View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery




Statement of
William McChesney Martin, Jr.,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Subcommittee on the Federal Reserve
of the Senate Committee on Banking and Currency

February 19, 1958

The year 1957 was a difficult one for those of us charged with
appraising financial and economic events and formulating appropriate
monetary policy. From its opening and on during much of the year,
inflationary pressures were dominant in this country and abroad. In
commodity markets, industrial prices were continuing to advance despite
generally downward reaction in prices of some internationally traded
basic materials following the Suez crisis. In consumer markets, prices
of goods and services were advancing at a very rapid pace for a nonpar
period. Prices of common stocks, which had tended down from mid-1956 to
early 1957, rose sharply to new highs in mid-summer under the influence of
creeping inflation doctrine and of widening confidence that the large
capital expansion in which business was engaging would be adequately
supported by the demands of a rapidly growing population for a rising
standard of living. The strength of inflationary pressures was exemplified
by the marked advances being recorded in the gross national product
measured in current dollars as compared with the relatively modest gains
that were being obtained in the physical volume of total output.
In spite of Federal Reserve actions taken to resist inflationary
trends—including six increases of Federal Reserve Bank discount rates in
1955 and 1956 and the pursuance of a restrictive credit policy—money lost
its value at a rate that was a matter of great concern to all. Inflationary
excesses had clearly gotten ahead of us and the economy stood in danger of
an inflation crisis• The adjustment problems that the economy is confronting
today are the aftermath of those excesses.




-2As a nation, we were trying to do too much too fast, and heavy
pressure was exerted against the available supply of savings©

In

retrospect, we underestimated the speed and force of the inflationary
boom and the widespread growth in speculative attitudes and commitments.
Consumer instalment credit rose substantially in 1955 when terms were
sharply relaxed and consumers used credit more freely than ever before
in the purchase of record number of new automobiles. Businesses greatly
increased their expenditures for plant and equipment. The rise from
1955 to 1956 amounted to more than one-fifth for business as a whole
and this advanced level was further exceeded in 1957. Stock investors
were too optimistic in capitalizing the income and dividends which this
investment might yield. Bankers and other lenders greatly expanded
their commitments to lend in these years. Also, liquidity positions of
banks and businesses were being reduced as their short-term liabilities
were increasing faster than their holdings of cash and Government
securities. Labor unions sought wage increases—and commitments for
future increases—that pressed against or exceeded gains in productivity.
State and local governments borrowed record amounts through the capital
markets in an effort to meet the needs of their citizens for community
facilities and services.
Inflationary trends continued through the summer months of last
yearo

There was an alarming spread of the belief, not only in this

country but also abroad, that creeping inflation under modern economic
conditions was a chronic and inevitable condition. Reflecting this
view, common stocks, the most popular hedge against inflation, rose




-3sharply in price in July to a level where for the first time in two
decades their yields fell below the yields on high-grade bonds. Also,
credit demands generally continued to show great strength, and interest
rates were rising. Large city banks on August 7 raised their lending
rate to prime business borrowers from 4 to 4-l/2 per cent. In this
situation, Federal Reserve Bank discount rates, which were below market
rates by a widening margin, were raised in mid-August from 3 to 3-1/2
per cent, thus increasing costs to member banks operating on the basis
of borrowed reserves.
In late summer and early autumn, developing uncertainties here
and abroad began to affect the short-term economic outlook. In European
exchange markets, widespread expectations of changes in exchange rate3
fostered large speculative movements of funds between European centers.
These expectations in part reflected further accentuation of inflationary
developments in some key countries, despite actions to tighten credit that
were taken in various countries during the summer. It was not until late
September, after the Bank of England established a 7 per cent discount
rate, that it became clear that key foreign currency values would be
maintained and that inflation would be strongly resisted.
In this country, the unexpected curtailment in defense payments
and changes in procurement policies that were inaugurated during the
summer, partly to avoid breaking through the debt ceiling, had an unsettling
effect on business. In September, nonagricultural employment, which had
been at a record level in August, began to show signs of slackening. The
Board!s index of industrial production declined slightly. Reflecting
these and other developments, common stock prices in late September broke




-4through the trading range that had prevailed during the past two years.
With changing attitudes toward the economic outlook, production and other
adjustments that had been occurring for some months in various lines of
activity, including some capital goods lines, came to be reappraised by
businessmen, investors, and the public generally.

In contrast to earlier

indications of strong credit demands, bank loans to business during early
autumn decreased contrary to usual seasonal tendencies.
The pace of business was maintained for a time despite these
uncertainties.

