
friend and has been a friend of housing in many
forms.

one room to an existing structure, not one house
on a vacant lot. The problem is a different sort of
a problem.
The second part of the housing problem carries
forward into the distant future. I have already indicated how important to our future, in terms of
health, of crime, of civic responsibility, in terms of
industrial activity and employment, housing can be
during the ensuing decade or even quarter of a century. But it can play its role fully only if the auspices
are appropriate. It can be strangled and throttled by
inappropriate auspices.
This leads me to what appears to be the guts of the
problem, and that is the cost of land and materials
and the unit cost of labor.
The National Housing Agency has completed a
study which I have graphically represented on Chart
10 (Exhibit X, page 13). This chart shows that a reduction of 20% in the interest on a mortgage will
reduce the cost by only 4.3%. It shows that extending the maturity ®f the mortgage 20% will increase
the cost of a house by 6 V2 %, through an extension of
the period in which interest is due and thus through
increasing the total amount of interest payable. Accordingly, the financial devices suggested in the bill
will increase the cost to the home owner.

Housing Bill Inadequate
In that setting may I say myfinalsay. The question
I would like to raise with you is whether a housing bill whose principal provisions, other than
the administrative ones, have to do with financial devices will actually encourage the construction of housing in adequate amounts and of
suitable quality, appropriately located and
within the income reach of a large part of the
population, either for the immediate emergency
or throughout the years that stretch ahead.

How to Obtain a 25% Reduction
On the other hand, a reduction in taxes of 20%
has the effect of decreasing the cost by 5.6%. A similar reduction in maintenance results in a decline in
cost of 4.4%. And a 20% reduction in the cost of
materials for the house, land, and unit labor cost—
and this is the significant part of the study — produces a reduction in cost of 15.4%. If the cost of
taxes, maintenance, supplies, land, and unit labor
costs, could be reduced by 20%, the cost of housing
would be made lower by 25% to all those who buy
homes.




I am not now raising the question whether housing, under the provisions of this bill, can be adequately provided, as the bill contemplates, under the
auspices of private enterprise. / think they cannot be.
I am raising the broader question as to whether adequate housing facilities within the income reach of a
large part of the population of the United States can
be provided economically by any instrumentality or
agency, public or private, under the terms of this bill.

14

WHERE THE HOUSING DOLLAR GOES
I
<Each ltan expressed a* ptre«nt of total coat of house and land)
1.

Coat o f Materiale a t SiWi

Coat o f
Manufacture

Coat of
Distribution

4.19
2.17
1.70
1.31
0.11

AM
0.73
0.66
1.54
0.06
0.32
1.02
3.10
0.34
0.29
0.90
0.30
0.40
0.30
U.80

Lumber
Masonry
Concrete and mortar
Plaster, l a t h and »allboard
Insulation
toofing
Flooring

Kiltork

Paint
Finish hardware
Plumbing
Heating
Electrical
Miscelleneoua
All material*
2

0.62

1.35
2.88
0.B8
O.S9

3.63
0.39
0.39
0.49
20.90

Coat of
Transportation

Combined Delivered
fronts
Price

1.42
0.30

0.33

0.46
0.03
0.10
0.24
0.38
0.04
0.03
0.35
0.09
0.05

m

1.60
0.25
0.44
0.96
0.04
0.21
0.34
1.00
0.15
0.10
0.60
O.U
O.U

6710

Cost of S i t e Construction Labor

-

r
r
r
r

7.

Contractor's and Subcontractors'

11.65

3.45
3.33
(.27
0.24
1.25
2.95
7.36
1.41
0.71
5.48
1.42
0.98

I

I
1
1
'

45^|
29.50

Overhead and Profit

12.30
87.50

Total Cost of Houaa

7.00

Value of Unimproved Land (Including profit on land)

5.50

Cost of Land Inproveaents (lncludln? p r o f i t on Improvements)

100.00

CAPITAL COST

MONTHLY COST TO OWN

Reduction

Usjuned cost of hoot* and land i s 15,coo)
1.

Initial Cash Psyaents:
Eewnpgyaent (90* mortgage)
Closing fees and commissions
Total cash payments

2.

Monthly Cost fort

in capital
costs

$11.31
Interest (51)
Amortization (25 years)
15.00
Loss of Interest on cash payments (3<) 1.50
Taxes (2}4)
10.42
Hasard insurance (2/13 of IX)
.83
Maintenance (SIX per annua)
8.33
Total monthly cost
S47.7?

is most
effective

Monthly costs of novsihg can oe cut by reducing any one of the following major l t e w i
Interest, aoortltatlon, taxes, maintenance, or cost of house*end land. The relative
effect on monthly costs of a 20J reduction in each of these Items separately, with
all other Items remaining unchanged, Is sho*n below. Reductions In two or more of
the Items together will of course ban a correspondingly greater effect.
Maior ltea and 2O< reduction In each
First
25 reare
Interest (froa 5( to iS)
An>rtltatlon (fron 25 years to 31i years)
Taxes (from 2}« to H)
Maintenance (Iron $100 to $80 per annoa)
(from $5000 to $4000)

Next
15 rears
0
0
9.9*
7.9<

4.5*»
4.4<

15.4*

VL.kt

• Represents savings per month owr 31} yean, tent of loan In this case
NOTE: Capital cost means cost of materials, labor and land.




v

EXHIBIT XI
WHERE THE HOUSING DOLLAR GOES
(SOURCE: "HOUSING COSTS" - National Housing Agency, December, 1944)

15