View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

"U.S. COMPETITIVENESS AND MONETARY POLICY"
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
Rotary Club of Jackson
Jackson, Tennessee
September 20, 1989

Federal

Reserve

monetary

policy

actions

profoundly—sometimes for good, sometimes for ill.

can

affect

our

lives

In search of the good

effects, people often plead for policies that they believe will benefit
them, at least in the short run.

Unfortunately, some of these demands

can have pernicious longer-run effects, not only on those making them,
but on the rest of us as well.
One example of this is the well-intentioned, but misguided pressure
on the Federal Reserve to do something about this nation's international
competitive position, which many believe has been dangerously weakened
in the 1980s.

The standard line is that the rising value of the dollar

from 1980 to 1985 undermined U.S. competitiveness; our goods became too
expensive for foreigners, while foreign goods became too cheap for U.S.
consumers to resist.

What can the Fed do about this?

According to

conventional wisdom, we can use monetary policy to drive down the dollar's
exchange value and thereby reverse our weakening competitive position.
I hope to convince you this afternoon that not only is this conventional wisdom about the solution wrong, but also that there isn't a
problem in the first place I
ability

to

compete, both

declined substantially

Despite much press to the contrary, our

domestically

and

during this decade.

internationally,

has not

Furthermore, deliberately

pursuing monetary policy actions intended to drive down the value of the
dollar would be disastrous.




- 2 -

Let's
competitive.

consider,

first,

the

claim

that

we

have

become

less

International competitiveness is a term that gets tossed

around casually, but is actually difficult to pin down when the discussion
gets specific.

Some people

think

competitiveness

can be

judged by

comparing the dollar's current value with the level that would achieve
so-called "purchasing power parity;" this is a situation in which goods
cost about the same in all countries.

Other people look at how much we

import or export compared to the size of the domestic market, as in the
case of steel or autos, or how much we trade compared to world trade, as
in the case of corn or other farm commodities.

Still others focus only

on the amount or growth of U.S. exports and imports, or on the pace of
innovation of new goods and services.
Which measure of U.S. competitiveness should we look at?

It turns

out that, while disagreements about the "best" measure of international
competitiveness might be interesting at times, we shouldn't let them
distract us.

There has to be a simple, clear-cut "bottom-line" comparison

that transcends all quibbles about definitions. And there is one that, I
think, we can all agree on.
If we have really lost our competitiveness, our economic performance
should have gotten worse: worse than our own past and worse relative to
that

of

other

nations—especially

competitiveness at our expense.
comparison?

those

who

supposedly

have

gained

Where can we look for this bottom-line

A nation's performance is generally measured by what is

happening to its productivity and output growth.

Thus, our record in

these areas, stacked up against those of other nations, should tell us a
great deal about our international competitiveness.




- 3 -

Let's look, then, at what really happened in the 1980s.

As you

know, from mid-1980 to early 1985, the foreign exchange value of the
dollar

skyrocketed

mushroomed.

and, at about

the

same

time, our

trade deficit

These two developments often are cited as proof positive that

our competitiveness eroded.

Imports rose and exports fell, presumably

proving that U.S. production fell while foreign production was spurred
upward.

Given this picture, our productivity must have declined relative

to our foreign competitors.
As convincing as this argument must seem, nothing could be further
from the truth!

A recent study completed at our Bank shows that, in

fact, the United States has enjoyed a renaissance of productivity in the
1980s, especially in the manufacturing industries where the trade deficit
rose the most.

Five industries—electric

and nonelectric

machinery,

transportation equipment, primary metals and apparel—account for about
three-fourths of the rise in the trade deficit in the 1980s.

Yet, the

average annual growth of output in those industries together was about
5 percent from 1980 to 1985, more than twice the growth rate of other
manufacturing industries or, for that matter, of the economy as a whole.
Moreover, this was a remarkable change from the 1970s, when these same
five industries, like the rest of manufacturing, grew at a dismal 1
percent annual rate.
Underlying the rapidly expanding output in these five industries
was a rebirth of U.S. productivity growth in general.

Productivity had

been stagnant in the 1970s, but it surged in the 1980s, especially in
manufacturing, where it rose nearly five times faster than it had in the
1970s.




- 4 -

The real key to the booming U.S. productivity and output growth in
the 1980s was investment in plant and equipment which, until recently,
was incredibly strong.

Adjusted for the business cycle, business invest-

ment was stronger from 1981 to 1985 than it had been since the late 1940s.
Meanwhile, in the rest of the world, investment declined to such an
extent in the early 1980s that few countries were able to regain their
1980 pace of real investment by 1985.

Among those few that did, the

United States was the clear leader, investing 21.6 percent more in 1985
than it had in 1980.

Next came Japan which, in 1985, invested 15.1

percent more than in 1980.

