View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Randall S. Kroszner

At the National Association for Business Economics Professional Development Seminar for
Journalists, Washington, D.C.
May 24, 2006

Innovative Statistics for a Dynamic Economy
Accurate and timely statistics are fundamental to sound financial and economic decisionmaking in
both the private and public sectors. The quality of the economic statistics in the United States is
among the best, if not the best, in the world, but that should not make us complacent. The U.S.
economy is extremely dynamic, and improvements in our economic statistics should reflect--and
measure--that ever-present change.
Naturally, markets work best when people are well informed. Business people rely on economic
statistics when they make and execute plans for production, investment, and hiring. Academics and
researchers around the world also use economic statistics to evaluate alternative models and theories
that further our understanding of how the economy and financial markets operate.
Reliable and timely economic statistics are crucial to the formulation and evaluation of budgetary
and monetary policies. Measuring U.S. gross domestic product (GDP), for example, is an
enormously difficult task, but accurate measurements are extremely important for policymakers'
decisions. An error of just 1/10 percentage point in projections of long-term real GDP growth, for
instance, can result in an error of approximately $270 billion in a ten-year budget forecast.
Monetary policy relies crucially upon sound statistics. I am sure that many of you have heard the
analogy comparing a monetary policy maker to the driver of a car. The policymaker is faced with
the decision of whether to tap on the accelerator or the brake to maintain the proper speed for the
economy. In 2004, then-Governor Bernanke commented that, in part given the imperfect nature of
economic statistics, "if making monetary policy is like driving a car, then the car is one that has an
unreliable speedometer, a foggy windshield, and a tendency to respond unpredictably and with a
delay to the accelerator or the brake."1 Trying to fix that speedometer and to clear some of the fog
from the windshield is what I want to focus on in my remarks today.
Let me start with a couple of concrete examples of the importance of improving economic statistics
for monetary policy. The first concerns the measurement of productivity, that is, the amount of
output for each hour of labor. Productivity is a key element in the evaluation of how rapidly the
economy can grow before raising concerns about inflationary pressures. Errors in measuring either
output or hours of work--unless they are in both and just happen to exactly offset each other--will
lead to distortions in the measurement of productivity. Such a distortion occurred in the mid-1990s.
Work done at the time by the Board's staff suggested that measured productivity in some sectors of
the economy was implausibly low.2 As a consequence, Chairman Greenspan urged the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) to pursue a more accommodative monetary policy than the
published productivity statistics, at the time, might have suggested. The result was a period of high
economic growth and low inflation.
Prices are another set of data that are important for monetary policy. The primary responsibility of
monetary policy is to ensure that we have a low and stable rate of inflation and the maximum
sustainable rate of employment growth. Inaccurate price measurement could result in inaccurate

forecasts of the direction of inflation and, thereby, lead to policy choices that are too tight or too
accommodative.
As a researcher, I find that timely and reliable information is critical for analyzing, measuring, and
calibrating the ways in which the various parts of our complex economy operate.
Although most people think of banks, money, and interest rates when they hear mention of the
Federal Reserve, the central bank is also an important producer of economic statistics. Among other
things, the Federal Reserve publishes data on interest rates, industrial production, and financial
accounts for the nation--the flow of funds system. The Federal Reserve also has a strong
commitment to promoting economic education and financial literacy. Recently we have begun using
the latest Internet-based technology to make the data we publish more accessible and easier to
understand. In particular, last month we added to our web site a new data download application,
which provides interactive access to Federal Reserve statistical data in a variety of electronic
formats. We view this new feature as a key element in our mission of promoting financial education.
A Cost-Benefit Framework
As an economist, I like to think about the issues surrounding the improvement of economic statistics
using the framework of cost-benefit analysis. As applied to economic statistics, cost-benefit analysis
essentially says that because the federal government has limited resources, it's important that the
statistical agencies and the nation get the biggest bang possible for the buck. The goal is to allocate
resources most efficiently and effectively, focusing on the data that are most important for private
and public decisionmaking.3
Improving the cost-benefit tradeoff for economic statistics has several elements, and I will focus on
two in my remarks. The common theme is that innovations in economic statistics must keep pace
with innovations in the economy.
One element to improving the cost-benefit tradeoff is removing legislative barriers that raise costs
without providing benefits. Sometimes individual federal statistical agencies must separately collect
information from the public on the same subject because the agencies are prohibited by law from
sharing the information with each other. In 2002, the Congress enacted an important piece of
legislation called the Confidential Information Protection and Statistical Efficiency Act (CIPSEA).
As a member of the President's Council of Economic Advisers at the time, I helped lead the effort to
urge passage of CIPSEA.4
CIPSEA tackled two important issues. First, the act strengthens the safeguards that protect the
confidentiality of information provided by the public. The legislation applies clear and uniform
statutory restrictions on the use of confidential statistical information. In particular, information
about individuals or organizations acquired for exclusively statistical purposes and under a pledge of
confidentiality can be used only for statistical purposes. The act replaced a patchwork of safeguards
with consistent tough penalties for the unauthorized disclosure of confidential statistical
information.
Second, the act authorized the limited sharing of business data among the Bureau of the Census, the
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), and the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) for statistical
purposes. Allowing the agencies to share certain businesses data has improved the accuracy and
reliability of economic statistics. In particular, enhanced data sharing among the agencies has
improved the ability of the Census Bureau, the BEA, and the BLS to track rapidly changing trends
in the U.S. economy. In addition, it has helped to reduce the duplicative paperwork burdens imposed
on businesses.
Even with the 2002 legislation, however, more can be done to realize the full benefits of data
sharing. What I'm about to discuss is going to sound very arcane, but it is quite important for the
improvement of economic statistics. So please bear with me.
The Census Bureau conducts a large number of business surveys the results of which are key inputs

