View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Are Interest Rates Too High?
a speech given by
Mark H. Willes
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

before the
Bank Administration Institute
Twin Cities Chapter
September 21, 1978
Normandy Motor Inn
Minneapolis, Minnesota

America's affection for locust plagues, air pollution, governmental corruption, or
swine flu is substantial compared to what it is for higher interest rates. If there were a
Siberia for dissident economic policymakers, surely the proponents of higher interest rates
would be sent there.

In fact, Siberia might be considered far too pleasant a place for

Federal Reserve officials who have recently allowed interest rates to rise to such "high"
levels.
We are now hearing warnings that high interest rates threaten the well-being of
various sectors of the economy, especially housing, and various groups, such as consumers.
And much is made of the notion that the Federal Reserve is seriously risking another
recession by allowing rates to rise.

Interest rates, of course, cannot keep rising

indefinitely without causing serious problems.

But in our current economic climate,

interest rates are not high at all. In fact, they are low.
Why "High" Interest Rates Are Low
The interest rates that banks, corporations, and the federal government
announce do indeed look high. However, these rates (usually called nominal rates) are
merely raw numbers.

Nominal rates do not take inflation into account—and this is

extremely important to borrowers and lenders. Both know that a loan in today's dollars
will have to be repaid in next year's inflated dollars. If the interest rate on a loan exactly
matched the rate of inflation, neither borrower nor lender would gain in purchasing power.
The borrower would have essentially free use of the borrowed money, and the lender
would gain nothing for the use of his funds. To a large extent, nominal interest rates are
high simply to make up for the dollar's loss of purchasing power from one year to the next.
To calculate what happens to their purchasing power, borrowers and lenders need
to subtract the rate of inflation from the nominal interest rate. This inflation-adjusted
rate (usually called the real rate) has dwindled in recent years because inflation has
accelerated.




- 2-

What has happened to the rate for three-month Treasury bills is typical of all
interest rates.

As Chart 1 shows, the unadjusted, or nominal, rate of these bills has

diverged greatly from the inflation-adjusted, or real, rate over the last ten years. The
real rate has rarely climbed above zero since 1973.
When income taxes are considered, the rate is even lower. For example, for the
average taxpayer who invests in Treasury bills and earns 7 percent, inflation reduces the
purchasing power of his interest income by, say, 8 percent.

In addition, he must pay

income taxes of perhaps another 2 percent on that interest income. Consequently, the
real after-tax return on his investment is minus 3 percent—i.e., he is losing 3 percent a
year in purchasing power. It is an understatement to say that this is a low rate of return.
Money Not "Tight"
Since real interest rates are so low, it is no surprise that people are still willing
to borrow money.

In fact, they are leaping into debt at a rapid pace.

continue to seek mortgages in large numbers.

Home buyers

Other consumers are also borrowing

heavily; installment borrowing has been growing at an annual rate of about 20 percent
during the past several months.

Businesses, too, are eager to take the plunge.

Their

short- and intermediate-term borrowings over the last few months have also grown by an
annual rate of nearly 20 percent.
While borrowers have been taking advantage of the low real interest rates,
investors have been taking a beating. Why they continue to make their money available to
borrowers is a matter of conjecture. Perhaps they have no good alternatives. Immedi­
ately spending the money may make planning for the future more difficult. Holding cash
is very expensive since inflation, in effect, makes each dollar worth less without yielding
any interest. Maybe investors feel that a little interest is better than none. But whatever
their reasons, they are still buying bonds, still saving money, still offering large amounts
of funds to borrowers—hardly the characteristics of "tight money."




- 3-

High Interest Rates Do Not Cause Inflation
One reason so many people are worried about high nominal rates is that they fear
that such rates intensify inflation. True, nominal interest rates have paralleled inflation
rates for at least the last decade in the United States, as Chart 2 illustrates. But this
does not mean that high interest rates cause inflation—the predominant relationship in
fact is just the reverse.
A chain of economic events determines interest rates. For example, growth in
the federal deficit often leads to an expansion of the money supply. This expansion of the
deficit and of the money supply has two results. The first and most immediate result is
that people expect more inflation.