By late October, the composite of most recent economic

information suggested that inflationary pressures were abating, and open
market operations were modified to lessen restraint on bank credit and
monetary expansion.

By mid-November, information becoming available,

incomplete though it was, indicated that a general downward adjustment
was setting in. In response to this change in basic economic conditions,
Federal Reserve Bank discount rates were reduced from 3-1/2 to 3 per cent.
Since that time, the use of open market and discount policies
has been complementary.

Open market operations have provided sufficient

reserves to permit member banks not only to repay a substantial portion
of their indebtedness to the Reserve Banks, but also to accumulate some
addition to reserves available for bank credit expansion. Discount rates
were lowered again in mid-January, from 3 to 2-3/4 per cent.
At the end of 1957, stock market credit to customers of brokers
and banks for purchasing and carrying listed securities was less than at
midyear and back to the level of early 1955. Thus, the need for using the
higher level of margin requirements, established in early 1955, to prevent




-5an excessive expansion of stock market credit had abated. The Board of
Governors in mid-January reduced margin requirements for purchasing or
carrying listed securities from 70 to 50 per cent.
System actions have contributed to a marked easing in the credit
and capital markets©

This is illustrated dramatically by the very sharp

drop in market rates of interest, the sharpest drop for any comparable
period of which I have knowledge. Yields on Treasury 90-day bills dropped
nearly two percentage points—from over 3-1/2 to a recent low of 1-1/2 per
cento

This adjustment in credit and capital markets is helping to facilitate

and cushion other adjustments in the economy as well as to strengthen
demands in important areas dependent on credit financing•

It is thus,

along with other Government programs, helping to set the stage for recovery
in activity and employment•
We all share the hope that recession will be moderate and short¬
lived, but it is not possible to be completely certain about the future
course of economic activity.

There is a range of views currently held

regarding the duration and extent of this recession and of the timing
and vigor of the ensuing recovery.
of the economy are many.

In my own view, the underlying strengths

The inflationary trends seem to have halted

before creating maladjustments of such severity as to lead to a protracted
period of liquidation and structural realignment in the economy. After
not too long a period of readjustment, healthy revival should set in,
progressing to new records of economic performance and new high levels
of national well being. A great deal depends upon the speed with which
needed readjustments are made©




-6We are all, of course, well aware that reasoning by analogy may
be misleading and that history does not repeat itself. Nevertheless, it
may be noted that the downward movement from the third quarter 1957 peak
has been reminiscent in many ways of the declines that occurred in 1948-49
and in

1953-54

In these two postwar recessions, lows in activity were

reached in less than a year from the cyclical peak and recovery to new
high levels of output, demands, and employment was rapid and substantial.
In both recessions, the industrial production decline was limited to
about 10 per cent from high to low# With the exception of the catastrophic
depression of the early 1930 ! s, the downward phase of every cycle since
World War I has been over or virtually over in the course of about a year.
Many basic forces in the present situation are favorable to hopes
for recovery. These include;




(1) Credit and capital market conditions have already
responded to relaxed monetary policy and are much easier
than they were a few months ago. Other important
financial adjustments have already been made or
started. Stock yields, for example, have adjusted
to a more normal relationship with high grade bond
yields. By borrowing from the capital market, more¬
over, business firms have been repaying bank debt,
thus rebuilding the liquidity positions of both
financing institutions and business enterprises•
(2) Consumer incentives to achieve still higher standards
of living are strong, and research continues to

-7provide new products of wide consumer appeal. As a
group, businessmen and consumers continue to have
confidence in the long-term growth prospects for our
economy. Total retail sales advanced both in December
and January and were at levels well above those a year
earlier despite lower sales of new automobiles.
(3) Population increase has been maintained at a rapid
pace—the rise of 1.8 per cent in 1957 compares with
a postwar average of 1.7 per cent, and hence the
market is expanding steadily.
(4) Consumer incomes have shown some cyclical decline
recently, but the decline has been small and moderated
by unemployment compensation benefits. Consumer
demands are supported by a record volume of financial
assets, the ownership of which is widely distributed.
Growth in such assets was rapid in 1956 and 1957,
while growth in consumer instalment and mortgage
debt, though not small, was at a much slower rate
than in 1955. The availability and terms of mortgage
credit have recently become more favorable to borrowers.
New housing starts increased in January and were
moderately above their low in the spring of 1957•
(5) At the State and local government level, community




demands for schools and teachers, for roads, public
buildings, and other community facilities are