into the estimation of the nation's GDP. The Census Bureau selects businesses to survey from a list
of establishments called a "business register." The Census Bureau uses tax reports as a way of
identifying establishments to include in its business register. It's very important to note that the
Census Bureau is not rummaging through individual line items on company tax reports but rather is
using the reports only to identify companies for inclusion in its surveys.
Meanwhile, every month the BLS conducts a survey of establishments to find out about such things
as employment and earnings. The BLS also uses a business register to decide which establishments
to contact. However, the BLS register comes from reports filed by firms to state unemployment
insurance offices.
Here's the rub: In many instances establishments show up as being part of different industries in the
two registers. As a result, industry analyses that use survey data on employment or prices from the
BLS and survey data on shipments from the Census Bureau may well provide unreliable
characterizations of changes in real output and productivity for particular industries.
How important is this problem? Let me give you a few examples. A limited study compared the
Census Bureau's and BLS's business registers for 1994 and found that 30 percent of the same singleestablishment firms had been assigned different detailed industry codes. Staff work at the Federal
Reserve Board found that, according to the BLS in 1997, 1.1 million workers were employed in the
industry category known as Management of Companies, whereas the Census Bureau tallied
employment at 2.6 million for that year!5 In other industries, the differences in 1997, though not as
large, still are dramatic. In the Oil and Gas Extraction industry, the employment counts differ by
more than 30 percent. In the Computer and Electronic Product Manufacturing industry, the BLS and
Census counts differ by more than 12 percent, and so on.
The reason the two business registers have not been harmonized is that current law prevents the
BLS from having the same access as the Census Bureau to business identifiers on tax forms.
Removing this barrier to sharing such data for statistical purposes would have significant payoffs.
Sharing of business registers would help provide for more accurate measures of industry output,
compensation, and productivity trends. It would permit the statistical agencies to keep abreast of our
dynamic economy by producing statistical samples that are consistently adjusted for the entry and
exit of new businesses in a timely manner, and it would allow the agencies to correct errors quickly
and efficiently. This is especially important for fast-growing and innovative industries such as
information technology. Such improvements would improve our ability to perceive emerging trends
in the economy and more accurately forecast economic activity.
The BEA, the statistical agency responsible for estimating GDP and the other components of the
national income and product accounts, cannot currently access information from business taxes.
Allowing the BEA to obtain certain aggregate numbers from business tax returns for statistical
purposes would let the BEA significantly improve its estimates of the role of noncorporate
businesses in the economy. This is important, in part, because many entrepreneurial start-up firms,
which are a source of dynamism in the economy, begin their lives organized as sole proprietorships
or partnerships--that is, not as corporations. Permitting the BEA to use limited business tax
information for statistical purposes could appreciably improve the measurement of this vibrant part
of the economy and, once again, improve our ability to spot new trends and forecast economic
activity. Of course, in obtaining this information, the BEA would continue to be subject to the strict
confidentiality requirements and disclosure penalties embodied in CIPSEA. Protecting data privacy
is of utmost concern, and I would certainly not suggest changes that would compromise
confidentiality.
I now would like to turn to the second element I want to emphasize in improving the cost-benefit
trade off for economic statistics, namely, that the statistical agencies hasten their move toward a
more effective allocation of current resources. The usefulness of economic statistics--the benefit
side of the cost-benefit tradeoff--is the key. The economy is constantly changing. In the past, there
has been a tendency to persist in a full and expensive compilation of detailed data for heretofore
cutting-edge industries far beyond the time at which those industries stopped being prominent in the

