View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Far release on delivery
10:00 A.M.
EST
November 16, 1989

Testimony by

Manuel H. Johnson

Vice Chairman

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

International Finance and Monetary Policy Subcommittee

of the

Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs

United States Senate

N o V emb er 16, 1989

I appreciate the opportunity to appear before this Subcommittee
to comment on the Treasury Department's report on U.S.

international

economic and exchange rate policy.
As indicated in the report,
in the U.S.
years.

there has been considerable change

trade and current account balances over the past couple of

The current account deficit (excluding capital gains or losses

reported by direct investors), which peaked at $160 billion in 1987, had
declined to $106 billion at a seasonally adjusted annual rate by the
first half of this year.

As a percentage of GNP the decline has been

from 3-1/2 percent to 2.1 percent over this same period.
The decline in our merchandise trade deficit has been of about
the same magnitude.

The volume of U.S. exports has been increasing at an

average annual rate of about 20 percent for nearly three years, while the
rate of growth of the volume of our non-oil imports has slowed
substantially.
The counterpart to the reduction in U.S. external deficits is
the reduction in external surpluses in a number of countries abroad,
notably Japan, Taiwan,

and Korea; a massive movement into current account

deficit in the United Kingdom;
some other European countries.
(3.6 percent of GNP)

and some further increase in deficits of
Japan's surplus declined from $87 billion

in 1987 to $67 billion (2.3 percent of GNP) at a

seasonally adjusted annual rate in the first half of 1989.

Taiwan's

current account surplus declined from $18 billion in 1987 to a $10
billion rate in the first half of this year.

Korea's surplus likewise

declined from $14 billion in 1988 to about a $4 billion annual rate this
year.

And the U.K.

current account deficit moved from $ 5 billion in

-

2

-

1987 to a deficit rate of $32 billion (3.8 percent of GNP) in 198 9 's
first half.
On the other hand,

there was no reduction in Germany's surplus,

which actually rose from $46 billion in 1987 to a $59 billion annual rate
(5 percent of GNP) in the first half of this year, accounted for by an
increase in Germany's surpluses with its EC partners.
The dramatic change in U.S. external balances in the past two
years was the result of the earlier decline in the dollar against major
foreign currencies and against the Taiwan dollar and the Korean won,
increases in productivity and cost competitiveness by U.S. producers,
slowing of the rate of growth in U.S. domestic demand,

the

and a sharp

increase in the rate of growth of domestic demand abroad.

While the

adjustment process has continued,

there are signs suggesting it has begun

to slow.

the necessary actions taken by foreign

This reflects,

in part,

industrial countries to reduce the growth of domestic demand in order to
contain inflationary pressures,

and the continued relative attractiveness

of assets denominated in U.S. dollars which has bid up dollar exchange
rates.
Since our current account deficits are significantly lower than
they were in 1985-1987,

the sustained financing of such deficits is more

likely now than was the case earlier.

In thinking about options to

improve our external accounts further,

it must be remembered that a

significant portion of our current account deficit reflects a worldwide
saving-investment imbalance.

Accordingly,

any strategy designed to

reduce the trade deficit should focus on policies that address this
fundamental structural issue.
adversely affect U.S.

Removing the many distortions which

savings must be high on the policy agenda.

Recent

-

3

-

suggestions by Treasury Secretary Brady to increase U.S. private savings
are constructive.

Reducing government deficit spending must also be a

high priority in order to free up more overall domestic savings and help
lower relative real interest rates.

In present circumstances, with the U.S. economy pressing on
capacity constraints and monetary policy focussing on containing
inflationary pressures, there is little room for substantial further
reduction in U.S. external deficits absent a significant reduction of the
saving-investment imbalance.

In the meantime our efforts should

concentrate on maintaining and improving the environment for the free
flow of capital and on resisting protectionist non-solutions.
The recognition that balanced and mutually consistent economic
policies among major countries are essential for a healthy and stable
world economy underlies the dialogue not just with other G-7 countries
but also with the newly industrializing countries.

We are pleased to see

that considerable progress has been made in Taiwan and Korea over the
past year in terms of allowing market forces to be reflected in the
operation of their exchange markets.
Having said all this with regard to external adjustment, it is
important to emphasize that the G-7 process of international economic
policy coordination properly is not concerned primarily with exchange
rates or external adjustment per se.

Rather, the aim is to achieve and

to sustain the maximum long-run growth for the world economy consistent
with low inflation.

Current account imbalances and exchange rates become

matters of policy concern when they threaten to lead to financial market
and other disturbances which could thwart the attainment of the
fundamental goal of sustainable growth with low inflation.