The second and more belated result is that in time

there really is more inflation. People's expectations of greater inflation quickly produce
higher interest levels as they seek to protect the purchasing power of their interest
income.

Through this chain of events, in other words, it's really inflation that causes

higher interest rates, and not the other way around.
Some people believe that the more money there is, the lower interest rates will
be. This has never been the case, at least not for long.

In the United States, interest

rates fell most rapidly not when the quantity of money was growing rapidly, but when it
was shrinking—during the Depression years from 1929 to 1933. Interest rates rose most
rapidly when the money supply was growing the fastest—in recent years.
All over the world, the story is the same.

In the United Kingdom and Italy,

nominal interest rates are even higher than they are here. In these countries the supply of
money has been increasing very quickly.

For comparison, in countries where interest

rates are low, like Switzerland, the money supply is relatively stable.
It is clear, on Chart 3, that Italy and the United Kingdom—the countries that
have had fast-growing money supplies—have had high inflation coupled with high interest
rates.

In contrast, Switzerland and West Germany—countries with more modestly

expanding money supplies—have had only moderate inflation coupled with low interest




-

rates.

k

The conclusion is almost inescapable:

-

a rapidly growing money supply leads to

more inflation and higher interest levels.
When our money becomes continually more plentiful, its price goes down. That
is, a dollar can be traded for fewer yen, fewer marks, and fewer goods and services. But
while the price of the dollar declines, the price of credit—the interest rate—escalates; it
costs more to borrow a dollar for the simple reason that people who lend money want to
get a fair return after inflation, and people who borrow money are willing to pay this rate.
Inflation: Economic Enemy Number 1
Today's high nominal interest rates, in short, are a result of high inflation, not a
cause of it.
The chain of events determining both inflation and interest rates starts with
large government deficits, rapid growth in money, and a host of laws, rules, and
regulations that lower the efficiency and competitiveness of the American economy. The
way to reduce inflation as well as nominal interest rates then is to cut the federal deficit,
rein in the money supply, and avoid or even reduce the special statutory and regulatory
actions that so aggrevate inflation.

This will require the determination of the Federal

Reserve System, the Administration, and Congress, and it won't be easy.
The problem is that the alternative to a more tightly controlled money supply
and a reduced federal deficit is continued inflation and even higher interest rates in the
long run. In that event, the public just might send us to Siberia—or someplace very much
hotter.




Chart 1

Three-Month Treasury Bill Rates
Semiannually, 1967-1978

%7o

%
10

10

Nominal Rate
8

8

6

6

'A /

4

4

2

2

Real Rate

o

0

•2

-2

-4

-4

Real After-Tax Rate

-6

-8




1968

1970

1972

-6

1974

1976

1978

-8

Chart 2

Inflation and Interest Rates

v
o
'




Annual Rate of Growth in the Consumer Price Index and
Rate of Interest on the Three-Month Treasury Bill
Semiannually, 1967-1978

%

14

12

Inflation
Rate
10

Nominal
Bill Rate

8

/V
6

4

2

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

0

Chart 3

Inflation Rates and Interest Rates
in Ten Major Countries
Annual Averages, 1973-April 1978*

%

20

1------------1------------1----------- 1------------ 1----------- 1----------- 1------------1------------ 1—

7]

/

18
/

16

/

3-Month Interest Rate

/

14
/

12

•Italy

/

• United
Kingdom

/^France

10

,

8

y/^Belgium
•Canada

^Netherlands * 'Japan
X ^United
'
States
•West
^Germany

6

•Switzerland

4
2

I_________ I_________ I_________ I

0

6

8

10

12

14

Inflation Rate
(Growth in Consumer Price Index)
‘ Switzerland = 1976-April 1978




16

18

20%