Italy did not achieve its 1980 pace until

1986; Germany and France, not until mid-1987.
U.S. manufacturing output growth climbed

It is no surprise that

from near

the bottom among

industrial nations in the 1970s to close to the top in the 1980s.
Why, then, are the facts so much at odds with popular perceptions
about trade and competitiveness?

The missing link is the understanding

that our imports can rise, or our exports can fall, while domestic
production of these internationally-traded goods rises; it is simply not
true that our production of these goods must decline when our trade
deficit rises.
income was
productivity

Improvements in U.S. productivity have meant that U.S.

rising

faster

advances

in

than

that

of

trading

partners.

Our

internationally-traded

goods

lowered the relative prices of these goods and redistributed

income

toward the United States.

manufacturing

our

Lower prices and higher incomes allowed U.S.

consumption of traded goods to boom.

As imports rose, U.S. production of

import-competing goods also rose sharply.

Imports rose, then, to meet

the booming demands of U.S. purchasers, not to replace declining output.




- 5 -

Likewise, while

exports

generally did not decline.
for

export

purchasers.

were

fell,

the

production

of

these

goods

Goods that formerly would have been produced

redirected

to meet

the

increased

demands

of U.S.

There are some exceptions, of course, like farm equipment;

in general, however, the decline in exports did not translate into
declining U.S. production.
This experience should raise doubts about whether we need to boost
U.S. competitiveness.

It also raises doubts about whether lowering the

value of the dollar is an appropriate way to do it, inasmuch as the
dollar's rise in the early 1980s apparently did not adversely affect U.S.
competitiveness.
exchange

value

The existence
of

the

dollar

of a link between
and

monetary

established—both in theory and in practice.

policy

the

international

actions

is well

Simply put, faster U.S.

money growth tends to reduce the dollar's value.

At home, faster U.S.

money growth means a rise in U.S. inflation; internationally, it means a
faster drop in the dollar's value against foreign currencies.
But, asking

the Fed to push up inflation just to raise U.S.

competitiveness doesn't seem like a good idea—even if it would work.
In fact, the notion that we can trade off a little more inflation for a
little more competitiveness is a mirage.

Inflating the currency to lower

the value of the dollar does not boost U.S. competitiveness.
inevitably lowers it.

Higher inflation raises taxes and pushes up the

cost of capital for business.
investment

incentives

Instead, it

and

Increased capital costs, in turn, reduce

domestic

productivity.

Lower

productivity

raises the cost of U.S. output relative to our competitors and reduces
both our ability to compete and our share of world markets.




- 6 -

The 1980-85 experience confirms these linkages between monetary
policy, which was generally restrictive during that period, the dollar
and international competitiveness.
linkages as well.

And there is further evidence of such

For example, money growth was quite rapid from mid-1976

to mid-1980; in response, the value of the dollar fell sharply, while
inflation surged from 5 percent in 1976 to double-digit levels by 1980.
During this period, U.S. investment, productivity

growth and

output

growth all stagnated compared to historical trends and compared to our
major foreign competitors.
Again, in early 1985, money growth surged and the value of the
dollar began to plummet.

The falling currency, however, did not signal

an improvement in U.S. competitiveness.

Instead, business fixed invest-

ment declined sharply from the end of 1985 until mid-1987, despite a boom
in output and employment.

And, productivity growth plummeted to less

than one-half of one percent, about one-quarter of its growth from 1980
to 1985.
Since early 1987, the growth rate of Ml has slowed.

Not surpris-

ingly, the value of the dollar stopped falling, and, since early 1988,
has generally moved higher.

Some analysts have argued that the slight

improvement in the value of the dollar is, once again, threatening U.S.
competitiveness.

If

the past

is any

guide, however, this view is

"flat-out" wrong.
So, what's the bottom line on U.S. competitiveness and monetary
policy?

Our

competitiveness

has

especially from 1980 to 1985.
policymakers need to focus

improved

markedly

Neither monetary

specifically

in

this decade,

policy nor monetary

on U.S. competitiveness; it

doesn't seem to require any special boost. More importantly, the strategy




- 7 -

often proposed to boost competitiveness is wrong.
the

dollar's

international

exchange

value

A strategy of lowering

requires

accelerated

and

inflationary monetary growth; such a policy is counterproductive in the
long run.

inflationary policy invariably has reduced

investment and

retarded the growth of productivity, output and our standard of living.
Instead,

I believe

that

monetary

long-term goal of price stability.

policy

should

focus

on the

Only this policy—of holding inflation

to a minimum—promotes both economic growth and competitiveness.

While a

rise in the dollar's value can occur under such a policy, this is not a
shortcoming.

Rather, it reflects both the rising value that foreign and

domestic money holders place on well-managed monetary assets and the
increased competitiveness of the U.S. economy.
Competitiveness is a worthy goal.

But, like all worthy goals, you

can't achieve it unless you get the "basics" right first.

When it comes

to monetary policy, getting the basics right means providing stable and
noninflationary growth in the monetary aggregates.

If the Fed does this,

it will be doing the best it can do to ensure our competitiveness.