economy. Consequently, statistical agencies need to be constantly assessing whether their data
reflect the changes--that is, you don't want to be spending all your resources on collecting
information about buggy whips in the age of the automobile.
An innovative economy needs to have innovative statistics. This means that the statistical agencies
need to be on the cutting edge in measuring the most dynamic parts of the economy. Typically, we
think of dynamism in terms of those segments of the economy--usually industries and sometimes
occupations--where output or employment are growing rapidly. But output and employment growth
are not the only criteria for dynamism. Rapid increases in what economists call "intangible capital"
are another characteristic of dynamic firms. This includes such things as expenditures on scientific
research and development (R&D) as well as the breakthrough improvements to businesses processes
that have made so many American companies successful. Dynamic firms are also characterized by
the proliferation of new products that incorporate large amounts of R&D as well as by rapid
improvements in the quality of products.
These brisk gains in intangible capital and the quality of products are important because they are an
important source of productivity growth. In other words, dynamic firms are the ones making the
largest contributions to the nation's overall productivity growth, which is, at bottom, the
fundamental source of rising standards of living. Accordingly, it is important that the economic
statistical system do a good job of measuring not only output and employment growth but also
intangibles, new cutting-edge products, and quality changes.
Given the speed and short histories of many of these changes and innovations, however, it is
particularly challenging to create statistics for new and dynamic parts of the economy that will be as
reliable as those in the more traditional sectors. We need to be mindful of the difficult burden that
the statistical agencies face in trying to maintain their very high standards for quality in such areas.
Re-allocation of resources is rarely easy since it means cutting back on something. It is not
appropriate for the Federal Reserve to get into the details of how the Congress or the statistical
agencies should spend the taxpayers' money. However, as consumers of the data produced by the
agencies, it is fitting for the Federal Reserve to indicate improvements to economic statistics that
would enhance their usefulness for the analyses and forecasts upon which we base our
decisionmaking. Indeed, in our role as data consumers, the agencies often seek our
recommendations.6 So, with that in mind, let me offer some specifics.
I'll start with the way in which the Census Bureau classifies the outputs of the economy into
particular categories for data collection purposes. The Census Bureau creates a list of so-called
"product codes" that identify the types of goods and services that companies produce and sell. They
group similar products into larger categories, but innovations in the economy have made those
groupings woefully out of date.
For the past several years, the Census Bureau has been developing more extensive product codes for
services, and that effort is to be applauded. It is precisely the right response to a dynamic economy
in which services have become much more important over time. In addition, improving product
codes for communications equipment and other high-tech components of manufacturing also should
be given high priority.
To illustrate, consider the product category "broadcast, studio, and related equipment." The Census
Bureau publishes sixteen subcategories of product data--items such as AM and FM radio
transmitters, for which shipments in 2004 were valued at $103 million; or cable-TV subscriber
equipment (decoders, switches, and so forth), with shipments worth $41 million; or studio
transmission links (the hardware to bring a live reporter's feed back to the studio), for which
shipments were worth $18 million.7
Now, contrast this with the product code called "data communications equipment." Unlike
"broadcast, studio, and related equipment," there are no break-downs into subcategories. Such
leading-edge products as large enterprise routers, gateways, bridges, and terminal servers are

