View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:00 p.m. E.S.T.
February 28, 1989

Issues Facing Monetary Policy
in 1989

Address by
Manuel H. Johnson
Vice Chairman

Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System
before
Seminar Sponsored by
The National Association of
Business Economists

Washington, D.C.
February 28, 1989

Issues Facing Monetary Policy in 1989
It is a pleasure to be here this afternoon to
address the National Association of Business Economists.

I

always enjoy talking with this group about issues relating
to monetary policy.
One way of addressing this topic would be

to

discuss the specifics of the Fed's current concerns and
goals for policy in 1989.
addressed

these points

However, Chairman Greenspan has

at the Humphrey-Hawkins hearings

before Congress just last week and I see no need to repeat
all the points in his statement.
Instead,

I would prefer to concentrate on the

following question:

to what extent is the real performance

of the economy relevant for monetary policy?
Conceptual Foundations
Recently, many analysts have argued that monetary
policy should be set to prevent real economic growth from
increasing too rapidly in order to avoid higher inflation.
According to this view, appropriate growth rates near full
employment depend on the growth of capacity or resource
constraints.

Economic

growth

in excess

of

capacity

resource growth inevitably leads to inflation.
numerical

estimates

for

non-inflationary

rates

or

Sometimes
of

real

economic growth are made explicit; these days 2.5 percent
appears to be a consensus figure for such a growth rate.
But estimates have been both higher and lower.

-

2

-

Of course, this approach suggests that differing
economic

circumstances would

lead to

alternative

policy

prescriptions.

Should economic growth be sluggish and less

than

growth,

capacity

for

example,

then

the

logically

consistent policy prescription would be a policy of monetary
stimulation.
This view is certainly appealing.

If timely and

accurate measurements and projections of capacity growth or
aggregate supply could be made and if macro policies could
precisely control

aggregate demand,

this model would be

quite valid.

In this case, it would be possible for growth

in

and

capacity

matched

by

resource

monetary

utilization

expansion.

to

be

Aggregate

accurately

demand

could

always be set equal to aggregate supply; monetary policy
would

produce

inflation.

full

utilization

of

resources

without

Macroeconomic equilibrium would always prevail.
It is easy to understand why such a view is so

attractive

to

many

economists.

Theoretical

academic

economists can assume both accurate projections of capacity
and precise control of aggregate demand by the monetary
authority.
A variation of this approach has been appealing to
certain policymakers.
for

years

by

Macroeconomic policy was dominated

theories

that

emphasized

demand-side

manipulation of the economy whereby changes in aggregate
demand

readily

influenced

economic activity or growth.

or

determined

alterations

in

-

3

-

In part, the influence of these demand oriented
theories is a legacy of the 1930s and the explanations
developed

to

assess

those

years.

During

that

period

aggregate demand had collapsed leaving the economy with a
great deal of excess supply or unused resources.
of this idle capacity readily available,
unconcerned

about

explaining the

aggregate supply.

Rather,

bulk of the attention.

With all

economists were

growth of

capacity

or

aggregate demand received the

In these circumstances, movements in

aggregate demand were associated with similar movements in
employment,
aggregate

production,
demand,

and economic growth.

not

aggregate

supply

Changes in
or

capacity,

therefore, were seen as being closely related to economic
growth.

Accordingly,

some policymakers

readily

embraced

theories prescribing the manipulation of aggregate demand to
influence real economic variables.
When circumstances changed so that the economy
approached

full

aggregate

demand

employment,

unanticipated

were

interpreted

still

increases
as

temporarily

influencing real variables and economic activity.
circumstances,
economic

however,

activity

led

such demand-induced
to

inflation.

in

In these

increases

in

Accordingly,

a

trade-off between higher levels of real economic activity
and inflation was seen to exist.

Therefore, lower inflation

could only be attained from a real economic slowdown.

In

this sense, it is easy to understand the attachment of some

-

n

-

policymakers to views that effectively treat changes

in

aggregate demand and real economic activity as synonymous.
Unfortunately,

an

exaggerated

emphasis

on

the

practical application of these views has led to arguments
for the use of real economic variables as policy indicators
or even policy targets.
Theoretical Concerns
This approach directly conflicts with some longĀ­
standing and fundamental lessons of monetary thought.

Since

the dawn of economic reasoning a basic message has been that
monetary growth cannot permanently or predictably influence
real economic variables like wealth or output growth.1
far

back

century,

as

the

both

late

David

eighteenth

Hume

and

and

Henry

early

As

nineteenth

Thornton

clearly

established that monetary expansion could only temporarily
influence

economic

activity.