-8continuing large and insistent. Bond issues of State
and local government authorities have advanced to
record levels.
(6) For the Federal Government, postwar budgets have
been dominated by the need to cope with critical
international stresses and tensions and to provide
adequate defense under conditions of major scientific
advance and rapid technological change. National
security and related problems continue to be urgent
(7) Insofar as international economic developments are
concerned, Western Europe still shows strength.
Industrial activity, while no longer expanding, has
generally been maintained at or close to record levels.
In general, balance of payments positions have improved
although in several countries reserves of gold and
foreign exchange are not as large as might be desired.
Outside Europe, however, raw materials producing
countries are facing difficulties because of declines
in volume and prices of their exports .
A primary uncertainty with respect to the timing of economic
revival and renewed growth relates to the course of business outlays
for new plant and equipment. Some observers view the business capital
goods boom of the past three years as having provided a margin of
industrial capacity over prospective demands greater than can be absorbed
quickly. These observers tend to expect a more protracted period of
adjustment than took place in the two preceding cycles•




-9This concern may turn out to have been well founded, but it may
be noted that capacity never appears more excessive than in the midst
of receding activity. Recovery, in due course, can certainly be expected
to be accompanied by effective and profitable use of the economy's Capacity
to produce and by still further additions to capacity• The important
factors working to expand business capital investment in the period ahead
should not be minimized. The advance in the technology of production,
in part the result of the hugs investment in research of recent years,
has been rapid and can be expected to continue. Incentives to reduce
costs, to meet competition, and to sustain or improve profitability, are
strong.
History shows that our market economy has cyclical characteristics,
and the consequences of this irregularity in terms of hardship and unemploy¬
ment are of deep concern to everyone. When downward readjustment becomes
unavoidable, it is incumbent on business enterprises, financial institutions,
and labor organizations, as well as Government generally, to adjust policies
and programs to foster recovery. We have been concerned, for example, at
the decline in output and employment while prices generally have been
maintained and some prices even have risen further. Currently, it may
be noted, consumer prices reached a new high in November and remained at
about that high in December and January. How soon recession is checked
and recovery is resumed will be influenced by the rapidity with which
economic corrections and adaptations are made in factors beyond the
province of monetary policy, that is to say, in business pricing policies,
selling practices and productive efficiency; in wage bargaining; in various




-10financing arrangementsj and in the incentives to consumers to buy. In
the past, price reductions during periods of contraction served to
stimulate increased buying and output and thus to contribute to general
recovery and expansion. Undoubtedly, lower prices now would prove to have
expansive benefits for economic activity generally.
If needed adjustments are promptly made, the current recession
may be moderate and short-lived. Furthermore, there will be the possi¬
bility that revival may develop without renewed inflationary tendencies.
Under such circumstances, the task of monetary policy would be to foster
such revival and to encourage the resumption of orderly growth.
If revival in over-all economic activity becomes exuberant,
however, there will be an accompanying danger of resurgence of inflationary
pressures. Postwar experience has demonstrated that, in a period of
expanding demand, upward pressures on prices and costs can develop
quickly. Once under way, inflationary movements tend to spread them¬
selves throughout the economy, not only because of normal market reactions,
but also because of a variety of institutional arrangements.
When contractive tendencies in economic activity set it, there
is always the hazard that recession may be deeper and more protracted
than many anticipate, with a greater degree of underutilization of man¬
power and industrial resources and with manifest deflationary tendencies.
In such an eventuality, further monetary action would need to be considered,
both to increase the liquidity of the economy and to encourage expansion
of spending financed by credit. Monetary policy by itself, however,
cannot assure resumption of high-level employment and sustainable economic
growth, although ready availability of credit at reasonable cost is an
essential ingredient for recovery.



-11Those charged with responsibility for national economic policies
must at all times reckon with the dangers both of inflation and of
deflation

The central policy problem, in one sense, is to prevent either

inflationary trends or deflationary trends from becoming dominant. Public
policies for one objective or another can have effects that go far beyond
those that are intended. Both fiscal and monetary policies must be
carefully formulated to exert enough pressure or ease but not too much.
That is a difficult task. It is one that you and I both must live with
every day, and do the very best we can to reach the judgments and come to
the decisions which in the long run will prove to have been wise.
As I have said on many occasions, anti-inflationary policies and
anti-deflationary policies are inseparably linked. Excesses on the upside
must be avoided in order to avoid the heavy costs and personal hardships
that unfortunately develop during the ensuing contraction. Now that we
are in the contractive phase, we must take whatever actions are needed
to minimize the hardships and to foster vigorous recovery. But in so
doing we also must recognize that excessive stimulus during recession
can sow seeds of inflation that can grow to jeopardize our long-run
stability and our economic strength at a time when as a nation we are
confronted with a special urgency to maintain all the productive strength
we can muster on a sustainable basis.