combined into a single category. In 2004, shipments from manufacturers of data communications
equipment totaled more than $10-1/2 billion. The current system of product codes thus provides as
much information about a well-established technology with shipments worth $18 million as a
grouping of rapidly changing technology products with shipments worth more than $10-1/2 billion.
Similarly, the current system of product codes tell us as much about shipments of public pay
telephone as it does about shipments of cellular system equipment--an industry that is more than 230
times larger ($43 million versus nearly $10 billion). The task of updating product lists is resource
intensive and time consuming, but it is critical to gaining a more comprehensive understanding of
developments in the most vibrant sectors of our economy.
In addition to updating product codes to reflect change, another data challenge of our dynamic
economy is to adjust the prices of high-tech equipment for improvements in quality. By adjusting
for quality, I mean price statistics that recognize that a computer that costs $1,000 today is several
times more powerful than a computer that cost $1,000 ten years ago. Accordingly, after taking
account of the quality improvements, one can say that today's computers cost far less than
computers cost ten years ago because you get much more for your money today. Government price
data for computers do try to adjust for quality improvements, and the agencies must be applauded
for undertaking such adjustments to keep pace with innovations in the economy.
Many dynamic sectors, however, still await adjustments for quality improvements. As a result, the
statistical measurement system is not fully capturing these critical technology improvements, which
are a key source of productivity gains in the IT sector.8 Many types of logic chips that are now
common in everything from cell phones to DVD players have been improving rapidly. Their prices,
however, have not been adjusted for quality and such chips are simply lumped in with "other
semiconductors." Because semiconductor prices are often used as a gauge of technological progress-the faster the prices fall, the faster technology is improving--inadequate price measurement may be
leading to inadequate assessment of the pace of technological progress.
Another product for which improved price statistics could be particularly valuable is medical
diagnostic equipment--the forgotten part of the high-tech equipment sector. 9 Government price
statistics combine all medical diagnostic equipment (CT scanners, MRI scanners, and the like) into a
single bundle. The pace of technological advances for these types of equipment has been
breathtaking and reflects, in part, ongoing miniaturization afforded by the increased use of
embedded computer-like components. Gathering additional information about high-tech medical
equipment would not only round out our picture of high-tech equipment and components but also
shed light on some, though certainly not all, of the questions that have been posed about the
contribution of medical technology to health-care costs.10
Let me leave price measurement and conclude with another area where innovative statistics are
valuable for enhancing our understanding of the economy. As I mentioned previously, intangible
capital is an important characteristic of dynamic firms. Currently, however, the government
publishes no comprehensive statistics on intangible capital. In their pathbreaking work, Federal
Reserve economists Carol Corrado and Daniel Sichel, along with University of Maryland economist
Charles Hulten, identify three broad types of intangible capital: computerized information-primarily software; innovative property--knowledge acquired through scientific R&D and
nonscientific inventive and creative activities; and economic competencies--knowledge embedded
in firm-specific human and structural resources.11
Later this year the BEA plans to issue a satellite account that will treat scientific R&D as
investment. This is a significant and valuable step forward. Scientific R&D is measured by an
important survey sponsored by the National Science Foundation and conducted by the Census
Bureau. As Corrado, Sichel, and Hulten note, entrepreneurs and businesses also devote a broad
array of "nonscientific" resources, including the development of entertainment and artistic originals,
to develop new products and processes. Further work to investigate the feasibility of capturing such
information at reasonable cost could produce benefits of increasing our understanding of

productivity and growth trends.12
In applying a cost-benefit framework, I think that it would be valuable for the statistical agencies to
continue to seek opportunities to partner with the private sector in order to boost efficiencies.13
Perhaps the private sector could help collect data and even help to process and disseminate it. Retail
chains have extensive electronic data systems on the details of consumer purchases--a wealth of data
on consumer spending patterns that is now being analyzed for statistical purposes.14 And high-tech
firms have excellent information on inventories, sales, and prices, which could help to provide a
better snapshot of innovations that are driving the most dynamic parts of the economy. To some
extent, the statistical agencies, including the Federal Reserve, already use data--both public and
proprietary--that are collected by the private sector. The key issue is finding more opportunities for
private-public partnerships that are efficient, mutually beneficial, and do not compromise the high
quality of federal statistics that we have come to expect.
Summary and Conclusion
As I noted in my introduction, the U.S. enjoys among the best, if not the best, economic statistics in
the world. My remarks have been focused on building on that excellent foundation using a costbenefit framework. Innovations in economic statistics must keep pace with innovations in the
economy. Barriers to useful sharing of information across statistical agencies should be removed to
reduce costs and enhance benefits, but in no way should we compromise the high standards of
privacy protection embodied in CIPSEA and other statutes. And allocating resources to better
measure the most dynamic parts of the economy will help us get the most bang per buck in
economic statistics by enhancing our ability to spot trends and improve forecasts of the direction of
the economy.
Policymakers, businesses, and average Americans are able to make better decisions with economic
statistics that reflect the latest innovations in the economy. Achieving an innovation-sensitive
statistical system can be fostered by removing legislative barriers that impose costs on the system
with no (or little) benefit. Also, statistical agencies need to be nimble at recognizing and responding
promptly to emerging trends in the structure of the economy. One way of achieving nimbleness is
by getting feedback from users in government, in the academy and in business. The Federal
Economic Statistics Advisory Committee and the BEA advisory committee are good examples of
statistical agencies trying to increase the amount of feedback they receive. And organizations like
the National Association for Business Economics can communicate more widely the importance of
innovative statistics for a dynamic economy. Together we can try to fix the speedometer and clear
the fog from the windshield to improve both public and private decisionmaking.