2

Correspondingly,

it

was

determined that only nominal prices would be permanently
influenced by monetary expansions or contractions.
another way

of

stating

the widely

This is

accepted homogeneity

postulate or the long-run neutrality of money which stands
as

a

fundamental

microeconomic

pillar

principles

of

monetary

of economics

thought.
tell

us

Indeed,
that

the

maximizing of utility and profit by individuals and firms
implies that demand curves and supply curves are homogeneous
of degree zero in nominal prices; that a movement in all
nominal prices has no effect on real supplies or demands. In
other words, microeconomic principles of economics tell us

5

-

-

that, theoretically, inflation has no necessary relation to
real economic activity.
These observations have a very important policy
implication.
near-term

If monetary expansion or restraint produces a

stimulation

or

contraction

of

real

economic

activity but no permanent, long-run influence, then clearly
there

must

exist

some

intermediate

period

between

the

near-term change and the long-term neutrality in which real
economic variables, if used to guide monetary policy, would
produce highly misleading signals.
Measurement Problems
But
concerns,

aside

a host

from

these

of practical

troubling

problems

theoretical

associated with

attempts to implement a real variable strategy are also
relevant.

For example, timely and accurate measurements of

aggregate resource usage or capacity constraints must be
readily obtainable.

While

current measurements

of

such

variables are likely the best available and are useful for
many purposes, they do not appear to be ideal for such a
strategy.
It has become increasingly evident that there are
serious problems associated with our current measures of
real

economic

activity

as

well

as

economic

potential.

Recent work by Professor Eisner describes many of these
problems related to the national income accounts that I will
not

repeat

difficulties,

here.

3

But

aside

from

actual

measurement

various real economic data are plagued by

-

6

-

sizeable revisions and seasonal adjustments.

And these data

often have significant lags associated with them, complicatĀ­
ing their usefulness for monetary policy.
Measures

of

potential

output

and

utilization have their own set of problems,

capacity

despite the

diligent efforts of talented analysts who compile

them.

According to one study, for example, when compared to other
groups of economic data classified as cyclical indicators,
capacity utilization series rank in the lowest group with
respect to "statistical adequacy." 4 None of the available
statistics measure economic capacity directly; surveys and
estimates of potential

capacity necessarily are used to

construct this series.
Furthermore, most capacity utilization numbers are
not comprehensive measures for the macroeconomy.
they

apply

only

to

a portion

of

including manufacturing and mining.

the

economy,

Instead,
usually

These sectors, however,

may have declined in overall economic importance in recent
decades.

Service

sectors,

agriculture,

government,

and

other non-manufacturing sectors are not normally included in
these measures.
become

Yet some of these excluded sectors

increasingly

important,

suggesting that

have

capacity

utilization estimates may pertain to a smaller portion of
the economy than was earlier the case.
Moreover,

capacity

numbers

often

attempt

to

measure the degree of existing capital utilization but not
that of other factors of production.

Utilization rates for

_

7

-

labor (and human capital), land, or natural resources, for
example, are often not included.

Yet these other factors of

production

may

are

important

and

sometimes

serve

as

substitutes for capital.
Finally, given our more integrated world economy,
domestic capacity usage rates have less and less relevance
as measures of overall resource constraints.

Foreign or

world capacity is obviously more pertinent today than in the
past.
Accordingly, a monetary policy strategy attempting
to equate real economic growth with the growth of potential
or full capacity is risky at best.
Corroboration with the Empirical Evidence
In addition

to

these

theoretical

concerns

and

measurement problems, there is another major reason why it
is dangerous to generalize that changes in real economic
growth lead to changes in prices. Sustained shifts in real
economic growth can only occur because of non-monetary,
supply-related adjustments, not monetary induced changes in
aggregate

demand.

technology,

labor

For

example,

or

changes

capital

in

investment,

productivity,

or

entrepreneurial and innovative activity can all promote more
or less real economic potential.

Similarly, broad changes

in trade barriers or other tax distortions can also work to
foster permanent shifts in real growth rates since these
actions alter factor productivity by allowing more or less
specialization.

8

-

On the one hand,

-

long-run increases in aggregate

supply are not inflationary.

However,

because changes in

real output can be associated with either supply factors or
demand

pressures,

there

is

no

consistent

between economic growth and inflation.
and

rapid

economic

growth

have

relationship

Periods of sustained

been

associated

with

deflation, inflation, and stable prices.
In the U.S., for example, in the period from 1865
to 1879 there were rapid increases in output and falling
prices.

Similarly,

the

decade

of

rapid growth and stable prices.^

inflation

actually

1920s

experienced

To be specific, during the

9-year period from 1921 to 1930,
while

the

real GNP growth was 4.1%

fell

1-1%!

Furthermore,

correlations between real GNP growth and inflation in the
U.S.

show

no

consistent

relationship

between

these

variables.^
Many countries with records of sustained strong
real

GNP

inflation.

growth

have

low

rather

than

The

record

of

Asia's

newly

high

rates

of

industrialized

countries certainly supports this contention.
On the other hand,

sustained periods of slow or

sluggish economic growth are often not associated with low
rates

of

inflation.

Adverse

supply-side

shocks

to

the

macroeconomy can retard real growth while contributing to
price pressures.

The experience of the U.S. economy in the

1970s serves as an all-too-familiar example.

9

-

-

And domestic policy mistakes, such as increases in
protectionism,
work to
higher,

tax rates,

stifle economic
not lower,

or regulatory burdens,
growth but will

prices.

Similarly,

can all

likely promote

other distortions

imposed on the price system such as minimum wage laws, usury
ceilings, rent controls, or other forms of price controls
work

to

adversely

affect

resource

allocation

thereby

retarding economic growth while at the same time setting the
stage for higher prices.
Moreover, there can be little doubt that countries
enduring long periods of inflation normally do not also
experience rapid economic growth.

The experience of many

Latin American economies is an obvious example.
Implications for Monetary Policy
In sum,

there are problems with the view that

monetary policy should target real GNP growth.

If real GNP

growth advances because of increases in aggregate supply,
Federal Reserve attempts to "prevent overheating" would lead
to suboptimal employment of resources and policy error.
Similarly,

if

adverse

supply

shocks

or macro-

economic policy errors work to stifle macroeconomic growth,
then monetary

stimulation

is not

an

appropriate

policy

response by the Federal Reserve.
In fact,

monitoring or targeting real economic

variables can mislead monetary policymakers and sometimes
work to promote a destabilizing variety of "fine-tuning."
As a consequence,

such an approach can prevent monetary

-

policy

from

achieving

10

the

-

one

goal

it

is

capable

of

achieving: namely, the provision of price stability.
For this reason,

it is critical

that monetary

policy focus on nominal and not real economic and financial
variables as policy indicators or targets.

For this reason

and the fact that monetary aggregates have recently become
less helpful, I have advocated the use of nominal financial
auction market prices as appropriate indicators for policy.
Use of such indicators (which I have spelled out elsewhere)
makes theoretical sense and is certainly consistent with
monetary thought.

Employing auction market prices as policy

indicators also makes practical sense in that many of the
above-cited measurement and data problems do not apply to
these variables.

Moreover,

their use is consistent with

what we know actually does work.
that

this

approach

will

receive

economists such as yourselves.
Thank you.

As a consequence, I hope
fair

consideration

by

Footnotes
See, for example, David Hume, "of Money," and "of
Interest" in David Hume, Writings on Economics edited
by Eugene Rotwein, Books for Libraries Press, 1955; pp.
33, 37, 48; Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature
and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, edited by Edwin
Cannon, University of Chicago Press, 1976, Volume I,
Book IV, pp. 450-473.
David Hume, op. cit, pp. 38, 40; Henry Thornton, An
Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit
of Great Britain (1802) edited with an Introduction by
F.A. Hayek, Augustus M. Kelley, Fairfield, 1978,
p. 238.
Robert Eisner, "Extended Accounts for National Income
and Product," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXVI
(December 1988) pp. 1611-1684.
Victor Zarnowitz, "On Functions, Quality, and
Timeliness of Economic Information," Reprint No. 250,
National Bureau of Economic Research, February 1982.
According to Zarnowitz, statistical adequacy consists
of "a number of attributes such as the quality of the
reporting system, coverage of process and time unit,
availability of estimates of sampling and reporting
errors, frequency of revisions, length of series, and
comparability over time."
See, for example, Milton Friedman, "The Supply of Money
and Changes in Prices and Output," in The Optimum
Quantity of Money and other Essays, by Milton Friedman,
Aldine, Chicago, 1969, pp. 183-184.
See for example, Thomas F. Cooley and Charles I.
Plosser, "Does A Strong Economy Mean Higher
Inflation?", Unpublished manuscript, p. 1;
Eugene F. Fama, "Inflation, Output, and Money", Journal
of Business, vol. 55, no. 2, April 1982;
Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, Monetary Trends
in the United States and the United Kingdom, University
of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1982, chapter 9, esp.
pp. 403-404; Milton Friedman, Inflation and
Unemployment, The 1976 Alfred Nobel Memorial Lecture,
published by the Institute of Economic Affairs, London,
1977, esp. pp. 18-23.