Footnotes
1. Ben S. Bernanke (2004), "The Logic of Monetary Policy", speech delivered before the National
Economists Club, December 2, 2004. Return to text
2. Carol Corrado and Lawrence Slifman (1999), "Decomposition of Productivity and Unit Costs,"
American Economic Review, vol. 89 (May), pp. 328 -32. Return to text
3. Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan, in comments submitted to the Senate
Banking Committee in 2002, said: "I am reluctant to support increased spending. In the case of
certain economic statistics, however, the benefits are so large relative to cost that there should be
little question as to its desirability" (Alan Greenspan, 2002, "Response to Written Questions," in
Federal Reserve's Second Monetary Policy Report for 2002, hearing before the Senate Committee
on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, July 16, 107 Cong. (Washington:
Government Printing Office), p. 47. Return to text
4. Randall S. Kroszner (2002), "Prepared Statement", in H.R. 5215, Confidential Information

Protection and Statistical Efficiency Act of 2002, hearing before the Subcommittee on Government
Efficiency, Financial Management and Intergovernmental Relations of the Committee on
Government Reform, U.S. House of Representatives, Sept. 17, 107 Cong. (Washington: Government
Printing Office), pp. 36-39. Return to text
5. Remarks of Carol Corrado in "Monetary Policy and Research at the Federal Reserve," in chap. 3
of Caryn Kuebler and Christopher Mackie, rapporteurs (forthcoming), Improving Business Statistics
Through Interagency Data Sharing: Summary of a Workshop (Washington: National Academies
Press). Return to text
6. For example, Lawrence Slifman (2002), "Bureau of Economic Analysis' Strategic Plan for 20012005: Comments" (636 KB PDF), Survey of Current Business (May), pp. 9-10. Return to text
7. U.S. Census Bureau (2005), "Communication Equipment: 2004" (293 KB PDF), Current
Industrial Reports, MA334P(04)-1 (Washington: Census Bureau, August). Return to text
8. See Stephen D. Oliner and Daniel E. Sichel (2000). "The Resurgence of Growth in the Late
1990s: Is Information Technology the Story?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 14 (Fall), pp.
3-22; and Dale W. Jorgenson and Kevin J. Stiroh (2000), "Raising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic
Growth in the Information Age," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 125-211. Return to
text
9. The discussion of medical equipment is based on Jack E. Triplett and Barry P. Bosworth (2004),
Productivity in the U.S. Services Sector (Washington: Brookings Institution Press), pp. 304-20.
Return to text
10. Refer, for example, to Kevin M. Murphy and Robert H. Topel (2003), "The Economic Value of
Medical Research," in Kevin M. Murphy and Robert H. Topel, eds., Measuring the Gains from
Medical Research: An Economic Approach (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 41-73.
Return to text
11. Carol Corrado, Charles Hulten, and Daniel Sichel (2005), "Measuring Capital and Technology:
An Expanded Framework," in Carol Corrado, John Haltiwanger, and Daniel Sichel, eds., Measuring
Capital in the New Economy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press ), pp. 11-45. Return to text
12. Carol Corrado, Charles Hulten, and Daniel Sichel (2006), "Intangible Capital and Economic
Growth", NBER Working Paper Series 11948 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research, January). Return to text
13. Randall S. Kroszner (2002), "Bureau of Economic Analysis' Strategic Plan for 2001-2005:
Comments" (636 KB PDF), Survey of Current Business (May), pp. 10-11 Return to text
14. For example, Robert C. Feenstra and Matthew D. Shapiro, eds. (2003), Scanner Data and Price
Indexes, Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 64 (Chicago : University of Chicago Press); and Erik
Hurst and Mark Aguiar (2005), "Lifecycle Prices and Production", NBER Working Paper Series
11601 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, September). Return to text
Data Download
Return to top